A Fundamental Property of All-Or-None Models, Binomial Distribution of Responses Prior to Conditioning, with Application to Concept Formation in Children

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A Fundamental Property of All-Or-None Models, Binomial Distribution of Responses Prior to Conditioning, with Application to Concept Formation in Children The Stanford Institute for Mathematical Studies in the Social Sciences APPLIED MATHEMATICS AND STATISTICS LABORATORIES STANFORD UNIVERSITY Reprint No. 70 A Fundamental Property of All-or-None Models, Binomial Distribution of Responses Prior to Conditioning, with Application to Concept Formation in Children PATRICK SUPPES AND ROSE GINSBERG Reprinted from Psychological Review Vol. 70, No.2, 1963 1963, Vol. 70, No.2, 139-161 A FUKDAl\IENTAL PROPERTY OF ALL-OR-i\ONE ::\IODELS, BE\O::\IIAL DISTRIBUTION OF RESPONSES PRIOR TO CONDITIONING, \VITH APPLICATION TO CONCEPT FORlVIATION IN CHILDREN 1 I. PATRICK SUPPES A~D ROSE GINSBERG Stanford University A basic ~sumption of the simple all-or-none conditioning model is that the probability of a correct response remains constant over trials before conditioning. 4 implications of this assumption were tested: (a) prior to the'last error there will be no evidence of learning, (b) the sequence of responses prior to the last error forms a sequence of BerJif\oulli trials, (c) responses prior to the last error exhibit a binomial distribution and (d) specific sequences of errors and successes are dis­ tributed in accordance with the binomial hypothesis. These 4 tests were performed on the data from 7 experiments concerned with concept formation in children, paired-associate learning and probability learning in adults, and T maze learning in rats. The statistical evidence from these various experimental groups provided substantial support of the all-or-none model. However, when Vincent curves were constructed for responses prior to the last error, some of the learning curves showed significant departures from stationariness. In the past year or two there has that the single stimulus element will been extensive application of a single be conditioned to the correct response. stimulus element conditioning model \Ve consider only those situations in' to paired-associate learning (Bower, which the subject is always informed 1961; Estes, 1961) and to concept of the correct response so that the formation in children (Suppes & Gins­ correct association may be learned on berg, 1962). In a paired-associate any trial. experiment the single stimulus element This all-or-none conditioning model represents a stimulus item from a list may be viewed as resulting from im­ of paired associates; in a concept posing special restrictions on more formation experiment the stimulus general models of stimulus sampling element represents a concept, or some theory. The statistics of this model aspect of a concept. The two essential have been analyzed in great detail in assumptions of the model are the Bower (1961). Supplementary sta­ following. First, until the single tistics for a finite number of trials at stimulus element is conditioned, there the end of which not all subjects are is a constant guessing probability, p, conditioned have been given by Estes that the subject responds correctly (1961) and Suppes and Ginsberg (the probability of an error on every (1962). trial is q = 1 - P). Second, on each The point of the present paper is to trial there is a constant probability, c, make explicit a simple but funda­ mentally important fact about the all­ 1 This research was performed pursuant to a or-none conditioning model: the as­ contract with the United States Office of Education, Department of Health, Education, sumption of a constant guessing and Welfare. probability on each trial before condi- 139 140 PATRICK SUPPES A;,-[D ROSE GIKSBERG tioning implies that there is a binomial Consider now how much simpler this distribution, with parameter p, of quantity is if we know whether or not responses prior to the last error. 2 This the subject is conditioned. Let Un observation has three important con­ stand for the unconditioned state on sequences for the analysis of experi­ Trial nand Cn for the conditioned state mental data. First, it implies that the on that trial, etc. Then the condi­ sequence of responses prior to the last tional probabilities are simply3 error forms a sequence of Bernoulli trials. This null hypothesis admits at P ,,(11/ U,,+I) = p2 [2J once the possibility of applying the P n (l1/ U n Cn+1) = p [3J many powerful statistics that are not applicable in the usual learning situa­ P,,(l1/C,,) =1 [4J tion for which the theory postulates dependence of responses from trial to Moreover, except for a few trials after trial. Second, the consideration of the last error when the subject may be response sequences prior to the last unconditioned but guessing correctly, error makes possible a deeper analysis we know what state he is in. In of response data than do statistics particular, on all trials prior to the which are averaged over subjects and last error we know he is in the un­ are a function of the conditioning conditioned state and thus that the parameter c. \Vhen statistics are ex­ probability of two successes in a row should be Relative to the third pressed as a function of c and the data pz. are analyzed in terms of all subjects point above, it may be noted that if the data are summed over subjects, regardless of whether or not they are test of Equation 1 requires the conditioned, then it is often the case that the large number of correct re­ assumption that all subjects have the same conditioning parameter sponses occurring after conditioning c, bias the statistics very favorably in whereas test of Equation 2 does not, and is compatible with the assumption terms of the model. Third, the ob­ of individual differences in condition­ servation that the distribution of re­ ing "propensi ty. " sponses prior to the last error should be binomial permits generalization of the model to admit individual differ­ STATISTICAL TESTS OF THE MODEL ences in the conditioning parameter c, Once the observation has been made while retaining a uniform guessing that according to the model responses parameter p. prior to the last error have a binomial These points may be emphasized by distribution, it is possible to consider considering just one example of a a variety of goodness of fit tests for familiar statistic for the model. Let this assumption. The virtue of these P" (11) be the joint pro babili ty of a goodness of fit tests is that in contra­ success on Trial n and on Trial n + 1. distinction to the many statistics It is easily shown that considered by Bower they permit a genuine statistical evaluation of the Pn(l1) null hypothesis that the model fits the = 1 - [1 - pZ (1 - c) - pc J data. There are four goodness of fit X (1 - c)n-l [lJ 3 There are only three cases to consider, 2 It is easy to demonstrate that it is sta­ namely, Un+1, UnC"+I, and Cn, because Un+1 tist~cally incorrect actually to include the last implies Un with probability one and Cn error in the analysis of response data. implies Cn+1 with probability one. A FUNDAMENTAL PROPERTY OF ALL-OR-NoNE MODELS 141 tests we believe to be of particular where i = 0, 1; n, (t) is the number of importance. In introducing these correct (i = 1) or incorrect (i = 0) four tests, we want to emphasize that responses in Block t; n (t) is the total we are not suggesting they are the number of responses in Block t; lh is only tests or that they are the only the number of correct (or incorrect) interesting ones. It seems to us, how­ responses summed over all blocks; ever, that they do ask the four most and N is the total number of responses important questions suggested by the summed over all blocks. The x2 "guessing" assumption of the model. statistic has the usual limiting dis­ The statistical properties of these four tribution with T - 1 degrees of tests are well known in the literature freedom, where T is the number of and do not need to be discussed here. blocks of trials. If there are m > 2 A good reference for the first two on responses, the number of degrees of stationarity and order is Anderson freedom is (m - l)(T - 1). Under ami Goodman (1957). the restriction to two responses, the Stationarity. Perhaps the most expression for X2 may be simplified to striking feature predicted is that if X2 = L [NnICt) - nln(t)]2/nln2n(t) data summed only over responses I made prior to the last error are con­ thus eliminating the summation over i. sidered, then there will be no evidence Order. The second property follow­ of learning over trials. Statistically ing from the guessing assumption this means the model predicts a which it is critical and significant to binomial distribution of responses test is that the sequence of responses with the constant parameter p. From the standpoint of learning theory this prior to the last error does indeed is a particularly interesting prediction form a sequence of Bernoulli trials, that is, that there is statistical in­ because of the classical emphasis on the mean learning curve. If the dependence in the responses made binomial assumption holds, the mean from trial to trial. There are various learning curve, when estimated over ways of testing this assumption but responses prior to the last error for it seems to us that the simplest and each subject, will be a horizontal line. most direct is to test the null hy­ Empirical tests of this prediction in pothesis that the dependence is zero experiments concerned with children's order versus the hypothesis that the concept formation, animal learning, dependence is first order. Acceptance probability learning, and paired-as­ of the null hypothesis has the strong sociate learning in human adults, are implication that we cannot predict given below.
Recommended publications
  • Zbwleibniz-Informationszentrum
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Cogliano, Jonathan Working Paper An account of "the core" in economic theory CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2019-17 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Cogliano, Jonathan (2019) : An account of "the core" in economic theory, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2019-17, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/204518 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu An Account of “the Core” in Economic Theory by Jonathan F. Cogliano CHOPE Working Paper No. 2019-17 September 2019 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3454838 An Account of ‘the Core’ in Economic Theory⇤ Jonathan F.
    [Show full text]
  • The Winners of the Blue Planet Prize 2009 Professor Hirofumi Uzawa
    The Winners of the Blue Planet Prize 2009 Professor Hirofumi Uzawa (Japan) Lord (Nicholas) Stern of Brentford (UK) 2009 Blue Planet Prize Professor Hirofumi Uzawa Lord (Nicholas) Stern of Brentford (Japan) (UK) Member of The Japan Academy Professor, The London School of Economics Professor Emeritus, The University of Tokyo GIFT: This Blue Planet we live on Is blessed to hold life In the universe full of stars brilliantly shining We humankind Are we spending the days by embracing from deep in our heart? The happiness of being born on this blue planet of life As a tiny life born on this planet Caring other lives, cherishing each other Are we pursuing in full, the meaning of our lives? By truly giving our appreciation To the blessings of the “planet of life” Earth It is our great pleasure If the fi lm this time Served you to think About the happiness of living on this blue planet Selected from the Slide Show Presented at the Opening By extending your thoughts of the Awards Ceremony To the gifts from the “planet of life” Earth 151 Their Imperial Highnesses Prince and Princess Akishino His Imperial Highness Prince Akishino congratulates congratulate the laureates at the Congratulatory Party the laureates The prizewinners receive their trophies from Chairman Seya Professor Hirofumi Uzawa Lord (Nicholas) Stern of Brentford Dr. Hiroyuki Yoshikawa, Chairman of the Selection Committee explains the rationale for the determina- tion of the year's winners Hiromichi Seya, Chairman of the Foundation Professor Ichiro Kanazawa, President, Science Council of delivers the opening address Japan (left) and Mr.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimum Investment in Social Overhead Capital
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Economic Analysis of Environmental Problems Volume Author/Editor: Edwin S. Mills, ed. Volume Publisher: NBER Volume ISBN: 0-87014-267-4 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/mill75-1 Publication Date: 1975 Chapter Title: Optimum Investment in Social Overhead Capital Chapter Author: Hirofumi Uzawa Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c2831 Chapter pages in book: (p. 9 - 26) Optimum Investment in Social Overhead Capital Hiro/umi Uzawa, University of Tokyo Introduction In most industrialized countries, the "environment" has come to play a significant role in recent years both in the process of resource allocation and in the determination of real income distribution. This is primarily due to the fact that, in these countries, the environment has become scarce relative to those resources which may be piivately appropriated and ef- ficiently allocated through the market mechanism. There is no inherent mechanism in a decentralized market economy whereby the scarcity of so- cial resources may be effectively restored. In decentralized economies, most research has been concerned with regulating the use of the environment; few researchers have analyzed the effects the accumulation of the environ- nient may have upon the pattern of resource allocation and income dis- tribution in general. In order to analyze the role played by the environment in the processes of resource allocation and income distribution, it may be convenient to introduce a broader concept of 'social overhead capital," of which the environment may be regarded as an important component.
    [Show full text]
  • Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited
    Seattle Journal for Social Justice Volume 5 Issue 2 Article 28 May 2007 Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited Alejandro Nadal Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/sjsj Recommended Citation Nadal, Alejandro (2007) "Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited," Seattle Journal for Social Justice: Vol. 5 : Iss. 2 , Article 28. Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/sjsj/vol5/iss2/28 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Publications and Programs at Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Seattle Journal for Social Justice by an authorized editor of Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 569 Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited Alejandro Nadal1 After the 1960s, a strong academic movement developed in the United States around the idea that the study of the law, as well as legal practice, could be strengthened through economic analysis.2 This trend was started through the works of R.H. Coase and Guido Calabresi, and grew with later developments introduced by Richard Posner and Robert D. Cooter, as well as Gary Becker.3 Law and Economics (L&E) is the name given to the application of modern economics to legal analysis and practice. Proponents of L&E have portrayed the movement as improving clarity and logic in legal analysis, and even as a tool to modify the conceptual categories used by lawyers and courts to think about
    [Show full text]
  • Involuntary Unemployment Versus "Involuntary Employment" Yasuhiro Sakai 049 Modern Perspective
    Articles Introduction I One day when I myself felt tired of writing some essays, I happened to find a rather old book in the corner of the bookcase of my study. The book, entitledKeynes' General Theory: Re- Involuntary ports of Three Decades, was published in 1964. Unemployment versus More than four decades have passed since then. “Involuntary As the saying goes, time and tide wait for no man! 1) Employment” In the light of the history of economic thought, back in the 1930s, John Maynard J.M. Keynes and Beyond Keynes (1936) wrote a monumental work of economics, entitled The General Theory of -Em ployment, Interest and Money. How and to what degree this book influenced the academic circle at the time of publication, by and large, Yasuhiro Sakai seemed to be dependent on the age of econo- Shiga University / Professor Emeritus mists. According to Samuelson (1946), contained in Lekachman (1964), there existed two dividing lines of ages; the age of thirty-five and the one of fifty: "The General Theory caught most economists under the age of thirty-five with the unex- pected virulence of a disease first attacking and decimating an isolated tribe of south sea islanders. Economists beyond fifty turned out to be quite immune to the ailment. With time, most economists in-between be- gan to run the fever, often without knowing or admitting their condition." (Samuelson, p. 315) In 1936, Keynes himself was 53 years old be- cause he was born in 1883. Remarkably, both Joseph Schumpeter and Yasuma Takata were born in the same year as Keynes.
    [Show full text]
  • Paul Samuelson's Ways to Macroeconomic Dynamics
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Boianovsky, Mauro Working Paper Paul Samuelson's ways to macroeconomic dynamics CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2019-08 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Boianovsky, Mauro (2019) : Paul Samuelson's ways to macroeconomic dynamics, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2019-08, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/196831 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Paul Samuelson’s Ways to Macroeconomic Dynamics by Mauro Boianovsky CHOPE Working Paper No. 2019-08 May 2019 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3386201 1 Paul Samuelson’s ways to macroeconomic dynamics Mauro Boianovsky (Universidade de Brasilia) [email protected] First preliminary draft.
    [Show full text]
  • The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory and Methods
    The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values The first edition of this important work was the winner of the 2002 Publication of Enduring Quality award by the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists. The continuing premise for the book is that estimates of the economic values of environmental and natural resource services are essential for effective policy-making. Like previous editions, the third edition, which includes two additional co-authors, presents a comprehensive treatment of the theory and methods involved in estimating environmental benefits. Researchers, policy-makers, and practitioners will welcome the work as an up- to-date reference on recent developments. Students will gain a better understanding of the contribution that economics as a discipline can make to decisions concerning pollution control and human health, recreation, environmental amenities, and other critical issues concerning the way we use and interact with environmental and natural resource systems. To reflect recent progress in both the theory and practice of non-market valuation, this third edition includes more details on empirical approaches to measurement, expanded discussion of the reasons for divergence between “willingness to pay” and “willingness to accept compensation,” and increased coverage of econometric issues encountered in estimation. In keeping with its cutting-edge orientation, it also includes more discussion of survey design, equilibrium sorting models, and the implications of behavioral economics for welfare measurements and benefit cost analysis. A. Myrick Freeman III is William D. Shipman Professor of Economics Emeritus at Bowdoin College in Maine, USA, and a former Senior Fellow at Resources for the Future (RFF), Washington DC, USA. Joseph A.
    [Show full text]
  • The Stability of Walrasian General Equilibrium with Decentralized Price Adjustment
    The Stability of Walrasian General Equilibrium with Decentralized Price Adjustment Herbert Gintis and Antoine Mandel∗† September 30, 2014 Abstract We study a completely decentralized Walrasian general equilibrium econ- omy with trade occurring out of equilibrium. Prices are fully controlled by economic agents and updated according to an evolutionary learning process. This approach to price dynamics overcomes the failure of a centralized price adjustment process (tˆatonnement) to provide dynamical foundations for gen- eral equilibrium. In our setting, the law of one-price, price-taking behavior and market equilibrium are stochastically approximated long-run emergent properties of a complex dynamical system. Journal of Economic Literature Classifications: C62—Existence and Stability Conditions of Equilibrium D51—Exchange and Production Economies D58—Computable and Other Applied General Equilibrium Economies 1 Introduction Walras (1874) developed a general model of competitive market exchange, but provided only an informal argument for the existence of a market-clearing equi- librium for this model. Wald (1951[1936]) provided a proof of existence for a simplified version of Walras’ model. This proof was substantially generalized by Debreu (1952), Arrow and Debreu (1954), Gale (1955), Nikaido (1956), McKenzie (1959), Negishi (1960), and others. ∗The authors contributed equally to this research. Gintis: Santa Fe Institute; Mandel: Paris School of Economics, University of Paris 1 Panth´eon-Sorbonne. The authors acknowledgethe support of In- stitute for New Economic Thinking grant INO1200022. Antoine Mandel also acknowledgessupport from the EU-FP7 project SIMPOL. We dedicate this paper to Hirofumi Uzawa. He will be sorely missed. †Corresponding author, email:[email protected], tel/fax:+3314407 8271/8301 1 The stability of the Walrasian economy became a central research focus in the years following the existence proofs (Arrow and Hurwicz 1958, 1959, 1960; Ar- row, Block and Hurwicz 1959; Nikaido 1959; McKenzie 1960; Nikaido and Uzawa 1960).
    [Show full text]
  • Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science
    Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science Volume 18 Editors-in-Chief Takahiro Fujimoto, Tokyo, Japan Yuji Aruka, Tokyo, Japan The Japanese Association for Evolutionary Economics (JAFEE) always has adhered to its original aim of taking an explicit “integrated” approach. This path has been followed steadfastly since the Association’s establishment in 1997 and, as well, since the inauguration of our international journal in 2004. We have deployed an agenda encompassing a contemporary array of subjects including but not limited to: foundations of institutional and evolutionary economics, criticism of mainstream views in the social sciences, knowledge and learning in socio-economic life, devel- opment and innovation of technologies, transformation of industrial organizations and economic systems, experimental studies in economics, agent-based modeling of socio-economic systems, evolution of the governance structure of firms and other organizations, comparison of dynamically changing institutions of the world, and policy proposals in the transformational process of economic life. In short, our starting point is an “integrative science” of evolutionary and institutional views. Furthermore, we always endeavor to stay abreast of newly established methods such as agent-based modeling, socio/econo-physics, and network analysis as part of our integrative links. More fundamentally, “evolution” in social science is interpreted as an essential key word, i.e., an integrative and /or communicative link to understand and re-domain various preceding
    [Show full text]
  • Inside the Economist's Mind: the History of Modern
    1 Inside the Economist’s Mind: The History of Modern Economic Thought, as Explained by Those Who Produced It Paul A. Samuelson and William A. Barnett (eds.) CONTENTS Foreword: Reflections on How Biographies of Individual Scholars Can Relate to a Science’s Biography Paul A. Samuelson Preface: An Overview of the Objectives and Contents of the Volume William A. Barnett History of Thought Introduction: Economists Talking with Economists, An Historian’s Perspective E. Roy Weintraub INTERVIEWS Chapter 1 An Interview with Wassily Leontief Interviewed by Duncan K. Foley Chapter 2 An Interview with David Cass Interviewed jointly by Steven E. Spear and Randall Wright Chapter 3 An Interview with Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Interviewed by Bennett T. McCallum Chapter 4 An Interview with Janos Kornai Interviewed by Olivier Blanchard Chapter 5 An Interview with Franco Modigliani Interviewed by William A. Barnett and Robert Solow Chapter 6 An Interview with Milton Friedman Interviewed by John B. Taylor Chapter 7 An Interview with Paul A. Samuelson Interviewed by William A. Barnett Chapter 8 An Interview with Paul A. Volcker Interviewed by Perry Mehrling 2 Chapter 9 An Interview with Martin Feldstein Interviewed by James M. Poterba Chapter 10 An Interview with Christopher A. Sims Interviewed by Lars Peter Hansen Chapter 11 An Interview with Robert J. Shiller Interviewed by John Y. Campbell Chapter 12 An Interview with Stanley Fischer Interviewed by Olivier Blanchard Chapter 13 From Uncertainty to Macroeconomics and Back: An Interview with Jacques Drèze Interviewed by Pierre Dehez and Omar Licandro Chapter 14 An Interview with Tom J. Sargent Interviewed by George W.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 3 the Basic OLG Model: Diamond
    Chapter 3 The basic OLG model: Diamond There exists two main analytical frameworks for analyzing the basic intertemporal choice, consumption versus saving, and the dynamic implications for the economy as a whole of this choice: the overlapping-generations (OLG) approach and the representative agent approach. In the first type of models the focus is on (a) the interaction between different generations alive at the same time, and (b) the never-ending entrance of new generations and thereby new decision makers. In contrast, the second type of models views the household sector as consisting of a finite number of infinitely-lived dynasties all alike.1 This approach, also called the Ramsey approach, will be described in Chapter 10. The OLG approach is the topic of the present and the next chapter. The life-cycle aspect of human behavior is at the center of attention. During lifetime one’seducational level, working experience, working capacity, income, and needs change and this is reflected in the individual labor supply and saving behavior. Different OLG models focusing on the aggregate implications of the behavior of coexisting individuals at different stages in their life have shown their usefulness for analysis of public debt, taxation of capital income, financing of social security (pensions), design of educational systems, non-neutrality of money, the possibility of speculative bubbles, etc. We will here present what is considered the basic macroeconomic OLG model, put forward by the American economist and Nobel Prize laureate Peter A. Dia- mond (1940-).2 Saving and dissaving are core elements in life-cycle behavior and hence also in Diamond’smodel.
    [Show full text]
  • The Core of "The General Theory"
    THE CORE OF "THE GENERAL THEORY" By TAKEO MlNOGUCHI* I Sources of Phllosophrcal Ideas of "The General Theory" It is not difficult to imagine that Keynes tried to make the foundation of philosophical ideas of "The General Theory", before he began to write it. However there are few which treated Keynes in this aspect. Perhaps "The Life of John Maynard Keynes" by Harrod may be the most helpful one. In this section I want to look for the philosophical sources of ideas of "The General Theory" m reference to Harrod and others. In doing so, I think, the central theme may be the infiuences of Cambridge philosophy by Moore, Russell, Whitehead and Wittgenstein on Keynes. I want to seperate them into three categories-ethics by Moore, probability by Russell and Whitehead, and philosophy of logic by Wittgenstein. ( I ) Influence of Moore It goes without saying that Keynes was under the strong influence of Moore as a member of Bloomsbury group. Especlally Moore s "Pnnprcra Ethica" gave him strong nnpact According to Harrod, "Ethica" tells that " 'good' is an attribute, the meaning of which is indefinable" or that "what is good depend on direct intuition in each particular case".1 This doctrine of intuitions "was interpreted-anyhow by those disciples who were to be for many years the intimate intellectual companions of Keynes-as giving fairly complete licence to judge all things anew."2 This ethical view of Moore overthrew the Victorian ethics. According to Robert Skidelsky, the Victorian ethical view was that "he once smoked a cigar and found it so delicious he never smoked again".3 This is nothing less than asceticism.
    [Show full text]