Behavioral Corporate Finance

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Behavioral Corporate Finance NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES BEHAVIORAL CORPORATE FINANCE Ulrike Malmendier Working Paper 25162 http://www.nber.org/papers/w25162 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 October 2018 I thank Alexandra Steiny, Marius Guenzel, and Woojin Kim for excellent research assistance. The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2018 by Ulrike Malmendier. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Behavioral Corporate Finance Ulrike Malmendier NBER Working Paper No. 25162 October 2018 JEL No. G02,G3,G4 ABSTRACT Behavioral Corporate Finance provides new and testable explanations for long-standing corporate-finance puzzles by applying insights from psychology to the behavior of investors, managers, and third parties (e. g., analysts or bankers). This chapter gives an overview of the three leading streams of research and quantifies publication output and trends in the field. It emphasizes how Behavioral Corporate Finance has contributed to the broader field of Behavioral Economics. One contribution arises from the identification of biased behavior (also) in successful professionals, such as CEOs, entrepreneurs, or analysts. This evidence constitutes a significant departure from the prior focus on individual investors and consumers, where biases could be interpreted as `low ability,' and it implies much broader applicability and implications of behavioral biases. A related contribution is the emphasis on individual heterogeneity, i. e., the careful consideration of the type of biases that are plausible for which type of individual and situation. Ulrike Malmendier Department of Economics 549 Evans Hall # 3880 University of California, Berkeley Berkeley, CA 94720-3880 and NBER [email protected] Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Three Perspectives3 2.1 Corporate Finance and Behavioral Corporate Finance.................3 2.2 Perspective 1: Biased Investors..............................6 2.3 Perspective 2: Biased Managers..............................9 2.4 Perspective 3: Biased Third Parties............................ 11 2.5 Which Perspective is Right?................................ 12 2.6 Where Do We Stand?|Quantifying Behavioral Corporate Research......... 13 3 An Illustration: Theory and Empirics of M&A 19 3.1 Stylized Facts........................................ 19 3.2 Biased Investors...................................... 23 3.2.1 Model and Predictions............................... 24 3.2.2 Empirical Evidence................................. 27 3.3 Biased Managers...................................... 33 3.3.1 Model and Predictions............................... 33 3.3.2 Empirical Evidence................................. 38 3.4 Biased Investors and Biased Managers.......................... 52 4 Key Areas of Research 54 4.1 Corporate Response to Biased Investors and Analysts................. 55 4.1.1 Timing non-rational investor beliefs....................... 55 4.1.2 Catering to non-standard investor demand.................... 59 4.1.3 Media, Attention, and Information........................ 62 4.2 Biased Managers...................................... 65 4.2.1 Overconfidence................................... 65 4.2.2 Other Managerial Biases and Characteristics.................. 73 4.3 Networks.......................................... 80 5 Past and Future Developments, Open Questions, and Conclusion 86 References 90 A Supplementary Material on Quantification of Behavioral Corporate Finance Re- search 105 2 A.1 Identification of Relevant Research Areas........................ 105 A.2 Quantification of Papers by Field and Journal...................... 109 A.3 Detailed Summary Statistics................................ 114 B Supplementary Material on Theory and Empirics of Mergers and Acquisitions 115 B.1 Additional Figures on Stylized Facts on M&A...................... 115 B.2 Additional Figures and Tables on Model and Empirics of Merger Example...... 116 1 Introduction The field of Corporate Finance might well be the area of economic research with the most misleading name (followed by Behavioral Economics as a close second). Many of the research papers identified as \Corporate Finance" deal neither with corporations nor with financing decisions. In this chapter of the Handbook, I first conceptualize the breadth and boundaries of Corporate Finance research, and then present the advances that have resulted from applying insights from psychology. I illustrate how the behavioral toolbox has allowed for progress on long-standing puzzles regarding corporate investment, mergers and acquisitions, and corporate financing choices. Naturally, this enterprise entails discussing the key research questions and developments in the field of Behavioral Corporate Finance. However, the most important contribution of Behavioral Corporate Finance might well go beyond the concrete applications of insights from psychology to corporate-finance puzzles. Research in Behavioral Corporate has been critical to the development of Behavioral Economics in that it was the first to apply behavioral assumptions not just to in- dividual consumers or small investors, but show that the behavioral framework is crucial for our understanding of the decision-making of smart and highly trained professionals who lead large or- ganizations. Even corporate leaders systematically deviate from our standard neoclassical model of rational decision-making and exhibit, for example, anchoring bias, loss aversion, and overconfidence when they make far-reaching corporate decisions. This step constituted a sharp departure from the emphasis in much of the prior behavioral research, which had focused on individuals outside the realm of their professional lives and train- ing. Bad consumption choices, ill-informed personal investment choices, biased expectations about variables the individual is not educated to assess (such as future interest rates), and similar ap- plications tended to be the focus of the existing theoretical and empirical research.1 Corporate Finance researchers have been among the first to argue theoretically and show empirically that top managers and professionals are subject to systematic biases. As such, they have altered the view on what the behavioral toolbox is able to do and why it is important to add psychological realism also to our models of top-level decision making. Two more general insights have emerged from Behavioral Corporate Finance research on high- level decision-makers. First, the evidence on biased behavior of smart and talented professionals implies that successful “fixes” of biased decision-making will need to be of a different nature than 1A notable exception is the study of professional baseball executives, as discussed in Lewis' intriguing book \Moneyball" (Lewis 2004) and analyzed more rigorously by Thaler and Sunstein (2003). They conclude that \the blunders of many [baseball executives] suggests the persistence of boundedly rational behavior in a domain in which market pressures might well have been expected to eliminate them." Relatedly, Romer (2006) analyzes the choice on fourth down in the National Football League, and provides evidence of systematic departures from the decisions that would maximize the chances of winning. Massey and Thaler (2013) study the annual player draft in the NFL and show that the professional scouts persistently overvalue top draft picks. 1 implied by the earlier emphasis on education and financial literacy. For widespread deviations from the standard rational model, such as overconfidence, for example, cognitive limitations are unlikely to be the root and explanations unlikely to be the remedy. Second, behavioral researchers should consider carefully which biases are plausible for which individual in which setting, rather than testing them uniformly in their \convenience sample." Being confronted with the objection that \successful CEOs surely won't be biased," or concerns about the seeming inconsistency of considering investor biases in one paper and managerial biases in another, researchers in Behavioral Corporate Finance had to think hard about the type of biases that are plausible for decision-makers in a corporate setting and how they differ from those consid- ered for the untrained individual. For example, psychological research provides ample motivating evidence to test for managerial overconfidence, but less for underconfidence or cognitive limitations that might be relevant for research in household finance. This focus on specific biases for specific settings is a perspective that is now percolating into other fields of Behavioral Economics.2 This handbook article presents the existing research and open questions in the field of Behavioral Corporate Finance with the intention of fostering its development and influence on the broader field, as well as inspiring further research along these lines. In the following pages, I first present a general introduction to research in Behavioral Corporate Finance (Section2). I distinguish between two main \perspectives:" research on individual investor biases (and managers' response), and research on managerial
Recommended publications
  • Under Pressure: Time Management, Self-Leadership, and the Nurse Manager
    administrative sciences Article Under Pressure: Time Management, Self-Leadership, and the Nurse Manager Elizabeth Goldsby 1,*, Michael Goldsby 2, Christopher B. Neck 3 and Christopher P. Neck 4 1 School of Nursing, Ball State University, Muncie, IN 47306, USA 2 Department of Management, Ball State University, Muncie, IN 47306, USA; [email protected] 3 College of Human Sciences & Education, Louisiana State University, Baton Rouge, LA 70803, USA; [email protected] 4 Department of Management and Entrepreneurship, Arizona State University, Tempe, AZ 85287, USA; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] Received: 6 May 2020; Accepted: 12 June 2020; Published: 28 June 2020 Abstract: Decision making by nurses is complicated by the stress, chaos, and challenging demands of the work. One of the major stressors confronting nurses is perceived time pressure. Given the potential negative outcomes on nurses due to perceived time pressures, it seems logical that a nurse manager’s ability to lead nurses in moderating this time pressure and in turn to make better decisions could enhance nurse well-being and performance. Paralleling research in the nursing literature suggests that, in order to improve patients’ judgement of the care they received, nurse managers should embrace ways to lower nurses’ perceived time pressure. In this conceptual paper, we propose a model to help mitigate time pressure on nurse managers and their frontline nurses based on the research regarding time pressure, psychosocial care, time management, and self-leadership. Three metaconjectures and suggested future studies are given for further consideration by organizational and psychological researchers. Keywords: nurse manager; time pressure; self-leadership; stress 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction Robert Gibbons and John Roberts
    Introduction Robert Gibbons and John Roberts Organizational economics involves the use of economic logic and methods to understand the existence, nature, design, and performance of organizations, especially managed ones. As this handbook documents, economists working on organizational issues have now generated a large volume of exciting research, both theoretical and empirical. However, organizational economics is not yet a fully recognized field in economics—for example, it has no JournalofEconomic Literature classification number, and few doctoral programs offer courses in it. The intent of this handbook is to make the existing research in organizational economics more accessible to economists and thereby to promote further research and teaching in the field. The Origins of Organizational Economics As Kenneth Arrow (1974: 33) put it, “organizations are a means of achieving the benefits of collective action in situations where the price system fails,” thus including not only business firms but also consortia, unions, legislatures, agencies, schools, churches, social movements, and beyond. All organizations, Arrow (1974: 26) argued, share “the need for collective action and the allocation of resources through nonmarket methods,” suggesting a range of possible structures and processes for decisionmaking in organizations, including dictatorship, coalitions, committees, and much more. Within Arrow’s broad view of the possible purposes and designs of organizations, many distinguished economists can be seen as having addressed organizational issues
    [Show full text]
  • History in the Study of Industrial Organization
    History in the Study of Industrial Organization David Genesove Hebrew University of Jerusalem and C.E.P.R. May 13 2016 Preliminary Draft *I am grateful for comments by discussants Konrad Stahl, Chaim Fershtman, John Sutton and Bob Feinberg, and others in presentations at the 2012 Nordic IO Conference, the IDC, Herzlya, the MAACI Summer Institute on Competition Policy, Israel IO Day and the 2015 EARIE Conference. I. Introduction In studying Industrial Organization, economists have at times turned to the past to illustrate and test its theories. This includes some of the seminal papers of the new empiricism (e.g., Porter, 1983). This readiness to cull from the historical record has neither been examined critically, nor accompanied by much of an attempt to follow the industrial organization of markets over time. This paper asks how history can help us understand markets, by posing the following dual questions: (a) what are the advantages and disadvantages of using old markets to illuminate our understanding of current ones, and (b) is a historical approach to the study of Industrial Organization possible and worth pursuing? We are talking about history in two different ways: as the past, and as an analytical approach. History as the past means using old markets in empirical work in the same way one uses contemporary markets, whether that is inductively learning about markets in the “theory-development role of applied econometrics” (Morgan, cited by Snooks, 1993), estimating parameters of interest, or “using historical episodes to test economic models for their generality” (Kindleberger, 1990, p. 3). History as an analytic approach means describing a sequence of events as a logical progression informed by economic theory but unencumbered by it, with room for personalities and errors, and perhaps emphasis on certain events with overwhelming importance.
    [Show full text]
  • Examining the Efficacy of a Time Management Intervention for High School Students
    Research Report ETS RR–13-25 Examining the Efficacy of a Time Management Intervention for High School Students Jeremy Burrus Teresa Jackson Steven Holtzman Richard D. Roberts Terri Mandigo November 2013 ETS Research Report Series EIGNOR EXECUTIVE EDITOR James Carlson Principal Psychometrician ASSOCIATE EDITORS Beata Beigman Klebanov Gary Ockey Research Scientist Research Scientist Heather Buzick Donald Powers Research Scientist Managing Principal Research Scientist Brent Bridgeman Gautam Puhan Distinguished Presidential Appointee Senior Psychometrician Keelan Evanini John Sabatini Managing Research Scientist Managing Principal Research Scientist Marna Golub-Smith Matthias von Davier Principal Psychometrician Director, Research Shelby Haberman Rebecca Zwick Distinguished Presidential Appointee Distinguished Presidential Appointee PRODUCTION EDITORS Kim Fryer Ruth Greenwood Manager, Editing Services Editor Since its 1947 founding, ETS has conducted and disseminated scientific research to support its products and services, and to advance the measurement and education fields. In keeping with these goals, ETS is committed to making its research freely available to the professional community and to the general public. Published accounts of ETS research, including papers in the ETS Research Report series, undergo a formal peer-review process by ETS staff to ensure that they meet established scientific and professional standards. All such ETS-conducted peer reviews are in addition to any reviews that outside organizations may provide as part of their own publication processes. Peer review notwithstanding, the positions expressed in the ETS Research Report series and other published accounts of ETS research are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Officers and Trustees of Educational Testing Service. The Daniel Eignor Editorship is named in honor of Dr.
    [Show full text]
  • March-Ing Towards Organizational Economics
    March-ing Towards Organizational Economics Robert Gibbons MIT and NBER April, 2019 I was a student of Jim March’s in 1983, meaning that I took a mandatory 10- week doctoral class on organization theory from him that changed my life. And I have been a student of Jim’s ever since, meaning that I have tried to keep learning about Jim’s ideas—about organizations and about life. During the course and for over a decade afterwards, most of my academic learning from Jim was about how disciplines other than economics think about organizations. More recently, I have tried to discern how the roots of my own field, organizational economics, often involve Jim. This note focuses on the latter, especially informed by precious summer discussions from 2013 to 2018.* Coase (1937) launched organizational economics by implicitly asking “If markets were perfect, why would we need firms?” An enormous literature eventually developed, greatly deepening our understanding of the roles that transaction costs and property rights play in determining the “institutional structure of production” (by which Coase (1992) meant not just the make-or-buy decision that determines the boundary of the firm, but also contracts and other governance structures between firms such as joint ventures and networks). Today, organizational economics consists of two halves: the “theory of the firm” (focused on the aforementioned institutional structure of production) and the “theory of internal organization” (focused on the decision processes within organizations that, in certain settings, perform sufficiently well to supplant the market alternative). One might ask whether the theory of internal organization has an animating question analogous to Coase’s for the theory of the firm (and, if so, who posed it, what else did they say, and what has become of this line of argument)? The answers I propose rest on Jim March’s collected works, especially March’s (1962) paper “The Business Firm as a Political Coalition” and Cyert and March’s (1963) emphasis on “unresolved conflict” in organizations.
    [Show full text]
  • Guide to Further Reading
    Guide to further reading To follow contemporary debates in organisational economics and organisation theory it is necessary to consult the journals, of which there are too many to list. For organisational economics I would recommend the Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. Of more relevance to this book, in terms of airing inter- and intradisciplinary differences, the Journal of Economic Perspectives is better. The leading journals in organisation theory have increasingly given attention to organisational economics. The most important are: Administrative Science Quarterly; Academy of Management Review; Organization Science; and Organization Studies. In addition, the editors of Human Relations are keen on including interdisciplinary work, particularly from sociologists, economists and psychologists. The main emphasis of this guide is not journal articles but edited collections of readings and introductory books. Starting with game theory, Poundstone, The Prisoner's Dilemma (1993), gives a straightforward introduction to, and a history of, the theory. Avoiding the maths again, Dixit and Nalebuff, Thinking Strategically (1991), gives an idea of the applications of game theory. Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (1990), is not only influential, but highly readable. Neoclassical, managerial and behavioural theories of the firm are all dealt with clearly in Sawyer's excellent little book, Theories of the Firm (1979). For more general overviews and explicit critiques of economics, Galbraith ought to be read at some point, and his book, A History of Economics (1987) is better than the many more scholarly histories of economics. Hodgson's Economics and Institutions (1988) is a more difficult and sustained critique of contemporary economics, but he gives considerable attention to organisational economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Development Through International Economic Integration: Institutional Change to Accommodate Foreign Direct Investment in Brazil and China
    Development through international economic integration: Institutional Change to accommodate Foreign Direct Investment in Brazil and China Henrique Estides Delgado ABSTRACT Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) that was mainly flowing to developing countries before the Second World War, became increasingly concentrated among developed economies since the aftermath of the war. A similar increase in the concentration of other capital flows and trade followed suit during the many decades in which the liberal post-war international order was far from being global. In the late 20th century, increased international willingness to expand global markets was matched by changes in the economic policy of developing countries, originating a process that started to reshape economic geography and reorient FDI flows and other economic flows. Eventually, in the wake of the 2008 global financial crisis, developing countries would again receive the bulk of global FDI flows. This paper argues that the primary reason for the new distribution of FDI is the way that institutional change at the global level interacted with institutional change within countries. As such, this interaction will also define the endurance of this reorientation. To sustain this point, the paper takes the cases of China and Brazil and demonstrates that the change in the incentive structure provided by the international environment around the end of the Cold War and the creation of the WTO, was accompanied by major institutional transformations in Brazil and in China along which greater integration with the global economy was pursued. FDI that was always present in Brazil gained a new relevance, while in China it would emerge during the reform era in a way that is responsible for a large part of the unprecedented growth experienced by the country.
    [Show full text]
  • Time Management and Polychronicity
    Journal of Managerial Time management and Psychology polychronicity 14,3/4 Comparisons, contrasts, and insights for 288 the workplace Received May 1998 Revised October 1998 Accepted November Carol Kaufman-Scarborough 1998 Rutgers University, Camden, New Jersey, USA, and Jay D. Lindquist Western Michigan University, Kalamazoo, Michigan, USA Keywords Individual behaviour, Time management, Work psychology Abstract The goals of this investigation are to identify behaviors and attitudes that are predictive of an individual's polychronic or monochronic time use, relating these findings to individuals' time management approaches. A modified polychronic attitude indicator (PAI3) scale is used as the overall measure of monochronic/polychronic tendencies. A series of potential predictor variables from the ``structure'' portion of the FAST scale, items related to the time structure questionnaire, and other items based on literature synthesis and researcher judgment were used. A stepwise multiple regression analysis resulted in an eight-predictor variable solution. It was concluded that polychronicity is related to different aspects of time management; recommendations are given for future study and for application in the workplace. Introduction Students of time management have attempted to analyze and understand the time use of those persons who want to become more efficient on the job, in their home lives, and in the other activities that they undertake. Through the years, some sets of common precepts have emerged. These include the need for prioritization, the creation and use of lists, and the assigning of activities to particular time slots on an individual's calendar (see, for example, Bond and Feather, 1988; Macan, 1994; Macan et al., 1990).
    [Show full text]
  • C:\Working Papers\11849.Wpd
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INERTIA AND INCENTIVES: BRIDGING ORGANIZATIONAL ECONOMICS AND ORGANIZATIONAL THEORY Rebecca Henderson Sarah Kaplan Working Paper 11849 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11849 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2005 This paper has benefited from the comments of participants in the 2004 Organization Science Conference “Frontiers of OS,” and from the comments of seminar participants at NYU, Wharton, INSEAD, the Stockholm School of Economics and the London Business School. We would also like to thank Robert Gibbons, Michael Jacobides, Bruce Kogut, Dan Levinthal, William Ocasio, Steven Postrel, Jesper Sørensen, Sid Winter and three anonymous reviewers. All errors or omissions remain our own.The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. ©2005 by Rebecca Henderson and Sarah Kaplan. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Inertia and Incentives: Bridging Organizational Economics and Organizational Theory Rebecca Henderson and Sarah Kaplan NBER Working Paper No. 11849 December 2005 JEL No. L0, M0 ABSTRACT Organizational theorists have long acknowledged the importance of the formal and informal incentives facing a firm’’s employees, stressing that the political economy of a firm plays a major role in shaping organizational life and firm behavior. Yet the detailed study of incentive systems has traditionally been left in the hands of (organizational) economists, with most organizational theorists focusing their attention on critical problems in culture, network structure, framing and so on n in essence, the social context in which economics and incentive systems are embedded.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomic Implications of Financial Imperfections: a Survey
    BIS Working Papers No 677 Macroeconomic implications of financial imperfections: a survey by Stijn Claessens and M Ayhan Kose Monetary and Economic Department November 2017 JEL classification: D53, E21, E32, E44, E51, F36, F44, F65, G01, G10, G12, G14, G15, G21 Keywords: asset prices, balance sheets, credit, financial accelerator, financial intermediation, financial linkages, international linkages, leverage, liquidity, macrofinancial linkages, output, real-financial linkages BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS. This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2017. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISSN 1020-0959 (print) ISSN 1682-7678 (online) Macroeconomic implications of financial imperfections: a survey Stijn Claessens and M. Ayhan Kose Abstract This paper surveys the theoretical and empirical literature on the macroeconomic implications of financial imperfections. It focuses on two major channels through which financial imperfections can affect macroeconomic outcomes. The first channel, which operates through the demand side of finance and is captured by financial accelerator-type mechanisms, describes how changes in borrowers’ balance sheets can affect their access to finance and thereby amplify and propagate economic and financial shocks. The second channel, which is associated with the supply side of finance, emphasises the implications of changes in financial intermediaries’ balance sheets for the supply of credit, liquidity and asset prices, and, consequently, for macroeconomic outcomes.
    [Show full text]
  • Authentic Leadership and Employee Health : a Conditional Process Model
    This is a repository copy of Authentic leadership and employee health : a conditional process model. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/171430/ Version: Accepted Version Article: Hildenbrand, K. orcid.org/0000-0001-8185-032X, Daher, P. and Akaighe, G. (2021) Authentic leadership and employee health : a conditional process model. Journal of Managerial Psychology. ISSN 0268-3946 https://doi.org/10.1108/JMP-07-2020-0362 This author accepted manuscript is deposited under a Creative Commons Attribution Non- commercial 4.0 International (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/) licence. This means that anyone may distribute, adapt, and build upon the work for non-commercial purposes, subject to full attribution. If you wish to use this manuscript for commercial purposes, please contact [email protected] Reuse This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial (CC BY-NC) licence. This licence allows you to remix, tweak, and build upon this work non-commercially, and any new works must also acknowledge the authors and be non-commercial. You don’t have to license any derivative works on the same terms. More information and the full terms of the licence here: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/ Takedown If you consider content in White Rose Research Online to be in breach of UK law, please notify us by emailing [email protected] including the URL of the record and the reason for the withdrawal request. [email protected] https://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/
    [Show full text]
  • The Job Demands‐Resources Model: State of the Art", Journal of Managerial Psychology, Vol
    Journal of Managerial Psychology The Job Demands-Resources model: state of the art Arnold B. Bakker, Evangelia Demerouti, Article information: To cite this document: Arnold B. Bakker, Evangelia Demerouti, (2007) "The Job Demands‐Resources model: state of the art", Journal of Managerial Psychology, Vol. 22 Issue: 3, pp.309-328, https:// doi.org/10.1108/02683940710733115 Permanent link to this document: https://doi.org/10.1108/02683940710733115 Downloaded on: 11 February 2019, At: 15:15 (PT) References: this document contains references to 75 other documents. To copy this document: [email protected] The fulltext of this document has been downloaded 91566 times since 2007* Users who downloaded this article also downloaded: (2008),"Talent management: A strategy for improving employee recruitment, retention and engagement within hospitality organizations", International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, Vol. 20 Iss 7 pp. 743-757 <a href="https://doi.org/10.1108/09596110810899086">https:// doi.org/10.1108/09596110810899086</a> (2003),"Workplace dimensions, stress and job satisfaction", Journal of Managerial Psychology, Vol. 18 Iss 1 pp. 8-21 <a href="https://doi.org/10.1108/02683940310459565">https:// doi.org/10.1108/02683940310459565</a> Access to this document was granted through an Emerald subscription provided by emerald-srm:393990 [] For Authors If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for Downloaded by University of the Sunshine Coast At 15:16 11 February 2019 (PT) Authors service information about how to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines are available for all. Please visit www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for more information.
    [Show full text]