The Stability of Walrasian General Equilibrium with Decentralized Price Adjustment

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Stability of Walrasian General Equilibrium with Decentralized Price Adjustment The Stability of Walrasian General Equilibrium with Decentralized Price Adjustment Herbert Gintis and Antoine Mandel∗† September 30, 2014 Abstract We study a completely decentralized Walrasian general equilibrium econ- omy with trade occurring out of equilibrium. Prices are fully controlled by economic agents and updated according to an evolutionary learning process. This approach to price dynamics overcomes the failure of a centralized price adjustment process (tˆatonnement) to provide dynamical foundations for gen- eral equilibrium. In our setting, the law of one-price, price-taking behavior and market equilibrium are stochastically approximated long-run emergent properties of a complex dynamical system. Journal of Economic Literature Classifications: C62—Existence and Stability Conditions of Equilibrium D51—Exchange and Production Economies D58—Computable and Other Applied General Equilibrium Economies 1 Introduction Walras (1874) developed a general model of competitive market exchange, but provided only an informal argument for the existence of a market-clearing equi- librium for this model. Wald (1951[1936]) provided a proof of existence for a simplified version of Walras’ model. This proof was substantially generalized by Debreu (1952), Arrow and Debreu (1954), Gale (1955), Nikaido (1956), McKenzie (1959), Negishi (1960), and others. ∗The authors contributed equally to this research. Gintis: Santa Fe Institute; Mandel: Paris School of Economics, University of Paris 1 Panth´eon-Sorbonne. The authors acknowledgethe support of In- stitute for New Economic Thinking grant INO1200022. Antoine Mandel also acknowledgessupport from the EU-FP7 project SIMPOL. We dedicate this paper to Hirofumi Uzawa. He will be sorely missed. †Corresponding author, email:[email protected], tel/fax:+3314407 8271/8301 1 The stability of the Walrasian economy became a central research focus in the years following the existence proofs (Arrow and Hurwicz 1958, 1959, 1960; Ar- row, Block and Hurwicz 1959; Nikaido 1959; McKenzie 1960; Nikaido and Uzawa 1960). Following Walras’ tˆatonnement process, these models assumed that there is no production or trade until equilibriumprices are attained, and out of equilibrium, there is a price profile shared by all agents (we call these public prices), the time rate of change of which is a function of excess demand. These efforts were largely unsuccessful (Fisher 1983). A novel approach to the dynamics of large-scale social systems, evolutionary game theory, was initiated by Maynard Smith and Price (1973), and adapted to dynamical systems theory in subsequent years (Taylor and Jonker 1978, Friedman 1991, Weibull 1995). The application of these models to economics involved the shift from genetic transmission to behavioral imitation as the mechanism for the replication of successful agents. Several authors have investigated market dynamics through this evolutionary lens. Vega-Redondo (1997) analyzes the convergence to the Walrasian outcome in a Cournot oligopoly where firms update quantities in an evolutionary fashion, Al´os–Ferrer et al. (2000) provide an evolutionary model of Bertrand competition, Serrano and Volij (2008) study the stability of the Walrasian outcome in markets for indivisible goods, and a number of contributions, including Mandel and Botta 2009, 2011, investigate evolutionary dynamics in specific exchange economies. We here assume a decentralized price adjustment process in which each agent in each period has complete control of the relative prices at which he is willing to trade. We treat an exchange economy as the stage game of an evolutionary process in which each agent’s initial inventory is replenished in each period, agents enter into a series of bilateral trades, at the end of which each agent consumes his final inventory. There are no inter-period exchanges. An agent’s trade strategy consists of a vector of private prices for the goods he produces and the goods he consumes, such that, according to the individual’s private prices, a trade is acceptable if the value of goods received is at least as great as the value of the goods offered in exchange. This representation of the exchange process has strong commonalities with the strategic bargaining literature, and in particular Rubinstein and Wolinsky (1985,1990), Gale (1986) and Binmore and Herrero (1988). In our model, competition is effective because when there is excess supply in one period, a seller who failed to secure a transaction can gain by slightly under- cutting his competitors’ prices. Similarly, when there is excess demand, a buyer who failed to secure a transaction increases utility by slightly outbidding his com- petitors. When markets are in disequilibrium, then, there always exist agents who stand to gain by altering their prices. Under rather mild conditions on the trad- 2 ing process, market-clearing equilibria are the only Nash equilibria of our market system, and these equilibria are strict. Thus, if we assume that the strategies of traders are updated according to a monotone dynamic, the stability of equilibrium is guaranteed (Weibull 1995). The intuition as to why decentralized pricing entails a stable equilibrium while the centralized tˆatonnement price adjustment process doesnotisthata smallchange in the private price vector for one agent has effects only for the few agents with whom he interacts, whereas a small change in publicprices impacts upon all agents in the economy and leads all buyers, respectively all sellers, to react in the same direction, producing significant macroeconomic effects. We illustrate this in Sec- tion 4. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces our model economy. Section 3 defines a class of bargaining games based on private prices in this econ- omy for which we provide an example in Section 4. Section 5 proves the stability of equilibrium assuming that each agent’s set of consumption goods is given inde- pendent of relative prices, and Section 6 extends this result to an arbitrary exchange economy. Section 7 discusses in greater detail the necessary conditions for compe- tition to entail a stable price adjustment process. 2 The Walrasian Economy We consider an economy with a goods h = 1,...,l, and agents i = 1,...,m. Rl R Each agent i has consumption set X = +, a utility function ui: X → + and an initial endowment ei = (ei1,...,eil) ∈ X . We denote this economy by E(u, e), where e =(e1,...,em). We use the following concepts. • The set of allocations is X m. An allocation x ∈ X m of goods is feasible if m m X xih ≤ X eih for h =1,...l. i=1 i=1 m We write A(e1,...,em) = A(e) ⊂ X for the set of feasible allocations. Rl • The set of prices is P ⊂ +. We assume strictly concave utility functions, so the demand of agent i is a mapping di : P × R+ → X that associates to a price p ∈ P and an income w ∈ R+ the unique utility-maximizing allocation: di(p,w) = argmax{u(x) x ∈ X ,p · x ≤ w}. 3 • A feasible allocation x ∈ A(e) is an equilibrium allocation if there exists a price p such that for all i, xi = di(p,p · ei). The price p is then called an equilibrium price. We denote the set of equilibrium prices by Pequi(u, e). If Pequi(u, e) is finite, we assume it is a subset of P . • A feasible allocation x ∈ A(e) and a price p ∈P form a quasi-equilibrium (p, e) if for all yi ∈ X , ui(yi) > ui(xi) implies p · yi >p · xi. To ensure the existence of a quasi-equilibrium, we assume that utility functions satisfy the following standard conditions. The strict concavity assumption is not necessary for the existence of a quasi-equilibrium but implies demand mappings are single-valued, which will prove useful below. Assumption 1 (Utility) For all i = 1,...,m, ui is continuous, strictly concave, and locally non-satiated. To ensure that every quasi-equilibrium is an equilibrium allocation, it suffices to assume that at a quasi-equilibrium, agents do not receive the minimal possi- ble income (Hammond 1993, Florenzano 2005). This condition is satisfied when all initial endowments are in the interior of the consumption set, as well as in set- tings with corner endowments such as those investigatedin Scarf (1960) and Gintis (2007). Formally, the assumption can be stated as follows. Assumption 2 (Income) For every quasi-equilibrium (p,x), and for every agent i, there exists an allocation yi such that p · xi >p · yi. Assumptions 1 and 2 imply that the economy E(u, e) has at least one equilibrium (Florenzano 2005). We restrict attention to the generic case where the set Pequi of equilibria is finite (Balasco 2009). 3 Exchange Processes with Private Prices Each agent i has a strategy consistingof a private price vector pi ∈P representing the prices at which he is willing to sell the goods he supplies to the market and the maximum prices he is willing to pay for the goods he demands. We associate with the economy E(u, e) the class of games G(u, e, ξ) where: • Each agent i has a finite strategy set Pi ⊂P. The set of strategy profiles for the game is P = P1 × ... × Pm. • There is an exchange mechanism ξ : P→A(e) that associates with π ∈ P a feasible allocation ξ(π)=(ξ1(π),...,ξm(π)) ∈ A(e). 4 • The payoff of player i given strategy profile π is ui(ξi(π)). Many exchange processes satisfy these conditions, including double auctions and simultaneous, multilateral exchanges (Grandmont 1977, B´enassy 2005), as well as sequences of bilateral trades such as those considered by Gintis (2007, 2012). The following example illustrates how such a process can induce converging price dynamics in the Scarf economy, which is a well-known example of the instability of the tˆatonnement process (Scarf 1960). 4 The Scarfeconomy We consider the Scarf economy (Scarf 1960) with three goods (` = 3) and three types ofagents (m =3).
Recommended publications
  • Zbwleibniz-Informationszentrum
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Cogliano, Jonathan Working Paper An account of "the core" in economic theory CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2019-17 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Cogliano, Jonathan (2019) : An account of "the core" in economic theory, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2019-17, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/204518 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu An Account of “the Core” in Economic Theory by Jonathan F. Cogliano CHOPE Working Paper No. 2019-17 September 2019 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3454838 An Account of ‘the Core’ in Economic Theory⇤ Jonathan F.
    [Show full text]
  • The Winners of the Blue Planet Prize 2009 Professor Hirofumi Uzawa
    The Winners of the Blue Planet Prize 2009 Professor Hirofumi Uzawa (Japan) Lord (Nicholas) Stern of Brentford (UK) 2009 Blue Planet Prize Professor Hirofumi Uzawa Lord (Nicholas) Stern of Brentford (Japan) (UK) Member of The Japan Academy Professor, The London School of Economics Professor Emeritus, The University of Tokyo GIFT: This Blue Planet we live on Is blessed to hold life In the universe full of stars brilliantly shining We humankind Are we spending the days by embracing from deep in our heart? The happiness of being born on this blue planet of life As a tiny life born on this planet Caring other lives, cherishing each other Are we pursuing in full, the meaning of our lives? By truly giving our appreciation To the blessings of the “planet of life” Earth It is our great pleasure If the fi lm this time Served you to think About the happiness of living on this blue planet Selected from the Slide Show Presented at the Opening By extending your thoughts of the Awards Ceremony To the gifts from the “planet of life” Earth 151 Their Imperial Highnesses Prince and Princess Akishino His Imperial Highness Prince Akishino congratulates congratulate the laureates at the Congratulatory Party the laureates The prizewinners receive their trophies from Chairman Seya Professor Hirofumi Uzawa Lord (Nicholas) Stern of Brentford Dr. Hiroyuki Yoshikawa, Chairman of the Selection Committee explains the rationale for the determina- tion of the year's winners Hiromichi Seya, Chairman of the Foundation Professor Ichiro Kanazawa, President, Science Council of delivers the opening address Japan (left) and Mr.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimum Investment in Social Overhead Capital
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Economic Analysis of Environmental Problems Volume Author/Editor: Edwin S. Mills, ed. Volume Publisher: NBER Volume ISBN: 0-87014-267-4 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/mill75-1 Publication Date: 1975 Chapter Title: Optimum Investment in Social Overhead Capital Chapter Author: Hirofumi Uzawa Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c2831 Chapter pages in book: (p. 9 - 26) Optimum Investment in Social Overhead Capital Hiro/umi Uzawa, University of Tokyo Introduction In most industrialized countries, the "environment" has come to play a significant role in recent years both in the process of resource allocation and in the determination of real income distribution. This is primarily due to the fact that, in these countries, the environment has become scarce relative to those resources which may be piivately appropriated and ef- ficiently allocated through the market mechanism. There is no inherent mechanism in a decentralized market economy whereby the scarcity of so- cial resources may be effectively restored. In decentralized economies, most research has been concerned with regulating the use of the environment; few researchers have analyzed the effects the accumulation of the environ- nient may have upon the pattern of resource allocation and income dis- tribution in general. In order to analyze the role played by the environment in the processes of resource allocation and income distribution, it may be convenient to introduce a broader concept of 'social overhead capital," of which the environment may be regarded as an important component.
    [Show full text]
  • Involuntary Unemployment Versus "Involuntary Employment" Yasuhiro Sakai 049 Modern Perspective
    Articles Introduction I One day when I myself felt tired of writing some essays, I happened to find a rather old book in the corner of the bookcase of my study. The book, entitledKeynes' General Theory: Re- Involuntary ports of Three Decades, was published in 1964. Unemployment versus More than four decades have passed since then. “Involuntary As the saying goes, time and tide wait for no man! 1) Employment” In the light of the history of economic thought, back in the 1930s, John Maynard J.M. Keynes and Beyond Keynes (1936) wrote a monumental work of economics, entitled The General Theory of -Em ployment, Interest and Money. How and to what degree this book influenced the academic circle at the time of publication, by and large, Yasuhiro Sakai seemed to be dependent on the age of econo- Shiga University / Professor Emeritus mists. According to Samuelson (1946), contained in Lekachman (1964), there existed two dividing lines of ages; the age of thirty-five and the one of fifty: "The General Theory caught most economists under the age of thirty-five with the unex- pected virulence of a disease first attacking and decimating an isolated tribe of south sea islanders. Economists beyond fifty turned out to be quite immune to the ailment. With time, most economists in-between be- gan to run the fever, often without knowing or admitting their condition." (Samuelson, p. 315) In 1936, Keynes himself was 53 years old be- cause he was born in 1883. Remarkably, both Joseph Schumpeter and Yasuma Takata were born in the same year as Keynes.
    [Show full text]
  • The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory and Methods
    The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values The first edition of this important work was the winner of the 2002 Publication of Enduring Quality award by the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists. The continuing premise for the book is that estimates of the economic values of environmental and natural resource services are essential for effective policy-making. Like previous editions, the third edition, which includes two additional co-authors, presents a comprehensive treatment of the theory and methods involved in estimating environmental benefits. Researchers, policy-makers, and practitioners will welcome the work as an up- to-date reference on recent developments. Students will gain a better understanding of the contribution that economics as a discipline can make to decisions concerning pollution control and human health, recreation, environmental amenities, and other critical issues concerning the way we use and interact with environmental and natural resource systems. To reflect recent progress in both the theory and practice of non-market valuation, this third edition includes more details on empirical approaches to measurement, expanded discussion of the reasons for divergence between “willingness to pay” and “willingness to accept compensation,” and increased coverage of econometric issues encountered in estimation. In keeping with its cutting-edge orientation, it also includes more discussion of survey design, equilibrium sorting models, and the implications of behavioral economics for welfare measurements and benefit cost analysis. A. Myrick Freeman III is William D. Shipman Professor of Economics Emeritus at Bowdoin College in Maine, USA, and a former Senior Fellow at Resources for the Future (RFF), Washington DC, USA. Joseph A.
    [Show full text]
  • Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science
    Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science Volume 18 Editors-in-Chief Takahiro Fujimoto, Tokyo, Japan Yuji Aruka, Tokyo, Japan The Japanese Association for Evolutionary Economics (JAFEE) always has adhered to its original aim of taking an explicit “integrated” approach. This path has been followed steadfastly since the Association’s establishment in 1997 and, as well, since the inauguration of our international journal in 2004. We have deployed an agenda encompassing a contemporary array of subjects including but not limited to: foundations of institutional and evolutionary economics, criticism of mainstream views in the social sciences, knowledge and learning in socio-economic life, devel- opment and innovation of technologies, transformation of industrial organizations and economic systems, experimental studies in economics, agent-based modeling of socio-economic systems, evolution of the governance structure of firms and other organizations, comparison of dynamically changing institutions of the world, and policy proposals in the transformational process of economic life. In short, our starting point is an “integrative science” of evolutionary and institutional views. Furthermore, we always endeavor to stay abreast of newly established methods such as agent-based modeling, socio/econo-physics, and network analysis as part of our integrative links. More fundamentally, “evolution” in social science is interpreted as an essential key word, i.e., an integrative and /or communicative link to understand and re-domain various preceding
    [Show full text]
  • Inside the Economist's Mind: the History of Modern
    1 Inside the Economist’s Mind: The History of Modern Economic Thought, as Explained by Those Who Produced It Paul A. Samuelson and William A. Barnett (eds.) CONTENTS Foreword: Reflections on How Biographies of Individual Scholars Can Relate to a Science’s Biography Paul A. Samuelson Preface: An Overview of the Objectives and Contents of the Volume William A. Barnett History of Thought Introduction: Economists Talking with Economists, An Historian’s Perspective E. Roy Weintraub INTERVIEWS Chapter 1 An Interview with Wassily Leontief Interviewed by Duncan K. Foley Chapter 2 An Interview with David Cass Interviewed jointly by Steven E. Spear and Randall Wright Chapter 3 An Interview with Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Interviewed by Bennett T. McCallum Chapter 4 An Interview with Janos Kornai Interviewed by Olivier Blanchard Chapter 5 An Interview with Franco Modigliani Interviewed by William A. Barnett and Robert Solow Chapter 6 An Interview with Milton Friedman Interviewed by John B. Taylor Chapter 7 An Interview with Paul A. Samuelson Interviewed by William A. Barnett Chapter 8 An Interview with Paul A. Volcker Interviewed by Perry Mehrling 2 Chapter 9 An Interview with Martin Feldstein Interviewed by James M. Poterba Chapter 10 An Interview with Christopher A. Sims Interviewed by Lars Peter Hansen Chapter 11 An Interview with Robert J. Shiller Interviewed by John Y. Campbell Chapter 12 An Interview with Stanley Fischer Interviewed by Olivier Blanchard Chapter 13 From Uncertainty to Macroeconomics and Back: An Interview with Jacques Drèze Interviewed by Pierre Dehez and Omar Licandro Chapter 14 An Interview with Tom J. Sargent Interviewed by George W.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 3 the Basic OLG Model: Diamond
    Chapter 3 The basic OLG model: Diamond There exists two main analytical frameworks for analyzing the basic intertemporal choice, consumption versus saving, and the dynamic implications for the economy as a whole of this choice: the overlapping-generations (OLG) approach and the representative agent approach. In the first type of models the focus is on (a) the interaction between different generations alive at the same time, and (b) the never-ending entrance of new generations and thereby new decision makers. In contrast, the second type of models views the household sector as consisting of a finite number of infinitely-lived dynasties all alike.1 This approach, also called the Ramsey approach, will be described in Chapter 10. The OLG approach is the topic of the present and the next chapter. The life-cycle aspect of human behavior is at the center of attention. During lifetime one’seducational level, working experience, working capacity, income, and needs change and this is reflected in the individual labor supply and saving behavior. Different OLG models focusing on the aggregate implications of the behavior of coexisting individuals at different stages in their life have shown their usefulness for analysis of public debt, taxation of capital income, financing of social security (pensions), design of educational systems, non-neutrality of money, the possibility of speculative bubbles, etc. We will here present what is considered the basic macroeconomic OLG model, put forward by the American economist and Nobel Prize laureate Peter A. Dia- mond (1940-).2 Saving and dissaving are core elements in life-cycle behavior and hence also in Diamond’smodel.
    [Show full text]
  • The Core of "The General Theory"
    THE CORE OF "THE GENERAL THEORY" By TAKEO MlNOGUCHI* I Sources of Phllosophrcal Ideas of "The General Theory" It is not difficult to imagine that Keynes tried to make the foundation of philosophical ideas of "The General Theory", before he began to write it. However there are few which treated Keynes in this aspect. Perhaps "The Life of John Maynard Keynes" by Harrod may be the most helpful one. In this section I want to look for the philosophical sources of ideas of "The General Theory" m reference to Harrod and others. In doing so, I think, the central theme may be the infiuences of Cambridge philosophy by Moore, Russell, Whitehead and Wittgenstein on Keynes. I want to seperate them into three categories-ethics by Moore, probability by Russell and Whitehead, and philosophy of logic by Wittgenstein. ( I ) Influence of Moore It goes without saying that Keynes was under the strong influence of Moore as a member of Bloomsbury group. Especlally Moore s "Pnnprcra Ethica" gave him strong nnpact According to Harrod, "Ethica" tells that " 'good' is an attribute, the meaning of which is indefinable" or that "what is good depend on direct intuition in each particular case".1 This doctrine of intuitions "was interpreted-anyhow by those disciples who were to be for many years the intimate intellectual companions of Keynes-as giving fairly complete licence to judge all things anew."2 This ethical view of Moore overthrew the Victorian ethics. According to Robert Skidelsky, the Victorian ethical view was that "he once smoked a cigar and found it so delicious he never smoked again".3 This is nothing less than asceticism.
    [Show full text]
  • Frontiers in Applied General Equilibrium Modeling in Honor of Herbert Scarf
    P1: Kcz CB757-FM CB757-Kehoe-v1.cls October 6, 2004 14:7 Frontiers in Applied General Equilibrium Modeling In Honor of Herbert Scarf Edited by TIMOTHY J. KEHOE University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis T. N. SRINIVASAN Yale University JOHN WHALLEY University of Western Ontario iii P1: Kcz CB757-FM CB757-Kehoe-v1.cls October 6, 2004 14:7 published by the press syndicate of the university of cambridge The Pitt Building, Trumpington Street, Cambridge, United Kingdom cambridge university press The Edinburgh Building, Cambridge CB2 2RU, UK 40 West 20th Street, New York, NY 10011-4211, USA 477 Williamstown Road, Port Melbourne, VIC 3207, Australia Ruiz de Alarcon´ 13, 28014 Madrid, Spain Dock House, The Waterfront, Cape Town 8001, South Africa http://www.cambridge.org C Cambridge University Press 2005 This book is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements, no reproduction of any part may take place without the written permission of Cambridge University Press. First published 2005 Printed in the United States of America Typeface Times Roman PS 10/12.5 pt. System LATEX2ε [TB] A catalog record for this book is available from the British Library. Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Frontiers in applied general equilibrium modeling / edited by Timothy J. Kehoe, T.N. Srinivasan, John Whalley. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0-521-82525-3 (hardback) 1. Equilibrium (Economics) – Mathematical models. I. Kehoe, Timothy Jerome, 1953– II. Srinivasan, T.N., 1933– III. Whalley, John. HB145.F76 2005 339.5015195 – dc22 2004045758 ISBN 0 521 82525 3 hardback iv P1: Kcz CB757-FM CB757-Kehoe-v1.cls October 6, 2004 14:7 Contents List of Contributors page vii Acknowledgments xi Introduction 1 Timothy J.
    [Show full text]
  • The Use of Mathematics in Economics and Its Effect on a Scholar's
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The use of mathematics in economics and its effect on a scholar’s academic career Espinosa, Miguel and Rondon, Carlos and Romero, Mauricio London School of Economics, International Monetary Fund, University of California San Diego September 2012 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/41341/ MPRA Paper No. 41341, posted 15 Sep 2012 00:30 UTC The use of Mathematics in Economics and its Effect on a Scholar’s Academic Career∗ (Preliminary version. Comments are welcome.) Miguel Espinosa† Carlos Rondon,‡ and Mauricio Romero§ September 14, 2012 Abstract There has been so much debate on the increasing use of formal methods in Economics. Although there are some studies tackling these issues, those use either a little amount of papers, a small amount of scholars or a short period of time. We try to overcome these challenges constructing a database characterizing the main socio-demographic and academic output of a survey of 438 scholars divided into three groups: Economics Nobel Prize winners; scholars awarded with at least one of six worldwide prestigious economics recognitions; and academic faculty randomly selected from the top twenty economics departments. We give statistical evidence on the increasing trend of number of equations and econometric outputs per article, showing that for each of these variables there have been four structural breaks and three of them have been increasing ones. Therefore, we provide concrete measures of mathematization in Economics. Furthermore, we found that the use and training in mathematics has a positive correlation with the probability of winning a Nobel Prize in certain cases.
    [Show full text]
  • Arrow, Kenneth Joseph (Born 1921)
    K000067 Arrow, Kenneth Joseph (born 1921) Kenneth Arrow is the author of key post-Second World War innovations in economics that have made economic theory a mathematical science. The Arrow Possibility Theorem created the field of social choice theory. Arrow extended and proved the relationship of Pareto efficiency with economic general equilibrium to include corner solutions and non-differentiable pro- duction and utility functions. With Gerard Debreu, he created the Ar- row–Debreu mathematical model of economic general competitive equilibrium including sufficient conditions for the existence of market-clear- ing prices. Arrow securities and contingent commodities extend the model to cover uncertainty and provide a cornerstone of the modern theory of finance. Kenneth Arrow is a legendary figure, with an enormous range of contribu- tions to 20th-century economics, responsible for the key post-Second World War innovations in economic theory that allowed economics to become a mathematical science. His impact is suggested by the number of major ideas that bear his name: Arrow’s Theorem, the Arrow–Debreu model, the Ar- row–Pratt index of risk aversion, and Arrow securities. Four of his most distinctive achievements, all published in the brief period 1951–54, are as follows: Arrow Possibility Theorem. Social Choice and Individual Values (1951a) created the field of social choice theory, a fundamental construct in theo- retical welfare economics and theoretical political science. Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics. ‘An extension of the basic theorems of classical welfare economics’ (1951b) presents the First and Sec- ond Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics and their proofs without requiring differentiability of utility, consumption, or technology, and in- cluding corner solutions (zeroes in quantities of inputs or outputs).
    [Show full text]