Financial Crises

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Financial Crises FINANCIAL CRISES Stefania Paredes Fuentes [email protected] Department of Economics, S2.121 University of Warwick Money & Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Crises are costly to the economy • Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) inflation crises, currency crises, sovereign crises and banking crises • Banking crises ‘lead to the closure, merging or takeover by the public sector of one or more financial institutions’ Characteristics: (1) deep and prolonged asset price collapses (2) large and lasting adverse impacts on output and employment (3) government debt explodes • IMF (2009) recessions associated with financial crises are more severe and long-lasting than those associated with other shocks Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Crises are costly to the economy • Great Moderation Inflation targeting regime, calm macroeconomic environment, low unemployment levels • levels of debt in households an banks increased dramatically - expansion of credit and debt in the financial and the household sectors - household debt/GDP from 44% in Spain and 69% in UK in 1999 to 88% and 105% in 2008 respectively • booms in assets prices • Central bank should only react to financial developments to the extent that they influenced forecast CPI inflation over the CB’s planning horizon Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Bank Behaviour and the Macro-Economy • Banks are a special case for policy makers: - Economic dependence of core banking services - Contagion: Spillovers from one bank affect the whole system • Bank bankruptcy is a special case vs other industries(?): → Expectation that govt. bails out failing banks to prevent crisis • Thus, policy makers face a trade-off between: - Maintaining the continuity of core banking services - Avoiding moral hazard on the part of households and banks Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Bank Behaviour and the Macro-Economy • Banks do not take into account the negative externalities of its decisions (e.g. in excessive risk taking) • There is also an information problem: The govt. may impose capital regulation (s.t. bank risks are at the socially optimal level), but this requires that risks are accurately observable. • Banking Activities: We distinguish between 2 types of bank activity: - Retail banking: Deposit-taking, lending, mortgages etc. - Investment Banking (IB): Trading in financial products (securitised assets, derivatives etc.) Also assume: Assets are ‘marked-to-market’ , risk-neutral IBs follow a Value at Risk (VaR) business model Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Origins - Risk Excess risk taking by & excessive leverage of banks: Ignored externalities and relied on bail-outs by the govt. Incentives of banks encouraged strategies that increased aggregate risk in the economy. Regulators allowed banks to use their own models to calculate and report riskiness. Widespread lack of concern for the financial system’s risk to the economy Benign macroeconomic environment and inflation targeting encouraged the belief in low aggregate risk. Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Risk • Raghuram Rajan (2005) “Has financial development made the world riskier?,” - query the value of recent innovation in the financial markets • Don Khon: “By allowing institutions to diversify risk, to choose their risk profiles more precisely, and to improve the management of the risks they take on, they have made institutions more robust … these development have also made the financial system more resilient and flexible - better able to absolve shocks without increasing the effects of such shocks on the real economy” • Ben Bernanke (2006). “Banking organisations of all sizes have made substantial strides over the past two decades in their ability to measure and manage risks” Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Risk • Is ‘risk’ another commodity? i.e. can standard economic tools be applied to the trading of risk? • Greenspan’s doctrine: “The effects of trade is to allocate risk to those investors most able and willing to take risk” • Behavioural finance: ‘irrational behaviour’: individuals chasing a dream, liking control, bias towards optimism ‘rational’ people judge uncertain situations by attaching probabilities to the various outcomes and revise their probabilities in the light of new information • Without the presumption that people act in rational self-interest the whole structure of risk evaluation fails (Markowitz model, Black Scholes model, EMH, Capital Asset Pricing Model, etc) Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Risk We are merely reminding ourselves that human decisions affecting the future, whether personal or political or economic, cannot depend on strict mathematical expectation, since the basis for making such calculations does not exist; and that it is our innate urge to activity which makes the wheels go round, our rational selves choosing between the alternatives as best we are able, calculating where we can, but often falling back for our motive on whim or sentiment or chance. “The State of Long-Term Expectation” in Keynes (1936), Ch. 12 Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS • Financial Cycle vs Business Cycle: Business cycles are based on GDP fluctuations; Financial cycles based on key financial variables (e.g. credit, house prices) Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Bank Behaviour and the Macro-Economy Key Features of the Financial Cycle: 1. Upswing: House prices ↑ → Household borrowing ↑ → Bank borrowing ↑ (positive feedback process) 2. Upswings often end with ↓ in house prices & a banking crisis 3. Downswing: Households & Banks deleverage (↓ indebtedness) → Banks ↑ int. rate spread, ↓ willingness to make loans 4. Housing boom reverses: Borrower households need to ↑ savings and recover from negative equity 5. 3. and 4. (balance sheet effects) imply a deeper recession 6. Public sector debt increases sharply Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Financial Cycles and Business Cycles Stylised Facts about the Financial Cycle: 1. Banks play a key role in the financial cycle through their lending and borrowing behaviour. 2. The housing sector is procyclical and house purchase is often financed by borrowing from banks 3. The inter-relationship between banks and housing is central to the fin. cycle; Peak of fin. cycle often followed by banking crisis. • The BIS measure of financial cycles uses 3 variables: Private credit, Private credit-to-GDP ratio, Residential property prices • Fluctuations in fin. cycle variables typically longer than business cycle fluctuations in output. Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Origins - Actors 1. Retail banks and govt-sponsored housing agencies US Regulations: Hard to ↑ leverage to ↑ returns, so instead,↑ riskiness of asset pool to ↑ returns ∴ Made sub-prime loans and sold them (via MBSs) to eliminate own credit risks → ↓ incentive to check borrower’s credit status 2. Global banks, rating agencies & financial regulators Europe: Lack of regulation on simple leverage; Lax treatment of ‘risk-weighted assets’ Basel II: Assets with a low risk weight do not need much or any equity to be held against it ∴ To purchase AAA-rated assets, banks can easily borrow to fund them, without equity (thus ↑ leverage) Heavy reliance was placed on CRAs; AAA assets proliferated. Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Origins - Actors 3. The shadow banking system Bank-like entities outside the scope of banking regulation also traded heavily in securitised assets. The rapidly growing shadow banking system further boosted aggregate risks in the regulated banking sector. 4. Bank concentration and interconnectedness Consolidation of banks into ‘too-big-to-fail’ financial giants Increased fin. dependence (mutual claims) between banks Homogeneity in the financial system increases systemic risk ∴ Need for focus on Macro-prudential regulation (to manage system-wide risks), as well as traditional Micro-prudential regulation (of individual banks) Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Origins - Subprime lending in the US • US government promoting home ownership extended housing loans to previously credit constrained households rapid expansion of sub-prime lending • source of aggregate demand (little attention to the potential risks of financial fragility from rising household indebtedness) • rising house prices increase value of banks’ collateral increase willingness of banks to lend without adequate checks Financial Accelerator: More lending → House P ↑ → ↑ Collateral → ↑ Further lending •expectations of rising house prices increased the incentive for households to borrow more their leverage increased Stefania Paredes Fuentes Money and Banking WESS 2016 THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Origins - Subprime lending in the US • Aron et al. (2012) - rise in house prices positively affects consumption in the UK and the US - the strength of this relationship increased as these economies became more financially liberalised during the Great Moderation • a fall of house pricing can wipe out all the equity of the household - any greater fall in the house price means that they own an asset worth less than the amount they owe on it • bubble in house prices - price of an asset rises
Recommended publications
  • Balance-Sheet Shocks and Recapitalizations∗
    Balance-Sheet Shocks and Recapitalizations∗ Damiano Sandri Fabian Valencia International Monetary Fund International Monetary Fund October 29, 2012 Abstract We develop a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with financial frictions on both financial intermediaries and goods-producing firms. In this context, due to high leverage of financial intermediaries, balance sheet disruptions in the financial sector are particularly detri- mental for aggregate output. We show that the welfare gains from recapitalizing the financial sector in response to large but rare net worth losses are as large as those from eliminating business cycle fluctuations. We also find that these gains are increasing in the size of the net worth loss, are larger when recapitalization funds are raised from the household rather than the real sector, and may increase after a reduction in financial intermediaries idiosyncratic risk that raises leverage. JEL No. C61, E21, G13 Keywords: Financial accelerator, bank bailouts, leverage, balance-sheet shocks ∗The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. The authors thank Christopher Carroll, Stijn Claessens, Giovanni Dell'Ariccia, Gregory de Walque, Robert Kollmann, Luc Laeven, Jose Luis Peydro, Jose Victor Rios-Rull, Thierry Tressel, Kenneth West, two anonymous refer- ees, and seminar participants at the NBER Summer Institute, the IMF, the CEPR-EBC-HEC-NYSE/Euronext-RoF Conference on \Financial Intermediation and the Real Economy", the National Bank of Poland's conference \DSGE and Beyond", and CEPR-National Bank of Belgium-JMCB-ECARES-Ghent University conference on \Macroeco- nomics and Financial Intermediation" for comments and discussions.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 24 Financial Accelerator
    Chapter 24 Financial Accelerator Starting in 2007, and becoming much more pronounced in 2008, macro-financial events took center stage in the macroeconomic landscape. The “financial collapse,” as many have termed it, had its proximate cause in the U.S., as several financial-sector institutions experienced severe or catastrophic downturns in the values of their financial assets. Various and large-scale policy efforts were implemented very quickly in the U.S. to try to contain possible consequences. The motivation behind these policy efforts was not to save the financial sector for its own sake. Instead, the rationale for policy responses was that severe financial downturns often lead to contraction in real macroeconomic markets (for example, think in terms of goods markets). Despite a raft of policy measures to try to prevent such effects, the severe financial disruption did cause a sharp contraction of economic activity in real markets: GDP declined by nearly four percent in the third quarter of 2008, the time period during which financial disruptions were at their most severe. This quarterly decline was the largest in the U.S. since the early 1980s, and GDP continued declining for the next three quarters. But the reason this pullback in GDP was especially worrisome was something history shows is common. When it is triggered by financial turbulence, a contraction in real economic activity can further exacerbate the financial downturn. This downstream effect was the real fear of policy makers. If this downstream effect occurred, the now- steeper financial downturn then could even further worsen the macro downturn, which in turn could even further worsen the financial downturn, which in turn could even further worsen the macro downturn, and ….
    [Show full text]
  • Capital Flows and Financial Stability: Monetary Policy and Macroprudential Responses∗
    Capital Flows and Financial Stability: Monetary Policy and Macroprudential Responses∗ D. Filiz Unsal International Monetary Fund The resumption of capital flows to emerging-market economies since mid-2009 has posed two sets of interrelated challenges for policymakers: (i) to prevent capital flows from exacerbating overheating pressures and consequent inflation, and (ii) to minimize the risk that prolonged periods of easy financing conditions will undermine financial stability. While conventional monetary policy maintains its role in counteract- ing the former, there are doubts that it is sufficient to guard against the risks of financial instability. In this context, there have been increased calls for the development of macropru- dential measures globally. Against this background, this paper analyzes the interplay between monetary and macropruden- tial policies in an open-economy DSGE model. The key result is that macroprudential measures can usefully complement monetary policy under a financial shock that triggers capital inflows. Even under the “optimal simple rules,” introducing macroprudential measures improves welfare. Broad macropru- dential measures are shown to be more effective than those that ∗I am grateful to the editor Douglas Gale and an anonymous referee for valu- able comments and suggestions. I also thank the participants at the IJCB 4th Financial Stability Conference on “Financial Crises: Causes, Consequences, and Policy Options,” particularly Gianluca Benigno, Gianni De Nicolo, and Rafael Portillo. Roberto Cardarelli, Sonali Jain-Chandra, Nicol´as Eyzaguirre, Jinill Kim, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Jaewoo Lee, and Steve Phillips; seminar participants in the IMF, in Korea University, and in the Central Bank of Turkey; and participants at the KIEP-IMF Joint Conference also provided insightful comments and sug- gestions.
    [Show full text]
  • What Has – and Has Not - Been Learned About Monetary Policy in a Low Inflation Environment? a Review of the 2000S
    What Has – and Has Not - Been Learned about Monetary Policy in a Low Inflation Environment? A Review of the 2000s. Richard H. Clarida* October 12, 2010 I. Introduction As the world economy recovers from the worst financial crisis and deepest, most synchronized global slump in 75 years, policymakers, regulators, and academics are focusing intensely and appropriately on lessons to be learned. Given the magnitude of the crisis, the depth of the recession and the concerns about a sluggish global recovery, there are certainly many questions to answer. Among the most important are: Are inflation expectations ‘well anchored’? What, if any, influence should asset quantities and/or prices have on monetary policy? Do we have sufficient confidence in our alternative monetary policy tools to stabilize the economy at the zero lower bound? The way one answers these questions depends importantly on the conclusions one has drawn about the conduct of monetary policy in last decade and the role of monetary policy, if any, in contributing to the crisis. The subtitle of this paper is not ‘ I Told You So’ and for a good reason. I didn’t, and it wasn’t because I was shy. Rather, as will be discussed later, I, like the vast majority of economists and policymakers, suffered – in retrospect – from Warren Buffet’s ‘lifeguard at the beach’ problem: “you don’t know who is swimming naked until the tide goes out”. In Section II, I first review and then offer my own assessment of the pre- crisis consensus about inflation targeting and the role of asset prices and quantities as an influence on policy in an economy in which inflation – and inflation expectations – are, or at least appear to be, well anchored.
    [Show full text]
  • The Financial Accelerator∗
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by University of Liverpool Repository The Financial Accelerator∗ Oliver de Grooty University of St Andrews March 24, 2016 Abstract The financial accelerator refers to the mechanism by which distortions (frictions) in financial markets amplify the propagation of shocks through an economy. This article sets out the theoretical foundations of the financial accelerator in financial friction DSGE (Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium) models and discusses the ability of these models to provide policy recommendations and a narrative for the 2007-08 financial crisis. ∗This article was prepared for the the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics yEmail: [email protected]. Introduction The financial accelerator refers to the mechanism by which frictions in financial markets amplify the propagation of shocks through an economy. With the financial accelerator, an initial deterioration in credit market conditions leads to rising credit spreads, creating an additional weakening of credit market conditions, and resulting in a disproportionately large drop in economic activity. The key building block of the financial accelerator is the existence of a friction in the intermediation of credit. In frictionless financial markets, loanable funds are intermedi- ated efficiently between savers and borrowers. And, in line with the insights of Modigliani and Miller (1958), the composition of borrowers' internal (own net worth) and external (borrowed) funds do not affect real economic outcomes. However, in reality, asymmetric information and imperfect contract enforcement creates principal-agent problems between borrowers and lenders. The Modigliani-Miller theorem no longer holds and fluctuations in borrower net worth have real economic consequences.
    [Show full text]
  • Theoretical Notes on Bubbles and the Current Crisis
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THEORETICAL NOTES ON BUBBLES AND THE CURRENT CRISIS Alberto Martin Jaume Ventura Working Paper 16399 http://www.nber.org/papers/w16399 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 September 2010 We dedicate this research to the memory of Paul Samuelson, the best economist of the twentieth century, and the first one to understand that pyramid schemes are possible and might raise welfare even if we are all rational and well informed. We thank Fernando Broner and Francesco Caselli for comments on an earlier draft, and Stavros Panageas for a very helpful discussion. We also thank Robert Zymek for excellent research assistance. We acknowledge financial support from the European Research Council, the Lamfalussy Program sponsored by the European Central Bank, the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation, the Generalitat de Catalunya, and the Barcelona GSE Research Network. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2010 by Alberto Martin and Jaume Ventura. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Theoretical Notes on Bubbles and the Current Crisis Alberto Martin and Jaume Ventura NBER Working Paper No. 16399 September 2010 JEL No. E32,E44,G01,O40 ABSTRACT We explore a view of the crisis as a shock to investor sentiment that led to the collapse of a bubble or pyramid scheme in financial markets.
    [Show full text]
  • The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework*
    Chapter 21 THE FINANCIAL ACCELERATOR IN A QUANTITATIVE BUSINESS CYCLE FRAMEWORK* BEN S. BERNANKE, MARK GERTLER and SIMON GILCHRIST Princeton University, New York University, and Boston Unicersity** Contents Abstract 1342 Keywords 1342 1. Introduction 1343 2. The model: overview and basic assumptions 1346 3. The demand for capital and the role of net worth 1349 3.1. Contract terms when there is no aggregate risk 1350 3.2. Contract terms when there is aggregate risk 1352 3.3. Net worth and the optimal choice of capital 1352 4. General equilibrium 1355 4.1. The entrepreneurial sector 1356 4.2. The complete log-linearized model 1360 4.2.1. Two extensions of the baseline model 1365 4.2.1.1. Investment delays 1365 4.2.1,2. Heterogeneous firms 1366 5. Model simulations 1367 5.1. Model parametrization 1367 5.2. Results 1368 5.2.1. Response to a monetary policy shock 1368 5.2.2. Shock to technology, demand, and wealth 1372 5.2.3. Investment delays and heterogeneous firms 1373 6. A highly selected review of the literature 1375 7. Directions for furore work 1379 Appendix A. The optimal financial contract and the demand for capital 1380 A. 1. The partial equilibrium contracting problem 1380 A.2. The log-normal distribution 1385 A.3. Aggregate risk 1385 * Thanks to Michael Woodford, Don Morgan and John Taylor for helpful conanents, and to the NSF and C.M Starr Center for financial support. ** Each author is also affiliated with the National Bmeau of Economic Research. Handbook of Macroeconomics, Volume 1, Edited by J..B.
    [Show full text]
  • What Happened: Financial Factors in the Great Recession
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT HAPPENED: FINANCIAL FACTORS IN THE GREAT RECESSION Mark Gertler Simon Gilchrist Working Paper 24746 http://www.nber.org/papers/w24746 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 June 2018 Prepared for the Journal of Economic Perspectives. Thanks to Ben Bernanke and Oscar Jorda for helpful comments and to Sneha Agrawal and James Graham for excellent research assistance. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2018 by Mark Gertler and Simon Gilchrist. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. What Happened: Financial Factors in the Great Recession Mark Gertler and Simon Gilchrist NBER Working Paper No. 24746 June 2018 JEL No. E32,E44 ABSTRACT Since the onset of the Great Recession, an explosion of both theoretical and empirical research has investigated how the financial crisis emerged and how it was transmitted to the real sector. The goal of this paper is to describe what we have learned from this new research and how it can be used to understand what happened during the Great Recession. In the process, we also present some new evidence on the role of the household balance sheet channel versus the disruption of banking.
    [Show full text]
  • How Should Central Banks Respond to Asset-Price Bubbles? the ‘Lean’ Versus ‘Clean’ Debate After the GFC
    How Should Central Banks Respond to Asset-Price Bubbles? The ‘Lean’ versus ‘Clean’ Debate After the GFC Frederic S Mishkin*, Visiting Scholar to the Reserve Bank Introduction become known in Australia as the global financial crisis (GFC). One of the most important issues facing central banks is whether they should respond to potential The conclusion that I reach is that the debate has asset-price bubbles. Because asset prices are a been miscast. Instead of focusing on asset prices, the central element in the transmission mechanisms focus should be on credit market conditions. The of monetary policy, the issue of how monetary case for leaning against potential credit bubbles, policy might respond to asset-price movements is a manifestation of financial market imbalances, is not whether it should respond at all but whether much stronger than the case for leaning against it should respond over and above the response asset-price bubbles. Not only does this suggest called for in terms of objectives to stabilise inflation that macroprudential measures should be used to and employment. Another way of stating the issue restrain over-exuberance in credit markets, but there is whether monetary policy should try to ‘pop’, are times when monetary policy may need to be or slow, the growth of possibly developing asset- tightened to lean against financial imbalances. price bubbles to minimise damage to the economy when these bubbles burst? Alternatively, should The Debate Before the GFC the monetary authorities not respond directly to Even before the global financial crisis, there was possible asset-price bubbles, but instead respond general agreement that asset-price bubbles have to asset price declines only after a bubble bursts negative effects on the economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Credit Supply Shocks and Economic Activity in a Financial Accelerator Model
    Credit Supply Shocks and Economic Activity in a Financial Accelerator Model Simon Gilchrist∗ Egon Zakrajˇsek† April 10, 2012 Abstract This paper uses the canonical New Keynesian macroeconomic model—augmented with the standard financial accelerator mechanism—to study the extent to which disruptions in financial markets can account for U.S. economic fluctuations during the 1985–2009 period. The key fea- ture of the model is that financial shocks drive a wedge between the required return on capital and the safe rate of return on household savings. A widening of this wedge causes a decline in investment spending and a worsening in the quality of borrowers’ balance sheets, factors that lead to a mutually-reinforcing deterioration in financial conditions. We employ the methodology developed by Gilchrist and Zakrajˇsek [2011b] to construct a measure of distress in the financial sector, which is used to simulate the model. Our simulations indicate that an intensification of financial stresses implies a sharp widening of credit spreads, a significant slowdown in economic activity, a decline in short-term interest rates, and a persistent disinflation. Moreover, such financial market disruptions account for the bulk of contraction in U.S. economic activity that occurred during the last three recessions; these disturbances also generate the investment booms that characterized the 1995–2000 and 2003–06 periods. We also consider the potential benefits of a monetary policy rule that allows the short-term nominal rate to respond to changes in financial conditions as measured by movements in credit spreads. We show that such a spread- augmented policy rule can effectively damp the negative consequences of financial disruptions on real economic activity.
    [Show full text]
  • Avoiding “Regulatory Wars” Using International Coordination of Macroprudential Policies
    Avoiding “regulatory wars” using international coordination of macroprudential policies Article by Luiz Awazu Pereira da Silva and Michael Chui1 Based on panel remarks at the Seminar on Financial Volatility and Foreign Exchange Intervention: Challenges for Central Banks, jointly organised by the Inter-American Development Bank and the Central Reserve Bank of Peru Cusco, 25–26 July 2017 Introduction Financial spillovers and spillbacks have increased significantly in magnitude since the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) posing a threat to financial stability. Using macroprudential policies (MaPs) following systematic countercyclical rules reduces volatility and contributes to financial stability, growth and investment. However, a multiplication of non-systematic, local MaPs, and capital flow management (CFM) measures including more aggressive capital controls, might result in a “regulatory war” and reduce global welfare. Instead, other avenues could be explored, as demonstrated by the adaptability of the policy frameworks used by emerging market economies (EMEs). They have constantly evolved as a result of lessons learned from crises and that should include the GFC. This evolution is part of a learning curve that uses past crisis experiences, policymaking and research to prevent vulnerabilities from developing into full-blown future crises. These remarks are meant to show how this process occurs, its importance for global stability and a last but much needed “new lesson”. Global financial stability needs international coordination on MaPs between major EMEs (those that represent a large combined share of the global economy) and the major advanced economies (AEs). These remarks are structured as follows. First, we go slightly back in time and look at the way in which EME economic policy frameworks have responded to the EME crises of the 1990s: adding “pragmatic flexibility” to manage the impossible trinity and obtain positive results.
    [Show full text]
  • A Simple Financial Accelerator in a Standard Macro-Econometric Model Statistiques Working Papers Du STATEC N° 101 Juillet 2018
    N° 101 Juillet 2018 A simple financial accelerator in a Auteurs: Ferdy ADAM (STATEC) et Christian standard macro-econometric model GLOCKER (Wifo) * Abstract Nowadays quite common in DSGE models, the linkages between the real and the financial sectors are usually absent in traditional macro-econometric models, used for forecasting and policy analysis. This work introduces a so called «financial accelerator» into a standard estimated macro-model, called Modux, representing the Luxembourgish economy. These linkages have been introduced both for machinery and equipment investment and residential investment. The present paper aims at bringing both extensions together in a recently re-estimated version of Modux. Model simulations show that the inclusion of the financial accelerator replicates the stylized facts of the literature (cycle amplification) and might also help to better design standard real demand multipliers. The financial accelerator also proves to be a useful tool to improve the forecasting performance of a general macro-econometric model, the more so in times of financial stress. Keywords: macroeconometric modelling, financial accelerator, public spending multipliers, financial crises JEL Codes: E17; E51; E63; G01 * The authors wish to thank above all the members of STATEC’s forecasting and modelling Division CMP for valuable comments, as well as Profs. M. Marcellino and L. Fontagné and some anonymous participants at Ecomod 2018 conference. Les articles publiés dans la série "Économie et statistiques" n'engagent que leurs auteurs. Ils ne reflètent pas forcément les vues du STATEC et n'engagent en rien sa responsabilité. Economie et A simple financial accelerator in a standard macro-econometric model Statistiques Working papers du STATEC N° 101 juillet 2018 2 Introduction Standard macroeconomic models usually assume perfect capital markets where there is no role for interactions between real and financial factors.
    [Show full text]