Tax Strategy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Tax Strategy METHODOLOGY UPDATES CSA 2021 Tax Strategy OVERVIEW: As part of the methodology development process for the 2021 CSA, we have created new questions and updated existing ones to ensure we are capturing the most material sustainability topics. Please find below the new and updated questions for this criterion in 2021. The question texts and methodology presented may be subject to change at any time before the end of March 2021. In addition, questions may look different in the Online Assessment Tool in terms of question structure and layout. Please note that all questions may not be applicable to your industry so please carefully consult the Industries Impacted section. Introduction Criterion Rationale Tax competition between tax territories (countries or regions within countries) has left room for companies to optimize their tax spending. While tax optimization has a positive impact on profitability and hence company value, a too-aggressive tax strategy might not be sustainable in the mid- to long-term and adds some risk to long-term profits. First, there is a reputational risk because of increased public and regulatory scrutiny which could result in lower brand value. Second, the relationship with the host country may be negatively impacted. This could result in approval delays or rejection of expansion projects or, in the worst cases, companies risk losing their license to operate. Third, earnings might be impacted if the tax authorities decide to change tax regulation which leads to direct financial risks. Finally, economic development risk arises if governments receive inadequate tax receipts for funding local infrastructure or education. Reason for update There is an increasing demand for tax transparency from investors and other stakeholders, and regulatory bodies are considering further requirements for detailed public reporting on a country- by-country level. With the updates to our questions, we aim to obtain a better understanding of a future expectations in this area. Summary of changes 1. Updated question: Tax Strategy and Governance 2. Updated question: Tax Reporting 1. Updated Question1 Question: Tax Strategy and Governance INDUSTRIES IMPACTED: ALU Aluminum ITC Electronic Equipment, Instruments & ATX Auto Components Components AUT Automobiles LEG Leisure Equipment & Products and BNK Banks Consumer Electronics BTC Biotechnology LIF Life Sciences Tools & Services BVG Beverages MNX Metals & Mining CHM Chemicals MTC Health Care Equipment & Supplies CMT Communications Equipment OGR Oil & Gas Refining & Marketing CNO Casinos & Gaming OGX Oil & Gas Upstream & Integrated COL Coal & Consumable Fuels OIE Energy Equipment & Services COM Construction Materials PUB Media, Movies & Entertainment COS Personal Products REX Restaurants & Leisure Facilities CSV Diversified Consumer Services RTS Retailing CTR Containers & Packaging SEM Semiconductors & Semiconductor DHP Household Durables Equipment DRG Pharmaceuticals SOF Software FBN Diversified Financial Services and STL Steel Capital Markets TEX Textiles, Apparel & Luxury Goods FDR Food & Staples Retailing THQ Computers & Peripherals and Office FOA Food Products Electronics FRP Paper & Forest Products TLS Telecommunication Services HOU Household Products TOB Tobacco IMS Interactive Media, Services & Home TRT Hotels, Resorts & Cruise Lines Entertainment TSV IT services INS Insurance QUESTION RATIONALE Tax avoidance strategies are usually set up in a legally sound way. Therefore, general statements operation are not enough. Every company should be able to give a coherent justification of their approach to key tax issues such as the use of tax minimization techniques in line with their approach to other CSR issues. The adoption of a formal tax policy serves to guide company practices and provide investors, 1 Updates are included within a red frame which practices, and disclosures can be compared. An effective policy should be overseen by the board of directors, created in conjunction with relevant senior management, and regularly reviewed to ensure emerging risks are addressed. This question seeks to determine if there is a group-wide tax policy or strategy available in the public domain that addresses sensitive or high-risk tax issues in a clear and sustainable way. KEY DEFINITIONS Tax avoidance: Tax avoidance is an abuse of the tax system, a deliberate attempt to get out of an obligation to pay tax by entering into a set of artificial financial arrangements which have little or no commercial purpose other than the reduction of a tax bill. Tax avoidance is unethical in that it seeks to undermine tax law and public policy and it is frequently found to be unlawful. Tax avoidance can be within the letter, but not the spirit, of the law. (Source: TaxWatch) The spirit of the tax laws refers the intention of the policy maker who wrote the respective law. The letter of the law refers to the literal interpretation of the law only. A low tax jurisdiction, for the purpose of this question, is any jurisdiction with significantly lower tax rates than other jurisdictions in which the company operates. Tax structures without commercial substance are artificial structures that are not based on the economic activities and the value generation of a company, but only serve to reduce the tax bill. iple: This valuation principle is commonly applied to commercial and financial transactions between related companies. It says that transactions should be valued as if they had been carried out between unrelated parties, each acting in his own best interest. Tax havens are (offshore) countries or jurisdictions offering little or no tax liability. Tax havens may only share limited or no financial information with foreign tax authorities and may not require businesses to operate out their country to receive tax benefits. The board of directors: For the purpose of this question, this can refer to the board of directors, its sub-committees, or a single named director. The tax policy must be approved or signed by the respective board representative(s), and /or clearly state their involvement in the creation of the tax policy. General statements regarding the responsibilities of the board of directors or regular reporting to the board are not enough. DATA REQUIREMENTS While many companies have group-wide tax accounting policies with clearly defined roles and responsibilities within the organization in place, we specifically look for taxation policies that address issues such as responsible taxation, transparency, transfer pricing, etc., going beyond minimum legal tax disclosure requirements. REFERENCES GRI: 207-1, 207-2 are relevant for this question. QUESTION LAYOUT Requirement: The question requires publicly available information. Does your company have a publicly available and group-wide tax policy, strategy or principles in place which indicate your approach towards taxation? o Yes, we have a publicly available, group-wide tax policy covering the following elements. Please provide the relevant web link: Reference box (max. 3 allowed) A commitment to compliance with the letter as well as the spirit of the tax laws and regulations in the countries in which the company operates A commitment not to transfer value created to low tax jurisdictions A commitment not to use tax structures without commercial substance A commitment to undertake transfer prici A commitment not to use secrecy jurisdictions or so-called "tax havens avoidance An approval process of the tax policy by the board of directors o No, we do not have a publicly available and group-wide tax policy. o Not applicable. Please provide explanations in the comment box below. o Not known. 2. Updated Question2 Question: Tax Reporting INDUSTRIES IMPACTED: ALU Aluminum ITC Electronic Equipment, Instruments & ATX Auto Components Components AUT Automobiles LEG Leisure Equipment & Products and BNK Banks Consumer Electronics BTC Biotechnology LIF Life Sciences Tools & Services BVG Beverages MNX Metals & Mining CHM Chemicals MTC Health Care Equipment & Supplies CMT Communications Equipment OGR Oil & Gas Refining & Marketing CNO Casinos & Gaming OGX Oil & Gas Upstream & Integrated COL Coal & Consumable Fuels OIE Energy Equipment & Services COM Construction Materials PUB Media, Movies & Entertainment COS Personal Products REX Restaurants & Leisure Facilities CSV Diversified Consumer Services RTS Retailing CTR Containers & Packaging SEM Semiconductors & Semiconductor DHP Household Durables Equipment DRG Pharmaceuticals SOF Software FBN Diversified Financial Services and STL Steel Capital Markets TEX Textiles, Apparel & Luxury Goods FDR Food & Staples Retailing THQ Computers & Peripherals and Office FOA Food Products Electronics FRP Paper & Forest Products TLS Telecommunication Services HOU Household Products TOB Tobacco IMS Interactive Media, Services & Home TRT Hotels, Resorts & Cruise Lines Entertainment TSV IT services INS Insurance QUESTION RATIONALE Leading companies have realized that public reporting on their revenues, operating profits and tax on a country-by-country basis helps to build trust in their corporation and complements the reporting on their broader economic contribution. In combination with key information about the names and tax residence of all constituent entities, the main activities by tax jurisdiction as well as the average number of employees, these numbers help investors better understand a 2 Updates are included within a red frame rates in a given jurisdiction, pro-active companies can steer and facilitate the discussion about
Recommended publications
  • Financial Transaction Tax and Economic Crisis: Is It Time for a Tax on International Transactions?
    RDTI Atual 05 IBDT | INSTITUTO BRASILEIRO DE DIREITO TRIBUTÁRIO Revista Direito Tributário Internacional Atual e-ISSN 2595-7155 FINANCIAL TRANSACTION TAX AND ECONOMIC CRISIS: IS IT TIME FOR A TAX ON INTERNATIONAL TRANSACTIONS? IMPOSTO SOBRE TRANSAÇÕES FINANCEIRAS E CRISE ECONÔMICA: É CHEGADA A HORA DE UM IMPOSTO SOBRE TRANSAÇÕES INTERNACIONAIS? Pedro Adamy Professor da Escola de Direito da Pontifícia Universidade Católica do Rio Grande do Sul (PUCRS). Doutorando em Direito na Universidade de Heidelberg, Alemanha. Mestre em Direito pela Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Sul (UFRGS). E-mail: [email protected] Recebido em: 15-04-2019 Aprovado em: 04-06-2019 ABSTRACT This paper aims at the legal problems that arise concerning the introduction of a financial transaction tax. The article analyzes the impact, characteristics and challenges of a tax on international financial transactions and its relationship to economic crises. KEYWORDS: FINANCIAL TRANSACTION TAX, ECONOMIC CRISIS, INTERNATIONAL TAXATION, REGULATORY MEASURES RESUMO Este artigo visa os problemas jurídicos que surgem com a introdução de um imposto sobre transações financeiras. O artigo analisa o impacto, as características e os desafios de um imposto sobre transações financeiras internacionais e sua relação com crises econômicas. PALAVRAS-CHAVE: IMPOSTO SOBRE TRANSAÇÕES FINANCEIRAS, CRISES ECONÔMICAS, TRIBUTAÇÃO INTERNACIONAL, MEDIDAS ADMINISTRATIVAS 157 Revista Direito Tributário Internacional Atual nº 05 p.157-171 - 2019 RDTI Atual 05 IBDT | INSTITUTO BRASILEIRO DE DIREITO TRIBUTÁRIO Revista Direito Tributário Internacional Atual e-ISSN 2595-7155 1. INTRODUCTORY REMARKS “Crisis is not the best advisor on formulating rules for normal times.”1 In the event of a financial crisis two phenomena will certainly occur: first, money will flow from unstable and poorer countries into more stable and richer ones; second, the discussion about a financial transaction tax (henceforth FTT) will be revived and gain attention among the press, economists, tax law professionals and oppositional politicians2.
    [Show full text]
  • Tax Competition and Tax Coordination in the European Union: a Survey
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Keuschnigg, Christian; Loretz, Simon; Winner, Hannes Working Paper Tax competition and tax coordination in the European Union: A survey Working Papers in Economics and Finance, No. 2014-04 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Social Sciences and Economics, University of Salzburg Suggested Citation: Keuschnigg, Christian; Loretz, Simon; Winner, Hannes (2014) : Tax competition and tax coordination in the European Union: A survey, Working Papers in Economics and Finance, No. 2014-04, University of Salzburg, Department of Social Sciences and Economics, Salzburg This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/122170 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu TAX COMPETITION AND TAX COORDINATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION: A SURVEY CHRISTIAN KEUSCHNIGG, SIMON LORETZ AND HANNES WINNER WORKING PAPER NO.
    [Show full text]
  • The Financial Transactions Tax Versus (?) the Financial Activities Tax
    The Financial Transactions Tax Versus (?) the Financial Activities Tax Daniel Shaviro NYU Law School Stanford Law School, February 21, 2012 1 Intervening in a horse race Prepared for conference (Amsterdam 12/9/11) discussing recent European Commission (EC) proposal to enact an FTT (financial transactions tax). Natural contrast to Int’l Monetary Fund (IMF) staff proposal to enact any of 3 variants of an FAT (financial activities tax). Key difference: gross tax on certain sales, vs. net tax on a broader range of activities. Discussion is organized around (but not chained to) stated rationales for taxing financial firms. Main conclusions: (1) I favor a hybridized version of the 3 FATs discussed by the IMF (and generally reject stated rationales for the FTT). (2) A possible FTT rationale (not identified by the EC) might conceivably support its enactment, whether or not an FAT is enacted. 2 Why has the European Commission proposed an FTT? The main stated grounds are (1) to ensure a fair contribution by the financial sector, (2) to respond to under-taxation of the sector, and (3) it “might be an appropriate tool to reduce excessive risk-taking.” Other possible grounds: harmonize FTT-like taxes that EU countries may be doing anyway; political feasibility & revenue? Grounds for rejecting FAT unclear. FTT’s greater revenue potential & direct impact on risks from excessive trading outweigh higher risks of relocation of transactions,” negative effects on GDP & employment? Possible unstated political feasibility rationale? (From FTT’s nominally lower rate, popular identification as the “Robin Hood tax.”) 3 FTT: History and Rationale > 200 years old (U.K.
    [Show full text]
  • The Relationship Between MNE Tax Haven Use and FDI Into Developing Economies Characterized by Capital Flight
    1 The relationship between MNE tax haven use and FDI into developing economies characterized by capital flight By Ali Ahmed, Chris Jones and Yama Temouri* The use of tax havens by multinationals is a pervasive activity in international business. However, we know little about the complementary relationship between tax haven use and foreign direct investment (FDI) in the developing world. Drawing on internalization theory, we develop a conceptual framework that explores this relationship and allows us to contribute to the literature on the determinants of tax haven use by developed-country multinationals. Using a large, firm-level data set, we test the model and find a strong positive association between tax haven use and FDI into countries characterized by low economic development and extreme levels of capital flight. This paper contributes to the literature by adding an important dimension to our understanding of the motives for which MNEs invest in tax havens and has important policy implications at both the domestic and the international level. Keywords: capital flight, economic development, institutions, tax havens, wealth extraction 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) from the developed world own different types of subsidiaries in increasingly complex networks across the globe. Some of the foreign host locations are characterized by light-touch regulation and secrecy, as well as low tax rates on financial capital. These so-called tax havens have received widespread media attention in recent years. In this paper, we explore the relationship between tax haven use and foreign direct investment (FDI) in developing countries, which are often characterized by weak institutions, market imperfections and a propensity for significant capital flight.
    [Show full text]
  • Where's the Harm in Tax Competition?
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by University of Limerick Institutional Repository Final Author’s Draft, submitted to Critical Perspectives on Accounting, published in 2005 Where’s the harm in tax competition? Lessons from US multinationals in Ireland Sheila Killian Kemmy Business School, University of Limerick, Ireland Abstract The term “harmful tax competition” has become endemic. It is taken as a tautology that competition among nations for the favors of multinational companies, using their tax systems as bait, is harmful. This is a view held even by those who believe competition to be an inherently good thing in most other areas of business. However, the nature of the harm is rarely analyzed, nor are the parties most harmed identified. This paper attempts to redress the balance. Using the case of technology-based US multinationals located in Ireland, it analyses the benefits and hazards to major stakeholders of tax rules that encourage multinationals to locate part of their operation offshore. I argue that tax competition, even that not considered harmful by the OECD, can damage not only the home country of the emigrating multinational, but also the host country gaining the investment, local communities and the environment. © 2005 Published by Elsevier Ltd. Keywords: Tax competition; Multinational; Double tax treaty; Stakeholders; Nation state; OECD; Ireland; Tax haven; Transfer pricing; Power 1. Introduction Shackelford and Shevlin (2001) , in a comprehensive review of empirical tax research in accounting, reduced the literature so far to three questions: Do taxes matter? If not, why not? If so, how much? The first question is critical.
    [Show full text]
  • The Theory of International Tax Competition and Coordination
    CHAPTER 5 The Theory of International Tax Competition and Coordination Michael Keen* and Kai A. Konrad†,‡ *International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Affairs Department,Washington DC 20431, USA †Max Planck Institute for Tax Law and Public Finance, Marstallplatz 1, 80539 Munich, Germany ‡Social Science Research Center Berlin, Germany Contents 1. Introduction 258 2. Uncoordinated Actions 262 2.1. Workhorse Models 263 2.1.1. The Zodrow, Mieszkowski, and Wilson (ZMW) Model 263 2.1.2. The Kanbur-Keen (KK) Model 275 2.2. Sequential Decision Making 278 2.3. Pure Profits and International Portfolio Diversification 282 2.4. Tax Competition with Multiple Instruments 284 2.5. Vertical Externalities and the Strategic Role of Internal Governance Structure 285 3. Coordination 288 3.1. Asymmetries and the Limits of Harmonization 289 3.2. Minimum Tax Rates 289 3.3. Coordination Among a Subset of Countries 293 3.4. Coordination Across a Subset of Instruments 295 3.5. Dynamic Aspects 296 3.5.1. Infinitely Repeated Interaction 296 3.5.2. Endogenous Savings and Time Consistent Taxation 298 3.5.3. Stock Effects and Agglomeration 302 4. Broadening the Perspective 303 4.1. Bidding for Firms 303 4.2. Preferential Regimes 305 4.3. Information Exchange and Implementation of the Residence Principle 308 4.4. Tax Havens 311 4.4.1. Which Countries Become Tax Havens? 311 4.4.2. Are Tax Havens Good or Bad? 312 4.4.3. Closing Down Tax Havens 314 4.5. Formula Apportionment 315 4.6. Political Economy and Agency Issues 318 4.6.1. Tax Competition and Leviathan 318 4.6.2.
    [Show full text]
  • Free: 115.52 KB
    ASIAN DEVELOPMENT BANK A XECUTIVE D E INSTITUTE Kasumigaseki Bldg. 8F 3-2-5 Kasumigaseki B SUMMARY Chiyoda-ku, Tokyo 100-6008 Japan I Tel: 81 3 3593 5500, Fax: 81 3 3593 5571 SERIES No. S52/01 Email: [email protected] http://www.adbi.org 2001 Tax Conference 5-11 September 2001, Tokyo Executive Summary of Proceedings CONTENTS 2 The governance of tax systems requires governments to Page continue their effort to stamp out corruption and insure Key Messages 1 that the tax systems help the majority and not hurt them in Introduction 3 such endeavors. This is another example of the need for Opening Remarks 3 international cooperation. Taxation in an Interdependent World 4 Japan and International Tax Cooperation 5 3 Tax havens are a genuine concern to all as they erode the Tax Competition Not Necessarily Harmful 5 revenue base. It is however important to understand how E-Commerce and Tax 6 harmful it is and to whom? Who really benefits from tax The Source of Income, Tax Arbitrage and havens? Perhaps this is an area, which deserves detailed Double Tax Agreements 7 research. Transfer Pricing–Advance Pricing Agreements 8 Rationale and Scope for Fiscal Restructuring in At the specific country level, fiscal restructuring and Asia 9 4 Environmental Tax 10 financial sector restructuring are areas where attention Tax Administration and Compliance 11 of national governments as well as donors should go for Electronic Filing of Tax Returns 13 a long-term solution to the ensuing problem from truly Country Experiences with Value Added Tax tax havens.
    [Show full text]
  • Environmental Taxation and International Eco-Industries Joan Canton
    Environmental Taxation and International Eco-Industries Joan Canton NOTA DI LAVORO 26.2007 FEBRUARY 2007 ETA – Economic Theory and Applications Joan Canton, GREQAM, Université de la Méditerranée This paper can be downloaded without charge at: The Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Note di Lavoro Series Index: http://www.feem.it/Feem/Pub/Publications/WPapers/default.htm Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://ssrn.com/abstract=970278 The opinions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the position of Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Corso Magenta, 63, 20123 Milano (I), web site: www.feem.it, e-mail: [email protected] Environmental Taxation and International Eco-Industries Summary Environmental policies are discussed when two countries differ in their ability to abate pollution. Northern eco-industries (the industry supplying abatement activities) are more efficient than Southern ones. Segmented environmental markets and a Northern monopoly yield identical second-best taxes in both countries. When markets are global, Southern countries underestimate the market power of eco-industries. Introducing competition creates positive (resp. negative) rent-shifting distortions in South (resp. North). Cooperation could reduce Northern pollution but has ambiguous consequences in South. Keywords: Eco-Industry, Strategic Environmental Policy, Asymmetric Oligopolies JEL Classification: D62, H23, F12 I would like to thank Hubert Stahn, Antoine Soubeyran and Tanguy Van Ypersele for their very helpful comments. I am also grateful to participants of Journées Doctorales de l'ADRES 2006 and of the Third World Congress of environmental and resource economics, in Kyoto. Address for correspondence: Joan Canton GREQAM, Université de la Méditerranée Chateau Lafarge route des Milles 13290 Les Milles France Phone: +33 04 42 93 59 80 Fax: +33 04 42 93 09 68 E-mail: [email protected] 1 Introduction One cannot deny huge di®erences in the stringency of environmental policies around the world.
    [Show full text]
  • The State Administration of International Tax Avoidance
    THE STATE ADMINISTRATION OF INTERNATIONAL TAX AVOIDANCE Omri Marian* Forthcoming, Harvard Business Law Review, 2016 Abstract This Article documents a process in which a national tax administration in one jurisdiction, is consciously and systematically assisting taxpayers to avoid taxes in other jurisdictions. The aiding tax administration collects a small amount tax from the aided taxpayers. Such tax is functionally structured as a fee paid for government-provided tax avoidance services. Such behavior can be easily copied (and probably is copied) by other tax administrations. The implications are profound. On the normative front, the findings should fundamentally change our understanding of the concept of international tax competition. Tax competition is generally understood to be the adoption of low tax rates in order to attract investments into the jurisdiction. Instead, this Article identifies an intentional “beggar thy neighbor” behavior, aimed at attracting revenue generated by successful investments in other jurisdictions, without attracting actual investments. The result is a distorted competitive environment, in which revenue is denied from jurisdictions the infrastructure and workforce of which support economically productive activity. On the practical front, the findings suggest that internationally coordinated efforts to combat tax avoidance are misaimed. Current efforts are largely aimed at curtailing aggressive taxpayer behavior. Instead, the Article proposes that the focus of such efforts should be curtailing certain rogue practices adopted by national tax administrations. To explain these arguments, the Article uses an original dataset. In November of 2014, hundreds of advance tax agreement (ATAs) issued by Luxembourg’s Administration des Contributions Directes (Luxembourg’s Inland Revenue, or LACD) to multinational corporate taxpayers (MNCs) were made public.
    [Show full text]
  • Tax, Trade and Harmful Tax Competition: Reflections on the FSC Controversy Reuven S
    University of Michigan Law School University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository Articles Faculty Scholarship 2000 Tax, Trade and Harmful Tax Competition: Reflections on the FSC Controversy Reuven S. Avi-Yonah University of Michigan Law School, [email protected] Available at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/articles/1072 Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/articles Part of the Business Organizations Law Commons, International Law Commons, Taxation- Transnational Commons, and the Transnational Law Commons Recommended Citation Avi-Yonah, Reuven S. "Tax, Trade and Harmful Tax Competition: Reflections on the FSC Controversy (Foreign Sales Corporations)." Tax Notes Int'l 21, no. 25 (2000): 2841-5. This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Articles by an authorized administrator of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Special Reports tion procedures in the case of any "subsidy ... which operates directly or indirectly to increase Tax, Trade, and Harmful exports of any product from, or to reduce imports of any product into, Tax Competition: [a contracting party's] territory."5 In addition, the article expressly Reflections on the FSC prohibits the use of any subsidy "on the export of any product ... Controversy which subsidy results in the sale of such product for export at a price by Reuven S. Avi-Yonah lower than the comparable price charged for the like product to Reuven S. Avi-Yonah is a professor of law at the buyers in the domestic market."6 A Michigan Law School.
    [Show full text]
  • Luxleaks: Tax Rulings and State Aid Law
    CLIENT MEMORANDUM Luxleaks: Tax Rulings and State Aid Law November 14, 2014 AUTHORS Jacques-Philippe Gunther | David Tayar | Adrien Giraud On November 5, 2014, the International Consortium of Investigative Journalists (ICIJ) disclosed online multiple favorable tax rulings that had been granted by the Luxembourg tax administration to approximately 340 multinational companies. The so-called “Luxleaks” case was widely covered in the press. It raises complex political and legal issues in the field of tax harmonization and State aid law. The issue of tax rulings is well known by the European Commission (the “Commission”), which is currently conducting in- depth investigations as to the legality, under State aid rules, of favorable tax rulings granted by the Luxembourg tax administration to Amazon and Fiat. Similar investigations were also opened regarding rulings granted by Ireland (to Apple) and the Netherlands (to Starbucks). The new European Commissioner for Competition, Margrethe Vestager, indicated on November 6 that the General Directory for Competition already contacted Luxembourg, as well as other countries, on this issue and added: “we will be vigilant to enforce state aid control in fair and justified manner.” Thus, it cannot be ruled out that the Commission may open other investigations on various tax rulings. Actually, the Competition Commissioner recently declared that Directorate-General (DG) for Competition may well open up new cases after the four ongoing investigations are concluded, possibly next spring. 1 Luxleaks: Tax Rulings and State Aid Law Continued THE QUALIFICATION AS STATE AID OF TAX RULINGS BY THE EUROPEAN COMMISSION The Commission is inclined to consider favorable tax rulings as State aid.
    [Show full text]
  • Corporate Tax Competition and Profit Shifting to Tax Havens
    Corporate Tax Competition and Profit Shifting to Tax Havens Simon Naitram∗ Adam Smith Business School, University of Glasgow October 2016 Abstract This paper presents the case that governments set corporate tax rates both in competition for real investment and in response to profit shifting. Multinational firms seek to maximize global profit by allocating capital across countries, leading to strategic interaction using corporate tax rates in competition for real investment. The role of tax havens in artificial profit shifting shows increased profit shifting has led to lower corporate tax rates. A simple theoretical model of tax competition and profit shifting predicts that statutory tax rates are strategic complements, and that tax rates respond negatively to profit shifting. These predictions are empirically confirmed by a spatial autoregressive model with bilateral investment weights instead of size, distance or uniform weights. Strategic interaction between governments for real investment is significant but smaller than previously estimated, and profit shifting to tax havens significantly affects corporate tax rates. The observed trend of falling corporate tax rates is a function of both tax competition for investment and profit shifting to tax havens. JEL: H0; H25; H77 Keywords: Tax Competition; Corporate Taxation; Profit Shifting; Tax Havens ∗Email: [email protected]. Room 206, 12 Southpark Terrace, Glasgow G12 8LG; Tel: +44 (0)752 126 1105 1 Introduction This research presents evidence on the existence and nature of international tax competition, and offers an alternative interpretation of the results. I incorporate two simple ideas that allow for an alternative explanation: firstly, multinational corporations are key decision-makers in cross- country investment decisions that shape tax competition; secondly, profit shifting is mainly under the purview of tax havens which do not compete for real investment.
    [Show full text]