The Implications of Algorithmic Pricing for Coordinated Effects Analysis and Price Discrimination Markets in Antitrust Enforceme

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Implications of Algorithmic Pricing for Coordinated Effects Analysis and Price Discrimination Markets in Antitrust Enforceme ARTICLES Antitrust, Vol. 32, No. 1, Fall 2017. © 2017 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association. Algorithmic Collusion Some applications of antitrust law in the age of machines will The Implications of be familiar. For example, the Department of Justice recently prosecuted two e-commerce sellers for agreeing to align their Algorithmic Pricing for pricing algorithms to increase online prices for posters.2 In that case, United States v. Topkins, the humans reached an explicit agreement to use technology to fix prices. The appli- Coordinated Effects cation of antitrust law to that agreement was straightfor- ward. As algorithms and the software running them become Analysis and more sophisticated, however, coordinated behavior may become more common without explicit “instruction” by humans. Challenging conduct where the role of humans in Price Discrimination decision making is less clear may be more difficult under cur- rent law.3 For example, while express collusion is illegal, mere Markets in Antitrust conscious parallelism is not.4 Separating one from the other can prove difficult even when dealing with solely human decision making. Professor Salil Mehra suggests that the rise Enforcement of “robo-sellers” may make the task more difficult still: a number of current inquiries used to distinguish conscious BY TERRELL MCSWEENY AND BRIAN O’DEA parallelism from express collusion will be of limited use in the machine context. Concepts such as “intent” and “meeting of the minds,” he writes, “presuppose quintessentially human mental states” and thus “may prove less useful in dealing HEN CONGRESS ENACTED THE with computer software and hardware.”5 Sherman and Clayton Acts over a century Algorithms Might Contribute to Overt Collusion. The ago, the term “robot” did not exist.1 The defendants in Topkins used pricing algorithms as an instru- framers of our antitrust laws would likely ment to facilitate a pre-arranged price fixing conspiracy.6 In Wbe amazed by the increasingly powerful and their recent book, Virtual Competition, Professors Ariel autonomous technologies, such as algorithms, machine learn- Ezrachi and Maurice Stucke refer to this as a “messenger” sce- ing, and artificial intelligence (AI) that have come to play a nario: the pricing algorithms were following explicit human significant role in many firms’ competitive behavior. These instructions to violate the antitrust laws and thus merely act- technologies have the potential to deliver meaningful con- ing as “messengers” among the various co-conspirators.7 sumer benefits. For example, algorithms may enable firms to It is worth pausing to consider why the Topkins defendants become more efficient and to provide consumers with per- chose to employ algorithms rather than setting prices and sonalized product recommendations. Big data and algorithms monitoring their agreement directly. Algorithms may facili- may also provide companies with insights that help them tate the stability of certain price-fixing schemes by enabling design better products and services. firms to more quickly detect, and respond to, attempts to But these technologies are also likely to present novel chal- cheat on the collusive pricing agreement. The U.S. antitrust lenges for competition enforcers. We must understand the agencies’ 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines specifically potential effects of intelligent, high-velocity pricing tech- note that speed in identifying and responding to competitors’ nologies on competition and adapt our enforcement approach strategic initiatives is a factor that makes markets more vul- to keep pace. For example, algorithmic pricing might con- nerable to coordinated conduct. Swift competitive reaction tribute to overt collusion or facilitate tacit collusion. It is also times diminish each firm’s “prospective competitive reward possible, as we show in this article, that increasingly sophisti- from attracting customers away from its rivals.”8 cated price discrimination may lead to narrower relevant prod- Margrethe Vestager, the European Commissioner for uct markets, potentially increasing the chances that a merger Competition, recently remarked on the potential for algo- will harm consumers in some relevant market. rithms to sustain cartel behavior: Every cartel faces the risk that its members will start cheat- Terrell McSweeny is a Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission. Brian ing each other as well as the public. If everyone else’s price O’Dea is Attorney Advisor to Commissioner McSweeny. The views expressed is high, you can gain a lot of customers by quietly under- in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the cutting them. So whether cartels survive depends on how views of the Federal Trade Commission or any other Commis sioner. The quickly others spot those lower prices, and cut their own authors thank Nathan Wilson for his thoughtful comments. price in retaliation. By doing that quickly, cartelists can make sure that others will be less likely to try cutting prices in the FALL 2017 · 75 ARTICLES ious features of pricing algorithms may increase market price 21 Competition enforcers must recognize the possibility transparency and reduce reaction times among competitors. But other features of pricing algorithms may enable firms to that algorithms might facilitate cartel formation and reduce transparency and mask their competitive initiatives. Algorithms can enable companies to engage in sophisticated maintenance. A second possibility is that algorithms price discrimination involving a combination of differential may facilitate tacit collusion between competitors. “list” prices and targeted discounts. Salcedo’s paper models a scenario in which firms have “the option to obfuscate their algorithms so they can never be decoded” but his model future. And the trouble is, automated systems help to do finds that, even with this option, firms “would never choose exactly that.9 to obfuscate their algorithms.”22 Competition enforcers must recognize the possibility that The increasing power of algorithms and AI may indeed algorithms might facilitate cartel formation and maintenance. lead to more coordinated interaction but it is too early to say Detection of such arrangements may require novel inves- this with certainty. Future research may prove especially valu- tigative approaches or additional resources.10 From a legal able in this area. If, in fact, new technologies are found to perspective, however, the analysis of the messenger scenario make coordinated interaction between competitors more is “relatively straightforward.”11 Once detected, competition likely, that would provide a strong argument for an enhanced enforcers have the tools to challenge overt collusion. As focus on coordinated effects in merger analysis and for lower Vestager put it, “no one should imagine they can get away thresholds of concern related to coordinated effects. with price-fixing by allowing software to make those agree- Notably, the use of a pricing algorithm, by itself, does not ments for them.”12 raise antitrust concerns. And as the DOJ’s successful prose- Algorithms Might Facilitate Tacit Collusion. A sec- cution of algorithmic price fixing shows, enforcers will be able ond possibility is that algorithms may facilitate tacit collusion to identify and challenge the improper use of these new tech- between competitors. Ezrachi and Stucke describe this as the nologies in many cases. Nonetheless, the potential that pric- “predictable agent” scenario.13 Professor Salil Mehra notes ing algorithms will facilitate tacit collusion beyond the reach that “automated pricing powered by algorithmic processing of Section 1 of the Sherman Act is far from fanciful. Indeed, and mass data collection should reduce the costs to firms [of] the Federal Trade Commission’s authority under Section 5 of interdependent pricing.”14 the FTC Act to prosecute “unfair methods of competition” The analysis closely follows that above, with the focus may be the only current tool available to police individual again on the speed with which algorithms can identify and instances of algorithmic collusion.23 react to changing market dynamics.15 Mehra posits that pric- ing algorithms will surpass humans in their ability to achieve Price Discrimination Markets and sustain elevated prices through coordinated interaction: To price discriminate successfully (i.e., charge different prices “the increased accuracy in detecting changes in price, greater to different groups of consumers), firms must possess some speed in pricing response, and reduced irrationality in dis- degree of market power and there must be factors limiting the count rates all should make the robo-seller a more skillful oli- potential for buyers’ arbitrage. Economists recognize three gopolist than its human counterpart in competitive intelli- main types of price discrimination: (1) first-degree, or so- gence and sales.”16 Ezrachi and Stucke contend that “as called perfect price discrimination, in which each customer competitors’ prices shift online, their algorithms can assess is charged a different price that perfectly matches his or her and adjust prices—even for particular individuals at partic- willingness to pay; (2) second-degree price discrimination, in ular times and for thousands
Recommended publications
  • Antitrust Enforcement and the Consumer
    Many consumers have never heard of antitrust laws, but when these laws are effectively and responsibly enforced, they can save consumers millions and even billions of dollars a year in illegal overcharges. Most States have antitrust laws, and so does the Federal Government. Essentially, these laws prohibit business practices that unreasonably deprive consumers of the benefits of competition, U.S. Department of Justice resulting in higher prices for inferior Washington, DC 20530 products and services. This pamphlet was prepared to alert consumers to the existence and importance of antitrust laws and to explain what you can do for antitrust enforcement and for yourself. 1. What Do the Antitrust Laws Do for the Consumer? Antitrust Antitrust laws protect competition. Free and open competition benefits consumers Enforcement by ensuring lower prices and new and better products. In a freely competitive and the market, each competing business generally Consumer will try to attract consumers by cutting its prices and increasing the quality of its products or services. Competition and the profit opportunities it brings also stimulate businesses to find new, innovative, and more efficient methods of production. Consumers benefit from competition through lower prices and better products and services. Companies that fail to understand or react to consumer needs may soon find themselves losing out in the competitive battle. When competitors agree to fix prices, rig bids, or allocate (divide up) customers, consumers lose the benefits of competition. The prices that result when competitors agree in these ways are artificially high; such prices do not accurately reflect cost and therefore distort the allocation of society’s resources.
    [Show full text]
  • Competition and Consumer Protection Implications of Algorithms, Artificial
    Competition and Consumer Protection Implications of Algorithms, Artificial Intelligence, and Predictive Analytics Remarks at Competition and Consumer Protection in the 21st Century November 14, 2018 D. Bruce Hoffman Director, Bureau of Competition, U.S. Federal Trade Commission Introduction Good morning and welcome to the seventh FTC hearing on competition and consumer protection in the 21st century. This is an incredibly important series of events, and we have fantastic panelists who have important and interesting things to say. It will help us create a record that will be useful for a long time to come. Let me start by giving a couple of disclaimers. First, everything I say today in this brief introductory speech will be only my personal remarks, not necessarily the views of the Federal Trade Commission or any Commissioner. I also want to thank Howard Law School for hosting this event—it’s a pleasure to be here. The other disclaimer I need to give is that this event is being photographed and webcast. It will be posted to the FTC website, and by participating in this event, you consent to these terms. I thought I would start by talking briefly about why we are holding hearings on competition and consumer protection in the 21st century, and why we are doing a hearing on artificial intelligence. I know Professor Gavil mentioned this yesterday, and I’d like to echo the important educational purpose of these hearings. At the Federal Trade Commission, we are very much in study and learning mode on the issue of antitrust and its application to modern and developing technologies.
    [Show full text]
  • The FTC and the Law of Monopolization
    George Mason University School of Law Law and Economics Research Papers Series Working Paper No. 00-34 2000 The FTC and the Law of Monopolization Timothy J. Muris As published in Antitrust Law Journal, Vol. 67, No. 3, 2000 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=235403 The FTC and the Law of Monopolization by Timothy J. Muris Although Microsoft has attracted much more attention, recent developments at the FTC may have a greater impact on the law of monopolization. From recent pronouncements, the agency appears to believe that in monopolization cases government proof of anticompetitive effect is unnecessary. In one case, the Commission staff argued that defendants should not even be permitted to argue that its conduct lacks an anticompetitive impact. This article argues that the FTC's position is wrong on the law, on policy, and on the facts. Courts have traditionally required full analysis, including consideration of whether the practice in fact has an anticompetitive impact. Even with such analysis, the courts have condemned practices that in retrospect appear not to have been anticompetitive. Given our ignorance about the sources of a firm's success, monopolization cases must necessarily be wide-ranging in their search for whether the conduct at issue in fact created, enhanced, or preserved monopoly power, whether efficiency justifications explain such behavior, and all other relevant issues. THE FTC AND THE LAW OF MONOPOLIZATION Timothy J. Muris* I. INTRODUCTION Most government antitrust cases involve collaborative activity. Collabo- ration between competitors, whether aimed at sti¯ing some aspect of rivalry, such as ®xing prices, or ending competition entirely via merger, is the lifeblood of antitrust.
    [Show full text]
  • Hearing on Oligopoly Markets, Note by the United States Submitted To
    Unclassified DAF/COMP/WD(2015)45 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 12-Jun-2015 ___________________________________________________________________________________________ _____________ English - Or. English DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE Unclassified DAF/COMP/WD(2015)45 HEARING ON OLIGOPOLY MARKETS -- Note by the United States -- 16-18 June 2015 This document reproduces a written contribution from the United States submitted for Item 5 of the 123rd meeting of the OECD Competition Committee on 16-18 June 2015. More documents related to this discussion can be found at www.oecd.org/daf/competition/oligopoly-markets.htm. English English JT03378438 Complete document available on OLIS in its original format - This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of English Or. international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. DAF/COMP/WD(2015)45 UNITED STATES 1. Following on our submissions to previous OECD roundtables on oligopolies, notably the 1999 submission of the U.S. Department of Justice and the U.S. Federal Trade Commission on Oligopoly (describing the theoretical and economic underpinnings of U.S. enforcement policy with regard to oligopolistic behavior),1 and the 2007 U.S. submission on facilitating practices in oligopolies,2 this submission focuses on certain approaches taken by the Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) and the U.S. Department of Justice Antitrust Division (“DOJ”) (together, “the Agencies”) to prevent the accumulation of unwarranted market power and address oligopoly issues. 2. Pursuant to U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Mini-Roundtable on Oligopoly
    For Official Use DAFFE/CLP/WD(99)13 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques OLIS : 30-Apr-1999 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Dist. : 03-May-1999 __________________________________________________________________________________________ English text only DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL, FISCAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS For Official Use DAFFE/CLP/WD(99)13 COMMITTEE ON COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY Cancels & replaces the same document: distributed 03-May-1999 MINI-ROUNDTABLE ON OLIGOPOLY -- Note by the US Department of Justice and the US Federal Trade Commission -- This note is submitted by the US Delegation to the Committee on Competition Law and Policy FOR DISCUSSION at its forthcoming meeting on 6-7 May 1999. English text only 77497 Document complet disponible sur OLIS dans son format d'origine Complete document available on OLIS in its original format DAFFE/CLP/WD(99)13 OVERVIEW OF THE APPLICATION OF THE US ANTITRUST LAWS TO OLIGOPOLY BEHAVIOR I. Introduction and Background 1. Since the passage of the Sherman Act in 1890 the United States has sought to minimize the welfare-reducing effects of oligopoly behavior. While early enforcement efforts under the Act focused on eradicating the formal cartels that were commonplace in American industry in the late 19th and early 20th centuries, enforcement officials have devoted considerable resources during the past 50 years toward uncovering and eliminating more covert forms of anticompetitive coordination (both express and tacit) as well as toward analyzing the potential effects of mergers in concentrated industries. The passage of the Federal Trade Commission and Clayton Acts in 1914 added significant dimensions to the enforcement scheme.
    [Show full text]
  • Federal Trade Commission Volume Decision
    FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION DECISIONS Findings, Opinions and Orders IN THE MATTER OF RUSSELL STOVER CANDIES, INC. FINAL ORDER, OPINION, ETC. , IN REGARD TO ALLEGED VIOLATION OF SEC. 5 OF THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION ACT Docket 9140. Complaint, July 1980-Final Order, July , 1982 This order requires a Kansas City, Mo. manufacturer, seller and distributor of candy products to cease, among other things, entering into, maintaining, or enforcing any ageement, understanding or arrangement to fix resale prices for its products; suggesting resale prices, by any means, without clearly stating that they are merely suggested; and seeking information relating to recalcitrant retailers. The respondent is prohibited from terminating, sus pending or taking any other adverse action against retailers who fail to conform to company s suggested prices; and required to reinstate those retailers who had been terminated for non-conformance to designated prices. The order additionally requires respondent to pay for a survey to ascertain what percentage of its products is sold at manufacturer-designated prices, and to cease suggesting resale prices if that percentae exceeds 87. 4%. Appearances For the Commission: Eugene Kaplan, Jayma M. Meyer and Warren Josephson. For the respondent: Lawrence R. Brown and David Everson, Stinson, Mag Fizzell Kansas City, Mo. and Tom Franklin, in- house counsel, Kansas City, Mo. COMPLAINT Pursuant to the provisions of the Federal Trade Commission Act as amended, and by virtue of the authority vested in it by said Act the Federal Trade Commission, having reason to believe that Russell Stover Candies, Inc. , a corporation, hereinafter referred to as respondent, has violated the provisions of said Act, and it appearing to the Commission that a proceeding by it in respect thereof would be in the public interest, hereby issues its complaint stating its charges in that respect as follows: FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION DECISIONS Initial Decision 100 F.
    [Show full text]
  • “Improving Health Care: a Dose of Competition” an Analysis of the FTC/DOJ Report
    “Improving Health Care: A Dose of Competition” An Analysis of the FTC/DOJ Report By Robert James Cimasi, ASA, CBA, AVA, FCBI, CM&A, CMP President HEALTH CAPITAL CONSULTANTS There is continuing debate over Certificate of Need (“CON”) health policy regulations in the various state legislatures. CON regulations require the establishment of need through an application process prior to a provider obtaining approval for the provision of new or expanded health facilities, services, and equipment. Thirty-six (36) states currently have some form of CON regulations for healthcare facilities. The crux of the argument over CON has traditionally appeared to center on whether it has been effective in reducing healthcare costs or has merely limited access to healthcare services by restricting competition and encouraging oligopoly control of markets. Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) and Department of Justice (“DOJ”) Hearings on Health Care and Competition Law and Policy In November, 2002, FTC Chairman, Timothy J. Muris, announced that the FTC would hold joint hearings with the DOJ on competition in healthcare in 2003.1 On July 23, 2004, following the conclusion of the hearings lasting over six (6) months, the FTC and DOJ (“agencies”) issued a joint report on July 23, 2004, entitled “Improving Health Care: A Dose of Competition” in which the agencies recommended that states decrease barriers to entry into provider markets. The agencies encourage states to reconsider whether CON programs “best serve their citizens’ health care needs.”2 Following testimony
    [Show full text]
  • 545095-00006.Pdf (100.94
    FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE/ ANTITRUST DIVISION HMG REVIEW PROJECT — COMMENT/ PROJECT No. P0929900 COMMENT SUBMITTED BY BROUILLETTTE & PARTNERS LLP The comment below is beingsubmitted byBrouillette & Partners LLPa boutique law firm located in Montréal, Québec, Canada founded by attorney and engineer Robert Brouillette. The firm offers legal services to start-up companies developing technology. (www.brouillette.ca.). The comment reflects our views, not those of any of our clients. Daniel Martin Bellemare, attorney at law, member of the Québec and Vermont Bar, has accepted to submit a comment on our behalf pro bono. Mr. Bellemare shares a business address with us. Our comment centers on two questions in the Commission’s Notice. Firstly, whether the Horizontal Merger Guidelines’ (“Guidelines”) five-step analytical process should be revised in order to provide more flexibility in reviewing mergers. Secondly, the weight that should be accorded non structural factors in merger analysis. These two questions are being addressed into a single comment. We are thankful to the Commission for having taken the initiative to seek public comment and for providing us with an opportunity to submit a comment on the advisability to revise the Guidelines. SUMMARY OF COMMENT A clarification should be brought to the Guidelines. For purposes of predictability and efficiency, the Guidelines should emphasize that the merger review process turns around three axes: (i) definition of the relevant market; (ii) increase in concentration within the relevant market; and, (iii) barriers to entry. The relevance of entry barriers in the merger review process must be -2­ reasserted, unequivocally, as the most important countervailing factor to post-merger market concentration increase.
    [Show full text]
  • A Structured Outline for the Analysis of Horizontal Agreements
    A STRUCTURED OUTLINE FOR THE ANALYSIS OF HORIZONTAL AGREEMENTS by Thomas B. Leary* The antitrust principles applied to “horizontal” arrangements are difficult to summarize. The principles have evolved over an extended period of time and have been shaped by decisions that are often hard to reconcile. I do not claim that the structure outlined below is the only way to read cases or frame issues, but it is one that I believe is consistent with the most recent precedent and learning. I. Introduction An agreement between actual or potential competitors to restrain their rivalry in some respect is commonly called a “horizontal restraint.” This kind of agreement should be distinguished from so-called “vertical” restraints that govern the interface between supplier and customers (who may also be competitors in another capacity). The distinction is fundamental because horizontal and vertical restraints are analyzed in different ways.1 The most significant difference is that horizontal restraints are more likely to be deemed illegal per se and vertical restraints are more likely to be subject to the “rule of reason.” * Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission. This revision of a paper first presented a year ago has been prepared for distribution at The Conference Board 2004 Antitrust Conference (Mar. 3-4, 2004). I have benefitted from discussions with FTC Chairman Timothy Muris, General Counsel William Kovacic, and attorney advisors Thomas Klotz, Lisa Kopchik and Holly Vedova in the preparation of this outline, but it does not necessarily reflect their views or the views of anyone else in the Commission. 1 See, e.g., discussion in ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 79-82 (5th ed.
    [Show full text]
  • Essential Facilities, Infrastructure, and Open Access*
    Working Draft for DOJ/FTC Hearings. Do Not Cite without Permission of Authors. Essential Facilities, Infrastructure, and Open Access* Brett Frischmann+ & Spencer Weber Waller++ I. INTRODUCTION There is a debate raging concerning the merits of private control over (or conversely, open access to) various types of resources. Treating something as private property grants the property holder the right to exclude others. Treating something as infrastructure or a commons conversely welcomes all users on a nondiscriminatory basis. The battle over which regime best serves society’s interests exists in numerous areas of the law including land use, intellectual property, regulated industries, antitrust, and most aspects of law and economics. It is currently in vogue to propertize, privatize, and deregulate legal regimes under a variety of rationales all connected with maximizing wealth, supporting price discrimination, promoting allocative efficiency, and internalizing externalities. In intellectual property law, these issues are most prominent in contemporary debates over * © 2006 Brett Frischmann & Spencer Waller. + Assistant Professor, Loyola University Chicago. Thanks to Michael Carrier, Michael Jacobs, Mark Lemley, Christopher Leslie, Frank Pasquale, Phil Weiser and Joshua Wright for their comments on earlier versions of this article. ++ Associate Dean for Faculty Research and Director, Institute for Consumer Antitrust Studies, Loyola University Chicago. Thanks to Lindsay Frank and Jackie Clisham for her research assistance with this project. 1 Working Draft for DOJ/FTC Hearings. Do Not Cite without Permission of Authors. the continued expansion of intellectual property rights.1 The conflict over access and exclusion is a central, persistent feature of intellectual property law. Those who create, invent, innovate, and participate in similar intellectually driven, productive activities often borrow from or share with others.
    [Show full text]
  • Relationship Between Public and Private Antitrust Enforcement, Note by the United States Submitted to the OECD Competition Commi
    Unclassified DAF/COMP/WP3/WD(2015)11 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 09-Jun-2015 ___________________________________________________________________________________________ _____________ English - Or. English DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE Unclassified DAF/COMP/WP3/WD(2015)11 Working Party No. 3 on Co-operation and Enforcement RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN PUBLIC AND PRIVATE ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT -- United States -- 15 June 2015 This document reproduces a written contribution from the United States submitted for Item III of the 121st meeting of the Working Party No. 3 on Co-operation and Enforcement on 15 June 2015. More documents related to this discussion can be found at: http://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/antitrust- enforcement-in-competition.htm Please contact Ms. Naoko Teranishi if you have any questions regarding this document [phone number: +33 1 45 24 83 52 -- E-mail address: [email protected]]. English JT03378179 Complete document available on OLIS in its original format - This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of Or. English international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. DAF/COMP/WP3/WD(2015)11 -- United States -- 1. The United States relies on a combination of federal, state,1 and private enforcers to combat anticompetitive conduct.2 The three enforcement groups play different, yet complementary, roles. Federal and state competition law enforcers have similar missions – to protect the public from the harms flowing from anticompetitive conduct. Federal enforcement seeks to protect the interests of all consumers across the nation or within interstate commerce, while state enforcers focus their efforts on the consumers in their respective states.
    [Show full text]
  • The F.T.C., Oligopoly, and Shared Monopoly
    The F.T.C., Oligopoly, and Shared Monopoly F.M. Scherer Harvard Kennedy School 2013 M-RCBG Faculty Working Paper Series | 2010-07 Mossavar-Rahmani Center for Business & Government Weil Hall | Harvard Kennedy School | www.hks.harvard.edu/mrcbg The views expressed in the M-RCBG Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the Mossavar-Rahmani Center for Business & Government or of Harvard University. M-RCBG Working Papers have not undergone formal review and approval. Papers are included in this series to elicit feedback and encourage debate on important public policy challenges. Copyright belongs to the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use only. The F.T.C., Oligopoly, and Shared Monopoly Faculty Research Working Paper Series F.M. Scherer Harvard Kennedy School September 2013 RWP13-031 Visit the HKS Faculty Research Working Paper Series at: http://web.hks.harvard.edu/publications The views expressed in the HKS Faculty Research Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the John F. Kennedy School of Government or of Harvard University. Faculty Research Working Papers have not undergone formal review and approval. Such papers are included in this series to elicit feedback and to encourage debate on important public policy challenges. Copyright belongs to the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use only. www.hks.harvard.edu THE F.T.C., OLIGOPOLY, AND SHARED MONOPOLY F. M. Scherer September 2013 One of the most important but equally difficult problems faced by antitrust agencies is posed by oligopolistic firms sufficiently few in number that they refrain from active price competition even without entering into explicit price-fixing agreements.
    [Show full text]