Expectations and the Meaning of Institutions

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Expectations and the Meaning of Institutions EXPECTATIONS AND THE MEANING OF INSTITUTIONS FOUNDATIONS OF THE MARKET ECONOMY SERIES Edited by Mario J.Rizzo, New York University and Lawrence H.White, University of Georgia A central theme of this series is the importance of understanding and assessing the market economy from a perspective broader than the static economics of perfect competition and Pareto optimality. Such a perspective sees markets as causal processes generated by the preferences, expectations and beliefs of economic agents. The creative acts of entrepreneurship that uncover new information about preferences, prices and technology are central to these processes with respect to their ability to promote the discovery and use of knowledge in society. The market economy consists of a set of institutions that facilitate voluntary cooperation and exchange among individuals. These institutions include the legal and ethical framework as well as more narrowly ‘economic’ patterns of social interaction. Thus the law, legal institutions and cultural or ethical norms, as well as ordinary business practices and monetary phenomena, fall within the analytical domain of the economist. Other titles in the series THE MEANING OF MARKET PROCESS Essays in the development of modern Austrian economics Israel M.Kirzner PRICES AND KNOWLEDGE A market-process perspective Esteban F.Thomsen KEYNES’ GENERAL THEORY OF INTEREST A reconsideration Fiona C.Maclachlan LAISSEZ-FAIRE BANKING Kevin Dowd EXPECTATIONS AND THE MEANING OF INSTITUTIONS Essays in economics by Ludwig Lachmann Edited by Don Lavoie London and New York First published 1994 by Routledge 11 New Fetter Lane London EC4P 4EE This edition published in the Taylor & Francis e-Library, 2005. “To purchase your own copy of this or any of Taylor & Francis or Routledge’s collection of thousands of eBooks please go to www.eBookstore.tandf.co.uk.” Simultaneously published in the USA and Canada by Routledge 29 West 35th Street, New York NY 10001 © 1994 Don Lavoie All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or utilized in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publishers. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Expectations and the meaning of institutions : essays in economics by Ludwig Lachmann / edited by Don Lavoie. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. 1. Economics 2. Rational expectations (Economic theory) 3. Financial institutions. I. Lachmann, Ludwig M. II. Lavoie, Don, 1951 HB34.E84 1994 93–29051 CIP ISBN 0-203-97655-X Master e-book ISBN ISBN 0-415-10712-1 (hbk) This book has been sponsored in part by the Austrian Economics Program at New York University. CONTENTS Editor’s note vii Acknowledgements viii INTRODUCTION: EXPECTATIONS AND THE 1 MEANING OF INSTITUTIONS Don Lavoie Part I Uncertainty, investment and economic crises 1 COMMODITY STOCKS AND EQUILIBRIUM 23 [1936] 2 UNCERTAINTY AND LIQUIDITY- 29 PREFERENCE [1937] 3 INVESTMENT AND COSTS OF PRODUCTION 41 [1938] 4 COMMODITY STOCKS IN THE TRADE 55 CYCLE [1938] (with F.Snapper) 5 ON CRISIS AND ADJUSTMENT [1939] 73 Part II Capital and investment repercussions 6 ON THE MEASUREMENT OF CAPITAL [1941] 87 7 FINANCE CAPITALISM? [1944] 103 8 A NOTE ON THE ELASTICITY OF 119 EXPECTATIONS [1945] 9 INVESTMENT REPERCUSSIONS [1948] 125 Part III Diagnosing the Austrian School’s ‘great depression’ 10 AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS UNDER FIRE: THE 141 HAYEK-SRAFFA DUEL IN RETROSPECT [1986] vi 11 THE SALVAGE OF IDEAS: PROBLEMS OF 159 THE REVIVAL OF AUSTRIAN ECONOMIC THOUGHT [1982] 12 JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES: A VIEW FROM 179 AN AUSTRIAN WINDOW [1983] 13 REFLECTIONS ON HAYEKIAN CAPITAL 193 THEORY [1975] Part IV Subjectivism and the interpretation of institutions 14 CARL MENGER AND THE INCOMPLETE 207 REVOLUTION OF SUBJECTIVISM [1978] 15 VICISSITUDES OF SUBJECTIVISM AND THE 213 DILEMMA OF THE THEORY OF CHOICE [1978] 16 FROM MISES TO SHACKLE: AN ESSAY ON 223 AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS AND THE KALEIDIC SOCIETY [1976] 17 G.L.S.SHACKLE’S PLACE IN THE HISTORY 235 OF SUBJECTIVIST THOUGHT [1990] 18 THE FLOW OF LEGISLATION AND THE 243 PERMANENCE OF THE LEGAL ORDER [1979] 19 THE MONETARY SYSTEM OF A MARKET 255 ECONOMY [1986] 20 SPECULATIVE MARKETS AND ECONOMIC 263 COMPLEXITY [1988] 21 AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS: A HERMENEUTIC 269 APPROACH [1991] APPENDIX: BIBLIOGRAPHY OF WORKS BY 285 LUDWIG M.LACHMANN Notes 291 References 313 Index 321 EDITOR’S NOTE This selection of essays by Ludwig Lachmann (1906–90) includes the most important of his works in English which were previously published only in scattered places, and not included in his own books. An excellent collection of many of his essays was put together by Walter Grinder in 1977, but there are many significant works that did not fit in that collection, and several others which have only appeared since 1977. In particular, the collection featured heavily what could be called Lachmann’s middle period, that is the 1950s and 1960s, but included no essays from the 1930s and only three from the 1940s. This collection then fills in the gaps, including nine essay from the early period, spanning from 1936 to 1948, and twelve from the later period, from 1975 to 1991. Two of the essays, ‘Reflections on Austrian capital theory’ and ‘Vicissitudes of subjectivism and the dilemma of theory of choice’, have not been previously published. The essays have been reproduced with no editorial alterations to the content, except for the insertion of some section headings to improve consistency. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to thank Bill Tulloh, whose work in gathering together the bibliography, and talking with me at length about the meaning of Lachmann’s work, was instrumental in moving this project forward. It was gratifying to see most of our entries verified in the bibliography that was separately collected by C.S.W.Torr, S.Böhm, and K.H.M.Mittermaier for the South African Journal of Economics, but there were a few items they found that we had missed, and we thank them for this help. Robert Baldini helped with the proofreading. Alan Jarvis of Routledge encouraged me in the idea of this book from the beginning, and never lost patience with my plodding efforts. INTRODUCTION Expectations and the meaning of institutions Don Lavoie The main social function of the economist is to provide the historian and the student of contemporary events with an arsenal of schemes of interpretation. Ludwig M.Lachmann1 Professor Lachmann’s contributions to economics, spanning six decades, and addressing issues in microeconomics, macroeconomics, methodology and the history of thought, are a treasure chest. His essays are consistently well written and extraordinarily insightful, yet his message has not yet been adequately appreciated, even by those who know some of his major works. As a dissident member of a dissident school of thought, the Austrian school, his work is not well known in the economics profession at large. Yet as these essays show, Lachmann’s challenges to mainstream economics in general, and to mainstream Austrian economics, even those he penned a half century ago, strike at the very heart of what has gone wrong with ‘the dismal science’. Lachmann lived through dramatic changes in the status of the Austrian school during his long career. He began his academic life when the school was at its peak, witnessed its rapid decline throughout the 1930s, survived its dark ages during the next three decades, and then contributed to its resurgence during the 1970s and 1980s.2 His work is now the inspiration of a growing group of Austrian-oriented critics of mainstream economics who are trying to recover what might be called its interpretive dimension.3 Among Austrian economists he is best known as the leading representative of the ‘radical subjectivist’ wing of the school. His allies understand this to be an honourable position and his critics understand it to be a serious danger: too much subjectivism, say the critics, 2 INTRODUCTION undermines the ability of economics to describe market processes as systematic in any sense. The critics’ concerns that Lachmann’s work leads to nihilism have, I think, been misplaced. They have distorted the main thrust of Lachmann’s work, by making it seem as though the issue his work is raising is some kind of metaphysical doubt about whether economic reality might be beyond any systematic understanding because it is completely chaotic, or even whether the real world exists at all. This is especially unjust in that Lachmann was in fact far more oriented to the real world of the economy than the vast majority of his professional colleagues. To treat this economist—who was as much at home discussing the latest news from the financial press or the intricate details of stock market options as he was discussing economic theory— as if he entertained doubts about whether there is a real world out there, is utterly absurd. The essays collected in this book make clear that on the contrary Lachmann’s contributions are precisely aimed at helping us to understand the systematic order and empirical complexity of real world market processes. Lachmann’s message does, to be sure, identify a conflict between neoclassical economics and the real world, but it is not the real world that he is saying needs to go. His work is as uncompromising a challenge to mainstream economics as can be found anywhere. It resembles in this respect, the work of his good friend George Shackle. But in one important respect he differs from Shackle. Lachmann saw his work not only as a criticism of mainstream economics, but as a constructive effort in building an alternative sort of economics, an alternative he thought could be put together primarily from the resources of the Austrian school, although freely borrowing from other sources.
Recommended publications
  • Neoliberal Reason and Its Forms: Depoliticization Through Economization∗
    Neoliberal reason and its forms: Depoliticization through economization∗ Yahya M. Madra Department of Economics Boğaziçi University Bebek, 34342, Istanbul, Turkey [email protected] Yahya M. Madra studied economics in Istanbul and Amherst, Massachusetts. He has taught at the universities of Massachusetts and Boğaziçi, and at Skidmore and Gettysburg Colleges. He currently conducts research in history of modern economics at Boğaziçi University with the support of TÜBITAK-BIDEB Scholarship. His work appeared in Journal of Economic Issues, Rethinking Marxism, The European Journal of History of Economic Thought, Psychoanalysis, Society, Culture and Subjectivity as well as edited volumes. His current research is on the role of subjectivity in political economy of capitalism and post-capitalism. and Fikret Adaman Department of Economics, Boğaziçi University Bebek, 34342, Istanbul, Turkey [email protected] Fikret Adaman studied economics in Istanbul and Manchester. He has been lecturing at Boğaziçi University on political economy, ecological economics and history of economics. His work appeared in Journal of Economic Issues, New Left Review, Cambridge Journal of Economics, Economy and Society, Ecological Economics, The European Journal of History of Economic Thought, Energy Policy and Review of Political Economy as well as edited volumes. His current research is on the political ecology of Turkey. DRAFT: Istanbul, October 3, 2012 ∗ Earlier versions of this paper have been presented in departmental and faculty seminars at Gettysburg College, Uludağ University, Boğaziçi University, İstanbul University, University of Athens, and New School University. The authors would like to thank the participants of those seminars as well as to Jack Amariglio, Michel Callon, Pat Devine, Harald Hagemann, Stavros Ioannides, Ayşe Mumcu, Ceren Özselçuk, Maliha Safri, Euclid Tsakalatos, Yannis Varoufakis, Charles Weise, and Ünal Zenginobuz for their thoughtful comments and suggestions on the various versions of this paper.
    [Show full text]
  • Peter J. Boettke
    PETER J. BOETTKE BB&T Professor for the Study of Capitalism, Mercatus Center at George Mason University, & University Professor of Economics and Philosophy Department of Economics, MSN 3G4 George Mason University Fairfax, VA 22030 Tel: 703-993-1149 Fax: 703-993-1133 Web: http://www.peter-boettke.com http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/cf_dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per_id=182652 http://www.coordinationproblem.org PERSONAL Date of birth: January 3, 1960 Nationality: United States EDUCATION Ph.D. in Economics, George Mason University, January, 1989 M.A. in Economics, George Mason University, January, 1987 B.A. in Economics, Grove City College, May, 1983 TITLE OF DOCTORAL THESIS: The Political Economy of Soviet Socialism, 1918-1928 PROFESSIONAL EXPERIENCE Academic Positions 1987 –88 Visiting Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, George Mason University 1988 –90 Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, School of Business Administration, Oakland University, Rochester, MI 48309 1990 –97 Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, New York University, New York, NY 10003 1997 –98 Associate Professor, Department of Economics and Finance, School of Business, Manhattan College, Riverdale, NY 10471 1998 – 2003 Associate Professor, Department of Economics, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA 22030 (tenured Fall 2000) 2003 –07 Professor, Department of Economics, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA 22030 2007 – University Professor, George Mason University 2011 – Affiliate Faculty, Department of Philosophy, George Mason University FIELDS OF INTEREST
    [Show full text]
  • Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative
    [Show full text]
  • Entrepreneurial Discovery and the Competitive Market Process
    Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XXXV (March 1997), pp. 60-85 EntrepreneurialDiscovery and the Competitive Market Process: An Austrian Approach ISRAEL M. KIRZNER New York University The aiithloris deeply grateful to Mario Rizzo, Peter Boettke, andc1Yat Nyarko, for exte.tsive and helpful comm7ents o an earlier draft Firther helpful coniiiiienit.swere provided by Joseph T Salernio,and by othieriaiemiibers of the AiustrianiEconomizics Colloquiumi71 at New York Univer- Oity.Several anioniymtouisreferee.s provided m1anzyadditionial valiuable suggestions. The auithlor is gr-atefiulto the Sarah Scaife Foundation for researchisupport. I stream economics. This paper sets forth the outlines of one important approach THE AUSTRIAN TRADITION is repre- within modern Austrian economics, an sented in modern economics by a approach offering a perspective on mi- "very vocal, feisty and dedicated subset croeconomic theory which (while it has of the economics profession" (Karen generated a considerable literature of its Vaughn 1994, p. xi). Much of the work of own) is not ordinarily well-represented this group of scholars is devoted to the either at the (mainstream) textbook most fundamental problems of micro- level, or in the (mainstream) journal lit- economics.1 This Austrian work, there- erature. Although the author subscribes fore, differs in character and content to and has contributed to this from a good deal of neoclassical theory approach, the purpose of this paper is exposition, which, despite widespread and growing not advocacy. References in the paper awareness of its limitations, continues to to criticisms of mainstream microeco- serve as the analytical core of main- nomics which have been discussed in the Austrian literature should be understood 1 The emphasis here on microeconomics ex- here not as arguments in favor of the presses the focus of the present paper, not the Austrian approach, but as clues that may scope of modern Austrian economics.
    [Show full text]
  • A Roundabout Approach to Macroeconomics 2
    A Roundabout Approach to Macroeconomics 2 another matter. Here, the time element is a debilitating problem: These expectations, if you can call them that, are baseless. The future is shrouded in an impenetrable fog of uncertainty, leaving the current level of investment spending to be determined by unruly psychological factors—Keynes’s infamous “animal spirits.” The resultant circular flow will gush and ebb and even on average may not entail enough flow to fully employ the labor force. The circular-flow framework, exercised in both its short-run and long-run modes, seems to me to be exactly the wrong framework for understanding and dealing with the A Roundabout Approach to Macroeconomics: time element in macroeconomics. Identifying the polar cases of “no problem” and Some Autobiographical Reflections* “debilitating problem” doesn’t get us any closer to a solution to all those intermediate cases lying between the poles. The tell-tale feature that inevitably characterizes this framework has been recognized in recent years by Robert Solow (1997)—namely the Roger W. Garrison** lack of any “real coupling” (Solow’s term) between the short run and the long run. In Solow’s reckoning, the two runs simply divide our discipline’s subject matter into (1) the problem of maintaining full employment of existing resources and (2) the I. Introduction: Setting the Stage determinants of economic growth. “Roundaboutness” is a concept featured in Austrian capital theory. Homely stories A viable alternative to the Keynesian circular flow framework is the Austrian about the bare-handed catching of fish are a prelude to a discussion of the economy’s means-ends framework.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Didn't Economists Predict the Great Depression?
    Why Didn’t Economists Predict the Great Depression? Leon Taylor KIMEP Social Research Working Paper No. 6 February 2011 © Copyright 2011 Leon Taylor KIMEP Social Research Working Papers ISSN 1996 -7020 2 Why didn’t economists predict the Great Depression? Leon Taylor 1 The Department of Economics and the Office of the President Kazakhstan Institute of Management, Economics and Strategic Research (KIMEP) Almaty, Kazakhstan Draft: January 2011 Version for researchers Abstract Economists failed to forecast the Great Depression, perhaps largely because they had lacked reason to theorize about business cycles. This paper tries to explain the lack of incentives. Since theory is a public good, the market produces too little of it. One non-market incentive, ex post fame, may be proportional to the value of the theory -- and thus induce more theory as its value grows. But fame comes from explaining famous events. A theory may explain a potential disaster so well as to enable policymakers to avert it. Since the event does not occur, its explainer cannot become famous. Theorists who anticipate this paradox will avoid work on the potential event; theorists who work nonetheless on events never to occur will become obscure. Another factor retarding business-cycle theory is scale economies. Learning-by-doing can induce theory by cutting its cost. Scale economies favor the first theories to be well-developed. These dealt with markets – not with business cycles – in the decades before the Depression which redirected attention to macroeconomics. ( JEL classifications: B10, E32) I. Introduction The Great Depression bemused economists of the day. “The slump in trade and employment and the business losses which are being incurred,” Keynes (1963: 148) said in 1931, “are as bad as the worst which have ever occurred in the modern history of the world.” Economists were caught off-guard.
    [Show full text]
  • Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School
    Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School Ralph Raico Foreword by Jörg Guido Hülsmann Preface by David Gordon LvMI MISES INSTITUTE The cover design by Chad Parish shows the Neptune Fountain, at the Schönbrunn Palace, in Vienna. Copyright © 2012 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute. Permission to reprint in whole or in part is gladly granted, provided full credit is given. Ludwig von Mises Institute 518 West Magnolia Avenue Auburn, Alabama 36832 mises.org ISBN: 978-1-61016-003-2 Dedicated to the memory of the great Ludwig von Mises Table of Contents Foreword by Jörg Guido Hülsmann . ix Preface by David Gordon . xiii Introduction . .xxv 1. Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School . .1 2. Liberalism: True and False . .67 3. Intellectuals and the Marketplace. 111 4. Was Keynes a Liberal? . .149 5. The Conflict of Classes: Liberal vs. Marxist Theories. .183 6. The Centrality of French Liberalism . .219 7. Ludwig von Mises’s Liberalism on Fascism, Democracy, and Imperalism . .255 8. Eugen Richter and the End of German Liberalism. .301 9. Arthur Ekirch on American Militarism . .331 Index. .339 vii Foreword “History looks backward into the past, but the lesson it teaches concerns things to come. It does not teach indolent quietism; it rouses man to emulate the deeds of earlier generations.” Ludwig von Mises1 The present book contains a collection of essays written through- out the past twenty years. I read virtually all of them when they were first published. They have been a central part of my education in the history of liberalism and of the Austrian School of economics, and I consider myself privileged indeed to have encountered Professor Raico and his work early on in my intellectual development.
    [Show full text]
  • The Present State of Austrian Economics by Murray N
    The Present State of Austrian Economics By Murray N. Rothbard 1 [This paper was delivered at the Tenth Anniversary Scholars’ Conference of the Ludwig von Mises Institute, October 9, 1992. Working Paper from the Ludwig von Mises Institute, November 1992. Reprinted in The Logic of Action One: Method, Money, and the Austrian School. Glos, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd., 1997, pp. 111-172. Reprinted in Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, Vol. 6 No. 1 (March 1995), pp. 43-89. ] In the past two decades, there has been a seeming growth of methodological sophistication in the world of economics. Until the early 1970s, a blind Walrasian formalism held total sway in microeconomics, while a triumphant Keynesianism dominated macro, all held together by an unthinking and arrogant empiricist epistemology of logical positivism. The micro and macro synthesis of the neoclassical paradigm were both embodied and symbolized in the work of Paul Samuelson, while the positivist methodology was enshrined in the famed 1953 article of Milton Friedman and the later work of Mark Blaug.1 Since that point, however, the dominant positivist paradigm has been effectively overthrown, to be replaced by a bracing and near-chaotic Kuhnian “crisis situation” in the methodology of economics. For the last two decades, a dozen, if not a hundred, schools of economic thought have been allowed to bloom. Unfortunately, however, the orthodox paradigms in macro and especially microeconomics are still dominant, although less aggressively held than before; the crisis situation in methodology has not yet been allowed to trickle down fully to the substantive bread-and-butter areas where economists, after all, earn their livelihood.
    [Show full text]
  • The Macroeconomic Models of the Austrian School: a History and Comparative Analysis Renaud Fillieule*
    THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS VOLUME 22 | No. 4 | 533–564 | WINTER 2019 WWW.QJAE.ORG The Macroeconomic Models of the Austrian School: A History and Comparative Analysis Renaud Fillieule* JEL Classification: B13, B25, B53, E14 Abstract: This paper offers a synthetic and comparative assessment of the most basic Austrian macroeconomic models, i.e. the models that analyze the static forces determining the equilibrium interest rate and structure of production (monetary disequilibria and business cycles are not part of this investigation). The three models presented here are those of Böhm-Bawerk ([1889] 1959), Hayek (1936, 1941), and Garrison (2001). This review shows that these models are largely inconsistent with each other, but also that at a more general level they share several important charac- teristics. Finally, a tentative explanation is offered as to why there is no cumulative tradition in the Austrian School in this kind of basic macroeconomic theorizing. INTRODUCTION he Austrian School is best known for its subjectivist approach Tand for its theories of the market process and the business cycle. This paper focuses upon a less familiar but nevertheless significant * Renaud Fillieule ([email protected]) is Professor of Sociology at the University of Lille, France, and member of the CLERSÉ research unit (UMR CNRS 8019). A preliminary version of this paper was presented at the Austrian Economics Research Seminar in Paris, France, May 9, 2017. The author wishes to thank Prof. Hülsmann for this invitation and the attendees for their remarks and suggestions. Quart J Austrian Econ (2019) 22.4:533–564 533 Creative Commons https://qjae.scholasticahq.com/ BY-NC-ND 4.0 License 534 Quart J Austrian Econ (2019) 22.4:533–564 topic.
    [Show full text]
  • Drei Methodenstreite and Intramural Strife
    DREI METHODENSTREITE AND INTRAMURAL STRIFE A University Thesis Presented to the Faculty of California State University, Hayward In Partial Fulfillment ofthe Requirements for the Degree Master ofArts in Economics By Christopher R. Inama February, 1996 Copyright © 1996 by Christopher R. Inama ii DREI METHODENSTREITE AND INTRAMURAL STRIFE By Christopher R. Inama Approved: Dated: iii TABLE OF CONTENTS l. INTRODUCTION II. 7lfF METHODENSTREIT 2 A. ORIGINS OF THE GERMAN HISTORICAL SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS 2 1. Some Forerunners ofthe German Historical School ofEconomics .,. 5 2. An Initial Criticism ofHistoricism , 10 B. THE GERMAN HISTORICAL SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS , 12 C. MENGER'S CHALLENGE 20 D. THE OUTCOME 27 III. FIFTY YEARS LATER 30 A. HAYEK'S THEORY 33 B. KEYNES'S THEORY 40 C. THE DISPUTE 43 D. THE OUTCOME 45 IV. AN ONGOING DEBATE 51 A. POSITIVISTS, COLLECTIVISTS, AND OTHERS OF THEIR ILK 52 B. AUSTRIAN RESPONSES TO THAT ILK 68 I. ADDITIONAL PHILOSOPHICAL INFLUENCES ON AUSTRIAN THOUGHT 68 2. SOME VARIATIONS WITHIN THE AUSTRIAN SCHOOL 80 C. SOME METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES 82 I. Internal Contradictions ofLogical Positivism 82 2. Is Empirical Knowledge Inconsistent with the Austrian Theory? 84 D. HAYEK'S CRITICISMS OF DIFFERENT FORMS OF POSITIVISM 85 IV. AN INTRAMURAL FRAY 90 A. SOME DIFFERENCES BETWEEN MISES AND HAYEK 90 B. A MISESIAN BRANCH OF THE FAMILY TREE 95 C. ANOTHER STUDENT OF MISES CLAIMS THE MIDDLE-GROUND 106 D. RADICAL SUBJECTIVISTS DESCENDED THROUGH HAYEK .... 108 V. CONCLUSION 111 BIBLIOGRAPHY ..................................................
    [Show full text]
  • George Mason University Economics and Public Policy Problems Spring Semester Economics 309
    George Mason University Economics and Public Policy Problems Spring Semester Economics 309 Professor: Dr. Thomas Carl Rustici Office: Enterprise Hall Room 322 Hours: MWF 9:30-10:15 & 12:30-1:15 pm & MW 4:30-5:30 pm Phone: Office 993-1137 Web Page mason.gmu.edu/-trustici Email [email protected] Objectives: The lectures and readings in this course are designed to familiarize students with the fundamental relationships between the individual citizen, government, business and society. Philosophy, political theory, economic theory, and legal history are brought together to better understand public policy issues. The nature of state, firm and markets are explored in a contractual context. Also, the effects of government regulation in a wide variety of market settings are highlighted throughout the course from a "constitutional perspective." Grades: There are two exams in this course, a mid-term and comprehensive final. There are also two required papers. The length requirement for each paper is as follows: paper 1 (5-7 pages), and paper 2 (approximately 15 pages). The semester grade is weighted below : Paper 1 15 % Paper 2 20 % Midterm 25 % Final 40 % * Project Option * Project Option: The project option is open to any student that desires to take 15% of the course weight off of their final exam. If the student chooses this option, their final exam is weighted only at 25% instead of 40%, and the project is worth 15%. The project includes a physical tour of both the National Archives and The Holocaust Museum in Washington D.C., and a written analysis approximately 5-7 pages in length.
    [Show full text]
  • Gadamer, Lavoie, and Their Critics
    Journal of Markets & Morality Volume 19, Number 1 (Spring 2016): 61–78 Copyright © 2016 Gadamer, Lavoie, and Their Critics The Hermeneutics Joshua Lee Harris Debate Revisited Institute for Christian Studies Don Lavoie’s 1985 paper, “The Interpretive Dimension of Economics,” marked the beginning of what would prove to be a potentially groundbreaking but ultimately unsuccessful development in Austrian economic methodology. Reexamining the importance of this project, this study argues for two basic theses: (1) Professor Lavoie’s appropriation of the German philosopher Hans-Georg Gadamer remains a robust philosophical framework for the Austrian science of praxeology; and (2) the Austrian critiques of his hermeneutical project ironically adopt the same epistemic presuppositions that have historically marginalized the distinctively Austrian methodology of praxeology. Lavoie’s hermeneutical Austrianism repre- sents an unfortunately forgotten, yet important development that is sorely needed in contemporary debates in economic methodology. Introduction Don Lavoie’s 1985 paper, “The Interpretive Dimension of Economics,” marked the beginning of what would prove to be a potentially groundbreaking but ultimately unsuccessful development in Austrian economic methodology.1 It was potentially groundbreaking insofar as it was a root-level philosophical reworking of a major school of economic thinking. It was ultimately unsuccessful because some of its most respected respondents happened to be outspoken critics—and vigorously so. Upon reexamination of the importance of this project, the present study argues two basic theses: (1) Professor Lavoie’s appropriation of the German philosopher Hans-Georg Gadamer remains a robust philosophical framework for the Austrian science of praxeology; and (2) some of the most important Austrian critiques of 61 Joshua Lee Harris his hermeneutical project ironically adopt the same epistemic presuppositions that classic figures of Austrianism have consistently rejected.
    [Show full text]