Consumption and the Great Recession;

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Load more

Consumption and the Great Recession Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and David Benson Introduction and summary the second-worst rebound observed in the data followed The Great Recession of 2008–09 was characterized by the 1974 recession and lasted just over one year. We the most severe year-over-year decline in consumption find that this persistence is reflected most in the sub- the United States had experienced since 1945. The components of nondurables and especially in services. consumption slump was both deep and long lived. It Our main findings from the analysis of the micro- took almost 12 quarters for total real personal con- data are as follows. First, expected nominal income sumption expenditures (PCE) to go back to its level growth declined significantly during the Great Recession. at the previous peak (2007:Q4). This is the worst drop ever observed in these data, and In this article, we document key facts about aggre- this measure has not yet fully recovered to pre-recession gate consumption and its subcomponents over time levels. Second, the decline exists for all age groups, and look at the behavior of important determinants of consumption, such as consumers’ expectations about Mariacristina De Nardi is a senior economist and research their future income and changes in consumers’ wealth advisor; Eric French is a senior economist and research advisor; positions related to house prices and stock valuations. and David Benson is an associate economist in the Economic Then, we use a simple permanent-income model to Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors thank Richard Porter and an anonymous referee determine whether the observed drop in consumption for helpful comments and Helen Koshy for editorial advice. can be explained by these observed drops in wealth and income expectations. © 2012 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago We begin our data analysis by using macroeco- Economic Perspectives is published by the Economic Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The views nomic data to study the behavior of consumption and expressed are the authors’ and do not necessarily reflect the views its subcomponents. We then use microeconomic data of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve from the Reuters/University of Michigan Surveys of System. 1 Charles L. Evans, President ; Daniel G. Sullivan, Executive Vice Consumers to study nominal expected income growth President and Director of Research; Spencer Krane, Senior Vice and inflationary expectations. President and Economic Advisor; David Marshall, Senior Vice Our main findings from the macrodata are the fol- President, financial markets group; Daniel Aaronson, Vice President, microeconomic policy research; Jonas D. M. Fisher, Vice President, lowing. First, the Great Recession marked the most macroeconomic policy research; Richard Heckinger,Vice President, severe and persistent decline in aggregate consump- markets team; Anna L. Paulson, Vice President, finance team; William A. Testa, Vice President, regional programs, Richard D. tion since World War II. All subcomponents of con- Porter, Vice President and Economics Editor; Helen Koshy and sumption declined during this period. However, the Han Y. Choi, Editors; Rita Molloy and Julia Baker, Production large drop in services consumption stands out most, Editors; Sheila A. Mangler, Editorial Assistant. Economic Perspectives articles may be reproduced in whole or in relative to previous recessions. Second, while the de- part, provided the articles are not reproduced or distributed for cline was historic, the trends in consumption and its commercial gain and provided the source is appropriately credited. subcomponents leading up the recession were not Prior written permission must be obtained for any other reproduc- tion, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works substantially different from past recessionary periods. of Economic Perspectives articles. To request permission, please Third, the recovery path of consumption following contact Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or email the Great Recession has been uncharacteristically weak. [email protected]. It took nearly three years for total consumption to re- ISSN 0164-0682 turn to its level just prior to the recession. In contrast, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 1 education levels, and income quin- FIGURE 1 tiles. Relative to previous recessions, Level of real personal consumption expenditures those with higher levels of income and education are more pessimistic billions of 2005 dollars coming out of this recession than 10,000 their poorer and less-educated counterparts. Third, expectations 8,000 for real income growth have also declined, and the decline in expected 6,000 real income growth is more severe when personal inflation expectations 4,000 are used instead of actual Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation. Fourth, 2,000 expected income growth is a strong predictor of actual future income 0 growth. Since expected income 1962 ’70 ’78 ’86 ’94 2002 ’10 growth is a very important determi- Note: PCE is personal consumption expenditures. nant of consumption decisions, the Source: Haver Analytics. observed drop in expected income has the potential to explain at least part of the observed decline in FIGURE 2 consumption. Nominal PCE to nominal GDP ratio during recessions since 1962 In the context of a simple perma- nent-income model, we find that the PCE – GDP ratio negative wealth effect (coming from 0.72 decreased stock market valuations 0.70 and housing prices) and consumers’ 0.68 decreased income expectations were 0.66 big factors in determining the ob- 0.64 served consumption drop. In fact, 0.62 we find that in this model, the ob- served drops in wealth and income 0.60 expectations can explain the observed 0.58 drop in consumption in its entirety, 0.56 depending on what we assume about 0.54 1962 ’68 ’74 ’80 ’86 ’92 ’98 2004 ’10 future income growth beyond the time horizon covered by the Reuters/ Notes: PCE is personal consumption expenditures; GDP is gross domestic product. Shaded areas indicate recession periods as defined by the National University of Michigan Surveys of Bureau of Economic Research. Consumers data set. Source: Haver Analytics. Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) have stressed the similarities be- tween the current financial crisis and many earlier ones shows a flattening out of the consumption growth rate stretching across centuries, continents, and economies. in 2008–09. The fact that this pattern is clearly visible, These crises entailed large declines in real housing even over a period of almost 50 years, highlights the prices, equity collapses, and profound declines in out- severity and persistence of the Great Recession and put and employment. They emphasize the importance the very slow recovery that is following it. of balance sheet repair. We complement their research Figure 2 shows that consumption growth outpaced by emphasizing the role played by consumers’ income gross domestic product (GDP) growth through past expectations, as well as wealth effects. recessionary periods. The nominal PCE–GDP ratio has increased in each recession since 1962. In contrast, Macrodata: Total real PCE during the Great Recession, it increased more modestly. Figure 1 displays the level of real PCE from 1962 Since the latest recession, this ratio has either fallen to 2011:Q3. Even over this long horizon, the chart or stagnated. Thus, as a share of GDP, consumption 2 1Q/2012, Economic Perspectives has been hit harder than in previous FIGURE 3 recessions. Normalized real PCE levels over recession periods Petev, Pistaferri, and Eksten (2011) document that while real per peak level = 1 capita consumption declined mono- 1.20 tonically until the middle of 2009, 1.15 real per capita disposable income 1.10 was relatively stable and its decline was significantly smaller. This stabil- 1.05 ity in per capita income is explained 1.00 entirely by a strong increase in gov- 0.95 ernment transfers to households, as wages and financial income fell. The 0.90 increase in government transfers was 0.85 partly due to higher take-up rates 0.80 for unemployment insurance and −16 −14 −12 −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0624 8 10 12 14 16 food stamps and partly due to the quarters since peak increased generosity of means-test- 1973:Q4 1981:Q3 2001:Q1 ed programs enacted by the federal 1980:Q1 1990:Q3 2007:Q4 government (such as extended un- employment benefits and increases Note: PCE is personal consumption expenditures. Sources: Haver Analytics and authors’ calculations. in food stamps and emergency cash assistance). Given that these transfers are means tested, they primarily help poorer households. Consistent with FIGURE 4 this finding, we find that in the Real total quarterly PCE growth over 2008–09 Reuters/University of Michigan versus previous recessions since 1974 Surveys of Consumers, the drop in quarterly growth (annual rate) income expectations for the next 6 12 months among poor households was smaller than that among all 4 other households. 2 Figure 3 compares the time path of real PCE over several recession- 0 ary time periods, where the level of PCE is normalized to 1 at the busi- −2 ness cycle peak (as defined by the National Bureau of Economic −4 Research, NBER) prior to each −6 recession. The NBER dates for −16 −14 −12 −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0624 8 10 12 14 16 the recessions’ peaks are 1973:Q4, quarters since peak 1980:Q1, 1981:Q3, 1990:Q3, Average of previous recessions 2001:Q1, and 2007:Q4. 2007:Q4 Figure 3 highlights that in the 2008–09 recession, consumption Note: PCE is personal consumption expenditures. dropped 3.4 percent from peak to Sources: Haver Analytics and authors’ calculations. trough (six quarters after the peak) and was slow to increase afterward. This pattern contrasts with every other recession since Figure 4 displays the time path of the real PCE 1974.
Recommended publications
  • Mariacristina De Nardi UCL, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, CEPR, IFS, and NBER 30 Gordon St, London, UK WC1H 0AY Denardim@Nber.Org

    Mariacristina De Nardi UCL, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, CEPR, IFS, and NBER 30 Gordon St, London, UK WC1H 0AY [email protected]

    Mariacristina De Nardi UCL, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, CEPR, IFS, and NBER 30 Gordon St, London, UK WC1H 0AY [email protected] www.nber.org/~denardim Education Ph.D., Economics, University of Chicago, August 1999. M.A., Economics, University of Chicago, June 1998. B.A., Economics, Università degli Studi di Venezia, Italy, November 1993 (with Distinction). Employment Professor of Economics, University College London, 2013 to present. Senior Economist and Economic Advisor, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Research Department, May 2009-present. On leave 2013-2015. Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Research Department, 2005-2009. Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of Minnesota, 2000-2007. Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Research Department, 1998-2000. Research Assistant, Professor Thomas J. Sargent, 1995 to 1998. Teaching Assistant (graduate classes), University of Chicago, 1996-1997. Research Fellow, Università degli Studi di Venezia, November 1993-1994. Research Interests Macroeconomics, Public Finance, Household Finance, Wealth Distribution, Savings, Social Security, Social Insurance Reform, and Human Capital. Work in Progress “Risks and Insurance over the Life Cycle for Couples and Singles,” with Margherita Borella and Fang Yang. “The Lifetime Costs of Bad Health,” with Svetlana Pashchenko and Ponpoje Porapakkarm “Implications of Richer Earnings and wage Dynamics for Consumption, Wealth, and Welfare in the U.K,” with Giulio Fella and Gonzalo Paz-Pardo. “Earnings and Wage Dynamics in the Netherlands," with Rob Alessie, Giulio Fella, Marike Knoef, Gonzalo Paz-Pardo, and Raun Van Ooijen. “Couples and Singles' Savings after Retirement,” With Eric French and John Jones. “The Insurance Role of Marriage,” with Fang Yang. “Producing Health in Old Age” with Margherita Borella.
  • Medical Spending and Savings of Aging Households

    Medical Spending and Savings of Aging Households

    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics De Nardi, Mariacristina Article Medical spending and savings of aging households NBER Reporter Provided in Cooperation with: National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, Mass. Suggested Citation: De Nardi, Mariacristina (2020) : Medical spending and savings of aging households, NBER Reporter, ISSN 0276-119X, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, MA, Iss. 2, pp. 17-20 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/234008 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu ine wage rates, rental costs, and home values 1 “What is BEPS?” Organisation 7 “The Effect of Taxes on Investment Medical Spending and Savings of Aging Households and find contemporaneous declines on all for Economic Co-operation and and Income Shifting to Puerto Rico,” of these indicators.
  • Mariacristina De Nardi University of Minnesota, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, CEPR and NBER 1925 S

    Mariacristina De Nardi University of Minnesota, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, CEPR and NBER 1925 S. 4th St., Minneapolis, MN 55455 [email protected] www.nber.org/~denardim CV updated: October 2021 Education Ph.D., Economics, University of Chicago, August 1999. B.A., Economics, Università degli Studi di Venezia, Italy, November 1993 (with Distinction). Employment Thomas Sargent Professor, University of Minnesota, Economics Department 2019 to present. Consultant, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 2019 to present. Senior Scholar, Opportunity and Inclusive Growth Institute, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 2018 to 2019. Professor of Economics, University College London, 2013 to 2019. On leave 2018-2019. Senior Economist and Economic Advisor, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Research Department, 2009 to 2018. On leave 2013-2015. Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Research Department, 2005-2009. Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of Minnesota, 2000-2005. Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Research Department, 1998-2000. Research Assistant, Professor Thomas J. Sargent, 1995 to 1998. Teaching Assistant (graduate classes), University of Chicago, 1996-1997. Research Fellow, Università degli Studi di Venezia, November 1993-1994. Research Interests Macroeconomics, Public Economics, Health, Wealth Distribution, Savings, Entrepreneurship, Social Security, Social Insurance Reform, and Human Capital. Work in Progress "U.S. Effective Taxes Over Time," with Margherita Borella, Michael Pak, Nicolo' Russo, and Fang 1 Yang. “Health, Mortality, and Genetics,” with Ross Abrams, Margherita Borella, and Elena Manresa. “Couples, Singles, Bequests, and Policy,” with Margherita Borella and Fang Yang. “Estimating Health Production in Old Age,” with Margherita Borella and Emily Nix. Working Papers “Couples and Singles' Savings During Retirement,” with Eric French, John Jones, and Rory McGee, NBER working paper no.
  • Household Inequality and the Consumption Response to Aggregate Real Shocks Gene Amromin, Mariacristina De Nardi, and Karl Schulze

    Household Inequality and the Consumption Response to Aggregate Real Shocks Gene Amromin, Mariacristina De Nardi, and Karl Schulze

    1 2018 https://doi.org/10.21033/ep-2018-1 Household inequality and the consumption response to aggregate real shocks Gene Amromin, Mariacristina De Nardi, and Karl Schulze Introduction and summary The drop in output and consumption that occurred during the Great Recession has been large and prolonged. Figure 1 displays per capita U.S. real gross domestic product (GDP) and personal consumption expenditures (PCE) between 1985 and 2016 and highlights the large drop in both consumption and output that occurred 1 starting in 2007 and its parallel shift compared with the previous trend. In this article, we ask why consumption has dropped so much and has been recovering so slowly. We also ask to what extent household inequality before and after the Great Recession interacted with the recession itself to generate such a large and persistent drop in consumption.1 To reach our goal, we first review two key papers, Krusell and Smith (1998) and Krueger, Mitman, and Perri (2016), and summarize what we understand from quantitative macro models with aggregate uncertainty about wealth inequality, borrowing-constrained households with heterogeneous marginal propensities to consume (MPCs), and the response of aggregate consumption to an aggregate shock. The key message from macroeconomic theory is that the extent to which households are borrowing constrained (which in these models means how many people have low wealth holdings) and how that changes both over time and with aggregate shocks are crucial to explaining the aggregate economy’s response and the speed of its recovery. That is, versions of these models with a realistic fraction of poor people can generate larger consumption drops in response to a total factor productivity (TFP) shock than models with fewer poor people.
  • Marco Bassetto's Curriculum Vitae

    Marco Bassetto's Curriculum Vitae

    Mariacristina De Nardi UCL, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, and NBER 30 Gordon St, London, UK WC1H 0AY [email protected] www.nber.org/~denardim Education Ph.D., Economics, University of Chicago, August 1999. M.A., Economics, University of Chicago, June 1998. B.A., Economics, Università degli Studi di Venezia, Italy, November 1993 (with Distinction). Employment Professor of Economics, University College London, summer 2013 to present. Senior Economist and Economic Advisor, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Research Department, May 2009-present. On leave 2013-2015. Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Research Department, July 2005-May 2009. Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of Minnesota, August 2000-May 2007. Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Research Department, July 1998-August 2000. Research Assistant, Professor Thomas J. Sargent, 1995 to 1998. Teaching Assistant (graduate classes), University of Chicago, 1996-1997. Research Fellow, Università degli Studi di Venezia, November 1993-July 1994. Research Interests Macroeconomics, Wealth Distribution, Savings, Social Security, Social Insurance Reform, and Human Capital. Academic Papers “Medical Spending of the U.S. Elderly,” with Eric French, John B. Jones, and Jeremy McCauley, NBER working paper no. 21270, 2015. “Savings After Retirement: A Survey,” with Eric French and John B. Jones, NBER working paper no. 21268, 2015. “Quantitative Models of Wealth Inequality: A Survey,” NBER working paper no. 21106, 2015. “Wealth Inequality, Family Background, and Estate Taxation,” with Fang Yang, NBER working paper no. 21047, 2015. “Medicaid Insurance in Old Age,” with Eric French and John B. Jones, NBER working paper no. 19151, 2013. “Social Security and Fertility,” with Larry Jones and Michele Boldrin, forthcoming, Journal of Demographic Economics, 2015.
  • John Bailey Jones, Curriculum Vitae

    John Bailey Jones, Curriculum Vitae

    John Bailey Jones Address: Research Department Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond P.O. Box 27622 Richmond, Virginia 23261 (804) 697-8206 E-mail: [email protected] Web Address: https://sites.google.com/view/jbjones-albany/home Education: Ph.D. (Economics), University of Wisconsin-Madison, August 1998 M.S. (Economics), University of Wisconsin-Madison, August 1995 B.A. (Interdisciplinary Studies), College of William and Mary, May 1987 Current and Previous Positions: 2016-present: Senior Economist and Research Advisor, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. 2005-17: Associate Professor, University at Albany, State University of New York (on leave 2016-17 academic year). 2014-16: Consultant, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. 2013 (June 3-14), 2012 (July 9-13), 2011 (June 13 – July 12), 2010 (June 2 – July 30), 2009 (July 27 – August 7): Consultant, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. 2004 (May 22-28): Visiting Scholar, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. 1998-2005: Assistant and Visiting Assistant (2003-04) Professor, University at Albany, State University of New York. 1987-1993: Analyst, Associate Analyst, Research Associate and Research Assistant, National Economic Research Associates (NERA), Cambridge, MA and White Plains, NY. Research Fields : Macroeconomics, Econometrics, Health Economics, Public Economics, Labor Economics JBJ: April 24, 2018 1 Teaching Fields: Undergraduate : Macroeconomics, Money and Banking. Masters: Macroeconomics Ph.D. : Macroeconomics (First-year core and topics courses) Refereed Publications: “The Effects of Collecting Income Taxes on Social Security Benefits,” (with Yue Li), Journal of Public Economics 159 (March 2018), pp. 128-145. “The Accuracy of Economic Measurement in the Health and Retirement Study” (with Eric French and Jeremy McCauley), Forum for Health Economics and Policy (available online October 2017).
  • Wealth Inequality: Data and Models

    Wealth Inequality: Data and Models

    Macroeconomic Dynamics, 12 (Supplement 2), 2008, 285–313. Printed in the United States of America. doi:10.1017/S1365100507070150 WEALTH INEQUALITY: DATA AND MODELS MARCO CAGETTI Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System MARIACRISTINA DE NARDI Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and NBER In the United States wealth is highly concentrated and very unequally distributed: the richest 1% hold one third of the total wealth in the economy. Understanding the determinants of wealth inequality is a challenge for many economic models. We summarize some key facts about the wealth distribution and what economic models have been able to explain so far. Keywords: Inequality, Savings, Life-Cycle Models 1. INTRODUCTION In the United States wealth is highly concentrated and very unequally dis- tributed: the richest 1% of the households own one-third of the total wealth in the economy. Understanding the determinants of wealth inequality is a challenge for many economic models. In this paper, we summarize what is known about the wealth distribution and what economic models have been able to explain so far. The development of various data sets in the past 30 years (in particular the Survey of Consumer Finances) has allowed economists to quantify more precisely the degree of wealth concentration in the United States. The picture that emerged from the different waves of these surveys confirmed the fact that a large fraction of the total wealth in the economy is concentrated in the hands of the richest percentiles: the top 1% hold one-third, and the richest 5% hold more than half of total wealth.