Appendix I Argentina's Potential Output Growth

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Appendix I Argentina's Potential Output Growth Appendix I Argentina’s Potential Output Growth s a result of Argentina’s strong growth perfor- A mance following the stabilization at the begin- Figure 14. Potential Output and Output Gap ning of the 1990s, and its recovery from the Tequila crisis, by mid-decade it was commonly assumed that Argentina’s potential output growth was in the range 130 !/2 Real GDP and Hodrick-Prescott Trend of 4 to 5 percent per year. At least in retrospect, Estimate1 however, there are reasons to believe that this repre- 125 A: HP filter sented a significant overestimate of potential output 1993–1999 growth. 120 Potential output growth is the growth rate of the economy at which, in the absence of monetary im- 115 pulses, there should be no inflationary pressures. 110 Conceptually, potential output growth need not be B: HP filter 1993–2000 constant. Indeed, to the extent that Argentina’s struc- 105 tural reforms (including deregulation, privatization, and labor market reforms) in the early part of the 100 decade gave a boost to the level of potential output, 95 potential output growth would surge initially but 1993 95 97 99 2001 then return toward its longer-run rate—especially as 20 structural reforms began to fizzle and in, some in- 9 Output Gap, Consumer Prices, stances, to be reversed. Unemployment Rate2 18 Unemployment rate One approach to estimating potential output (right scale) growth is to fit a smoothing filter to actual real GDP. 4 16 This allows for some variation in the growth rate of 14 potential output. Given the structural changes of the –1 12 economy, however, the key question concerns the pe- 10 riod over which the filter should be applied. Quar- Consumer price index terly (seasonally adjusted) national accounts data are –6 (net of import prices) 8 available from 1993, and given that growth in 6 1991–92 was probably driven by a rebound from the –11 Output gap 4 collapse during the hyperinflation, 1993 provides a convenient starting point. More tricky is the choice 2 0 of the end-point. Figure 14 shows two possible –16 1995 96 97 98 99 2000 01 choices, ending the sample period in 1999:Q4 (la- beled A) or 2000:Q4 (labeled B); beyond these ter- 1A Hodrick-Prescott filter is applied to the period minal dates, potential output growth is extrapolated 1993:1–1999:4 (Trend A) or 1993:1–2000:4 (Trend B); potential 44 output thereafter is extrapolated using the last quarter’s growth using the final quarter’s growth rate. rate. 2Output gap implied by Trend A; positive output gap indicates 44By 2001, the economy is clearly in collapse and including actual output above estimated potential output. 2001 in the estimation sample leads to a downward bias of poten- tial output over the entire period. 46 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Appendix I Using Trend A, output was on average 2 percent 1998 (only semi-annual data are available) and above potential in 1997 and, on average, almost 3!/2 started increasing thereafter. The evidence thus sug- percent above potential in 1998. The growth slow- gests that, while output was above potential in the down brought the economy to 2!/2 percent below po- first part of 1998, by end-1998 and early 1999, a tential in 1999, 5!/2 percent below potential by 2000, clear output gap was emerging—consistent with and almost 12 percent below potential by 2001. Trend A, but not with Trend B. Using Trend B, output was almost 4!/2 percent above According to Trend A, potential growth decreased potential in 1998, close to its natural level in 1999, from 3!/2 percent per year during 1993–97 to 3 per- 2!/2 percent below potential in 2000, and 7!/2 percent cent by 1998 and 2!/2 percent thereafter. For the pe- below potential in 2001. The deceleration in poten- riod 1993–2001, potential output growth averaged 3 tial output growth in 1999–2000 implied by trend B percent per year—well below the 4!/2 to 5 percent po- seems implausibly large, and the small output gaps tential output growth underlying medium-term debt inconsistent with the behavior of other macroeco- sustainability projections. This may also be com- nomic data. For instance, consumer prices, purged of pared to Argentina’s fitted growth rate implied by the the effect of import prices, were increasing through cross-country growth regression reported in Box 8 of the first half 1998, but began to decline in the fourth the text, which also yields an average growth rate of quarter of the year and continue to fall through 2001 3.0 percent per year when the effects of deflation are (see Figure 14, bottom panel).45 Likewise, unemploy- excluded.46 ment reached its lowest level in the second half of 46The model estimated for Box 8 includes a term to capture low 45The figure shows the residual from an OLS regression of the or negative inflation, on grounds that deflation may lower aggre- logarithm of the consumer price index regressed on the logarithm gate demand. This term is excluded here, since deflation is likely of the import price index. to affect aggregate demand but not potential output. 47 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Appendix II Chronology of Key Developments in 2001–2002 2001 Jan. 12 IMF approves augmentation of Argentina’s a face value of $29.5 billion are voluntarily Stand-By Arrangement to $14 billion and exchanged for longer-term instruments. completes second review. June 15 Economy Minister Cavallo announces Mar. 2–3 Economy Minister Josehuis Machinea re- package of tax and trade measures, includ- signs. Ricardo Lopez-Murphy is appointed ing a trade compensation mechanism Minister of Economy. for exporters and importers of non- energy goods. Mar.16 Economy Minister Lopez-Murphy announces plan of budget cuts to meet fiscal targets July 10 Government pays yield of 14.1 percent to agreed with the IMF. place $827 million of 90-day paper. July 11 Economy Minister Cavallo announces dras- Mar. 19–20 Economy Minister Lopez-Murphy resigns. tic program of fiscal adjustment aimed at Domingo Cavallo is appointed Minister eliminating the federal government deficit of Economy. from August 2001 onwards (the “zero- Mar. 26–28 Risk rating agencies lower Argentina’s deficit plan”). long-term sovereign rating (S&P from BB July Risk rating agencies lower Argentina’s long- to B+ and Moody’s from B1 to B2). term sovereign rating further (S&P from B to B– and Moody’s first from B2 to B3 and Mar. 28 Economy Minister Cavallo secures “emer- then from B3 to Caa1). gency powers” from Congress. Announces economic program comprising a tax on July 30 Senate approves the zero-deficit plan bank transactions, changes in other taxes (lower house of Congress had approved it and tariffs, and sectoral “competitiveness on July 20). plans.” Aug. 21 IMF announces likely $8 billion augmenta- April Central bank reduces liquidity require- tion of Argentina’s Stand-By Arrangement ments and allows banks to include govern- credit. ment securities up to 2 billion pesos among liquidity requirements. Sept. 7 IMF approves augmentation of stand-by credit to about $21.6 billion and completes April 16 Minister Cavallo sends to Congress a bill Fourth Review. to include the euro in addition to the Sept. 20 The Central Bank activates the contingent U.S. dollar in the Convertibility Law. repo facility with international banks, April 23 Authorities suspend scheduled auction of boosting gross reserves by about government bonds. $1.2 billion ($500 million was disbursed in October). April 26 Roque Maccarone replaces Pedro Pou as Oct. 9–12 Risk rating agencies lower Argentina’s President of the Central Bank. long-term sovereign rating further (S&P – May 8 Standard & Poor’s lowers Argentina’s from B to CCC and Moody’s from Caa1 long-term sovereign rating further from to Caa3). B+ to B. Oct. 14 Ruling coalition obtains less than 25 per- cent of the votes in mid-term congres- May 21 IMF completes third review of Argentina’s sional elections. Stand-By Arrangement, reprofiling the path for the federal government deficit target Oct. 28 Economy Minister Cavallo announces that during 2001 to accommodate the devia- he will seek a “voluntary” restructuring of tions observed during the first quarter. all the government debt. June 3 Authorities announce the completion of Oct. 30 Standard & Poor’s lowers Argentina’s long- the “mega-swap.” Government bonds with term sovereign rating from CCC to CC. 48 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Appendix II Nov. 1 The authorities announce a new fiscal transactions, including a weekly 250 pesos package, including a new batch of competi- cash withdrawal limit on sight accounts. tiveness plans, the rebate of VAT payments on debit card transactions, a temporary re- Dec.10 The central bank imposes a 98 percent duction in employee social security contri- reserve requirement on deposit increases butions, a corporate debt restructuring after December 1, 2001, aimed at limiting scheme, and a tax amnesty that writes off flight to quality within the system. interest and penalty obligations accrued to end-September 2001. Dec. 13 Phase one of the government debt exchange is completed. Nov. 6 Standard & Poor’s lowers Argentina’s long- term sovereign rating from CC to SD Dec. 19 State of emergency is declared to stop (selective default). protests against Economic Minister Cav- allo’s economic policies.The lower house Nov. 23 The central bank introduces an effective cap of Congress repeals the special legislative on bank deposits, by imposing a 100 percent powers granted to Cavallo.
Recommended publications
  • 1 Political Shocks and Asset Prices Daniel Carnahan
    Political Shocks and Asset Prices Daniel Carnahan (Business Insider) Sebastian Saiegh (University of California San Diego) Abstract We estimate how asset prices respond to a range of political shocks, including changes in a country’s economic stewardship, national elections, coup d'états, wars, and terrorist attacks. Multiple instances of these events took place in Argentina between 1967 and 2020. Using an event study approach and over 13,000 daily prices from the Buenos Aires exchange, we find that stock-market volatility increases in the days immediately following unexpected, major policy- shifting events. These results hold irrespective of whether market returns are measured in nominal terms, in local consumption units, or in US dollars. Our analysis allows us to establish comparisons across different types of political shocks while avoiding the identification problems of multi-country event studies. The most significant increase in post-event risk is associated with irregular government turnovers (coup d'états, presidential death, resignations); approximately 100 percent on average, when returns are expressed in US dollars. Volatility also increases in the days immediately following a defeat in an international war, national elections and changes in the country’s economic stewardship. No changes in stock market volatility occur, however, after terrorist attacks or when the date of a new administration’s inauguration is publicly known and determined sufficiently far in advance. Word Count: 10,929 1 Introduction Investors concerned about non-commercial risks need to consider their exposure to political events that may affect the value of their assets. These political risks can originate in specific government actions, such as laws or regulations.
    [Show full text]
  • President Duhalde Moves Election Forward LADB Staff
    University of New Mexico UNM Digital Repository NotiSur Latin America Digital Beat (LADB) 7-12-2002 President Duhalde Moves Election Forward LADB Staff Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalrepository.unm.edu/notisur Recommended Citation LADB Staff. "President Duhalde Moves Election Forward." (2002). https://digitalrepository.unm.edu/notisur/13049 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Latin America Digital Beat (LADB) at UNM Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in NotiSur by an authorized administrator of UNM Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. LADB Article Id: 53031 ISSN: 1089-1560 President Duhalde Moves Election Forward by LADB Staff Category/Department: Argentina Published: 2002-07-12 Unable to make headway in Argentina's financial crisis or to stop the increasingly violent social unrest, President Eduardo Duhalde scheduled early presidential elections for March, saying the troubled country needs new leadership. Duhalde admitted in late June that it might be impossible to reach any agreement with the International Monetary Fund (IMF). At the same time, the head of the central bank resigned. Duhalde's one achievement avoiding the street violence that toppled his predecessor last December vanished when protests in late June ended with two people dead, evidently executed by the police. Central bank president resigns Central bank (Banco Central de la Republica Argentina, BCRA) president Mario Blejer had said in mid-June he would leave his post once an agreement with the IMF was achieved. Blejer said he was leaving "for personal reasons," but his growing problems with Economy Minister Roberto Lavagna were well-known.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Reform—And Political Crisis
    32921 Development Public Disclosure Authorized Challenges in the 1990s Leading Policymakers Speak from Experience Montek S. Ahluwalia Eduardo Aninat Public Disclosure Authorized Leszek Balcerowicz Mario I. Blejer Kwesi Botchwey Fernando Henrique Cardoso Kemal Dervis¸ Alejandro Foxley Yegor Gaidar Rima Khalaf Hunaidi Public Disclosure Authorized Lawrence H. Summers John Williamson Zhou Xiaochuan EDITED BY TIMOTHY BESLEY & ROBERTO ZAGHA Public Disclosure Authorized Development Challenges in the 1990s Leading Policymakers Speak from Experience Development Challenges in the 1990s Leading Policymakers Speak from Experience Edited by Timothy Besley and Roberto Zagha A copublication of the World Bank and Oxford University Press © 2005 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street, NW Washington,DC 20433 All rights reserved. 1 2 3 4 08 07 06 05 A copublication of The World Bank and Oxford University Press. Oxford University Press 198 Madison Avenue New York NY 10016 This volume is a product of the staff of the International Bank for Recon- struction and Development / The World Bank.The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the views of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they rep- resent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work.The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgement on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorse- ment or acceptance of such boundaries. Rights and Permissions The material in this publication is copyrighted.
    [Show full text]
  • Lawrence J. Christiano
    1 August, 2016 LAWRENCE J. CHRISTIANO VITA Personal Data Home Address Office Address 2517 Thornwood Department of Economics Wilmette, Illinois 60091 Northwestern University (847) 251-5710 Evanston, Illinois 60208 Citizenship: U.S.A. (847) 491-8231 Education Degree Field Institution Year Ph.D. Economics Columbia University 1982 M.Sc. Econometrics/Mathematical London School of Economics 1977 Economics M.A. Economics University of Minnesota 1975 B.A. History/Economics University of Minnesota 1973 Experience September 1 2002 – present: Alfred W. Chase Chair in Business Institutions, Northwestern University. Summers 1999, 2000, 2001: Visiting Scholar, International Monetary Fund. Summers, 2001 and 2002: Visiting Scholar, European Central Bank. Fall 1999 – present: Short courses on ‘Monetary Economics’ at Stockholm School of Economics, International Monetary Fund, Banca D’Italia, Central Bank of Portugal, Central Bank of Chile, European Central Bank, University of Bonn, New University of Lisbon, Humboldt University, Bocconi University, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Study Center Gerzensee, Central Bank of Israel, Central Bank of Turkey, European Business Cycle Network, Brazilian Central Bank, Reserve Bank of New Zealand, Swiss National Bank, University of Amsterdam, University of Toronto, American Economic Association, Central Bank of Peru, Central Bank of Colombia, Central 2 Bank of Hungary, Central Bank of Czech Republic, Kiel Institute, Central Bank of Korea, Hanqing Advanced Institution of Economics and Finance, Renmin University of China, Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance. Summer 1996 – 2007, consultant, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Fall 2008 - present, consultant, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. July, 1995: consultant, Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System. August 1993, May-June 1998, Summers 1999, 2000, 2001: Visiting Scholar, International Monetary Fund.
    [Show full text]
  • Argentina : an Alternative Proposal to Overcome the Crisis
    ARGENTINA : AN ALTERNATIVE PROPOSAL TO OVERCOME THE CRISIS LUIS BECERRA, ALBERTO BONNET, ALFONSO FLORIDO, GUILLERMO GIGLIANI, CLAUDIO KATZ, JORGE MARCHINI, ALBERTO TESZKIEWICZ. In the background of Argentina’s actual dramatic economic downfall a meeting hold in the Faculty of Economic Sciences of the University of Buenos Aires , placed in the center of attention the need to work on alternative proposals to deal with the crisis. The following document aims just to open the debate, pointing out initiatives that are based on the principle that the extraordinary weight of the disaster has to be burdened on those who bankrupted the country and not on workers, unemployed, professionals and small producers, traders and investors. This crisis surpasses earlier ones in Argentina in 1975, 1981 and 1989 due to the spiraling growth of poverty . the industrial dismantling and the regional breakdown Argentina’s depression has not been caused exclusively by the “convertibility “ (the now collapsed currency board in force since 1991 with the peso quotation to the US dollar in fix 1 to 1 rate) , the “model” or “trade opening” if not synthesized the combined effect of periodic convulsions of capitalism, the country’s peripheral assortment and last decade neo-liberal policies. Our initiative echoes the popular revolt that tumbled a retrograde government and continues claiming through quotidian protests and banging pots and pans (known as “cacerolazos”) We actively participate in the popular movement and reject the actual political regime that is based on the government by Excecutive Order , the legislative delegation of powers to enable harder adjustments and the continuity of a Supreme Court that warrant impunity to the national treasury robbers.
    [Show full text]
  • 14469-9781462367689.Pdf
    STAFF PAPERS PETER HOLE Chair, Editorial Committee lAN S. McDoNALD Editor and Deputy Chair MARINA PRIMORAC Assistant Editor Editorial Committee F. Charles Adams Malcolm D. Knight Mario I. Blejer Pau 1 R. Masson David Burton Donald J. Mathieson Daniel A. Citrin Susan M. Schadler David J. Goldsbrough Subhash M. Thakur Peter Isard Howell H. Zee G. Russell Kincaid Among the responsibilities of the International Monetary Fund, as set fonh in its Anicles of Agreement, is the obligation to "act as a centre for the collection and exchange of information on monetary and financial problems." Staff Papers makes available to a wider audience papers prepared by the members of the Fund staff. The views presented in the papers are those of the authors and are not to be interpreted as necessarily indicating the position of the Executive Board or of the Fund. To facilitate electronic storage and retrieval of bibliographic data. StaffPapers has adopted the subject classification scheme developed by the Journal of Economic Literature. Subscription: US$54.00a volume or the approximate equivalent in the currencies of most countries. Four numbers constitute a volume. Single copies may be purchased at $18.00. Individual academic rate to full-time professors and students of universities and colleges: $27 a volume. Subscriptions and orders should be sent to: International Monetary Fund Publication Services 700 19th Street. N.W. Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A. Telephone: (202) 623-7430 Telefax: (202) 623-7201 Internet: [email protected] ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS Vol. 42 No. 4 DECEMBER 1995 ©International Monetary Fund.
    [Show full text]
  • SSRN Author Website
    1 June, 2013 Andrew Feltenstein Andrew Feltenstein is Professor of Economics, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University. He was previously Program Director for Economics at the National Science Foundation, and until November 2008 he was Senior Advisor at the International Monetary Fund, in charge of the IMF’s Internal Economics Training Program. He holds a B.A. in mathematics from Harvard University, an M.A. in mathematics from Yale University, and a Ph.D. in economics from Yale. Mr. Feltenstein has held a number of academic positions, including assistant professor at the University of Massachusetts at Amherst, professor at the University of Kansas, and professor at Virginia Tech. After teaching at Massachusetts, he joined the International Monetary Fund in the Young Professionals program, and worked in the Research and Fiscal Affairs departments before moving to the World Bank in the Country Policy Department. Mr. Feltenstein’s primary fields of research are public economics and applied general equilibrium, while his current interests involve the analysis of financial assets in the context of banking and macroeconomic reform in developing countries. He has worked as a consultant for the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank, the Asian Development Bank, the UNDP, the Monetary Authority of Singapore, the African Economic Research Consortium, and the Ministry of Finance of China. As part of this consulting work he has carried out research on a variety of countries including China, Singapore, Bangladesh, Pakistan,
    [Show full text]
  • The Argentina Crisis Introduction
    The National Bureau of Economic Research Program on Exchange Rate Crises in Emerging Markets Martin Feldstein and Jeffrey Frankel, Directors The Argentina Crisis July 17, 2002 Sebastian Edwards and Jeffrey Frankel, Organizers Report: Romi Bandura and Anne Le Brun Introduction The most recent of NBER’s country sessions on exchange rate crises in emerging markets was held in Cambridge, on July 17th, 2002. With Argentina still reeling from the impact of the devaluation and the default, and with its recovery path still undecided, the meeting took a certain sense of urgency. Many of the themes that dominated the discussion at previous country meetings reappeared in the case of Argentina—the roles of the fixed exchange rate, a weakened banking system, politically-driven policy decisions, and fiscal irresponsibility. But the Argentina crisis also sparked a new debate, on the viability of an exchange rate regime previously broadly lauded, the currency board. The meeting drew a large number of high-ranking former Argentine government officials, including the architect of the currency board, Domingo Cavallo, members of the current U.S. government, officials from international organizations, including the IMF’s First Deputy Managing Director, Anne Krueger, financial market participants and academics focused on the field international financial markets. The conference was divided into four sessions. The first three sessions aimed at understanding the causes of and the lessons to be learned from the crisis, from three different perspectives: 1) the banking sector, 2) the hard peg, and 3) debt. A final panel considered ‘desperation remedies’ that were adopted or discussed during 2000-2002, and attempted to look forward.
    [Show full text]
  • A Fresh Look at Central Bank Independence
    Institute of Global Affairs A FRESH LOOK AT CENTRAL BANK INDEPENDENCE Mario I Blejer and Paul Wachtel Cato Journal, Vol. 40, No. 1 (Winter 2020). A FRESH LOOK AT CENTRAL BANK INDEPENDENCE Paul Wachtel and Mario I. Blejer Paul Wachtel is Professor of Economics at New York University Stern School of Business. Mario I. Blejer is Visiting Professor in the Institute of Global Affairs at the London School of Economics and Political Science. This article builds on presentations by Wachtel at the Colloquium on “Money, Debt and Sovereignty,” Université de Picardie Jules Verne, December 11–12, 2017; the XXVI International Rome Conference on Money, Banking and Finance, LUMSA University, Palermo, Italy, December 14–16, 2017; and the Center for Advanced Studies on the Foundations of Law and Finance, Goethe University, May 20, 2019; and by Wachtel and Blejer at the Conference on Financial Resilience and Systemic Risk, London School of Economics, January 30–31, 2019; and the 25th Dubrovnik Economic Conference, June 15–16, 2019. This article is part of the LSE IGA Financial Resilience project supported by the Rockefeller Foundation. Central bank independence (CBI) became a globally accepted truth of economics about 30 years ago. It is clearly valuable for insuring that monetary policy is conducted in a way that is consistent with appropriate central bank objectives and free of political influences. Nevertheless, CBI has been under attack in both the developed world (President Trump is a frequent critic) and in emerging markets (e.g., in Turkey and India). Thus, the time is ripe to take a new look at CBI.
    [Show full text]
  • How Robust Is the New Conventional Wisdom in Monetary Policy?
    How Robust is the New Conventional Wisdom in Monetary Policy? The surprising fragility of the theoretical foundations of inflation * ** targeting and central bank independence Willem H. Buiter, Professor of European Political Economy European Institute London School of Economics and Political Science, Universiteit van Amsterdam, NBER and CEPR April 15, 2007 * Paper to be presented at the Bank of England’s Chief Economists' Workshop, 16-18 April 2007. An earlier version of this paper was presented at the 2006 Central Bank Governors’ Symposium “Challenges to Monetary Theory”, at the Bank of England on June23, 2006. Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the Norges Bank’s Conference on Monetary Policy 2006, Evaluating Monetary Policy, 30 March 2006, and at the 37rd Konstanz Seminar on Monetary Theory and Policy, May 30 - June 2. 2006. I would like to thank Gianluca Benigno, Pierpoalo Benigno, Jarle Bergo, Mario Blejer, Guillermo Calvo, Stephen Cecchetti, Vittorio Corbo, Lawrence Christiano, Casper de Vries, Stefan Gerlach, Svein Gjedrem, Kjersti Haugland, Rachel Lomax, Manfred Neumann, Jorunn Paulson, Huw Pill, Robert Rasche, Martin Redrado, Irma Rosenberg, Michael Saunders, Anne Sibert, Zdenek Tuma, Jurgen von Hagen, Axel Weber and Fredrik Wulfsberg for helpful comments. Alan Blinder offered wide-ranging and insightful comments on an earlier version of the paper, and I am greatly in his debt. None of the aforementioned bear any responsibility for the content of this paper. ** © Willem H. Buiter 2006, 2007. Abstract Flexible inflation targeting - the minimisation of the expected discounted sum of current and future period losses, with the period loss function given by the weighted sum of squared deviations of inflation from a constant target rate and the squared output gap - cannot be rationalised, except in a single, practically uninteresting special case, using conventional welfare economic criteria.
    [Show full text]
  • Credit Crunch and Keynesian Contraction: Argentina in Crisis ∗
    Credit Crunch and Keynesian Contraction: Argentina in crisis ¤ Marcus Miller ,y Javier Garc¶³aFronti zand Lei Zhang x February 2005 Abstract The collapse of the Argentine convertibility regime, where the peso was ¯xed at parity with US dollar for more than a decade, was accompanied by sovereign debt default. In the absence of credible compensation, however, the government's bold e®ort to imitate President Roosevelt in \pesifying" dollar loans and deposits destroyed bank net worth and sent the Argentine economy into deep depression. To help analyse these events, we extend the model of Aghion et al (2000) to in- clude a domestic credit crunch | exacerbated by asymmetric pesi¯cation | and a Keynesian contraction of demand. In addition, the banking crisis is characterised as a game between government and banks about who pays for recapitalisation. Key words: Argentina debt crisis, Currency and banking crises, Keynesian reces- sion, Asymmetric pesi¯cation, Conflicting Beliefs JEL Classi¯cation: E12, E51, F34, G18 ¤We are grateful to the ESRC for ¯nancial support supplied to the research project RES-051-27- 0125 \Debt and Development" and to Elba Roo for research assistance funded in part by the CSGR. We thank Lisandro Barry, Mario Blejer, Luis C¶espedes, Guillermo Escude, Matthew Fisher, Daniel Heymann, Daniel Laskar, Santiago Acosta-Ormaechea, Andrew Powell and Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel for helpful suggestions; but responsibility for views expressed is our own. yUniversity of Warwick and CEPR [email protected] zUniversity of Warwick xUniversity of Warwick 1 Why did Argentina collapse in the worst economic crisis in its history? What brought a monetary system that attracted great praise and popular support until the last moment to such a catastrophic end? Gerchuno® & Llach (2003) I Introduction In one key respect the currency board system implemented in Argentina in 1990 proved extraordinarily successful: hyperinflation was promptly replaced by price stability.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal Deficits and Balance of Payments Disequilibrium in IMF Adjustment Programs*
    Fiscal Deficits and Balance of Payments Disequilibrium in IMF Adjustment Programs* VITO TANZI AND MARIO I. BLEJER CONCEPT OF FISCAL DEFICIT One of the most important and lasting contributions of J. M. Keynes's thought to the development of modern economic theory has been the central role he assigned to fiscal policy in stabilizing output. Within the Keynesian framework, the economic result of the fiscal sector, whether a deficit or a surplus, is the most important balancing factor in the economy. The magnitude of the deficit or surplus is the central piece in the determination of the levels of aggregate demand, income, prices, and, eventually, in an open economy, of the balance of payments. A point that has been considered as fundamental in the theory developed by Keynes is that an economy may converge to an equilibrium that is stable but which may be suboptimal or undesirable since it may involve unemploy- ment or inflationary pressures.1 In the Keynesian model, fiscal policy is the main instrument that has the power of shifting the economy from one equilibrium position to another. The implicit assumption of this Keynesian view is that the government has the means and the will to regulate the size of its revenues and expenditures and, in such a way, direct the economy toward a desirable level of equilibrium. This view is based on the conception that it is feasible for the fiscal authority to control, at each point in time, the size of the fiscal balance so as to bring it close to what the government wants it to be.
    [Show full text]