The Critical Need for Fiscal Adjustment and Labor Market Reform in Industrial Countries

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Critical Need for Fiscal Adjustment and Labor Market Reform in Industrial Countries IV The Critical Need for Fiscal Adjustment and Labor Market Reform in Industrial Countries he April 1993 Declaration by the IMF Interim imply, threaten to reduce the growth of potential T Committee on a cooperative effort to strengthen output and jeopardize future improvements in living global activity called on the industrial countries to standards. At the same time, pressures on govern- adhere to a strategy of low inflation, deficit reduc- ment budgets will continue to increase as popula- tion, and structural reform to reduce unemployment tions in industrial countries age. Unless credible (see the May 1993 World Economic Outlook, p. x). actions and reforms are implemented in the near Similar medium-term objectives have been pursued term to contain prospective deficits, future genera- by most countries at least since the early 1980s. tions will not only face a substantial increase in However, although substantial progress has been taxes to support a growing share of pensioners and made during the past decade in reducing inflation, to service the public debt, they will also experience little, if any, progress has been made in tackling a marked decline in productivity and real income fiscal imbalances or unemployment. growth because of insufficient capital formation. For many countries, the failure to consolidate fis- These problems are already visible. In the United cal positions during the 1980s means that budgetary States, stagnating or falling real wages for some situations have become unsustainable. Public debt categories of the labor force have resulted in the burdens have risen sharply, and most countries have phenomenon of the working poor; in Europe, high all but lost the ability to use fiscal policy as a stabi- real interest rates and low rates of investment have lization tool. Several governments recently have contributed to inadequate new job creation. announced or adopted new deficit-reduction plans, There is also an urgent need for structural reform despite the difficulties of doing so during a period of in labor markets. The persistence of high rates of cyclical weakness. The baseline projections imply, unemployment in many countries over the past two however, that current policies—including these new decades suggests that in the absence of substantial measures—will lead to only modest reductions of and broadly based labor market reforms there is a the underlying deficits for most countries, and that risk that unemployment will not be reduced suffi- levels of public debt will continue to rise rapidly. ciently when growth recovers. In addition to unac- Major additional efforts are therefore necessary to ceptable social, economic, and budgetary costs, the achieve fiscal sustainability as well as broader eco- high levels of unemployment have contributed to nomic objectives, particularly the restoration of heightened protectionist sentiment in a number of adequate national saving rates and higher growth. countries. The large fiscal deficits need to be addressed with a considerable degree of urgency. Rather than pro- viding support to activity, the large fiscal imbal- The Stance of Monetary Policies ances in Europe and North America—and markets' expectations that these will persist in the medium Although the relative emphasis differs across term—are a principal cause of the high levels of real countries, the principal goals of monetary policy long-term interest rates seen since the early 1980s are to achieve and maintain a high degree of price stability and to alleviate fluctuations in output and and the lackluster growth performance seen re- 18 cently. Because of widespread uncertainty about fu- employment over the business cycle. These goals ture policies, the large deficits are undoubtedly also are consistent if monetary policy follows a "nonac- a major factor behind the depressed levels of con- commodating" policy stance over the cycle, which sumer and business confidence in many countries. provides scope for interest rates to ease during re- And in Europe, the large deficits have resulted in an cessions and, symmetrically, to rise in order to unsustainable policy mix, which has generated a dampen inflationary pressures as recoveries mature. deep recession and provoked unprecedented turmoil The task of pursuing these two goals, however, was in the EMS. complicated in the 1980s by relatively high infla- Over the medium to longer run the large fiscal imbalances, and the persistent diversion of re- 18See the discussion on price stability in the May 1993 World sources from investment to consumption that they Economic Outlook, Box 2, pp. 24-26. 48 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution The Stance of Monetary Policies tionary expectations following the acceleration of inflation during the 1970s, by high structural fiscal deficits in some countries, and by financial innova- tion and deregulation and an apparent breakdown of the relationship between money and credit growth and economic activity in many countries. Much- reduced inflationary expectations following the largely successful disinflation of the 1980s, as well as fulfillment of fiscal consolidation programs, should significantly reduce the risk of a resurgence of inflationary pressures in the short term and pro- Chart 20. United States: Monetary Indicators vide room for short-term interest rates to remain (In percent unless otherwise noted) relatively low during the period ahead in most in- dustrial countries. Because of the relative success in achieving the low-inflation objective, monetary conditions have been eased substantially to support economic recov- ery in the United States, Canada, the United King- dom, and Japan. Of course, as economic slack is reduced in each of these countries, monetary policy will need to be adjusted to safeguard the substantial progress that has been achieved in reducing infla- tion and to help lower underlying inflation further over the medium term. In continental Europe, nom- inal interest rates have declined markedly in recent months, but monetary conditions are still tight given the weakness of activity and recent and pro- spective inflation trends. In many countries, the scope for interest rates to decline further depends on actions to reverse recent deteriorations in fiscal positions. In the United States, both the discount rate and the federal funds rate have remained at low levels of about 3 percent as mixed signals about the strength of the recovery and generally moderate inflation in- dicators have justified a relatively easy policy stance. Long-term interest rates have continued to decline and are now at their lowest level since the late 1970s, which is evidence of market expecta- tions of lower inflation (Chart 20). Even though households and businesses have significantly low- ered their debt-service payments and financial inter- mediaries have improved their financial position, monetary growth, at least for the broader aggre- gates, has remained relatively weak for this stage of the economic recovery. In Japan, in response to the economic downturn, the Bank of Japan lowered the discount rate in six steps between June 1991 and February 1993, from 6 percent to 2 1/2 percent. Both the three-month certifi- cate of deposit rate and the ten-year government bond rate declined considerably and are now well below previous cyclical lows (Chart 21). Growth of the monetary aggregates has remained modest be- cause of a combination of weak income growth, the continuing adverse consequences on wealth of asset price deflation, and a shift of deposits into the postal saving system. Given the absence of infla- 49 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IV INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES: FISCAL ADJUSTMENT AND LABOR MARKET REFORM tionary pressures in goods, labor, and asset mar- kets, and the recent strength of the yen, there would seem to be room for further interest rate reductions. Monetary conditions in Germany have continued to ease as the Bundesbank has responded to the weakening economy, improved prospects for lower inflation, and the recent agreement on a fiscal con- solidation program (Chart 22). Since the beginning of this year both the discount rate and the Lombard rate have been reduced in several steps, the latest on Chart 21. Japan: Monetary Indicators September 10, from 8 1/4 percent to 6 1/4 percent, and (In percent unless otherwise noted) from 9 1/2 percent to 7 1/4 percent, respectively. Both short- and long-term market interest rates have de- clined considerably from their peaks in 1992, with the yield curve in Germany remaining inverted. Nevertheless, using World Economic Outlook pro- jections of inflation as an estimate of expected infla- tion, both short-term and long-term real interest rates are still high for this stage of the business cycle. Cost inflation has declined significantly, and new wage contracts are now generally consistent with the 2 percent normative inflation objective of the Bundesbank. Although underlying consumer price inflation has begun to moderate, monetary growth remains above the top end of the target range owing to a rapid expansion of credit to the public sector. In the other major European countries, short- term interest rates generally declined during the first half of 1993 as the tensions within the ERM earlier in the year diminished (see Chart 18). In France, three-month money market rates had fallen below those in Germany, from about 12 percent in January 1993 to less than 7 percent at end-June, as the Banque de France reduced its official interest rate, but in July interest rates were raised again to support the franc. Long-term rates in France have declined considerably since the beginning of the year, but, as in Germany, the yield curve has re- mained inverted. In Italy, short-term interest rates have continued to ease, particularly at the short end, although rates have remained high in real terms. In the United Kingdom, short-term rates have remained at 6 percent; a further easing to sup- port economic recovery may depend on progress in reducing the fiscal imbalance.
Recommended publications
  • This Version: July 6, 2017 MY PAPERS in ECONOMICS: an ANNOTATED BIBLIOGRAPHY Edmar Bacha1
    1 This version: July 6, 2017 MY PAPERS IN ECONOMICS: AN ANNOTATED BIBLIOGRAPHY Edmar Bacha1 1. Introduction Since the mid-1960s, I have written extensively on development economics, the economics of Latin America and Brazil’s economic problems. My papers include essays on persuasion and reflections on economic policy-making experiences. I review these contributions roughly in chronological order not only because of the variety of topics but also because they tend to come together in specific periods. There are seven periods to consider, identified according to my main institutional affiliations: Yale University, 1964- 1968; ODEPLAN, Chile, 1969; IPEA-Rio, 1970-71; University of Brasilia and Harvard University, 1972-1978; PUC-Rio, 1979-1993; Academic research interregnum, 1994-2002; and IEPE/Casa das Garças since 2003. 2. Yale University, 1964-1968 My first published text was originally a term paper for a Master’s level class in international economics at Yale University. In The Strategy of Economic Development, Albert Hirschman suggested that less developed countries would be relatively more efficient at producing goods that required “machine-paced” operations. Carlos Diaz-Alejandro interpreted machine-paced as meaning capital-intensive 1 Founding partner and director of the Casa das Garças Institute of Economic Policy Studies, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil. With the usual caveats, I am indebted for comments to André Lara- Resende, Alkimar Moura, Luiz Chrysostomo de Oliveira-Filho, and Roberto Zahga. 2 technologies, and tested the hypothesis that relative labor productivity in a developing country would be higher in more capital-intensive industries. He found some evidence for this. I disagreed with his argument.
    [Show full text]
  • The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers
    Pursuit - The Journal of Undergraduate Research at The University of Tennessee Volume 9 Issue 1 Article 7 July 2019 The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers Jenna Demeter The University of Tennessee, Knoxville, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://trace.tennessee.edu/pursuit Part of the Business Administration, Management, and Operations Commons, Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, Economic History Commons, Gender and Sexuality Commons, Growth and Development Commons, Income Distribution Commons, Industrial Organization Commons, Inequality and Stratification Commons, International and Comparative Labor Relations Commons, International Economics Commons, International Relations Commons, International Trade Law Commons, Labor and Employment Law Commons, Labor Economics Commons, Latin American Studies Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Macroeconomics Commons, Political Economy Commons, Politics and Social Change Commons, Public Economics Commons, Regional Economics Commons, Rural Sociology Commons, Unions Commons, and the Work, Economy and Organizations Commons Recommended Citation Demeter, Jenna (2019) "The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers," Pursuit - The Journal of Undergraduate Research at The University of Tennessee: Vol. 9 : Iss. 1 , Article 7. Available at: https://trace.tennessee.edu/pursuit/vol9/iss1/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by
    [Show full text]
  • DEFENDING the WOLF the Useful Contradiction of the Bundesbank Carlo Bastasin
    DEFENDING THE WOLF The Useful Contradiction of the Bundesbank Carlo Bastasin SEP Policy Brief No. 1 - 2014 The Deutsche Bundesbank, the German central bank, is commonly regarded as the Euroarea's boogeyman. The pressure imparted by the German monetary authority, for instance, rendered the European Central Bank reluctant to follow the footprints of the Federal Reserve and of other central banks, and engage in non- standard monetary policy measures that might rapidly put an end to the crisis that has been plaguing the euro zone. At several stages, during the current crisis, the ECB has been forced to take actions and prevent severe economic and financial dislocations. Given the institutional vacuum at the area-wide level and the lack of political capacity of the other institutions, the European Central Bank had often to move across the borders of its traditional domain. This has given reason to a slew of criticisms repeatedly and loudly voiced by the Bundesbank. Being also the most vocal policy actor evoking the fiscal risks associated with effecting implicit cross-border transfers via the ECB's balance sheet, the Bundesbank has appeared to have a “non- monetary” hidden agenda or even a “national political” mission. In fact, the Bundesbank has regularly appealed to two fundamental principles of sound economic and monetary policy management that cannot be easily overlooked by anybody concerned that monetary policy may lose its ability to preserve price stability. Should monetary independence be eroded by the increasing tasks devolved to the central banks, wider economic and political consequences might then arise. The first principle is the need to avoid fiscal dominance, not allowing inflation to be determined by the level of fiscal debts; the second is the “principle of responsibility” that sees a contradiction if individual responsibility is blurred by the intervention of joint liability as in the case of a State running unsound fiscal policies and being automatically bailed out by the mutualization of its liabilities.
    [Show full text]
  • From Designers to Doctrinaires: Staff Research and Fiscal Policy Change at the Imf
    FROM DESIGNERS TO DOCTRINAIRES: STAFF RESEARCH AND FISCAL POLICY CHANGE AT THE IMF Cornel Ban ABSTRACT Soon after the Lehman crisis, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) surprised its critics with a reconsideration of its research and advice on fiscal policy. The paper traces the influence that the Fund’s senior man- agement and research elite has had on the recalibration of the IMF’s doctrine on fiscal policy. The findings suggest that overall there has been some selective incorporation of unorthodox ideas in the Fund’s fis- cal doctrine, while the strong thesis that austerity has expansionary effects has been rejected. Indeed, the Fund’s new orthodoxy is con- cerned with the recessionary effects of fiscal consolidation and, more recently, endorses calls for a more progressive adjustment of the costs of fiscal sustainability. These changes notwithstanding, the IMF’s adaptive incremental transformation on fiscal policy issues falls short Elites on Trial Research in the Sociology of Organizations, Volume 43, 337 369 À Copyright r 2015 by Emerald Group Publishing Limited All rights of reproduction in any form reserved ISSN: 0733-558X/doi:10.1108/S0733-558X20150000043024 337 338 CORNEL BAN of a paradigm shift and is best conceived of as an important recalibra- tion of the precrisis status quo. Keywords: IMF; staff research; Keynesian; New Consensus Macroeconomics; austerity FROM GREAT EXPECTATIONS TO MODEST RECALIBRATIONS In 2008, many expected that the widespread outrage and economic hard- ship caused by the financial crisis would lead to the replacement of the neo- liberal policy paradigm. The rediscovery of Keynesian macroeconomics in 2008 2009 by the lea- ders of the G20 seemed to indicate that change was imminent.À Indeed, mainstream macroeconomic and finance economics seemed on their way to a historical trial.
    [Show full text]
  • György Szapáry [email protected]
    György Szapáry [email protected] Education 1957-61: MA in economics, University of Louvain, Belgium 1966: Ph.D. in economics, University of Louvain. Work 1962 - 64: Research assistant at the University of Louvain 1965 - 66: EC Commission in Brussels. December 1966- August 1993: International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington, DC. Last position: Assistant Director April 1990 - August 1993 Senior IMF Resident Representative in Hungary Sept. 1993 - 99 Deputy Governor of the National Bank of Hungary and member of the Monetary Council. Sept. 1999 – February 2001 Advisor to the President of the National Bank of Hungary. February 2001 – February 2007 Deputy Governor of the National Bank of Hungary and member of the Monetary Council. Other functions 1994 - 95: Alternate Governor for the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development 1993-2001 President of the Board of Directors, International Training Centre for Bankers, Budapest 1997-2001 Member of the Board, Budapest Commodity Exchange 1997-2001 Member of the Pensions Council, Budapest 1995 - 99: President of the Foundation for Enterprise Promotion of the Province of Jász-Nagykun-Szolnok, Hungary Since 1999: Member of the Advisory Council, European Studies Foundation (Europe 2002), Budapest Since 2001 Member of the Euro 50 Group Since 2006: Member of the Gyula Andrássy Foundation, Budapest May 2004 – February 2007 Member of the Economic and Financial Committee of the European Commission and of the European Central Bank’s International Relations Committee. August 2004 – February 2007 Member of the Hungarian Economic and Social Council (a consultative body of the Hungarian Government) Since March Member of the Supervisory Board and Audit Committee of T-Com Hungary Member of a steering group on public finances, EC Commission, Brussels Awards Sándor Popovics Award in recognition for outstanding contribution in the field of banking and monetary policy.
    [Show full text]
  • The Institutional and Political Determinants of Fiscal Adjustment
    Bank of Canada Banque du Canada Working Paper 2006-1 / Document de travail 2006-1 The Institutional and Political Determinants of Fiscal Adjustment by Robert Lavigne ISSN 1192-5434 Printed in Canada on recycled paper Bank of Canada Working Paper 2006-1 February 2006 The Institutional and Political Determinants of Fiscal Adjustment by Robert Lavigne International Department Bank of Canada Ottawa, Ontario, Canada K1A 0G9 [email protected] The views expressed in this paper are those of the author. No responsibility for them should be attributed to the Bank of Canada. iii Contents Acknowledgements. iv Abstract/Résumé. v 1. Introduction . 1 2. The Literature. 3 2.1 Political stability . .4 2.2 Vested interests . .5 2.3 Social divisions . .5 2.4 Institutions . 6 3. Methodology . 7 3.1 Generating the dependent variable . 10 3.2 Selecting the explanatory variables . 15 3.3 Descriptive statistics . 17 3.4 Estimation framework. 19 4. Estimation Results . 22 4.1 Overview. .22 4.2 Developing countries . 23 4.3 Advanced countries. 26 5. Conclusion . 28 References. 31 Tables . 35 iv Acknowledgements The author wishes to thank Ryan Felushko for his excellent research assistance as well as Claudia Verno, Eric Santor, Jim Haley, Larry Schembri, Robert Lafrance, Denise Côté, Rose Cunningham, Marc-André Gosselin, Michael Francis, Glen Keenleyside, and Marianne Johnson for valuable comments and suggestions. v Abstract The author empirically assesses the effects of institutional and political factors on the need and willingness of governments to make large fiscal adjustments. In contrast to earlier studies, which consider the role of political economy determinants only during periods of fiscal consolidation, the author expands the field of analysis by examining periods when governments should be making fiscal efforts but fail to do so (or do not try), as well as periods when no adjustment is required.
    [Show full text]
  • Hyperinflation in Venezuela
    POLICY BRIEF recovery can be possible without first stabilizing the explo- 19-13 Hyperinflation sive price level. Doing so will require changing the country’s fiscal and monetary regimes. in Venezuela: A Since late 2018, authorities have been trying to control the price spiral by cutting back on fiscal expenditures, contracting Stabilization domestic credit, and implementing new exchange rate poli- cies. As a result, inflation initially receded from its extreme Handbook levels, albeit to a very high and potentially unstable 30 percent a month. But independent estimates suggest that prices went Gonzalo Huertas out of control again in mid-July 2019, reaching weekly rates September 2019 of 10 percent, placing the economy back in hyperinflation territory. Instability was also reflected in the premium on Gonzalo Huertas was research analyst at the Peterson Institute foreign currency in the black market, which also increased for International Economics. He worked with C. Fred Bergsten in July after a period of relative calm in previous months. Senior Fellow Olivier Blanchard on macroeconomic theory This Policy Brief describes a feasible stabilization plan and policy. Before joining the Institute, Huertas worked as a researcher at Harvard University for President Emeritus and for Venezuela’s extreme inflation. It places the country’s Charles W. Eliot Professor Lawrence H. Summers, producing problems in context by outlining the economics behind work on fiscal policy, and for Minos A. Zombanakis Professor Carmen Reinhart, focusing on exchange rate interventions. hyperinflations: how they develop, how they disrupt the normal functioning of economies, and how other countries Author’s Note: I am grateful to Adam Posen, Olivier Blanchard, across history have designed policies to overcome them.
    [Show full text]
  • Is There More Room to Negotiate with the IMF on Fiscal Policy?
    November 2014 Paper 9 Is There More Room to Negotiate with the IMF on Fiscal Policy? By Cornel Ban Executive Summary During the 1980s the IMF emerged as a global “bad cop,” demanding harsh austerity measures in countries faced with debt problems. Has the Great Recession changed all that? Is there more room to negotiate with the Fund on fiscal policy? The answer is yes. If we take a close look at what the IMF researchers say and what its most influential official reports proclaim, then we can see that there has been a more “Keynesian” turn at the Fund. This means that today one can find arguments for less austerity, more growth measures and a fairer social distribution of the burden of fiscal sustainability. The IMF has experience a maJor thaw of its fiscal policy doctrine and well-informed member states can use this to their advantage. These changes do not amount to a paradigm shift, a la Paul Krugman’s ideas. Yet crisis-ridden countries that are keen to avoid punishing austerity packages can exploit this doctrinal shift by exploring the policy implications of the IMF’s own official fiscal doctrine and staff research. They can cut less spending, shelter the most disadvantaged, tax more at the top of income distribution and think twice before rushing into a fast austerity package. This much is clear in all of the Fund’s World Economic Outlooks and Global Fiscal Monitors published between 2009 and 2013 with regard to four themes: the main goals of fiscal policy, the basic options for countries with fiscal/without fiscal space, the pace of fiscal consolidation, and the composition of fiscal stimulus and consolidation.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper Fiscal Adjustments: What Do We Know and What Are We Doing?
    No. 10-61 September 2010 WORKING PAPER FISCAL ADJUSTMENTS: What Do We Know and What Are We Doing? By Alberto Alesina The ideas presented in this research are the author’s and do not represent official positions of the Mercatus Center at George Mason University. 1) Introduction ∗ In the aftermath of the Great Recession, many OECD countries need to reduce large public-sector deficits and debts. The conventional wisdom about the political economy of fiscal adjustments goes more or less as follows. Deficit-reduction policies cause recessions. Voters do not like either spending cuts or tax increases, and they dislike the recessions associated with them. Therefore incumbent governments see fiscal adjustments as the kiss of death. They postpone them, and if they finally do implement adjustments, they will pay at the polls. In fact, many governments do the opposite: they try to increase deficits in order to win elections. Thus, we should expect fiscally “loose” governments to stay in office longer and fiscally prudent ones to be voted out of office. If this view—which is a combination of textbook Keynesianism with “conventional” notions of naive voters’ behavior—were true, we would face a dark near-future. Governments would postpone the bitter medicine of fiscal adjustments, and when they eventually enacted tight fiscal policies, they would face both recessions and incumbent political losses. The result would be a sort of so-called “W” recovery along with the political turmoil created by the loss of fiscally responsible governments. Fortunately, the accumulated evidence paints a different picture. First of all, not all fiscal adjustments cause recessions.
    [Show full text]
  • INFLATION and the COSTS of STABILIZATION Public Disclosure Authorized Historical and Recent Experiences and Policy Lessons
    INFLATION AND THE COSTS OF STABILIZATION Public Disclosure Authorized Historical and Recent Experiences and Policy Lessons Andres Solimano Public Disclosure Authorized This article reviews various experiences with stabilization. It first examines sta- bilization programs in the context of hyperinflation-looking at the experi- ences of Austria and Germany in the early 1920s and Bolivia in 1985-and then reviews and interprets the results of orthodox stabilization plans (applied in Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay during the mid-1970s and early 1980s) and those of heterodox programs (the austral plan in Argentina and the cruzado plan in Brazil, with a glance at the Mexican and Israeli experiences). The paper concludes with a discussion of conceptual issues and implications for the de- sign of stabilization policies. Public Disclosure Authorized Theaim of stabilization policies is to bring inflation down on a perma- nent basis and, if possible, at a low economic cost. This article exam- ines several anti-inflationary programs, both historical and recent, giving attention to the response of inflation to different stabilization measures and the real costs-in output losses and cuts in real wages-of bringing infla- tion down in the course of economic stabilization. The purpose is to shed light on the difficulties several economies are experiencing with stabilization and to draw lessons for policy from experience in the field. In the three cases examined-stabilization undertaken in conditions of hy- perinflation, orthodox programs, and heterodox plans (defined in the relevant sections that follow)-we examine the role played in the success or failure of each program by fiscal adjustment, incomes policies, stabilization of the exchange rate, the availability of foreign resources, and conflicts over income Public Disclosure Authorized The World Bank Research Observer, vol.
    [Show full text]
  • The Benefits of Fiscal Consolidation in Uncharted Waters
    OCCASIONAL PAPER SERIES NO 121 / NOVEMBER 2010 THE BENEFITS OF FISCAL CONSOLIDATION IN UNCHARTED WATERS by Philipp Rother, Ludger Schuknecht and Jürgen Stark OCCASIONAL PAPER SERIES NO 121 / NOVEMBER 2010 THE BENEFITS OF FISCAL CONSOLIDATION IN UNCHARTED WATERS by Philipp Rother, Ludger Schuknecht and Jürgen Stark NOTE: This Occasional Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB. In 2010 all ECB publications feature a motif taken from the €500 banknote. This paper can be downloaded without charge from http://www.ecb.europa.eu or from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=1646279. © European Central Bank, 2010 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Internet http://www.ecb.europa.eu Fax +49 69 1344 6000 All rights reserved. Any reproduction, publication and reprint in the form of a different publication, whether printed or produced electronically, in whole or in part, is permitted only with the explicit written authorisation of the ECB or the author(s). Information on all of the papers published in the ECB Occasional Paper Series can be found on the ECB’s website, http://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/scientifi c/ ops/date/html/index.en.html ISSN 1607-1484 (print) ISSN 1725-6534 (online) CONTENTS CONTENTS ABSTRACT 4 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS 5 SUMMARY 6 1 INTRODUCTION
    [Show full text]
  • Constructing Continuity in Economic Ideas in the IMF
    Constructing continuity in economic ideas in the IMF By: Gary Lowery A thesis submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy The University of Sheffield Faculty of Social Sciences Department of Politics April 2016 2 Acknowledgements To Cheryl and Bruce who, for entirely different reasons this would never have happened. To every other family member who has helped along the way, particularly Dave for taking the time to read and offer comments. 3 4 Contents Abstract 9 Introduction 11 Chapter 1: Theoretical approach 31 Chapter 2: The IMF in historical context 57 Chapter 3: Contextualising the failure of neoliberal economic ideas 85 Chapter 4: Economic policy I 109 Chapter 5: Economic policy II 135 Chapter 6: Financial sector liberalization I 163 Chapter 7: Financial sector liberalization II 191 Conclusion 233 Bibliography 5 6 Abbreviations AFC Asian Financial Crisis BIS Bank for International Settlements BWS Bretton Woods System FAD Fiscal Affairs Department FSAP Financial Sector Assessment Programme FSB Financial Stability Board FSF Financial Stability Forum GFSR Global Financial Stability Report GDP Gross Domestic Product IMF International Monetary Fund IPE International Political Economy IR International Relations MacPR Macro-prudential regulation MCMD Monetary and Capital Markets Department MicPR Micro-prudential regulation NDB New Development Bank UMPs Unconventional Monetary Policies VAR Value at Risk WEO World Economic Outlook ZLB Zero Lower Bound 7 8 Abstract In 2008 the neoliberal economic ideas steering the course of global economic governance seemingly collapsed as the world entered into the greatest financial and economic crash since the Great Depression. Initially a range of precipitating causes were offered including lax monetary policy and a miss-pricing of risk, common to which was an assumption that although severe, the downturn was limited to policy failures in a relatively stable economic framework, and therefore constituted a crisis for neoliberal global economic governance.
    [Show full text]