Ipos) and Direct Public Offerings (Dpos

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Ipos) and Direct Public Offerings (Dpos Underpricing of Initial Public Offerings (IPOs) and Direct Public Offerings (DPOs) Abstract This paper examines the difference in underpricing between initial public offerings (IPOs) and direct public offerings (DPOs). The data set consists of 4,484 companies that went public between the 1st of December 2012 and the 1st of December 2017 in the U.S. For this sample I find no significant difference between the types of offering on the level of underpricing. Keywords: IPO, DPO, initial return, underpricing. Student: Martin van Dieten Number: 11022329 Program: Economics and Business Track: Economics and Finance Supervisor: Shivesh Changoer Credits: 12 Date: 12 June 2018 1 Statement of Originality This document is written by Martin van Dieten who declares to take full responsibility for the contents of this document. I declare that the text and the work presented in this document are original and that no sources other than those mentioned in the text and its references have been used in creating it. The Faculty of Economics and Business is responsible solely for the supervision of completion of the work, not for the contents. 2 1. Introduction An initial public offering (IPO) is an event where a company raises external capital from the public, by listing itself on the stock exchange (Berk & DeMarzo, 2013). When the price of the offering turns out higher than the offer price at the day of issuing, investors who purchases the shares can make significant returns. This scenario is called underpricing and reduces the capital raised by the issuing firm. According to Ibbotson (1975), Baron and Holmstrom (1980) and Baron (1982) IPOs are on average underpriced. This underpricing is costly, due to underwriter fees, time and effort and results in less revenues for the issuing firm, including the shareholders (Ritter & Ibbotson, 1995). Therefore, different types of offerings exist to minimize these type of costs. One of these types is a direct public offering (DPO). Direct public offerings are a type of offering on the stock exchange without an underwriter managing the offering (Gregoriou, 2008). DPOs have several advantages. The main advantage is that issuing firms are not forced by an underwriter to underprice the offering. Underwriters have namely the incentive to set a lower offer price, because it has a commitment of buying the leftover shares, which will provide substantial costs (Baron & Holmstrom, 1980). A second advantage of DPOs is that issuing companies can avoid paying high fees for underwriters and other commissions within the process (Gregoriou, 2008). Another advantage is that firms that are small, have insufficient economic success or have bad growth prospects have the possibility to list on the exchange via a DPO. Furthermore, companies that are rejected by underwriters to take the company public can use a DPO (Gregoriou, 2008). To examine whether DPOs are less underpriced than IPOs I examine if there is a significant difference in underpricing between Initial Public Offerings (IPOs) and Direct Public Offerings (DPOs). The answer on this question concludes if a DPO is more advantageous than an IPO. Data are obtained from the Thomson One database between the 1st of December 2012 and the 1st of December 2017 in the U.S stock market. For my sample of 4,484 firms I find no significant difference in underpricing between IPOs and DPOs. This finding adds to prior research that there is no free lunch when conducting a DPO instead of an IPO and therefore, DPOs are not more advantageous even though no underwriter fees have to be paid. Several studies have been done about the underpricing of IPOs. Studies from for example Loughran & Ritter (2004), Ibbotson (1975) and Baron & Holmstrom (1980) show that there is, on average, underpricing of initial public offerings. Nonetheless, there has been little 3 research done about DPO underpricing compared to IPO underpricing. This is because traditionally only a handful of small companies in industries such as food and biotech have gone public via DPO every year. Therefore, my research extends the research that has been done about IPO underpricing by testing if there is a significant difference in underpricing between an IPO and a DPO. In the following section the literature and background information on IPOs are discussed. The third section contains the hypothesis and literature on DPOs. The method and data are described in section 4. The descriptive statistics, correlations, univariate and multivariate regressions are reviewed in section 5. In section 6 a sensitivity analysis is done. Section 7 contains the conclusion of the thesis. 2. Literature and background information 2.1.IPOs An Initial Public Offering (IPO) is an event whereby a company offers its common stock for the first time on a public stock exchange (Berk & DeMarzo, 2013). Initial Public Offerings are managed by an investment banker called an underwriter, who manages the offering and outlines its structure (Berk & DeMarzo, 2013). Between the period of 1980 and 2001 there was more than 1 IPO per business day in the U.S (Ritter & Welch, 2002). However, this amount varied between a minimum of 100 and a maximum of 400 IPOs from year to year (Ritter & Welch, 2002). These IPOs had an average deal size of 78 million dollars, with a total of 488 billion dollars in gross proceeds (Ritter & Welch, 2002). According to Ritter & Welch (2002) the underpricing was on average 18.8 percent after one day of trading. Within 3 years the underpricing increased to 22.6 percent. The two biggest advantages of IPOs, with respect to staying private, are an increase in liquidity and better access to capital (Berk & DeMarzo, 2013). Furthermore, founders and shareholders are given the possibility to convert their capital into cash at a future date (Ritter & Welch, 2002). The fact that companies increase their publicity with an IPO plays mostly a minor role (Ritter & Welch, 2002). Besides that, there are advantages when comparing an IPO to a DPO. According to Gregoriou (2008) issuing firms can signal their quality by the chosen underwriter. Another advantage is that underwriters can stake out investors or confirm the quality of the securities (Anand, 2003). The disadvantages consist of direct and indirect costs. These direct costs include mostly legal, auditing and underwriter expenses (Ritter & Ibbotson, 1995). The indirect costs are the time and effort from conducting the IPO (Ritter & Ibbotson, 1995). Another disadvantage 4 according to Ritter and Ibbotson (1995), is the possibility for dilution of shares, because the shares are being sold to the public at, on average, a lower offering price. As mentioned before, some companies find these costs expensive. One of the types that does not incur these cost is a direct public offering, which will be elaborated in section 3. 2.2 IPO underpricing Underpricing of an initial public offering is one of the most researched phenomena regarding IPOs, see for example Loughran & Ritter (2004), Ibbotson (1975) and Baron & Holmstrom (1980). The mentioned studies show that there is, on average, underpricing of initial public offerings. This means that the issuing firms leave money on the table (Loughran & Ritter, 2004). If there is a positive initial performance it indicates that offerings are underpriced. This means that the share price turned out greater than the offer price set by the underwriter (Ibbotson, 1975). According to Baron and Holmstrom (1980) the main reason why IPOs are underpriced are incentives of the underwriter. Issuing companies asks underwriters to set an offer price, because the underwriter has better information on the demand of the securities and the condition of the capital market (Baron & Holmstrom, 1980). The underwriter uses this freedom to set a lower offer price, because it has a commitment of buying the leftover shares, which will provide substantial costs (Baron & Holmstrom, 1980). This way the underwriter has an incentive to limit these costs and advice an offer price below the interest of the issuer. This ensures that the shares will be sold easily and will limit the loss for the underwriter (Baron & Holmstrom, 1980). Loughran and Ritter (2002) further investigate the conflict between the freedom of the underwriter and the issuing firm. As mentioned before, the discretion in share allocation of the underwriter is not used in the best interest of the issuer. According to Loughran and Ritter (2002) underwriters deliberately underprice the offering to sell shares to favoured buy-side clients. This to gain quid pro quos (Loughran & Ritter, 2002). Baron (1982) supports this theory. He argues that, when the underwriter has better information regarding market demand prior to the contracting, the underwriter sets the price below the first-best offer price to limit the costs and risks for the underwriter (Baron D. P., 1982). Benveniste and Spindt (1989) also assumes that there is asymmetric information. They argue that, when investors are more informed than the issuers underwriters can use bookbuilding to obtain information from investors. To truthfully reveal the demand of the investors, underwriters offer to underprice offerings (Benveniste & Spindt, 1989). 5 Another theory is based on the assumption that there is asymmetric information. It is assumed that issuers are better informed than investors. This causes rational investors to fear a lemons problem (Ritter & Welch, 2002). This implies that only issuing firms with a below average quality want to sell the shares at an average price (Ritter & Welch, 2002). Therefore, high-quality issuers try to signal their quality by underpricing. There are also theories based on symmetric information. Hughes and Thakor (1992) argue that issuing firms wants to underprice the offering to reduce their legal liability. This is because overvalued IPOs have a higher chance to be sued (Hughes & Thakor, 1992). Therefore, to avoid subsequent lawsuits issuers want to leave money on the table. (Hughes & Thakor, 1992).
Recommended publications
  • Sec Formalizes Its Position on Pipe Transactions
    June 2007 SEC FORMALIZES ITS POSITION ON PIPE TRANSACTIONS By Jeffrey T. Hartlin, Elizabeth A. Brower and Michael L. Zuppone Private investment in public equity offerings, labeled primary offering made on behalf of the issuer, in which “PIPEs” by market participants, have become a case the PIPE investors would be viewed as effectively permanent alternative for raising equity capital by public acting as statutory underwriters with respect to the companies in need of financing. Pursuant to informal resale of their shares to the public. guidance issued by the Staff of the Securities and BACKGROUND Exchange Commission (“SEC”) in the mid 1990s, PIPEs have been treated as completed private placements not PIPE transactions have two components. The first subject to integration with subsequent registered component involves the original issuance of the secondary offerings by selling securityholders. Under securities – i.e., the private placement of securities by a this guidance, PIPE investors have been able to have the public company to one or more accredited investors in shares issued in (or the shares underlying convertible reliance on the statutory private placement exemption securities issued in) the PIPE transaction registered for provided by Section 4(2) of the Securities Act and/or public resale into the trading market concurrently with private offering exemption provided by Regulation D or soon after the closing of the PIPE transaction. under the Securities Act. The securities sold in PIPEs Recently, as described below, the treatment of PIPEs may include common stock, straight or convertible investors in registered offerings as just selling preferred stock, convertible debt or a combination of securityholders, as opposed to statutory underwriters, these securities, as well as warrants that are issued to has been called into question in certain circumstances.
    [Show full text]
  • Vermont Sense
    VERMONT DOLLARS, VERMONT SENSE A Handbook for Investors, Businesses, Finance Professionals, and Everybody Else BY MICHAEL H. SHUMAN & GWENDOLYN HALLSMITH Foreword by STUART COMSTOCK-GAY A PROJECT OF POST CARBON INSTITUTE, VERMONTERS FOR A NEW ECONOMY, GLOBAL COMMUNITY INITIATIVES, THE PUBLIC BANKING INSTITUTE, AND THE FRESH SOUND FOUNDATION ii Copyright © 2015 by Post Carbon Institute. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be transmitted or Image credits: cover, upper left image © Erika Mitchell (via reproduced in any form by any means without permission in Shutterstock), other images as noted below; page 19, courtesy writing from the publisher. of City Market; page 23, courtesy of SunCommon; page 33, courtesy of Vermont Creamery; page 37, courtesy of Gwendolyn Interior design: Girl Friday Productions Hallsmith; page 50, courtesy of Real Pickles; page 53, courtesy Development and partnerships: Ken White of Opportunities Credit Union; page 71, courtesy of UVM Editing and production: Daniel Lerch Special Collections. ISBN-13: 978-0-9895995-3-5 Special thanks to John Burt and the Fresh Sound Foundation for ISBN-10: 0989599531 providing the funding for this handbook. Additional research and writing assistance was provided by Matt Napoli, now a graduate Post Carbon Institute of St. Michael’s College. 613 Fourth St., Suite 208 Santa Rosa, California 95404 Post Carbon Institute’s mission is to lead the transition to a more (707) 823-8700 resilient, equitable, and sustainable world by providing individ- uals and communities with the resources needed to understand www.postcarbon.org and respond to the interrelated economic, energy, and ecological www.resilience.org crises of the 21st century.
    [Show full text]
  • Can European Unicorns Defend the High Valuations?
    Norwegian School of Economics Bergen, Spring 2018 Can European Unicorns Defend the High Valuations? A challenge of the post-money valuation approach Kristian Hansen Lomheim & Ola Thune Øritsland Supervisor: Nataliya Gerasimova Master thesis in Financial Economics NORWEGIAN SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS This thesis was written as a part of the Master of Science in Economics and Business Administration at NHH. Please note that neither the institution nor the examiners are responsible − through the approval of this thesis − for the theories and methods used, or results and conclusions drawn in this work. 2 Abstract We apply a DCF-based R-model on a sample of 12 European unicorns to show that post- money valuations overstate the fair value of VC-backed companies. At best, the initial result suggests that the majority of the sample is overvalued whereas some firms are slightly undervalued. The median overvaluation of the sample is 25%. When we increase the conservative cost of capital estimates with one percentage point, all firms are overvalued with a median overvaluation of 75% in the sample. Our results indicate that many of the firms will need an abnormal operational improvement toward steady state in addition to significantly outperform the peer group and industry forecasts in order to generate cash flows that are sufficient to defend the post-money valuation. 4 Contents 1. INTRODUCTION .......................................................................................................................8 1.1 PURPOSE & BACKGROUND OF THE STUDY ................................................................................8
    [Show full text]
  • Maximizing Shareholder Value? Spotify Direct Public Offering
    Journal of International & Interdisciplinary Business Research Volume 6 Article 6 November 2019 Maximizing Shareholder Value? Spotify Direct Public Offering Hoje Jo Santa Clara University, [email protected] John Throne Santa Clara University Michael Fieber Santa Clara University Follow this and additional works at: https://scholars.fhsu.edu/jiibr Part of the Business Commons Recommended Citation Jo, Hoje; Throne, John; and Fieber, Michael (2019) "Maximizing Shareholder Value? Spotify Direct Public Offering," Journal of International & Interdisciplinary Business Research: Vol. 6 , Article 6. Available at: https://scholars.fhsu.edu/jiibr/vol6/iss1/6 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by FHSU Scholars Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal of International & Interdisciplinary Business Research by an authorized editor of FHSU Scholars Repository. Jo et al.: Spotify Direct Public Offering MAXIMIZING SHAREHOLDER VALUE? SPOTIFY DIRECT PUBLIC OFFERING Hoje Jo, Santa Clara University John Throne, Santa Clara University Michael Fieber, Santa Clara University The typical method of going public has traditionally been an initial public offering (IPO), whereby a company works with an underwriter syndication to establish a price at which shares will be offered to the public before listing them. The purpose of this paper, however, is to evaluate whether IPOs are truly the best method for taking a company public. To answer this question, at least partially, we explore the upsides and downsides of a direct listing using the music streaming company Spotify (NYSE: SPOT) as a case study. Having officially registered to go public with the SEC and direct listed on April 3, 2018 with $149.01 closing price and a $26.5 billion market capitalization, Spotify becomes the first major private company to list its shares directly to the public on the NYSE without using an underwriter.
    [Show full text]
  • Universita' Degli Studi Di Padova
    UNIVERSITA’ DEGLI STUDI DI PADOVA DIPARTIMENTO DI SCIENZE ECONOMICHE ED AZIENDALI “M.FANNO” CORSO DI LAUREA MAGISTRALE IN BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION TESI DI LAUREA UNDERPRICING AND DIRECT PUBLIC OFFERINGS: THE SPOTIFY DIRECT LISTING CASE RELATORE: CH.MA PROF.SSA ELENA SAPIENZA LAUREANDA: SILVIA BRUSON MATRICOLA N. 1179585 ANNO ACCADEMICO 2018 – 2019 Il candidato dichiara che il presente lavoro è originale e non è già stato sottoposto, in tutto o in parte, per il conseguimento di un titolo accademico in altre Università italiane o straniere. Il candidato dichiara altresì che tutti i materiali utilizzati durante la preparazione dell’elaborato sono stati indicati nel testo e nella sezione “Riferimenti bibliografici” e che le eventuali citazioni testuali sono individuabili attraverso l’esplicito richiamo alla pubblicazione originale. The candidate declares that the present work is original and has not already been submitted, totally or in part, for the purposes of attaining an academic degree in other Italian or foreign universities. The candidate also declares that all the materials used during the preparation of the thesis have been explicitly indicated in the text and in the section "Bibliographical references" and that any textual citations can be identified through an explicit reference to the original publication. Firma dello studente _________________ TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................................. 3 CHAPTER 1 - THE LISTING
    [Show full text]
  • The Internet Direct Public Offering: Establishing Trust in a Disintermediated Capital Market
    The Internet Direct Public Offering: Establishing Trust in a Disintermediated Capital Market Jason Trainor² Introduction Whereas the process of financial intermediation was once human capital and relationship intensive, 5 it is now mall- and medium-sized business enterprises (SMEs) 1 heavily influenced by technological innovation and con- S have consistently encountered difficulties in tapping sumer demand, factors which have tended to disrupt the into the public equity markets in Canada. This problem monopoly power of financial intermediaries. has been shaped by a number of economic, regulatory Technological innovation alone, however, is not suf- and functional barriers to full participation by smaller ficient to replace the institutions and actors that previ- issuers in the Canadian capital market. ously dominated the market for public offerings; rather, The fundamental dilemma involves reducing the the concept of disintermediation by definition creates a informational asymmetries between the private business vacuum that must be filled. Law firms and other enterprise and its prospective public investors. For intermediaries can create additional value for their cli- smaller firms, the costs of disclosing firm-specific infor- ents by assuming some or all of the tasks currently mation to potential investors is substantial in relation to apportioned to investment bankers in the public offering the size of the investment. 2 Given the fundamental pre- process. cept of securities regulation that investors must be Theoretical models created
    [Show full text]
  • Ipos Versus Reverse Mergers
    2009s-06 The Value of Capital Market Regulation: IPOs versus Reverse Mergers Cécile Carpentier, Douglas Cumming, Jean-Marc Suret Série Scientifique Scientific Series Montréal Avril 2009 (mis à jour en décembre 2010) © 2009 Cécile Carpentier, Douglas Cumming, Jean-Marc Suret. Tous droits réservés. All rights reserved. Reproduction partielle permise avec citation du document source, incluant la notice ©. Short sections may be quoted without explicit permission, if full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. CIRANO Le CIRANO est un organisme sans but lucratif constitué en vertu de la Loi des compagnies du Québec. Le financement de son infrastructure et de ses activités de recherche provient des cotisations de ses organisations-membres, d’une subvention d’infrastructure du Ministère du Développement économique et régional et de la Recherche, de même que des subventions et mandats obtenus par ses équipes de recherche. CIRANO is a private non-profit organization incorporated under the Québec Companies Act. Its infrastructure and research activities are funded through fees paid by member organizations, an infrastructure grant from the Ministère du Développement économique et régional et de la Recherche, and grants and research mandates obtained by its research teams. Les partenaires du CIRANO Partenaire majeur Ministère du Développement économique, de l’Innovation et de l’Exportation Partenaires corporatifs Banque de développement du Canada Banque du Canada Banque Laurentienne du Canada Banque Nationale du Canada Banque Royale du Canada Banque Scotia Bell Canada BMO Groupe financier Caisse de dépôt et placement du Québec DMR Fédération des caisses Desjardins du Québec Gaz de France Gaz Métro Hydro-Québec Industrie Canada Investissements PSP Ministère des Finances du Québec Power Corporation du Canada Raymond Chabot Grant Thornton Rio Tinto Alcan State Street Global Advisors Transat A.T.
    [Show full text]
  • The Truth About Reverse Mergers
    THE TRUTH ABOUT REVERSE MERGERS * WILLIAM K. SJOSTROM, JR. This article examines the reverse merger method of going public. It describes the principal features of reverse mergers, including deal structure and legal compliance. Although reverse mergers are routinely pitched as cheaper and quicker than traditional IPOs, this article argues that such pitches are misleading and, for many companies, irrelevant. I. INTRODUCTION A reverse merger (“RM”) is a non-traditional method of going public. Instead of hiring an underwriter to market and sell the company’s shares in an initial public offering (“IPO”), a private operating company works with a “shell promoter” to locate a suitable non-operating or shell public company.1 The private operating company then merges with the shell company (or a newly-formed subsidiary of the shell company).2 In the merger, the operating company shareholders are issued a majority stake in the shell company in exchange for their operating company shares.3 Post-merger, the shell company contains the assets and liabilities of the operating company and is controlled by the former operating company shareholders.4 The shell company’s name is changed to the name of the operating company, its directors and officers are replaced by the directors and officers of the operating company,5 and its shares continue to trade on whichever stock market they were trading prior to the merger.6 Hence, the operating company’s business is still controlled by the same group of shareholders and managed by the same directors and officers, but it is now contained within a public company.
    [Show full text]
  • Initial Public Offering Investopedia
    Initial Public Offering Investopedia AsymmetricDerick never and piecing nittiest any Davoud tropicbirds deafens short-list her remittorsvegetably, instillment is Obadiah disannuls exclusory and and diapers given dishonestly. enough? Is Vincents stained when Tremain invalidate binaurally? When it hopes to abandon the issuer can tax, public offering date against delivery requirements, such activities and demat account The offering and investopedia receives critical information is already established. Companies offer ipos, offers that means that is offered. Fintech Disruption in the Financial Industry. This article are offered only through offer to public offering offers services to see who happened to expansion of potential. Who were financial concepts for public offer stock that all trades in fact in case of scenario. The initial price band exists for profitability each process? This fresh capital. There is mitigated the class action lawsuits in. Have specific question exist your retirement, including where is live? In spirit, some stocks flounder after their IPOs. An initial public. The Airbnb IPO last week created a month of excitement within the investment community. Morgan, or Morgan Stanley for underwriting services. When companies issue IPOs, they notify brokerage firms, who, in request, notify investors. Nothing found guilty, public offerings are offered through this phase or what exactly is not be. These top tier markets and browse the sake of who is consummated, a placement agents in public offering? In the case of a straightforward account relationship with the CSD or ICSD. The cover page modify the prospectus details how many shares are being sold by selling shareholders, if any. There are examples of financial institutions.
    [Show full text]
  • The Secrets of Wall Street
    A Person Who Won’t Read Has No Advantage Over A Person Who Can’t Read. ~Mark Twain Table of Contents FOREWORD ................................................................................................................ - 4 - Chapter 1: An Introduction to Raising Capital in the United States ....................... - 8 - Chapter 2: The Perfect Storm: Are you Ready? ..................................................... - 28 - Chapter 3: Capitalizing On the Winds of Change ................................................... - 41 - Chapter 4: Knowledge is Power: The Power-Play .................................................. - 45 - Chapter 5: Conduct a Series of Related Securities Offerings ................................. - 58 - Chapter 6: Why Entrepreneurs Fail to Raise Capital............................................. - 67 - Chapter 7: The Four Professional Functions of a Securities Offering .................. - 76 - Chapter 8: Organizational Structures & Management Mindsets .......................... - 82 - Chapter 9: Deal Structuring ...................................................................................... - 91 - DEAL STRUCTURES FOR OPERATING COMPANIES ....................................................... - 94 - DEAL STRUCTURES FOR FUNDS .................................................................................. - 98 - Chapter 10: Company Valuation and Securities Pricing ...................................... - 109 - Chapter 11: Attracting Capital: Warping the Risk - Return Continuum ........... - 120
    [Show full text]
  • Community Investment in the Local Food System
    Community Investment in the Local Food System How a small local food business in western Massachusetts preserved its social mission through transitioning to a worker-owned cooperative and using an innovative financing strategy Author: Jonathan Ward Special Projects Intern Community Involved in Sustaining Agriculture (CISA) Contributors: Margaret Christie Community Involved in Sustaining Agriculture (CISA) Addie Rose Holland Dan Rosenberg Real Pickles Jeff Rosen Solidago Foundation Sam Stegeman Pioneer Valley Grows (PVGrows) This publication with live links is available online at: www.buylocalfood.org/real-pickles-financing-case-study/ Abstract “We’re re-writing the standard storyline for these decisions, the worker-owners drew from the experience a successful organic food business,” says that one of them had working with Equal Exchange, a successful cooperative with a long history of raising capital Dan Rosenberg, founder of the twelve-year-old by selling non-voting preferred stock. Later, they sought the Greenfield, Massachusetts company Real Pickles, expertise of the PVGrows collaborative network in western which makes naturally fermented and raw pickles Massachusetts. A financing expert in PVGrows also connected Real Pickles to Cutting Edge Capital, a pioneering consulting from regionally grown vegetables in a 100% firm in the Bay Area that helped them navigate many legal solar-powered facility. hurdles. In the end, the worker-owners decided that the best way for them to raise $500,000 was to sell non-voting Instead of selling their growing company to a large preferred stock through a direct public offering. Real Pickles industrial-food corporation, as happens so often with officially launched a community investment campaign in March successful natural products businesses (think: Odwalla, 2013.
    [Show full text]
  • Entrepreneurial Finance Strategy, Valuation, and Deal Structure
    Entrepreneurial Finance Strategy, Valuation, and Deal Structure CONTENTS List of Illustrations xvii Abbreviations xxiii Preface xxvii Why Study Entrepreneurial Finance? xxviii What Makes Entrepreneurial Finance Different from Corporate Finance? xxix Interdependence between Investment and Financing Decisions Diversifiable Risk and Investment Value Managerial Involvement of Investors Information Problems and Contract Design Incentive Alignment and Contract Design The Importance of Real Options Harvesting the Investment Value to the Entrepreneur What’s New about This Book? xxxiv Intended Audience xxxv A Note about the Website and Internet Resources xxxvi Simulation Spreadsheets and Templates Acknowledgments xxxix About the Authors xli PART 1 Getting Started Chapter 1 Introduction 3 1.1 Entrepreneurship and the Entrepreneur 3 Survival and Failure Rates of New Businesses Economic Downturns and Entrepreneurship Globalization of Entrepreneurship Types of Entrepreneurship Corporate Venturing Social Venturing 1.2 The Finance Paradigm 12 The Importance of Real Options Objective: Maximum Value for the Entrepreneur 1.3 The Rocket Analogy 14 1.4 The Stages of New Venture Development 15 1.5 Measuring Progress with Milestones 17 1.6 Financial Performance and Stages of New Venture Development 19 1.7 The Sequence of New Venture Financing 21 1.8 The New Venture Business Plan 24 Business Plans of New Ventures Are Different What Makes a Business Plan Convincing? 1.9 Organization of the Book 29 1.10 Summary 31 Review Questions 32 Notes 33 References and Additional
    [Show full text]