Is China's Textile Industry Still a Labour-Intensive Industry?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Is China's Textile Industry Still a Labour-Intensive Industry? Jianlei Zhang1,*, Lin He1,**, Is China’s Textile Industry Still Longdi Cheng2 a Labour-Intensive Industry? DOI: 10.5604/01.3001.0014.5038 1 Jiaxing University, Abstract College of Business, Is China’s textile industry (CTI) still a laboor-intensive one? To answer this question, this Faculty of Marketing, study measures the capital-labour intensity and technology intensity of CTI and its sub- 56 South Yuexiu Rd, 314001, Jiaxing, China, sectors during 2006-2018, then applies factor intensity classification and cluster analysis * e-mail: [email protected], to identify their industrial attributes. The results show that CTI and its sub-sectors are still ** e-mail: [email protected] the labour- and non-technology-intensive. All the indexes of capital-labour intensity and 2 Donghua University, technology intensity of CTI and its sub-sectors are below 100, lower than the average of College of Textile, industry sectors, indicating that they are not separate from the category of labour-intensive Faculty of Textile Industry Economics, industry and still heavily dependent on labour. And cluster analysis verifies the industrial 2999 North Renmin Rd, Shanghai, China, classification results. So CTI still needs to keep on increasing its capital intensity and tech- e-mail: [email protected] nology intensity to achieve the goal of industrial transformation and upgrading in the future. Key words: textile industry, labor-intensive industry, factor intensity classification, capital -labour intensity, technology intensity. Introduction some views that CTI [3] part of textile tion process, in which labor, capital and sub-sectors [2, 4] in some regions have technology account for the largest pro- All along the textile industry has been taken off the “hats” of “labor-intensive portion, respectively and show its com- regarded as a typical labour-intensive industry” and become technology-inten- parative advantage. Literature on indus- industry. As it absorbs a large amount of sive instead. trial classification by factor intensity is the labor force, the textile industry has little and scattered. The capital-labour also become a traditional pillar industry As discussed above, different views and ratio and technology ratio are commonly of China’s economy. Nowadays, the in- thoughts regarding CTI attributes have used to classify an industry [7-10], but no telligent manufacturing level of China’s been fostered and developed in academ- literature has been retrieved that studies textile industry (CTI for short, hereafter) ia. So what are the industrial attributes of the factor intensity of CTI. Referring to has been continuously improving with today’s CTI? Is it still a labour-intensive the index system and statistical method the introduction of new equipment, tech- industry? What level of factor intensity designed by Liu Renyi [7], this study nologies and materials. Its production has it reached? Faced with these ques- chooses two sets of indicators to measure mode is gradually changing from exten- tions, this paper firstly measures the fac- the factor intensity of CTI. sive production to intensive production, tor intensity of CTI and its sub-sectors from factor-driven production to efficien- during 2006-2018, then applies factor The first set of indicators includes the cy-driven production, which not only ef- intensity classification and cluster anal- capital-labor ratio, capital-output ratio fectively alleviates the operation pressure ysis to identify their industrial attributes and output-labor ratio, which are used brought about by the rising production in order to answer whether CTI is still to measure the capital-labor intensity of cost and environmental protection but a labor-intensive industry or not. Lastly, CTI and to determine whether the textile also promotes industrial transformation some policy suggestions are recommend- industry is a labor-intensive or capital-in- and upgrading. More importantly, it ex- ed for the transformation and upgrading tensive industry. The capital-labour ratio erts a subtle influence on people’s view of CTI. is the most widely used and most impor- on the attribute of CTI as a labor-inten- tant indicator. It refers to the ratio of fixed sive industry. capital to labour input in the production Methods & data sources process of an industry. The capital-out- For example, the number of workers used put ratio refers to the ratio of fixed capi- Factor intensity classification per 10,000 spindles in a cotton mill has tal used per output, and the output-labour decreased from about 300 in the 1990s The industrial classification schemes ratio is the labour productivity, where to less than 100 now. Several mills have commonly used include two major cat- larger indicators mean higher CTI capi- even reached the minimum of 17 [1]. egories of classification, three industry tal intensity, while lower indicators mean The spinning workshop and printing & classifications, factor intensity classi- higher labour intensity. dyeing workshop of Lutai Textile, one fication, Standard Industry Classifica- of the listed CTI companies, has dra- tions (SIC), the North America Indus- The second set of indicators includes the matically reduced workers and greatly trial Classification System (NAICS), the R&D expenditure-sale ratio, R&D per- improved production efficiency through Global Industry Classification Standard sonnel-employee ratio and R&D expend- importing the most advanced production (GICS), Hoffman classification, Chen- iture-R&D personnel ratio, which are equipment [2]. With the upgrading of ery-Taylor classification and so on [5-6]. used to measure the technology intensi- equipment and the improvement of pro- Factor intensity classification divides ty of CTI from the perspective of R&D duction efficiency in the textile industry, industry sectors into labor-intensive in- expenditure input, R&D personnel input now most indicators point to CTI shifting dustry, capital-intensive industry and and input intensity, respectively, and then from a labor-intensive industry to a tech- technology-intensive industry based on judging whether it belongs to the tech- nology-intensive industry. There are also the input factor intensity in the produc- nology-intensive industries or not. Larg- Zhang J, He L, Cheng L. Is China’s Textile Industry Still a Labour-Intensive Industry? 13 FIBRES & TEXTILES in Eastern Europe 2021; 29, 1(145): 13-16. DOI: 10.5604/01.3001.0014.5038 Table 1. Capital-labour intensity of China's textile industry (2006-2018). and all data are obtained from the China Statistical Yearbook and China Industry Capital-labour ratio Capital-output ratio Output-labor ratio Statistical Yearbook. Fixed capital is rep- (thousand CNY per (thousand CNY per (thousand CNY per Mean Year person) thousand CNY) person) Index resented by the total fixed assets of CTI, Amount Index Amount Index Amount Index and labour is the number of employees, 2006 93.53 43 0.38 76 243.17 57 59 represented by the total workers in CTI. 2007 112.65 45 0.39 78 290.05 57 60 Since the China Statistical Yearbook no 2008 127.10 46 0.40 81 317.86 56 61 longer counts the gross industrial output 2009 140.41 45 0.39 75 364.17 59 60 value after 2012 and the revenue of the 2010 153.95 44 0.35 74 434.25 59 59 principal business is close to the gross in- 2011 186.03 44 0.34 74 548.35 60 59 dustrial output value, the output and sales 2013 192.09 44 0.27 64 700.84 69 59 are represented by the revenue of princi- 2014 234.77 46 0.30 65 781.20 70 60 pal business of CTI. R&D expenditure 2015 256.42 45 0.30 60 860.95 76 60 and R&D personnel are represented by 2016 279.19 45 0.30 59 936.32 77 60 the R&D expenditure and R&D person- 2017 284.53 43 0.31 59 923.26 73 59 nel of CTI, respectively. 2018 301.60 41 0.36 65 839.76 64 57 Table 2. Technology intensity of China's textile industry (2006-2018). Results of factor intensity classification R&D expenditure-sale R&D personnel- R&D expenditure-R&D ratio -employee ratio personnel ratio Factor intensity of China’s textile Mean Year (thousand CNY per (persons per thousand (thousand CNY per billion CNY) persons) person) Index industry Amount Index Amount Index Amount Index This study calculates the values and in- 2006 2291.01 44 3.20 34 173.83 74 51 dexes of capital-labour intensity indica- 2007 2386.59 45 3.26 30 212.42 86 54 tors (Table 1) and technology intensity 2008 2573.48 48 4.12 36 198.64 75 53 indicators (Table 2) of CTI during 2006- 2009 3078.66 52 5.48 37 204.50 83 57 2018. Since the China Statistical Year- 2010 3011.02 52 5.15 36 253.66 87 58 book does not count the number of CTI 2011 4212.74 59 8.64 41 267.43 87 62 employees in 2012, Table 1 and 2 do not 2013 4281.14 54 10.33 42 297.41 89 62 include the results for 2012. 2014 4640.27 56 11.60 44 312.53 89 63 2015 5193.32 58 13.30 49 336.26 89 65 2016 5384.75 57 14.59 51 345.62 85 65 According to the calculation results of 2017 6456.68 61 16.61 54 358.99 82 66 the capital-labour intensity indicator, 2018 9167.61 74 22.41 60 343.58 79 71 CTI is still a labor-intensive industry. From 2006 to 2018, the capital-labour ratio index, capital-output ratio index er indicators mean that CTI’s technology Cluster analysis and output-labor ratio index of CTI are intensity is higher and its dependence on In order to check the result reliability all less than 100, and the mean index technology input is also greater.
Recommended publications
  • Is Apparel Manufacturing Coming Home? Nearshoring, Automation, and Sustainability – Establishing a Demand-Focused Apparel Value Chain
    Is apparel manufacturing coming home? Nearshoring, automation, and sustainability – establishing a demand-focused apparel value chain McKinsey Apparel, Fashion & Luxury Group October 2018 Authored by: Johanna Andersson Achim Berg Saskia Hedrich Patricio Ibanez Jonatan Janmark Karl-Hendrik Magnus 2 Is apparel manufacturing coming home? Table of Contents Introduction 4 Is apparel manufacturing coming home? 6 Era of change 6 Nearshoring breakeven 10 Overcoming challenges in nearshoring 12 The prospect of automation 15 Promising automation technologies 15 Economic viability of automation 18 How quickly can the prospect become reality? 21 The automation journey 23 Embarking on the journey 24 Defining the future sourcing and production strategy 24 Developing new skills and changing mindsets 26 Building a new ecosystem of partnerships 27 Taking the first step 28 Table of Contents 3 Introduction Tomorrow’s successful apparel companies will be those that take the lead to enhance the apparel value chain on two fronts: nearshoring and automation. It cannot be just one of them and it must be done sustainably. Apparel companies can no longer conduct business as usual and expect to thrive. Due to the Internet and stagnation in key markets, competition is fiercer than ever and consumer demand is more difficult to predict. Mass-market apparel brands and retailers are competing with pure-play online start-ups, the most successful of which can replicate trendy styles and get them to customers within weeks. Furthermore, apparel companies have lost much of their clout in trendsetting. In most mass-market categories, today’s hottest trends are determined by individual influencers and consumers rather than by the marketing departments of fashion companies.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade in Labor-Intensive Manufactures
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Imports of Manufactures from Less Developed Countries Volume Author/Editor: Hal B. Lary Volume Publisher: NBER Volume ISBN: 0-870-14485-5 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/lary68-1 Publication Date: 1968 Chapter Title: Trade in Labor-Intensive Manufactures Chapter Author: Hal B. Lary Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c4980 Chapter pages in book: (p. 86 - 115) 4 TRADEIN LABOR-INTENSIVE MANUFACTURES Selection of Labor-Intensive Items Application of Value-Added Criterion Judged by the criterion of value added per employee, both in the United States and in other countries, a number of industries have been found to be clearly capital-intensive and a number of others clearly labor-intensive. This is true of such major industry groups as chemicals and petroleum products on the one hand and textiles and wood products on the other. It is true also of many of the component industries of other major groups. As always, the problem of classification concerns mainly the observations in an intermediate position—in this instance, those industries which, at the finest level of industrial detail given, are near the national average on the value-added scale.' The general rule followed in this study has been to count as labor- intensive all manufactures which meet both of two conditions. The first is that, in value added per employee in the United States, they do not exceed the national average for all manufacturing by more than 10 per cent.
    [Show full text]
  • Multifactor Productivity in U.S. Manufacturing, 1949-83
    Multifactor productivity in U .S . manufacturing, 1949-83 New, more comprehensive measures of multifactor productivity permit the analysis of numerous issues, including developments at the detailed industry level and the importance of factor substitution in labor productivity growth WILLIAM GULLICKSON AND MICHAEL J . HARPER The strong labor productivity advance exhibited by the U.S . second, they consider intermediates-raw materials and busi- economy over the 25 years following World War II gave ness service inputs-explicitly, so that economies in those way to sluggish growth beginning in the early 1970's. The inputs can be assessed along with those in labor and capital. manufacturing sector, which accounts for about 20 percent Changes over time in these new multifactor measures of gross national product, has experienced a similar pattern . reflect many influences, including variations in output (es- Prior to about 1973, the rapid productivity growth in manu- pecially in the short term, during which most inputs are facturing contributed to swift increases in the U .S . standard partially fixed), the utilization of capacity, changes in the of living, and also to a favorable international balance of characteristics and efforts of the work force, changes in payments . After 1973, and particularly during the late managerial skill, and technological developments . Meas- 1970's, manufacturing productivity growth fell short of its ures of multifactor productivity have a specific relationship earlier performance . to measures of labor productivity : Labor productivity In this article, the Bureau of Labor Statistics introduces a growth can be seen as deriving from (1) growth in multifac- new set of multifactor productivity measures designed to tor productivity and (2) changes in the ratios of labor to strengthen the statistical basis with which labor productiv- other inputs, or labor intensity ratios .
    [Show full text]
  • Productivity Growth and Levels in France, Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States in the Twentieth Century
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH AND LEVELS IN FRANCE, JAPAN, THE UNITED KINGDOM AND THE UNITED STATES IN THE TWENTIETH CENTURY Gilbert Cette Yusuf Kocoglu Jacques Mairesse Working Paper 15577 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15577 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2009 The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2009 by Gilbert Cette, Yusuf Kocoglu, and Jacques Mairesse. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Productivity Growth and Levels in France, Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States in the Twentieth Century Gilbert Cette, Yusuf Kocoglu, and Jacques Mairesse NBER Working Paper No. 15577 December 2009 JEL No. E22,J24,N10,O47,O57 ABSTRACT This study compares labor and total factor productivity (TFP) in France, Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States in the very long (since 1890) and medium (since 1980) runs. During the past century, the United States has overtaken the United Kingdom and become the leading world economy. During the past 25 years, the four countries have also experienced contrasting advances in productivity, in particular as a result of unequal investment in information and communication technology (ICT).
    [Show full text]
  • The Service-Producing Sector
    The service-producing sector: some common perceptions reviewed Many service industries are capital intensive, and the range of expansion in output per hour is not significantly different from that found among goodsproducing industries RONALD E. KUTSCHER and JEROME A. MARK Over the past three decades, the rapid growth of the services and excluding transportation, communication, economy's service sector and the increasing interest in wholesale and retail trade, finance, insurance, and real the sector on the part of both scholars and policymak- estate. All three definitions will be referenced in the fol- ers have helped give currency to three perceptions about lowing discussion. service industries . The perceptions are that (1) the ser- vice sector is composed entirely of industries that have Growth rates vary widely by industry. The first apparent- very low rates of productivity growth; (2) service indus- ly generally held perception of the service sector is that tries are highly labor intensive and low in capital inten- it consists entirely of industries with low growth in pro- sity; and (3) shifts in employment to the service- ductivity. Comparison of growth rates for output and producing sector have been a major reason for the employment by industry over the last two decades slowdown in productivity growth over the past 10 to 15 might seem to lend support for this belief, for the data years. This article examines these perceptions in the show that the widely discussed growth in services in the light of available data. U.S. economy has been more pronounced from an em- ployment perspective than from the output view.
    [Show full text]
  • Agricultural Labor Intensity and the Origins of Work Ethics ∗
    Agricultural Labor Intensity and the Origins of Work Ethics ∗ Vasiliki Foukay Alain Schlaepferz September, 2015 Abstract This study examines the historical determinants of differences in attitudes towards work across societies today. Our hypothesis is that a society's work ethic depends on the role that labor has played in it historically, as an input in agricultural pro- duction: societies that have for centuries depended on the cultivation of crops with a high equilibrium labor to land ratio will work longer hours and develop a prefer- ence for working hard. We formalize this prediction in the context of a model of endogenous preference formation, with altruistic parents that can invest in reducing their offsprings’ disutility from work. To empirically found our model, we construct an index of potential agricultural labor intensity, that captures the suitability of a location for the cultivation of crops with a high estimated labor share in their production. We find that this index positively predicts the number of desired work hours and the importance placed on work in contemporary European regions. We find support for the hypothesis of cultural transmission, by examining the correla- tion between potential labor intensity in the parents' country of origin and hours worked by children of European immigrants in the US. ∗We thank Alberto Alesina, Jeanet Bentzen, Pedro Forquesato, Oded Galor, Stelios Michalopoulos, Nathan Nunn, James Robinson, Tetyana Surovtseva, Felipe Valencia, Hans-Joachim Voth, Yanos Zyl- berberg and participants in the 7th End-of-Year Conference of Swiss Economists Abroad, the Brown University Macro Lunch and the 2014 European Meeting of the Econometric Society at Toulouse for helpful comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economic Anomaly of Mining (Study)
    96 CHAPTER THREE The Economic Anomaly of Mining—Great Wealth, High Wages, Declining Communities Thomas Michael Power, Department of Economics, University of Montana ineral extraction activities pay among the highest source of 20 percent or more of labor earnings Mwages available to blue collar workers, about between 1970 and 2000. There are about one hun- twice the average. In New Mexico in 2000, mineral dred such counties that could be identified out of the extraction jobs paid $50,000 per year whereas the 3,100 counties in the U.S. Data disclosure problems average wage and salary job paid $28,000. Given prevented the identification of some mine-dependent these high wages, one would expect communities that counties. rely heavily on mineral extraction to be unusually The U.S. mining-dependent counties are spread out prosperous. That, in general, is not the case. Across over half of the American states but are geographically the United States, mining communities, instead, are clustered in the Appalachian (Pennsylvania, West noted for high levels of unemployment, slow rates of Virginia, Tennessee, Kentucky, and Virginia) and growth of income and employment, high poverty Mountain West states. The century-old copper mines rates, and stagnant or declining populations. In fact, of Upper Michigan, Montana, Utah, Arizona, and New our historic mining regions have become synonymous Mexico are included, as are the new gold mines in with persistent poverty, not prosperity: Appalachia Nevada. The older coal mines in southern regions of (coal), the Ozarks (lead), and the Four Corners (coal) the Great Lakes states (Illinois, Indiana, and Ohio) are areas are the most prominent of these.
    [Show full text]
  • Cutting Back on Labor Intensive Goods? Implications for Fiscal Stimulus
    Cutting Back on Labor Intensive Goods? Implications for Fiscal Stimulus Cristian Alonso∗y First Version: November 2016 Job Market Paper Please download the latest version from here Abstract I show that the effectiveness of fiscal stimulus as a tool for counter-cyclical stabiliza- tion depends not only on how much of changes in income households spend, but also on the composition of that expenditure. By combining expenditure and production data I measure the extent to which households cut back expenditure on labor-intensive goods upon unemployment. The result is quantitatively relevant because the labor share with which different final consumption goods are produced varies widely across the econ- omy. I find that upon unemployment, a household reduces demand for other workers' labor by 6.5%, 15% more than what is implied when heterogeneity in production and expenditure is ignored. In the context of the Great Recession, the expenditure re- sponse to unemployment accounts for a fifth of the drop in labor compensation. Using a multi-good, multi-sector New-Keynesian model with heterogeneous agents, I show that my findings have significant implications for the targeting and evaluation of fiscal stimulus. First, the fiscal multiplier of government purchases of labor-intensive goods is almost five times larger than for purchases of capital-intensive goods. Second, the heterogeneity I document explains the lower effectiveness to stimulate the economy of capital-intensive military spending, as compared to highly labor-intensive general government spending. Third, I show that the decline of the labor share in the last decades has reduced the effectiveness of fiscal policy.
    [Show full text]
  • 8. the Spread of the Industrial Revolution
    Gregory Clark Econ 110B Winter 2000 8. THE SPREAD OF THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 8.1 INTRODUCTION So far we have looked at the revolutionary changes that occurred in Britain until 1850. Now we consider what effects the Industrial Revolution had on the rest of the world up until 1914 and the eve of World War I. The Industrial Revolution, as we have seen, was based on knowledge. It was largely increases in knowledge that propelled the rise in output per worker in Britain after 1850, so that by 1850 British income per capita was far ahead of most other countries. But the fact that the Industrial Revolution came from an increase in knowledge, rather than from capital accumulation, or from the exploitation of natural resources, seemed to imply that it would spread with great rapidity to other parts of the world. For while developing new knowledge is an arduous task, copying innovations is generally much easier. The new technologies of the early Industrial Revolution were not particularly sophisticated. They were quickly transmitted to other European countries despite the ban on exports of machinery and of artisans. Table 8.1 shows how long it took for discoveries originating in Britain before 1850 to reach other parts of Europe and other parts of the world. The increasing prosperity and economic power of Britain impressed both governments and individuals in foreign countries. There was thus a rapid response in terms of attempts to import the new British technologies. A series of Acts were passed in Britain in the eighteenth century restricting the export of both artisans and machinery, plans, or models in the textile and other industries.
    [Show full text]
  • Food Manufacturing Productivity and Its Economic Implications / TB-1905 Economic Research Service/USDA Summary
    Electronic Report from the Economic Research Service United States Department www.ers.usda.gov of Agriculture Technical Bulletin Food Manufacturing Productivity Number 1905 and Its Economic Implications October 2003 Kuo S. Huang Abstract The gross-output multifactor productivity index for U.S. food manufacturing grew 0.19 percent per year between 1975 and 1997. This productivity growth is low when compared with an estimate of 1.25 percent per year for the whole manufacturing sector. Low invest- ment in research and development (R&D) could be one reason. Although productivity has been relatively low, food manufacturing output has grown significantly at 1.88 percent over the last two decades. Indeed, the expansion of combined factor inputs provided signif- icant impetus to food manufacturing output. Food manufacturing is materials-intensive, and declining real producer prices of crude food and feedstuffs fueled the expansion of input utilization and drove down prices of processed foods paid by consumers. Keywords: Food manufacturing, multifactor productivity, labor productivity. Acknowledgments The author thanks Mark Denbaly, Nicole Ballenger, David Davis, Paul Heisey, and Mike Ollinger of the Economic Research Service, Bob Chambers of the University of Maryland, and Tom Lutton of the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight for helpful review of the earlier drafts of this report; John Connor of Purdue University and Gerry Schluter of the Economic Research Service for their suggestions in compiling the Census of Manufacturing data; Lou King for editorial advice and Wynnice Pointer- Napper for the final document layout and charts. Contents Summary . .iii Introduction . .1 Production and Factor Inputs . .2 Gross and Net Outputs .
    [Show full text]
  • The Fourth Industrial Revolution and Its Impact on Occupational Health and Safety, Worker's Compensation and Labor Conditions
    Safety and Health at Work 10 (2019) 400e408 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Safety and Health at Work journal homepage: www.e-shaw.net Review Article The Fourth Industrial Revolution and Its Impact on Occupational Health and Safety, Worker's Compensation and Labor Conditions Jeehee Min 1, Yangwoo Kim 1, Sujin Lee 1, Tae-Won Jang 2, Inah Kim 2, Jaechul Song 2,* 1 Department of Occupational and Environmental Medicine, Hanyang University Hospital, Republic of Korea 2 Department of Occupational and Environmental Medicine, Hanyang University, Republic of Korea article info abstract Article history: The “fourth industrial revolution” (FIR) is an age of advanced technology based on information and Received 2 July 2019 communication. FIR has a more powerful impact on the economy than in the past. However, the pros- Received in revised form pects for the labor environment are uncertain. The purpose of this study is to anticipate and prepare for 18 September 2019 occupational health and safety (OHS) issues. Accepted 22 September 2019 In FIR, nonstandard employment will be common. As a result, it is difficult to receive OHS services and Available online 27 September 2019 compensation. Excessive trust in new technologies can lead to large-scale or new forms of accidents. Global business networks will cause destruction of workers' biorhythms, some cancers, overwork, and Keywords: Fourth industrial revolution task complexity. The social disconnection because of an independent work will be a risk for worker's fi Occupational health and safety mental health. The union bonds will weaken, and it will be dif cult to apply standardized OHS regu- Workers' compensation lations to multinational enterprises.
    [Show full text]
  • Will the Accumulation of Capital Grow and Labor Intensity Decrease?
    A New Era of Machinery: Will the Accumulation of Capital Grow and Labor Intensity Decrease? Askar Akaev Moscow State University Andrei Rudskoi Peter the Great St. Petersburg Polytechnic University Askar Sarygulov Saint Petersburg State University of Economics Valentin Sokolov Saint Petersburg State University of Economics ABSTRACT In order to forecast the macroevolution of the contemporary deve- loped societies it appears essential to take into account the dynamics of a number of economic and technological indicators. In the present paper we undertake such an attempt. Almost ten years after the start of the last economic crisis, the world economy is looking for the most effective plans for recovery. Such recovery is often associated with the fourth industrial revolution, in which the technological factor becomes a key driver of development. However, like any technological breakthrough, it will bring not only ‘roses of prosperity’ but ‘prickly thorns’ of disappointment as well. The key challenges will be the pro- vision of a new quality of economic growth and addressing the asso- ciated employment problem. In this paper, we attempt to show the trends in the ratio between capital and output, as well as the possible effects on employment in the industrialized countries and China until 2050. We used a modified production function with labor-saving tech- nological progress. It is shown that by 2050 the capital-output ratio will not undergo significant changes, and in case of a rejection of in- stitutional reforms and legislative diversification of new types of labor activity in different segments of the economy, there may be a decrease in the number of employed by an average of 20 per cent.
    [Show full text]