The Politics of India's Special Economic Zones Rob Jenkins* Research Colloquium

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Politics of India's Special Economic Zones Rob Jenkins* Research Colloquium The Politics of India’s Special Economic Zones Rob Jenkins* Research Colloquium: ‘India’s Great Transformation?’ Columbia University 14-16 September 2007 WORKSHOP DRAFT – DO NOT QUOTE OR CITE. I. Overview India’s Special Economic Zone Act, 2005 received the President’s assent on June 23, 2005. Well before the detailed regulations that would govern its implementation came into force in February 2006, various government agencies and private-sector actors had begun responding to the Act’s provisions. As of this writing (in August 2007), very little actual construction in those areas officially designated as Special Economic Zones (SEZs) has taken place, and the policy’s economic and political effects are still a matter of conjecture. Even so, there is more than two years of fairly robust policy and implementation history to examine; more than seven years if we include the precursor measures contained within the Exim Policy introduced in 2000. Policy regimes have been formulated in various states pursuant to the central SEZ Act, and these (as well as the Government of India’s own SEZ guidelines) have been revised in several respects on a number of occasions. Moreover, ‘implementation’ (in the form of approvals for the creation of SEZs) has moved forward rapidly. * Professor of Political Science, Birkbeck College, University of London, and Visiting Fellow, Ralph Bunche Institute for International Studies, The Graduate Center, City University of New York. Jenkins Page 1 of 36 This paper assesses the political dynamics that have arisen in the wake of the Act’s passage. Its larger objective is to determine what these might reveal about the politics of economic reform in India more broadly. There are inherent dangers in using a single policy domain to derive generalizations about processes of much broader scope. This is especially true of a policy still in its infancy. On the other hand, if ever a single policy initiative were capable of serving as a microcosm for the politics of reform it would be India’s SEZ Act, which intentionally draws within its ambit such diverse issues as investment (domestic and foreign), trade, taxation, industrial relations, land-use and land reform, environmental sustainability, and others of an even more specialized nature. The Act also affects the policy environment facing state governments; indeed, it requires their active involvement to achieve its objectives. There are implications for the functioning of India’s system of local government as well. The political actors concerned are similarly diverse, including almost all political parties, a huge range of business interests and associations (each concerned with the broad policy framework, and many with an intense interest in rules applicable to their sector), bureaucratic actors with turf to protect, and a staggering array of movement groups spread throughout India. Many of the issues involved in implementing the SEZ policy lend themselves to litigation that will have strong political repercussions, especially where these involve land and taxation. Some cases are likely to be of constitutional significance. Such a multifaceted process – especially one in which the policy regime itself as well as the economic response and political reactions are still a work in progress – militates against the formulation of generalizable findings. Nevertheless, the story of India’s SEZ policy to date would seem to hold at least three important lessons. First, in seeking to manage the process by which the SEZ policy has been introduced, India’s governing elites – indeed its policymaking establishment more generally, which extends beyond those in positions of direct or indirect state authority – have run up against the limits of what can be achieved by practicing ‘reform by stealth’, or by seeking to insulate policymaking from the effects of ‘mass politics’. Second, the political dilemmas that have emerged in the process of trying to implement the SEZ policy highlight an important structural weakness of India’s political system at this stage in the process of India’s economic transformation: the increasing inability of the state to broker accommodations that would advance its preferred policy objectives. This is largely a result of pervasive corruption and a recent history littered with broken promises – both of which, it is worth noting, were integral to the process of reforming by stealth. Jenkins Page 2 of 36 Third, the SEZ policy is more than just another case of businesses seeking to avoid high levels of taxation or to evade onerous regulation. SEZs represent a desire by both political elites and those who aspire to middle-class status to, in a sense, secede from the rest of India – to, in the language of this conference’s framework, escape the consequences of India’s recent ‘democratic upsurge.’ In the eyes of many social elites and middle-class aspirants, the political ascendancy of historically oppressed groups threatens to sabotage the dream of a more prosperous, efficient, and powerful India. That SEZs might offer a way of permitting the inhabitants of this upwardly mobile India to pursue this dream, without the need to emigrate abroad, while simultaneously creating enclaves within which foreign economic influence can be quarantined before spreading to the rest of India, has proven equally appealing to the political wing of India’s Hindu nationalist movement. The paper is organized as follows: Section II overviews the SEZ concept and the policy decisions through which it has taken root in India; Section III outlines the political logic underlying SEZ reform, including how best it might be viewed in the context of existing theories of how India’s reformers have contended with the constraints imposed by democracy; Section IV examines the forms of opposition to which the SEZ policy has given rise; Section V summarizes the government’s response; Section V concludes by elaborating on the three propositions advanced in this introduction. II. India’s SEZ Policy An SEZ is a geographic region within a nation-state in which a distinct legal framework provides for more liberal economic policies and governance arrangements than prevail in the country at large, the intent being to stimulate investment, trade, and employment. Roughly 2,500 SEZs exist worldwide, spread across 120 countries.1 SEZs are, in theory, supposed to attract large volumes of investment by providing world-class infrastructural facilities, a favourable taxation regime, and the benefits of economic clustering. The benefits for the wider economy are, in theory, more exports, particularly in high- value-added sectors, and ultimately an increase in the rate of sustainable economic growth. Employment generation is also often cited as a potential consequence of an SEZ model. In the Indian context, the new SEZ policy can be thought of as ushering in a third generation of economic reforms: while the first two phases were dominated, respectively, by efforts to liberalize the macro policy environment, and by the creation of institutions for regulating a market economy, phase three has a special emphasis on facilitating a global presence for India’s largest private- 1 www.sethassociates.com/special_economic_zones.php Jenkins Page 3 of 36 sector firms and rapidly enhancing the physical infrastructure within which such firms operate.2 Though India did not pass an SEZ Act until 2005, it has been experimenting with the concept since the 1960s. The Kandla Export Processing Zone (EPZ) in Gujarat is said to have been the world’s first. This was followed in the 1970s by the creation of the Santa Cruz Electronics Export Zone (SEEZ), which in the 1980s was expanded to include gems and jewelry. The 1980s also saw the creation of EPZs in Noida, Chennai, Cochin, and Falta (West Bengal), followed by the Vishakhapatnam EPZ in 1994. Immediately thereafter, also in 1994, the policy was revised to permit (in addition to the central government) state governments, autonomous agencies, and private-sector firms to develop and operate EPZs. A private sector EPZ in Surat was the first to emerge under the 1994 EPZ policy.3 But India’s push toward a more comprehensive SEZ policy began in earnest following a visit by then-Commerce Minister Murasoli Maran to China in 2000. Hugely impressed by what he had seen in China’s SEZs – and by discussions with Chinese officials – Maran acted quickly to initiate a change in India’s policy regime. This took the form of new SEZ rules notified in the Commerce Ministry’s Export-Import Policy of April 2000. This produced a precursor of what would later become the 2005 SEZ Act. The 2000 Exim Policy converted the existing EPZs into SEZs. The main difference between EPZs and SEZs concerns comprehensiveness. Whereas EPZs can be thought of as industrial estates, SEZs typically contain the fully array of social facilities – housing, hospitals, schools, retail developments – that make up a small city. Moreover, SEZs are designed to operate on the principle of ‘self-certification’ on tax-exempt transactions, whereas EPZs usually require official attestation. Finally, SEZs tend to be governed by comprehensive legislation, under which far-reaching regulations are authorized, rather than through notifications and orders issued by a range of ministries. Between 2000 and 2005, when the SEZ Act was passed, only three additional EPZs had been established – in Indore (MP), Manikanchan-Salt Lake (West Bengal), and Jaipur. Several states, however, enacted SEZ legislation or developed policy frameworks within the context of existing legal provisions. These included relatively under-industrialized states such as Uttar Pradesh, 2 Second generation reforms is a term sometimes used to denote, in general, all the reform items left over from the first decade or decade and a half of reform. More specifically, it can take on one of three meanings: (1) the politically difficult reforms that have been sidestepped (labour reform, thorough fiscal reform, privatization); (2) reforms that will be more inclusive, reducing the disparities that have given reform an anti-poor image; or (3) reforms to institutions of governance to make the process of continuous policy change more transparent, predictable, and efficient.
Recommended publications
  • UN Habitat Discussion Paper on Special Economic Zones and Urbanization
    Discussion Paper – July 1, 2020 Special Economic Zones and Urbanization Factory workers producing masks for protection against viruses. [Shutterstock/ Pgallery] masks for protection producing workers Factory 1. Introduction – objective of the settings within which to respond effectively to the pandemic. Existing inter-urban inequalities are likely to be exacerbated, paper with the most vulnerable sectors of society, including urban informal sectors, being the hardest hit by the negative economic consequences of the crisis. In a post-pandemic Special Economic Zones (SEZs) continue to be widely used context with a weak global economy and strained government across all regions and seek to achieve different economic resources, the role of SEZs to contribute to sustainable policy objectives, with significantly varying degrees of impact. urbanization will be increasingly challenging but also more Experience has shown that proximity to urban centers is critical. a key determinant of success for SEZs. At the same time, as policymakers seek to achieve objectives related to the This paper seeks to address the link between SEZs and Sustainable Development Goals, the success of SEZs will be urbanization and builds on an earlier exchange between increasingly defined in terms of how they can contribute to experts on this subject in February 2020 at the Tenth Session them and to sustainable urbanization in particular. of the World Urban Forum (WUF10) in Abu Dhabi.1 The COVID-19 pandemic has brought to light some of the 1 Speakers at the UNCTAD-WUF10 meeting Urbanization and the Role of SEZs on challenges associated with increased urbanization, including 11 February 2020 in Abu Dhabi included: Mr.
    [Show full text]
  • An Historical Perspective of Hong Kong, Shenzhen and The
    AN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE OF HONG KONG, SHENZHEN AND THE SPECIAL ZONES IN CHINA by ROBERT LOW A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS in THE FACULTY OF GRADUATE STUDIES History We accept this thesis as conforming to the required standard THE UNIVERSITY OF BRITISH COLUMBIA December 23 1988 © Robert Low, 1989 In presenting this thesis in partial fulfilment of the requirements for an advanced degree at the University of British Columbia, I agree that the Library shall make it freely available for reference and study. I further agree that permission for extensive copying of this thesis for scholarly purposes may be granted by the head of my department or by his or her representatives. It is understood that copying or publication of this thesis for financial gain shall not be allowed without my written permission. Department of HlSToRV The University of British Columbia Vancouver, Canada Date )8 JAti ' W . DE-6 (2/88) ABSTRACT The Special Economic Zones (SEZs) are an important part of China's latest economic development strategy in its long history and drive for modernization. In many ways, they are as much a product of China's past as they are a product of the post-Mao Open Door Policy and economic reforms, and a precursor of things to come in China. Specially designated zones for trade and contact with foreigners have existed in China since the Tang dynasty when China conducted a frontier trade with its neighbours. The Canton system and the treaty ports were subsequent versions of special zones in China.
    [Show full text]
  • Russia's Eastern Exposure.Pdf (PDF, 108.39KB)
    Russia's Eastern Exposure Moscow's Asian Empire Crumbles Originally published at: https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/russian-federation/2015-07- 05/russias-eastern-exposure July 5, 2015 Salvatore Babones Contemporary analysis of Russian foreign policy understandably focuses on Ukraine and the Caucasus, but real drama is unfolding much farther east. Having lost its European empire in the twentieth century, Russia may find that its biggest threat in the twenty-first is that of the loss of its Asian empire. Stretching for thousands of miles east of Siberia, the Russian Far East is thinly settled and poorly integrated into the rest of the country. In 1867, Russia sold Alaska to the United States because it could neither govern nor defend it. Today’s Russia must act soon to prevent a similar scenario on its eastern flank. Until its fall in 1644, China’s Ming dynasty claimed suzerainty over all of what is now the Russian Far East and much of Central Asia. With its own political system lacking the modern concept of sovereignty, China did not establish settler colonies to reinforce its claims to these territories. And so, when Russia began to expand eastward from Siberia into the Far East in the 1600s, it did not encounter any Chinese garrisons. By 1689, Russian presence in the region was sufficient to prompt the negotiation of the Treaty of Nerchinsk, which defined a formal boundary between the Russian and Chinese spheres. In time, Russia grew overwhelmingly more powerful than China. In 1858, representatives of Tsar Alexander II and the Qing Xianfeng emperor signed the Treaty of Aigun.
    [Show full text]
  • Special Economic Zones (Sezs) in Myanmar
    Working paper Special Economic Zones for Myanmar Amit K. Khandelwal Matthieu Teachout February 2016 IGC Policy Note: Special Economic Zones for Myanmar∗ Amit K. Khandelwaly Matthieu Teachoutz February 2016 1 Introduction Myanmar is a developing country that ranks among the most difficult markets in the world to operate a business. Since 2010, the Myanmar government has implemented political and eco- nomic reforms aimed at spurring growth and increasing the country’s participation in the global economy. One objective of these reforms is to bring about structural change that makes Myanmar more reliant on the manufacturing sector. Efforts to advance this objective centre on the creation of Special Economic Zones (SEZs), designated enclaves that facilitate imports, exports and foreign direct investment.1 This report examines the current state of Myanmar’s industrial sector, draws comparisons to its neighboring countries, and discusses the potential impacts of SEZ policy on the economy. A key finding of the report is that even relative to other comparable countries in the region, Myanmar’s economy is dominated by commodity and natural resource sectors. Its manufacturing sector is characterized by low levels of productivity and attracts only a fraction of the foreign investment into the country. According to several metrics, Burmese firms are less globally engaged than man- ufacturing firms in other countries and face particularly high import and export costs. Myanmar’s recent SEZ policy has the potential to reduce these trade costs, trigger productivity improvements, and jumpstart manufacturing activity. While the use of SEZs appear quite sensible in theory, they are costly for governments and success does not come easily.
    [Show full text]
  • Channels of Corruption in Establishment of Special Economic Zones in Ukraine
    CHANNELS OF CORRUPTION IN ESTABLISHMENT OF SPECIAL ECONOMIC ZONES IN UKRAINE by Violeta Skrypnykova A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MA in Economic Analysis Kyiv School of Economics 2013 Thesis Supervisor: Professor Olena Nizalova Approved by _____________________________________________ Head of the KSE Defense Committee, Professor Wolfram Schrettl ____________________________________________ ____________________________________________ ____________________________________________ Date ___________________________________ Kyiv School of Economics Abstract CHANNELS OF CORRUPTION IN ESTABLISHMENT OF SPECIAL ECONOMIC ZONES OF UKRAINE by Violeta Skrypnykova Thesis Supervisor: Professor Olena Nizalova Special economic zones (SEZ) were established in Ukraine in 1998-2000 period. We investigated the influence of oligarchs on the government’s decision for selection of rayons for SEZ program. The research is done on rayon level with probit regression using Mundlak-Chamberlain approach. The evidence for the positive effect of oligarchs’ presence in rayons before SEZs establishment on the selection of treated rayons is found. No evidence is found for the reverse causality checked whether businessmen were attracted to rayons after SEZs were established. To my Mom TABLE OF CONTENTS Number Page Chapter 1: INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................ 1 Chapter 2: LITERATURE REVIEW ............................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • World Investment Report 2019 Special Economic Zones IUre IV IstRical Trend in Sezs MErs O CoNtries An Sezs
    CHAPTER IV SPECIAL ECONOMIC ZONES INTRODUCTION Special economic zones (SEZs) – geographically delimited areas within which governments facilitate industrial activity through fiscal and regulatory incentives and infrastructure support – are widely used across most developing and many developed economies. Although the performance of many zones remains below expectations, failing either to attract significant investment or to generate economic impact beyond their confines, new zones continue to be developed, as governments increasingly compete for internationally mobile industrial activity. Policymakers face not only the traditional challenges of making SEZs succeed, including the need for adequate strategic focus, regulatory and governance models, and investment promotion tools, but also new challenges brought about by the sustainable development imperative, the new industrial revolution and changing patterns of international production. SEZs go by many names and come in many varieties and sizes. They have in common that, within a defined perimeter, they provide a regulatory regime for businesses and investors distinct from what normally applies in the broader national or subnational economy where they are established. The most common types of SEZs are variations on free zones, which are essentially separate customs territories. In addition to relief from customs duties and tariffs, most zones also offer fiscal incentives; business-friendly regulations with respect to land access, permits and licenses, or employment rules; and administrative streamlining and facilitation. Infrastructure support is another important feature, especially in developing countries where basic infrastructure for business outside these zones can be poor. In return for these customs, fiscal and regulatory concessions; business-support measures; and investments in physical infrastructure, governments expect investors operating in SEZs to create jobs, boost exports, diversify the economy and build productive capacity.
    [Show full text]
  • FINANCING SPECIAL ECONOMIC ZONES Different Models of Financing and Public Policy Support Judith E
    FINANCING SPECIAL ECONOMIC ZONES Different models of financing and public policy support Judith E. Tyson September 2018 1 FINANCING SPECIAL ECONOMIC ZONES | DIFFERENT MODELS OF FINANCING AND PUBLIC POLICY SUPPORT Acknowledgements This paper has been authored by Dr Judith Tyson, with inputs from Neil Balchin. Material is taken from the SET workshop held on this topic in Dar es Salaam on 5 and 6 June 2018 and from research interviews. The author thanks those who have kindly given their time to provide insightful and helpful critiques of the paper, including participants of the SET workshop. She gratefully acknowledges DFID support of this paper. © SUPPORTING ECONOMIC TRANSFORMATION. The views presented in this publication are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of DFID or ODI. ii FINANCING SPECIAL ECONOMIC ZONES | DIFFERENT MODELS OF FINANCING AND PUBLIC POLICY SUPPORT ACRONYMS AfDB African Development Bank AVCA African Venture Capital Association CIIP Competitive Industries and Innovation Program DFI development finance institute DFID UK Department for International Development EIB European Investment Bank EPZ export processing zone EU European Union FDI foreign direct investment FDN Financiera de Desarrollo Nacional (Colombia) IDA International Development Association IFC International Finance Corporation IFI international financial institution IMF International Monetary Fund IPDC Industrial Parks Development Corporation (Ethiopia) MDB multilateral development bank PPP public–private partnership PSW Private
    [Show full text]
  • The Development of Special Economic Zones and Industrial Parks Sergey Sosnovskikh
    Available online at www.sciencedirect.com Russian Journal of Economics 3 (2017) 174–199 www.rujec.org Industrial clusters in Russia: The development of special economic zones and industrial parks Sergey Sosnovskikh University of Greenwich, London, United Kingdom Abstract This paper investigates the process of developing and implementing special economic zones (SEZs) and industrial parks in Russia. Governments commonly use SEZ policies to develop and diversify exports, create jobs and launch technology/knowledge sharing. The industrial cluster concept is based on the significance of rivalry and supplier net- works within the cluster, the combination of geographical specificities and government policies that lead to innovation and productivity growth. This study reveals that in Russia the government’s approach in developing these initiatives has strongly interfered with business activities and prevented the vital competitive and collaborative behavior of firms within these economic zones. © 2017 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”. Hosting by Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: F23, G18, M16, M21, O19, P25, P33. Keywords: industrial cluster, special economic zone, industrial park, Russia, state, competition, collaboration, innovation 1. Introduction Industrial cluster policies are a key and widely used tool for economic devel- opment in local and regional economic development planning. Industrial clusters, i.e., groups of geographically proximate companies within a similar industry, are believed to enhance employment, diversify exports and transfer technology and managerial know-how. Crucial elements of the industrial cluster model include the provision of a collaborative and competitive environment, an appropriate geographical location and proximity to resources, related and supporting firms, and state regulations and strategic programs that facilitate innovation and pro- E-mail address: [email protected] Peer review under responsibility of Voprosy Ekonomiki.
    [Show full text]
  • Regimes of Dispossession: Special Economic Zones and the Political Economy of Land in India
    Regimes of Dispossession: Special Economic Zones and the Political Economy of Land in India By Michael James Levien A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Sociology in the Graduate Division of the University of California, Berkeley Committee in Charge: Professor Michael Burawoy, Chair Professor Raka Ray Professor Peter Evans Professor Michael Watts Spring 2013 Abstract Regimes of Dispossession: Special Economic Zones and the Political Economy of Land in India by Michael James Levien Doctor of Philosophy in Sociology University of California, Berkeley Professor Michael Burawoy, Chair The aim of the present work is to advance a theoretical framework for the comparative study of dispossession by explaining how the political economy of land dispossession has transformed from state-led developmentalism to neoliberalism in India. The dissertation compares the archetypical forms of dispossession in each period and argues that they constitute different regimes of dispossession. A regime of dispossession is an institutionalized way of expropriating landed assets from their current owners or users. Each regime of dispossession is distinguished by: 1) a set of purposes for which a state is willing to dispossess land and 2) a way of producing compliance to that dispossession. Under different regimes, dispossession facilitates different kinds of accumulation with variable developmental consequences. These consequences crucially effect the long-term political stability of a regime of dispossession. Between independence in 1947 and economic liberalization in the early 1990s, India operated under a developmentalist regime of dispossession. Under this regime, the Indian state dispossessed land for state-led industrial and infrastructural projects, ensuring compliance through coercion and powerful ideological appeals to national development.
    [Show full text]
  • China's Special Economic Zones And
    China’s Special Economic Zones and Industrial Clusters: Success and Challenges Douglas Zhihua Zeng © 2012 Lincoln Institute of Land Policy Lincoln Institute of Land Policy Working Paper The findings and conclusions of this Working Paper reflect the views of the author(s) and have not been subject to a detailed review by the staff of the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Contact the Lincoln Institute with questions or requests for permission to reprint this paper. [email protected] Lincoln Institute Product Code: WP13DZ1 Abstract In the past 30 years, China has achieved phenomenal economic growth, an unprecedented development “miracle” in human history. How did China achieve this rapid growth? What have been its key drivers? And, most important, can China sustain the incredible success? While policy makers, business people, and scholars continue to debate these topics, one thing is clear: the numerous special economic zones and industrial clusters that emerged after the country’s reforms are without doubt two important engines of China’s remarkable development. The special economic zones and industrial clusters have made crucial contributions to China’s economic success. Foremost, the special economic zones (especially the first several) successfully tested the market economy and new institutions and became role models for the rest of the country to follow. Together with the numerous industrial clusters, the special economic zones have contributed significantly to gross domestic product, employment, exports, and attraction of foreign investment. The special economic zones have also played important roles in bringing new technologies to China and in adopting modern management practices. However, after 30 years’ development, they also face many significant challenges in moving forward.
    [Show full text]
  • A Viking-Age Settlement in the Hinterland of Hedeby Tobias Schade
    L. Holmquist, S. Kalmring & C. Hedenstierna-Jonson (eds.), New Aspects on Viking-age Urbanism, c. 750-1100 AD. Proceedings of the International Symposium at the Swedish History Museum, April 17-20th 2013. Theses and Papers in Archaeology B THESES AND PAPERS IN ARCHAEOLOGY B New Aspects on Viking-age Urbanism, c. 750-1100 AD. Proceedings of the International Symposium at the Swedish History Museum, April 17–20th 2013 Lena Holmquist, Sven Kalmring & Charlotte Hedenstierna-Jonson (eds.) Contents Introduction Sigtuna: royal site and Christian town and the Lena Holmquist, Sven Kalmring & regional perspective, c. 980-1100 Charlotte Hedenstierna-Jonson.....................................4 Sten Tesch................................................................107 Sigtuna and excavations at the Urmakaren Early northern towns as special economic and Trädgårdsmästaren sites zones Jonas Ros.................................................................133 Sven Kalmring............................................................7 No Kingdom without a town. Anund Olofs- Spaces and places of the urban settlement of son’s policy for national independence and its Birka materiality Charlotte Hedenstierna-Jonson...................................16 Rune Edberg............................................................145 Birka’s defence works and harbour - linking The Schleswig waterfront - a place of major one recently ended and one newly begun significance for the emergence of the town? research project Felix Rösch..........................................................153
    [Show full text]
  • Special Economic Zones Public Disclosure Authorized Progress, Emerging Challenges, and Future Directions
    Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized DIRECTIONS IN DEVELOPMENT Trade Special Economic Zones Public Disclosure Authorized Progress, Emerging Challenges, and Future Directions Thomas Farole, Gokhan Akinci Editors Public Disclosure Authorized Special Economic Zones Special Economic Zones Progress, Emerging Challenges, and Future Directions Edited by Thomas Farole Gokhan Akinci International Trade Department Investment Climate Department World Bank World Bank © 2011 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank 1818 H Street NW Washington DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000 Internet: www.worldbank.org All rights reserved 1 2 3 4 14 13 12 11 This volume is a product of the staff of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this volume do not necessarily reflect the views of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgement on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Rights and Permissions The material in this publication is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this work without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant permission to reproduce portions of the work promptly. For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with complete information to the Copyright Clearance Center Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA; telephone: 978-750-8400; fax: 978-750-4470; Internet: www.copyright.com.
    [Show full text]