The Interaction of Entrepreneurship and Institutions Magnus

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Interaction of Entrepreneurship and Institutions Magnus IFN Working Paper No. 830, 2010 The Interaction of Entrepreneurship and Institutions Magnus Henrekson and Tino Sanandaji Research Institute of Industrial Economics P.O. Box 55665 SE-102 15 Stockholm, Sweden [email protected] www.ifn.se * The Interaction of Entrepreneurship and Institutions Magnus Henrekson1 and Tino Sanandaji1,2 April 15, 2010 Abstract: Previous research, notably Baumol (1990), has highlighted the role of insti- tutions in channeling entrepreneurial supply into productive, unproductive or destruc- tive activities. However, entrepreneurship is not only influenced by institutions— entrepreneurs often help shape institutions themselves. The bilateral causal relation between entrepreneurs and institutions is examined in this paper. Entrepreneurs affect institutions in at least three ways. Entrepreneurship abiding by existing institutions is occasionally disruptive enough to challenge the foundations of prevailing institutions. Entrepreneurs sometimes have the opportunity to evade institutions, which tends to undermine the effectiveness of the institutions, or cause institutions to change for the better. Lastly, entrepreneurs can directly alter institutions through innovative political entrepreneurship. Like business entrepreneurship, innovative political activity may be productive or unproductive, depending on the incentives facing entrepreneurs. JEL Codes: L5; M13; O31; P14. Keywords: Entrepreneurship; Innovation; Institutions; Regulation; Self-employment. 1 2 Research Institute of Industrial Harris School of Public Policy Economics (IFN) University of Chicago Box 55665 1155 East 60th Street SE-102 15 Stockholm 60637 Chicago IL Phone: +46-8-665 45 00 Fax: +46-8-665 45 99 e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] * This paper builds on work that originally included Robin Douhan as a key contributor. Robin unexpectedly and tragically passed away on 10 August 2009. His death, at the age of 31, was caused by sudden heart failure. His friendship, kindness and talent are deeply missed. Our profound intellectual debt to Robin is hereby acknow- leged. Financial support from the Jan Wallander and Tom Hedelius Research Foundation and from the Gustaf Douglas Research Program on Entrepreneurship at IFN is gratefully acknowledged. We are grateful for useful comments and suggestions on earlier versions of this paper from Johan Almenberg, William Baumol, Selva Baziki, Niclas Berggren, Pete Boettke, Dan Johansson, Linda Nyberg and two anonymous referees. 1. Introduction It has been recognized for some time that institutions shape the actions of entrepreneurs (e.g., Parker, 2004, ch. 3). Yet Baumol‘s seminal work (1990) contributed to the literature by show- ing that institutions determine not only the level, but also the type of entrepreneurship. Indi- viduals put their entrepreneurial talent to use in activities that are productive, unproductive or destructive. The institutional setup or ―the rules of the game‖ dictate relative return, and hence the allocation across these activities. However, institutions do not merely control entrepre- neurs, entrepreneurs control them—through business activity, evasive methods and political entrepreneurship. This paper will explore both sides of this interaction: how the institutional framework influences entrepreneurship and how entrepreneurs in turn influence the emer- gence and evolution of institutions. An influential stream of research has built on the insight that productive abilities can also be used for rent-extracting purposes (e.g., Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny 1991, and Acemoglu 1995). This literature typically stresses that institutions determine the relative rates of return of productive and unproductive types of activities. This relationship has typically been as- sumed to be unilateral, running from institutions to entrepreneurship, while a potential reverse or bilateral causality has been largely neglected.1 Yet entrepreneurship does interact with institutions within the course of a bilateral relation- ship. This possibility has been touched upon previously in the public choice school. Buchanan (1980, p. 14) noted: Faced with a prospect of differentially unfavorable tax treatment by government, a person or a group may (1) engage in lobbying effort; (2) engage directly in politics to secure access to deci- sion-making power, and/or (3) make plans to shift into or out of the affected activity. In general terms, Buchanan concludes that entrepreneurs affect institutions by: (i) market in- novations that alter institutions or the effect of institutions; (ii) evasion of institutions; and (iii) direct political entrepreneurship. 1 Boettke and Coyne (2009) thoroughly analyze the link between institutions and entrepreneurship (and also offer a comprehensive review of the related literature). Boettke and Coyne (2003) probably contains the strong- est assertion that institutions are the ultimate cause of growth, whereas entrepreneurship is merely a proximate cause, since according to them its supply and direction is fully determined by the institutional setup. 1 2. Entrepreneurship Defined and Categorized 2.1 Entrepreneurial Talent In line with Baumol (1990) and Murphy et al. (1991), an entrepreneur is defined here accord- ing to a set of talents. There is no consensus in the literature regarding the nature of these tal- ents; some scholars emphasize cognitive abilities while others point to motivation (prefe- rences).2 We define entrepreneurial talent as a combination of perceptiveness, the ability to detect opportunities, and the capability of undertaking new ventures in response. The defini- tion thus includes both motivation and ability. Profitable business projects, the chance to ap- propriate or earn rents and the possibility to affect policy constitute the opportunities explored here. Self-employment and start-ups embody the most typical forms of business entrepreneurship. Our definition of entrepreneurship precludes many forms of self-employment, however. Most importantly, self-employment that is not innovative in nature does not qualify as entrepre- neurship. In reality, no clear boundary delineating truly innovative entrepreneurship from non-innovative self-employment can be drawn; as a result, we employ a continuum of self- employment activity organized from purely non-innovative to highly dynamic entrepreneur- ship. The idea that innovative individuals contribute to institutional change has a long history in political science. In his case study of political power in New Haven, Dahl (1961) introduced the term ―political entrepreneurs,‖ individuals who recombine resources in the policy arena to bring about change. The political arena in New Haven was entrepreneurial in its alertness to ―citizen desires‖ and ―the ease with which the political stratum can be penetrated‖ (Dahl 1961, p. 93) by new individuals. In accordance with political scientists, we also call entrepre- neurship undertaken with the direct aim of altering institutions political entrepreneurship.3 2 Research on typical entrepreneurial properties focus on two major themes: cognitive abilities and motivation. The model entrepreneur is someone who is alert to opportunities. Cognitively, this amounts to efficiently struc- turing abundant information in order to make feasible judgments (Gaglio and Katz, 2001). It also involves a capacity to think in novel ways (Ward, 2004). In regard to motives, the longest standing characterization of an entrepreneur is associated with the need to achieve and create (Weber, 2001[1905]; McClelland, 1961). Further- more, an entrepreneur exhibits a willingness to take calculated (but not necessarily calculable) risks. Knight (1921) claims that the ability to cope with uncertainty is the main function of entrepreneurship. For a survey of empirical evidence on these motivational aspects, see Rausch and Frese (2000). These properties are consistent with the historical accounts in Schumpeter (1934) and Kirzner (1973, 1992). 3 Van der Steen and Groenewegen (2009) distinguish between political entrepreneurship, institutional entrepre- neurship and policy entrepreneurship. In order to avoid an overabundance of definitions, we use political, institu- tional and policy entrepreneurship interchangeably. 2 The term business or market entrepreneur is used here, somewhat loosely, to refer to tradi- tional Schumpeterian entrepreneurs, distinct from political entrepreneurs. Similar to business entrepreneurs, political entrepreneurs are people who are alert to opportunities, bear risk, reorganize coalitions and resources, and ultimately bring about innovation, be it socially posi- tive or negative. Despite clear differences in undertakings and goals, business and policy entrepreneurs enjoy similar functions. Law-abiding business entrepreneurs and institution-altering political entre- preneurs both discover and meet unfulfilled needs, and both must bear the personal risk asso- ciated with their ventures. Lastly, all entrepreneurs need to coordinate and reorganize the re- sources needed to undertake change, be it capital, labor or political alliances. In light of these parallel functions, it is likely that all types of entrepreneurs share at least some individual cha- racteristics. Lee Kuan Yew, Robert Mugabe and Silvio Berlusconi are some of the major political entre- preneurs discussed here. While they are quite obvious examples, Lee, Mugabe and Berlusconi only form the tip of the iceberg of political entrepreneurship. Innovative political activity oc- curs constantly on all levels of government.
Recommended publications
  • Thesis Notes
    The Costs of the Free Movement of Labor A Thesis Presented to The Faculty of The Cevro Institute In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Arts Maxime Renaud September 2019 "1 CONTENTS ! Introduction......................................................................................................................3! Methodology....................................................................................................................4! Crime rates.......................................................................................................................5! Economic Impacts..........................................................................................................22! Education........................................................................................................................34! Politics and voting patterns............................................................................................39! Conclusion......................................................................................................................45! Sources...........................................................................................................................47! "2 The costs of the free movement of labor The free movement of labor is one of the few topics left on which most economists, and increasingly many politicians, seem to agree. Even President Donald J. Trump, the ultimate "anti-immigrant" politician as far as the media is concerned, pushes for more immigration
    [Show full text]
  • Superentrepreneurs
    SuperEntrepreneurs And how your country can get them TINO SANANDAJI AND NIMA SANANDAJI WITH AN AFTERWORD BY PROFESSOR STEFAN FÖLSTER THE AUTHORS Tino Sanandaji is a full-time researcher at the Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN) in Stockholm. He holds a PhD degree in public policy from the University of Chicago. Nima Sanandaji has written numerous books and reports about issues such as integration, women’s career opportunities and reform policies. He holds a PhD in polymer technology from the Royal Institute of Technology in Stockholm. Acknowledgements Support towards the publication of this study was given by the Institute for Policy Research ISBN No. 978-1-906996-79-6 Centre for Policy Studies, April 2014 Printed by 4 Print, 138 Molesey Avenue, Surrey CONTENTS Summary 1. Introduction 1 2. Defining entrepreneurship 4 3. Fairness and entrepreneurship 10 4. Who has most entrepreneurs? 19 5. The right preconditions 24 6. The right tax rates 30 7. The right regulations 39 8. Charitable instincts? 44 9. Why is the US so entrepreneurial? 49 10. The limits of government action 51 11. Which industries are most open to entrepreneurs? 55 12. Seven characteristics 60 13. Conclusions 63 Afterword: The world’s up and coming superentrepreneurs 65 Bibliography Appendices “Throughout history, poverty is the normal condition of man. Advances which permit this norm to be exceeded – here and there, now and then – are the work of an extremely small minority, frequently despised, often condemned, and almost always opposed by all right-thinking people.” Robert A. Heinlein SUMMARY This report examines about 1,000 self-made men and women who have earned at least $1 billion dollars and who have appeared in Forbes magazine list of the world’s richest people between 1996 and 2010 – the SuperEntrepreneurs.
    [Show full text]
  • Schumpeterian Entrepreneurship in Europe Compared to Other Industrialized Regions
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Henrekson, Magnus; Sanandaji, Tino Working Paper Schumpeterian entrepreneurship in Europe compared to other industrialized regions IFN Working Paper, No. 1170 Provided in Cooperation with: Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN), Stockholm Suggested Citation: Henrekson, Magnus; Sanandaji, Tino (2017) : Schumpeterian entrepreneurship in Europe compared to other industrialized regions, IFN Working Paper, No. 1170, Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN), Stockholm This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/183399 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu IFN Working Paper No. 1170, 2017 Schumpeterian Entrepreneurship in Europe Compared to Other Industrialized Regions Magnus Henrekson and Tino Sanandaji Research Institute of Industrial Economics P.O.
    [Show full text]
  • SCANDINAVIAN Unexceptionalism
    SCANDINAVIAN unexceptionalism CULTURE, MARKETS and the FAILURE of THIRD-WAY SOCIALISM Nima SANANDAJI Foreword by Tom G. Palmer Scandinavian Unexceptionalism SCANDINAVIAN UNEXCEPTIONALISM Culture, Markets and the Failure of Third-Way Socialism NIMA SANANDAJI First published in Great Britain in 2015 by The Institute of Economic Affairs 2 Lord North Street Westminster London SW1P 3LB in association with London Publishing Partnership Ltd www.londonpublishingpartnership.co.uk The mission of the Institute of Economic Affairs is to improve understanding of the fundamental institutions of a free society by analysing and expounding the role of markets in solving economic and social problems. Copyright © The Institute of Economic Affairs 2015 The moral right of the author has been asserted. All rights reserved. Without limiting the rights under copyright reserved above, no part of this publication may be reproduced, stored or introduced into a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means (elec- tronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise), without the prior written permission of both the copyright owner and the publisher of this book. A CIP catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. ISBN 978-0-255-36705-9 (interactive PDF) Many IEA publications are translated into languages other than English or are reprinted. Permission to translate or to reprint should be sought from the Director General at the address above. Typeset in Kepler by T&T Productions Ltd www.tandtproductions.com CONTENTS The
    [Show full text]
  • The Geography of Europe's Brain Business Jobs
    The Geography of Europe’s Brain Business Jobs Dr. Nima Sanandaji Prof. Stefan Fölster European Centre for Policy Reform and Entrepreneurship Supported by NC Advisory AB, advisor to the Nordic Capital Funds 1 The Nordics are well known as a dynamic and creative region. As reported by the Telegraph, Stockholm, the Swedish capital, is the world’s second most prolific tech hub on a per capita basis, behind only Silicon Valley. This isn’t a coincidence. Talented professionals thrive in Scandinavia – a fact that has now received further confirmation through the report you are holding in your hands. As an active investor in Europe – particularly in the Nordic region – Nordic Cap- ital’s continuous goal is to develop understanding of the business environment and ways in which it can be improved. We are therefore pleased to have had the opportunity to support this report. Nordic Capital is one of the longest established and most active private equity investors in the Nordic region, and this report ex- pands understanding of brain business jobs – jobs that are crucial for income and productivity growth. This report gives the reader an excellent overview of the various sectors where brain business jobs are found, as well as an allocation of these sectors between countries and capital regions in Europe. The report also sheds light on the shift- ing landscape for knowledge-intensive businesses. On an ever-changing playing field, it is crucial to closely monitor developments to identify ways in which organ- isations can address changes and work to remain one step ahead. The Nordics are top-ranked in the study, with Sweden ranked number one in terms of attracting brain business jobs.
    [Show full text]
  • The Portrayal of Sweden in American Alt-Right Media, As Exemplified By
    Centre for Languages and Literature Lund University Joint Faculties of Humanities and Theology The portrayal of Sweden in American alt-right media, as exemplified by Breitbart News Author: Viktor Andersson Supervisor: Mattias Nowak EUHK30, Bachelor’s thesis Abstract The alt-right is a fairly recent addition to the pantheon of political ideologies. Its rise to prominence is seen by many as the driving force behind Donald Trump’s presidency. The youth of the ideology has also created a natural relationship between it and the fields of new media and cyberculture. In alt-right media, the topic of Sweden is frequently recurring, and the theme is most often of a nation heading for ruins. This paper sets out to identify and analyse the arguments that alt-right media typically uses in their depiction of Sweden, and the underlying premises behind the arguments. To that end, the basic history and ideological framework of the alt-right is presented and examined. Breitbart News is then identified as an alt-right publication and a leading platform for alt-right thought. By using the Toulmin method of argument analysis, Breitbart’s arguments in their articles about Sweden can be analysed. The results show that Breitbart depicts Sweden as a country where immigration from non- European Islamic countries has led to a society rife with violent and sexual crime. Also, that the Swedish government and media are complicit in a cover-up to conceal the truth of migrant criminality from the Swedish people. Additionally, the results establish that Breitbart’s arguments are fundamentally rooted in alt-right ideology.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal Illusion and Fiscal Obfuscation Tax Perception in Sweden
    SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE! “The Independent Review does not accept “The Independent Review is pronouncements of government officials nor the excellent.” conventional wisdom at face value.” —GARY BECKER, Noble Laureate —JOHN R. MACARTHUR, Publisher, Harper’s in Economic Sciences Subscribe to The Independent Review and receive a free book of your choice* such as the 25th Anniversary Edition of Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government, by Founding Editor Robert Higgs. This quarterly journal, guided by co-editors Christopher J. Coyne, and Michael C. Munger, and Robert M. Whaples offers leading-edge insights on today’s most critical issues in economics, healthcare, education, law, history, political science, philosophy, and sociology. Thought-provoking and educational, The Independent Review is blazing the way toward informed debate! Student? Educator? Journalist? Business or civic leader? Engaged citizen? This journal is for YOU! *Order today for more FREE book options Perfect for students or anyone on the go! The Independent Review is available on mobile devices or tablets: iOS devices, Amazon Kindle Fire, or Android through Magzter. INDEPENDENT INSTITUTE, 100 SWAN WAY, OAKLAND, CA 94621 • 800-927-8733 • [email protected] PROMO CODE IRA1703 Fiscal Illusion and Fiscal Obfuscation Tax Perception in Sweden F TINO SANANDAJI AND BJO¨ RN WALLACE iscal illusion refers to “the notion that systematic misperception of key fiscal parameters may significantly distort fiscal choices by the electorate” (Oates F 1988, 65). The premise is that the tax system’s design can lead to underesti- mation of the costs of public expenditure, with the public not being fully informed of taxation’s total costs.
    [Show full text]
  • Genes, History and Economics
    Genes, History and Economics iii Genes, History and Economics Björn Wallace iv Dissertation for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy, Ph.D. Stockholm School of Economics, 2011 Keywords: Behavioral economics; Experimental economics; Behavioral genetics; Ultimatum game; Risk; Dictator game; Behavioral anomalies; Economic history; Slave trades; Longevity. Genes, History and Economics c SSE and Björn Wallace, 2011 ISBN 978-91-7258-853-0 Printed by: Intellecta Infolog, Göteborg 2011 Distributed by: The Research Secretariat Stockholm School of Economics Box 6501, SE-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden www.hhs.se v Preface This report is a result of a research project carried out at the Economics department at the Stockholm School of Economics (SSE). This volume is submitted as a doctor’s thesis at SSE. The author has been entirely free to conduct and present his research in his own ways as an expression of his own ideas. SSE is grateful for the …nancial support which has made it possible to ful…ll the project. Filip Wijkström Associate Professor SSE Director of Research vi Till min familj viii ix Acknowledgements By the standards of economics I have an unusually high number of coauthors. As a consequence I am indebted to many. Two thirds of this dissertation stems from a research project that I, my supervisor Magnus Johannesson, and David Cesarini have been working on for the last …ve years. For me, Magnus has been the perfect supervisor, and David is as good a coauthor as anyone could wish for. Without their remarkable energy and productivity, this dissertation would not have been what it now is.
    [Show full text]
  • Interpreting Policy Convergence Between the Left and the Right Essays on Education and Immigration
    JOHAN WENNSTRÖM LINKÖPING STUDIES IN ARTS AND SCIENCES NO. 760 INTERPRETING POLICY CONVERGENCE BETWEEN THE LEFT AND THE RIGHT: ESSAYS ON EDUCATION AND IMMIGRATION ON EDUCATION AND THE RIGHT: ESSAYS CONVERGENCE BETWEEN THE LEFT INTERPRETING POLICY INTERPRETING POLICY CONVERGENCE BETWEEN THE LEFT AND THE RIGHT ESSAYS ON EDUCATION AND IMMIGRATION JOHAN WENNSTRÖM 2019 760 Linköping University Department of Management and Engineering Division of Political Science SE- Linköping Linköping © Johan Wennström ISBN ---- ISSN - Printed by LiU-Tryck, Linköping For Malin ............................ Abstract ....................................... List of Essays ................................... Acknowledgements ............................... . Introduction .................................. . e Setting of the Studies ......................... . eoretical Frameworks .......................... . Material and Methods ........................... . Summary of the Essays ........................... . Concluding Discussion........................... References ..................................... ........................................ ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... INTRODUCTORY ESSAY is dissertation is made up of four essays that address major problems in the policy areas of education and immigration in Sweden and an introductory essay that offers an overarching analysis of the results of the four individual studies. e first three essays
    [Show full text]
  • Econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Henrekson, Magnus; Sanandaji, Tino Working Paper Superentrepreneurship in Europe Compared to Other Industrialised Regions IFN Working Paper, No. 1049 Provided in Cooperation with: Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN), Stockholm Suggested Citation: Henrekson, Magnus; Sanandaji, Tino (2014) : Superentrepreneurship in Europe Compared to Other Industrialised Regions, IFN Working Paper, No. 1049, Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN), Stockholm This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/109078 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu IFN Working Paper No. 1049, 2014 Superentrepreneurship in Europe Compared to Other Industrialised Regions Magnus Henrekson and Tino Sanandaji Research Institute of Industrial Economics P.O.
    [Show full text]
  • Swedes and Immigration End of Homogeneity?
    September 2018 SWEDES AND IMMIGRATION END OF HOMOGENEITY? Tino SANANDAJI fondapol.org SWEDES AND IMMIGRATION: END OF HOMOGENEITY? (1) Tino SANANDAJI The Fondation pour l’innovation politique is a French think tank for European integration and free economy. Chair: Nicolas Bazire Vice-chair: Grégoire Chertok Executive Director: Dominique Reynié Chair of Scientific and Evaluation Board: Christophe de Voogd l’innovation politique l’innovation | fondapol 4 FONDATION POUR L’INNOVATION POLITIQUE A French think tank for European integration and free economy The Fondation pour l’innovation politique provides an independent forum for expertise, opinion and exchange aimed at producing and disseminating ideas and proposals. It contributes to pluralism of thought and the renewal of public discussion from a free market, forward-thinking and European perspective. Four main priorities guide the Foundation’s work: economic growth, the environment, values and digital technology. The website www.fondapol.org provides public access to all the Foundation’s work. Anyone can access and use all the data gathered for the various surveys via the platform “Data.fondapol” and the data relating to international surveys is available in several languages. In addition, our blog “Trop Libre” (Too Free) casts a critical eye over the news and the world of ideas. “Trop Libre” also provides extensive monitoring of the effects of the digital revolution on political, economic and social practices in its “Renaissance numérique” (Digital Renaissance) section. Additionally, reflecting the Foundation’s editorial policy, our blog (1) homogeneity? of end immigration: and Swedes “Anthropotechnie” aims to explore new avenues prompted by human enhancement, reproductive cloning, human/machine hybridization, genetic engineering and germline manipulation.
    [Show full text]
  • Small Business Activity Does Not Measure Entrepreneurship Magnus
    IFN Working Paper No. 959, 2013 Small Business Activity Does not Measure Entrepreneurship Magnus Henrekson and Tino Sanandaji Research Institute of Industrial Economics P.O. Box 55665 SE-102 15 Stockholm, Sweden [email protected] www.ifn.se Small Business Activity Does not Measure Entrepreneurship Magnus Henreksona and Tino Sanandajib January 24, 2014 Abstract: Entrepreneurship policy mainly aims to promote innovative “Schumpeterian” entrepreneurship. However, the rate of entrepreneurship is commonly proxied using quantity-based metrics, such as small business activity, the self-employment rate or the number of startups. We argue that those metrics give rise to misleading inferences regarding high-impact Schumpeterian entrepreneurship. In order to unambiguously identify high-impact entrepreneurs we focus on self- made billionaires (in USD) who appear in Forbes Magazine’s list and who became wealthy by founding new firms. We identify 996 such billionaire entrepreneurs in fifty countries in 1996–2010, a systematic cross-country study of billionaire entrepreneurs. The rate of billionaire entrepreneurs correlates negatively with self-employment, small business ownership and firm startup rates. Countries with higher income, higher trust, lower taxes, more venture capital investment and lower regulatory burdens have higher billionaire entrepreneurship rates but less self-employment. Despite its limitations, the number of billionaire entrepreneurs appears to be a plausible cross-country measure of Schumpeterian entrepreneurship. Keywords: Entrepreneurship;
    [Show full text]