The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson VOLUME V THE COLLECTED SCIENTIFIC PAPERS OF PAUL A. SAMUELSON Edited by Kate Crowley • (C A<ri N • THE MIT PRESS Cambridge, Massachusetts, and London, England CONTENTS Volume V Author's Preface xi Editor's Preface xii Part I. Economic Theory 293. "Bergsonian Welfare Economics," in Economic Welfare and the Eco- nomics of Soviet Socialism: Essays in Honor of Abram Bergson, Steven Rosefielde (ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981, 223-266. 3 294. "Reaffirming the Existence of 'Reasonable' Bergson-Samuelson So- cial Welfare Functions," Economica, vol. 44, February 1977, 81-88. 47 295. "When It Is Ethically Optimal to Allocate Money Income in Stipu- lated Fractional Shares," in Natural Resources, Uncertainty, and General Equilibrium Systems: Essays in Memory of Rafael Lusky, Alan S. Bunder and Philip Friedman (eds.). New York: Academic Press, 1977, 175-195. 55 296. "A Chapter in the History of Ramsey's Optimal Feasible Taxation and Optimal Public Utility Prices," in Economic Essays in Honour of J0rgen H. Getting, Svend Andersen, Karsten Larsen, P. Norre- gaard Rusmussen, and J. Vibe-Pedersen (eds.). Copenhagen: Danish Economic Association, 1982, 157-181. 76 297. "Pseudo-Maximization to the Rescue of Derived Factor Demand of a Competitive Industry," in Breadth and Depth in Economics: Fritz Machlup—The Man and His Ideas, Jacob S. Dreyer (ed.). Lexing- ton, Mass.: D. C. Heath, A Lexington Book, 1978, 87-118. 101 298. "St. Petersburg Paradoxes: Defanged, Dissected and Historically Described," Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 15, no. 1, March 1977, 24-55. 133 Contents 299. "Second Thoughts on Analytical Income Comparisons," Economic Journal, vol. 94, June 1984, 267-278. 165 300. "Unattainability of Integrability and Definiteness Conditions in the General Case of Demand for Money and Goods," with Ryuzo Sato, American Economic Review, vol. 74, no. 4, September 1984, 588- 604. 177 301. "Balanced Growth Equilibrium in the General Multi-Class Saving Model," Quantitative Wirtschaftsforschung: Wilhelm Krelle zum 60. Geburstag, Horst Albach, Ernst Helmstadter, and Rudolf Henn (eds.). Tubingen: J. C. B. Mohr, 1977, 569-577. 194 302. "Paul Douglas's Measurement of Production Functions and Marginal Productivities," The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 87, no. 5, part 1, October 1979, 923-939. 203 303. "Rigorous Observational Positivism: Klein's Envelope Aggregation; Thermodynamics and Economic Isomorphisms," in Global Econo- metrics: Essays in Honor of Lawrence R. Klein, F. Gerard Adams and Bert G. Hickman (eds.). Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press, 1983, 1-38. 220 Part II. Marx, Keynes, and Schumpeter 304. "1983: Marx, Keynes and Schumpeter," Eastern Economic Journal, vol. 9, no. 3, July-September 1983, 166-180. 261 305. "The Keynes Centenary," The Economist, 25 June 1983, 19-21. 275 306. "The House That Keynes Built," The New York Times, 29 May 1983. 279 307. "Succumbing to Keynesianism," Challenge, January-February 1985, 4-11. 283 308. "Comment [on Axel Leijonhufvud's 'What Would Keynes Have Thought of Rational Expectation?']," in Keynes and the Modern World, David Worswick and James Trevithick (eds.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983, 212-221. 291 309. "Schumpeter as an Economic Theorist," in Schumpeterian Econom- ics, Helmut Frisch (ed.). London: Praeger, 1982, 1-27. 301 310. "Schumpeter's Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy," in Schumpe- ter's Vision: Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy After 40 Years, Arnold Heertje (ed.). London: Praeger, 1981, 1-21. 328 311. Foreword to Marx's Economics: Origin and Development, by Al- exander Balinky, Lexington, Mass.: D. C. Heath, 1970, xi-xii. 349 312. "The Normative and Positivistic Inferiority of Marx's Values Para- digm," Southern Economic Journal, vol. 49, no. 1, July 1982, 11- 18. 351 313. "Marx Without Matrices: Understanding the Rate of Profit," in Marxism.) Central Planning, and the Soviet Economy: Economic Essays in Honor of Alexander Erlich, Padma Desai (ed.). Cam- bridge, Mass.: The MIT Press, 1983, 3-18. 359 314. "Durable Capital Inputs: Conditions for Price Ratios to be Invariant to Profit-Rate Changes," Zeitschriftfur Nationalokonomie, vol. 43, no. 1, 1983, 1-20. 375 Part III. International Economics 315. "A Corrected Version of Hume's Equilibrating Mechanism for In- ternational Trade," in Flexible Exchange Rates and the Balance of Payments: Essays in Memory of Egon Sohmen, John S. Chipman and Charles P. Kindleberger (eds.). Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1980, 141-158. 397 VI Contents 316. "Comparative Advantage, Trade, and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods," with Rudiger Dornbusch and Stanley Fischer, American Economic Review, vol. 67, no. 5, Decem- ber 1977, 823-839. 415 317. "Heckscher-Ohlin Trade Theory with a Continuum of Goods," with Rudiger Dornbusch and Stanley Fischer, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 95, no. 2, September 1980, 203-224. 432 318. "Summing Up on the Australian Case for Protection," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 96, no. 1, February 1981, 147-160. 454 319. "Justice to the Australians," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 96, no. 1, February 1981, 169-170. 468 320. "Interest Rate Equalization and Nonequalization by Trade in Leon- tief-Sraffa Models," Journal of International Economics, vol. 8, 1978, 21-27. 470 321. "Free Trade's Intertemporal Pareto-Optimality," Journal of Inter- national Economics, vol. 8, 1978, 147-149. 477 322. "Analytics of Free-Trade or, Protectionist Response by America to Japan's Growth Spurt," in Economic Policy and Development: New Perspectives, Toshio Shishido and Ryuzo Sato (eds.). Dover, Mass.: Auburn House, 1985, 3-18. 480 323. "Japan and the World at the Century's End," NEXT Magazine, August 1984, 4-15. (Original English version provided for translation into Japanese.) 496 324. "To Protect Manufacturing?" Zeitschrift fur die gesamte Staatswis- senschaft (Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics), Band 137, Heft 3, September 1981, 407-414. 510 325. "America's Interest in International Trade," in New England Mer- chants Company, Inc., 1979 Annual, 4-5. 518 326. "The Future of American Industry in a Changing Economy," The Journalist, Fall 1984, 3-5, 19. 520 Part IV. Stochastic Theory 327. "Stochastic Land Valuation: Total Return as Martingale Implying Price Changes—A Negatively Correlated Walk," speech given 19 January 1984, University of California, San Diego. 527 328. "Paul Cootner's Reconciliation of Economic Law with Chance," in Financial Economics: Essays in Honor of Paul Cootner, William F. Sharpe and Cathryn M. Cootner (eds.). Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1982, 101-117. 537 329. "Why We Should Not Make Mean Log of Wealth Big though Years to Act Are Long," Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 3, 1979, 305-307. 554 330. "Economics of Futures Contracts in Basic Macroeconomic Indexes: An Economist's Appraisal," Futures: Policy and Prospects for a Dynamic Market. Washington, D.C.: National Journal, 1983, 43-44. 557 331. "Hanging in There," Newsweek, 13 February 1978, 80. 559 332. "Coping Sensibly," Newsweek, 6 March 1978, 88. 560 333. "Gold and Common Stocks," Newsweek, 21 August 1978, 65. 561 334. "Time to Sell," Newsweek, 11 December 1978, 90. 562 335. "No-Fuss Canny Investing," Newsweek, 4 February 1980, 68. 563 336. "Crackpot Investing," Newsweek, 26 January 1981, 67. 564 337. "Canny Investing," McGraw-Hill Economics Newsletter, Spring 1981. 565 vii Contents 338. Foreword to On the Factorial Approach to Index Number Problems, Consumption Analysis and Orthogonal Decomposition of National Income: A Summary, by K. S. Banerjee. College Park, Md.: World Academy of Development and Cooperation, Special Studies Publi- cation, no. 2, 1985, ii-iv. 570 Part V. Classical Economics 339. "Thiinen at Two Hundred," Journal of International Literature, vol. 21, December 1983, 1468-1488. 575 340. "The Canonical Classical Model of Political Economy," Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 16, December 1978, 1415-1434. 598 341. "Noise and Signal in Debates Among Classical Economists: A Re- ply," Journal of International Literature, vol. 18, June 1980, 575- 578. 618 342. "A Modern Theorist's Vindication of Adam Smith," The American Economic Review, vol. 67, no. 1, February 1977, 42-49. 622 343. "Quesnay's 'Tableau Eco'nomique' as a Theorist would Formulate it Today," in Classical and Marxian Political Economy: Essays in Honor of Ronald L. Meek, Ian Bradley and Michael Howard (eds.). New York: St. Martin's Press, 1982, 45-78. 630 344. "Land and the Rate of Interest," in Theory for Economic Efficiency: Essays in Honor of Abba P. Lerner, Harry I. Greenfield, Albert M. Levenson, Wiliam Hamovitch, and Eugene Rotwein (eds.). Cam- bridge, Mass.: The MIT Press, 1979, 167-185. 664 345. "Correcting the Ricardo Error Spotted in Harry Johnson's Maiden Paper," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 91, no. 4, No- vember 1977, 519-530. 683 Part VI. Mathematical Biology 346. "Maximizing and Biology," Economic Inquiry, vol. 16, April 1978, 171-183. 697 347. "Complete Genetic Models for Altruism, Kin Selection and Like- Gene Selection," Journal of Social and Biological Structures, vol. 6, 1983, 3-15. 710 348. "Modes of Thought in Economics and Biology," The American Eco- nomic Review, vol. 75, no. 2, May 1985, 166-172. 723 349. "Comparison of Linear and Nonlinear Models for Human Population Dynamics," with Joel Yellin, Theoretical Population Biology, vol. 11, no. 1, February 1977, 105-126. 730 350. "Fischer's 'Reproductive Value' as an Economic Specimen in Mer- ton's Zoo," Transactions of the New York Academy of Sciences, series 2, vol. 39, April 1980, 126-142. 752 351. "Generalizing Fischer's 'Reproductive Value': Linear Differential and Difference Equations of 'Dilute' Biological Systems," Proceed- ings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, vol. 74, no. 11, November 1977, 5189-5192. 769 352. "Generalizing Fischer's 'Reproductive Value': Nonlinear, Homoge- neous, Biparental Systems," Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, vol. 74, no. 12, December 1977, 5772-5775. 773 353. "Generalizing Fischer's 'Reproductive Value': Overlapping and Non- overlapping Generations with Competing Genotypes," Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, vol.
Recommended publications
  • Paul H. Douglas Interviewer: John Newhouse Date of Interview: June 6, 1964 Place of Interview: Washington, D.C
    Paul H. Douglas, Oral History Interview – 6/6/1964 Administrative Information Creator: Paul H. Douglas Interviewer: John Newhouse Date of Interview: June 6, 1964 Place of Interview: Washington, D.C. Length: 33 pages, 2 addenda Biographical Note Douglas, a U.S. Senator from Illinois from 1949 to 1967, discusses his memories of John F. Kennedy as a Senator and as President, including his work on labor and civil rights legislation, among other issues. Access Open. Usage Restrictions According to the letter of agreement signed February 2, 1972, copyright of these materials has been assigned to the United States Government. Users of these materials are advised to determine the copyright status of any document from which they wish to publish. Copyright The copyright law of the United States (Title 17, United States Code) governs the making of photocopies or other reproductions of copyrighted material. Under certain conditions specified in the law, libraries and archives are authorized to furnish a photocopy or other reproduction. One of these specified conditions is that the photocopy or reproduction is not to be “used for any purpose other than private study, scholarship, or research.” If a user makes a request for, or later uses, a photocopy or reproduction for purposes in excesses of “fair use,” that user may be liable for copyright infringement. This institution reserves the right to refuse to accept a copying order if, in its judgment, fulfillment of the order would involve violation of copyright law. The copyright law extends its protection to unpublished works from the moment of creation in a tangible form.
    [Show full text]
  • National Academy of Arbitrators HISTORY COMMITTEE INTERVIEW Arthur Stark NAA President, 1977 Interviewed by Dennis Nolan May
    National Academy of Arbitrators HISTORY COMMITTEE INTERVIEW Arthur Stark NAA President, 1977 Interviewed by Dennis Nolan May 29,1980 1 ARTHUR STARK PRESIDENT OF THE NATIONAL ACADEMY OF ARBITRATORS 1977 TO 1978 INTERVIEWED BY DENNIS NOLAN AT THE CHICAGO HILTON AND TOWERS, CHICAGO, ILLINIOS MAY, 29, 1989 Dennis Nolan: This is Monday, May 29, in Chicago, Illinois, on the first day of the Annual Meeting of The National Academy of Arbitrators. I am Dennis Nolan and I am interviewing today Arthur Stark, who was president of The National Academy in 1977. Arthur, perhaps you could start us off with some information on your background. Could you tell me, first of all, where you were born, raised, educated. Arthur Stark: Well, I was born three score and ten years ago in New York City. I was raised in Manhattan, on the upper west side. I went to elementary and high school at something called the Ethical Cultures School in New York. We lived across the street from Columbia University on Broadway and 115th Street and I played on the Columbia tennis couirts. I went, are you interested 2 in college, at this point? Yes, you might as well, go on. Since Columbia was so close, I decided to go to College at the University of Chicago. The reason, principley, was that I was interested in labor relations even at that tender age. Looking around the country, there were two Universities that appealed to somebody like me. One was the University of Wisconsin, one was the University of Chicago and I chose Chicago.
    [Show full text]
  • The Institutionalist Reaction to Keynesian Economics
    Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Volume 30, Number 1, March 2008 THE INSTITUTIONALIST REACTION TO KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS BY MALCOLM RUTHERFORD AND C. TYLER DESROCHES I. INTRODUCTION It is a common argument that one of the factors contributing to the decline of institutionalism as a movement within American economics was the arrival of Keynesian ideas and policies. In the past, this was frequently presented as a matter of Keynesian economics being ‘‘welcomed with open arms by a younger generation of American economists desperate to understand the Great Depression, an event which inherited wisdom was utterly unable to explain, and for which it was equally unable to prescribe a cure’’ (Laidler 1999, p. 211).1 As work by William Barber (1985) and David Laidler (1999) has made clear, there is something very wrong with this story. In the 1920s there was, as Laidler puts it, ‘‘a vigorous, diverse, and dis- tinctly American literature dealing with monetary economics and the business cycle,’’ a literature that had a central concern with the operation of the monetary system, gave great attention to the accelerator relationship, and contained ‘‘widespread faith in the stabilizing powers of counter-cyclical public-works expenditures’’ (Laidler 1999, pp. 211-12). Contributions by institutionalists such as Wesley C. Mitchell, J. M. Clark, and others were an important part of this literature. The experience of the Great Depression led some institutionalists to place a greater emphasis on expenditure policies. As early as 1933, Mordecai Ezekiel was estimating that about twelve million people out of the forty million previously employed in the University of Victoria and Erasmus University.
    [Show full text]
  • Paul Douglas, of the Cobb-Douglas Production/Utility Function
    Paul Douglas, of the Cobb‐Douglas Production/Utility Function The Cobb‐Douglas production function was developed in the 1920s by Charles Cobb (a mathematician at Amherst College) and Paul Douglas (an economics professor at the University of Chicago). Douglas led an interesting life: an economics professor, then a war hero in World War II (enlisting as a private at the age of 50!), then 18 years as a US Senator from Illinois. You can read about him at http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Paul_Douglas Note especially the section on military service. The book "With the Old Breed," written by WW II enlisted man E.B. Sledge, has been called "one of the most important accounts of war that I have ever read" by one historian, and "one of the finest memoirs to emerge from any war" by another. The book is about the horrific, bloody battles for the Pacific islands of Peleliu and Okinawa. Substantial parts of Ken Burns’s series The War were based on Sledge’s book. Here's an excerpt about Paul Douglas from Sledge’s book: We hadn't noticed him before he spoke. He wore green dungarees, leggings, and a cloth‐covered helmet like ourselves and carried a .45 caliber automatic pistol like any mortar gunner, machine gunner, or one of our officers. Of course, he wore no rank insignia, being in combat. What astonished us was that he looked to be more than fifty years old and wore glasses ‐‐ a rarity (for example, only two men in Company K wore them). When he took off his helmet to mop his brow, we saw his gray hair.
    [Show full text]
  • Marriner S. Eccles and the 1951 Treasury – Federal Reserve Accord: Lessons for Central Bank Independence
    Working Paper No. 747 Marriner S. Eccles and the 1951 Treasury – Federal Reserve Accord: Lessons for Central Bank Independence by Thorvald Grung Moe* Levy Economics Institute of Bard College January 2013 * Thorvald Grung Moe is a senior adviser at Norges Bank, the central bank of Norway, and a research associate at the Levy Economics Institute. The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the position of Norges Bank. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2013 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X ABSTRACT The 1951 Treasury – Federal Reserve Accord is an important milestone in central bank history. It led to a lasting separation between monetary policy and the Treasury’s debt-management powers, and established an independent central bank focused on price stability and macroeconomic stability. This paper revisits the history of the Accord and elaborates on the role played by Marriner Eccles in the events that led up to its signing. As chairman of the Fed Board of Governors since 1934, Eccles was also instrumental in drafting key banking legislation that enabled the Federal Reserve System to take on a more independent role after the Accord.
    [Show full text]
  • Institutional Economics
    INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS AT COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY Malcolm Rutherford University of Victoria (This Draft: March 2001) This paper draws on archival work using the James Bonbright Papers, J. M. Clark Papers, Joseph Dorfman Papers, Carter Goodrich Papers, Robert Hale Papers, and Wesley Mitchell Papers, all at the Rare Book and Manuscript Library, Columbia University, the Arthur F. Burns Papers at the Eisenhower Library, Abilene, Kansas, and the John R. Commons Papers at the State Historical Society of Wisconsin. My thanks to Lowell Harriss, Aaron Warner, Eli Ginzberg, Donald Dewey, Mark Perlman, Daniel Fusfeld, Mark Blaug, and Walter Neale for sharing their recollections of Columbia. Thanks also to my research assistant Cristobal Young. Any errors are my responsibility. This research has been supported by a Social Science and Humanities Research Council of Canada research grant (project # 410-99-0465). 1 1. Introduction In a number of recent papers I have attempted to outline the nature of the institutionalist movement in American economics in the interwar period (Rutherford 2000a, 2000b, 2000c). At that time institutionalism was a very significant part of American economics. In terms of research output and the production of graduate students, the main centers for institutionalism were the university of Chicago (until 1926 and the departure of J. M. Clark), the University of Wisconsin, the Robert Brookings Graduate School (which existed only briefly between 1923 and 1928), and, after the arrival of Wesley Mitchell in 1913, and J. M. Clark in 1926, Columbia University. Columbia University became the academic home of a large concentration of economists of institutionalist leaning, and other Schools and Departments in the University, particularly Business, Law, Sociology, and Philosophy, also contained many people of similar or related persuasion.
    [Show full text]
  • Medicare and Pediacare: a Fantastic Strategy That Never Matured
    Medicare and Pediacare: A Fantastic Strategy That Never Matured John E. Tropman Abstract: This article surveys the life and work of Wilbur Cohen, an architect of and behind-the-scenes actor in War on Poverty legislation and politics. It focuses specifically on his mastery of the incrementalist approach to policy goals, the quantitative foundation of his work, and his dual role as policy developer and professor which formed his practitioner-academic approach to knowledge and activism during a pivotal point in American history. Keywords: Wilbur Cohen, Medicare, Pediacare, War on Poverty, public policy, incrementalism Wilbur Cohen was a man of the ages; a son of action intellectual, a consummate bureaucrat, and a Jewish immigrants who was passionately committed relentless incrementalist, Cohen was a master to creating a floor of security for all Americans. By behind-the-scenes player who turned legislative way of introduction to the man and his work, let us compromise into an art form. He inhabited a world reflect briefly on a sketch from Edward Berkowitz’s in which the passage of legislation was the ultimate (1995) biography of Cohen, Mr. Social Security: reward. Driven by his progressive vision, he time and again persuaded legislators on both sides of the JFK tagged him “Mr. Social Security.” LBJ aisle to introduce and support expansive social praised him as the “planner, architect, builder and programs. Like a shuttle in a loom he moved repairman on every major piece of social invisibly back and forth, back and forth, until the legislation [since 1935].” The New York Times finely woven legislative cloth emerged before the called him “one of the country’s foremost public’s eye.
    [Show full text]
  • The Midway and Beyond: Recent Work on Economics at Chicago Douglas A
    The Midway and Beyond: Recent Work on Economics at Chicago Douglas A. Irwin Since its founding in 1892, the University of Chicago has been home to some of the world’s leading economists.1 Many of its faculty members have been an intellectual force in the economics profession and some have played a prominent role in public policy debates over the past half-cen- tury.2 Because of their impact on the profession and in­uence in policy Correspondence may be addressed to: Douglas Irwin, Department of Economics, Dartmouth College, Hanover, NH 03755; email: [email protected]. I am grateful to Dan Ham- mond, Steve Medema, David Mitch, Randy Kroszner, and Roy Weintraub for very helpful com- ments and advice; all errors, interpretations, and misinterpretations are solely my own. Disclo- sure: I was on the faculty of the then Graduate School of Business at the University of Chicago in the 1990s and a visiting professor at the Booth School of Business in the fall of 2017. 1. To take a crude measure, nearly a dozen economists who spent most of their career at Chicago have won the Nobel Prize, or, more accurately, the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Eco- nomic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel. The list includes Milton Friedman (1976), Theo- dore W. Schultz (1979), George J. Stigler (1982), Merton H. Miller (1990), Ronald H. Coase (1991), Gary S. Becker (1992), Robert W. Fogel (1993), Robert E. Lucas, Jr. (1995), James J. Heckman (2000), Eugene F. Fama and Lars Peter Hansen (2013), and Richard H. Thaler (2017). This list excludes Friedrich Hayek, who did his prize work at the London School of Economics and only spent a dozen years at Chicago.
    [Show full text]
  • HAUGE, GABRIEL: Records, 1952-58
    DWIGHT D. EISENHOWER LIBRARY ABILENE, KANSAS HAUGE, GABRIEL: Records, 1952-58 Pre-Accession Processed by: JLH and JWL Date Completed: 7-12-73 The records of Gabriel Hauge, Assistant to the President for Economic Affairs, 1953-1958, were deposited in the Dwight D. Eisenhower Library in 1962, along with other records received from the White House. The records are considered a part of President Eisenhower’s papers and are governed by the letter of gift of Dwight D. Eisenhower to Franklin Floete dated April 13, 1960. Linear feet shelf space occupied: -1 Approximate number of pages: 1600 Approximate number of items: 500 Literary rights in the records have passed to the United States as indicated in President Eisenhower’s letter of April 13, 1960. As indicated in Eisenhower’s letter April 13, 1960, the following classes of documents will be withheld from research use: 1. Papers that are security-classified pursuant to law or Executive Order, until such classification shall be removed. 2. Papers the use of which may be prejudicial to the maintenance of good relations with foreign nations. 3. Papers containing statements made by or to me in confidence. 4. Papers relating to my family or private business affairs, and papers relating to the families or private business affairs of persons who have had correspondence with me. 5. Papers containing statements about individuals which might be used to injure or harass them or members of their families. 6. Such other individual files as I, or my representative, or the Administrator of General Services may specify. SCOPE AND CONTENT NOTE The Records of Gabriel Hauge, Assistant to the President for Economic Affairs, 1953-1958, span the years 1952-1958.
    [Show full text]
  • The Art of the Possible: Everett Dirksen's Role in Civil Rights Legislation of the 1950S and 1960S
    The Art of the Possible: Everett Dirksen’s Role in Civil Rights Legislation of the 1950s and 1960s Unable to secure enfranchisement and equality for African Americans through the executive and judicial branches, civil rights proponents turned to the legislative branch in the 1950s and 1960s. The Civil Rights Act of 1957 is often criticized as a weak compromise that lacked definitive power but it was very important because it demonstrated that it was possible to pass civil rights legislation. Southern congressmen and senators prevented any legislation from passing for decades due to their domination of powerful committees and their use of the filibuster. The 1957 act showed cracks in the system. There was another civil rights act in 1960 but southern opponents restricted its scope through the use of the filibuster. Civil rights proponents in Congress learned through these experiences that if they intended to pass meaningful legislation, they had to overcome the filibuster. The tool chosen to defeat the filibuster was cloture. The Senate adopted cloture, also known as Rule 22, in 1917. It allowed sixteen or more senators to file a petition and after a set amount of debate, senators voted and if two-thirds of the members present approved it, the filibuster stopped. The rules changed in 1949 to require two-thirds of the entire Senate. Cloture was difficult to invoke because many senators felt the filibuster was the only tool they had to oppose legislation introduced by a majority. Conservatives and senators from small states were especially wary of cutting off debate. In order to achieve cloture, and ultimately meaningful civil rights legislation, supporters had to assemble bipartisan coalition for a bill.
    [Show full text]
  • By Way of Analogy: the Expansion of the Federal Government in the 1930S
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the American Economy in the Twentieth Century Volume Author/Editor: Michael D. Bordo, Claudia Goldin and Eugene N. White, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-06589-8 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/bord98-1 Publication Date: January 1998 Chapter Title: By Way of Analogy: The Expansion of the Federal Government in the 1930s Chapter Author: Hugh Rockoff Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c6891 Chapter pages in book: (p. 125 - 154) 4 By Way of Analogy: The Expansion of the Federal Government in the 1930s Hugh Rockoff 4.1 Ideological Change and the Growth of the Federal Bureaucracy The major turning point in the growth of the federal government was, of course, the New Deal. A host of programs were added that in themselves ac- count for a substantial share of the growth of government in the twentieth cen- tury, and the propensity to add new programs increased. The New Deal was the result of a unique concatenation of forces: the unprecedented magnitude of the contraction, the political accident that the party favoring bigger government was out of power when the contraction began, and the unique personalities of Hoover and Roosevelt were among the most important. Moreover, as many historians of the Great Depression have recognized, there was an important ideological factor in the equation: intellectuals had already been converted to the cause of an expanded federal sector.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 CHICAGO and INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS1 Malcolm Rutherford
    CHICAGO AND INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS1 Malcolm Rutherford University of Victoria 1. Introduction For most economists the terms “Chicago economics” and “institutionalism” denote clearly antithetical approaches to the discipline. Various members of the modern “Chicago School” have made highly dismissive remarks concerning American institutionalism. Coase has commented that American institutionalists were anti-theoretical, and that “without a theory they had nothing to pass on except a mass of descriptive material waiting for a theory, or a fire” (Coase 1984, p. 230). Some of these attitudes have their roots in the interwar period, most obviously in Frank Knight’s bitingly critical attacks on the methodology and policy positions of institutionalist and advocates of the “social control” of business (Knight 1932). Nevertheless, what this presentation seeks to reveal is a much more complex interrelation between institutional and Chicago economics. To fully understand this relationship it is necessary to begin with the early years of the Chicago Department of Economics. 2. Chicago Economics and Institutionalism 1892-1919 The Chicago Department of Political Economy was begun in 1892 with Laurence Laughlin as its head. While Laughlin was extremely conservative in his economic and political views, and very much at odds with the historicist or “new” school influence in American economics, he built a department that was extremely diverse in its interests and had significant representation of those critical of “orthodox” economics (Nef 1934). Most obviously, Laughlin brought Thorstein Veblen with him from Cornell, and shortly thereafter placed him in charge of editing the Journal of Political Economy. As Hodgson has argued (Hodgson 2004), Veblen’s years at Chicago (from 1892 to 1906) were remarkably creative ones.
    [Show full text]