Forward Pricing

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Forward Pricing Forward pricing Assets with no cash flows Assets with know discrete cash flows Assets with continuous cash flows (index) Finance 7523 Spring 1999 Assistant Professor Steven C. Mann Neeley School , TCU Forward price of a stock S(0) = $25. Stock pays no dividends is(6 month) = 7.12% ( T = 1/2 ) if you borrow $25 today you repay $25[1+ 0.0712(1/2)] = $25.89 f = six month forward price of stock Consider strategy: now T=6 months later borrow $25 25.00 -$25.89 buy stock - 25.00 S(T) sell 6-month forward 0 - [ S(T) - f ] total 0 f - 25.89 = f - S(0)[ 1 + is T] Arbitrage-free forward pricing: f (0,T) = S(0)(1 + isT) = $25.89 Cash and Carry forward pricing Forward contract with delivery date T; spot asset with no cash flows “Cash and carry” strategy: now at date T buy asset at cost S(0) - S(0) S(T) borrow asset cost + S(0) -S(0)(1+isT) sell forward at f(0,T) 0 -[ S(T) -f(0,T)] Total 0 f(0,T) - S(0)(1+isT) Forward price is “future value” f(0,T) = S(0)( 1 + isT) of spot price f(0,T) [ 1/(1+isT)] = S(0) S(0) = f(0,T)B(0,T) Spot price is “present value” of the forward price S(t) = f(t,T) B(t,T) Forward valuation (post-initiation and “off-market”) Value = V[forward price, time] at initiation, value is zero: V[ f(0,T), 0 ] ð 0. At maturity: V[ f(0,T), T ] = S(T) - f(0,T) at some time t (post initiation): V[ f(0,T), t ] = ? 1) Valuation by offset: At time t: long f(0,T). Sell f(t,T) value at T: S(T) - f(0,T) - [ S(T) - f(t,T) ] total value at T: f(t,T) - f(0,T) value at t: B(t,T)[ f(t,T) - f(0,T) ] 2) Valuation by algebra: V[f(0,T),t] = PV( V[f(0,T),T]) = PV[ S(T) - f(0,T)] note S(t) = PV[S(T)]; and S(t) = f(t,T)B(t,T) (prior page) so V(f(0,T),t] = f(t,T)B(t,T) - f(0,T)B(t,T) =B(t,T) [ f(t,T) - f(0,T)] = PV(price difference) Example - problem 2.3: forward pricing and valuation Non-dividend paying asset; S(0) = $65 contract maturity is 90 days simple interest rate is 4.50% ; daycount is actual/365. a) find forward price f(0,90/365) = S(0)(1+is(90/365)) = $65(1 + 0.045(90/365) ) = $65.72 value of contract is zero. b) You are asked to value a 90-day forward on this asset with delivery price = $60. This is an “off-market’ forward: value is nonzero. Value of long forward with off-market delivery price: value = PV( difference in forward prices) = B(0,T)[ market forward price - contract forward price] = B(0,T) [ 65.72 - 60.00] = (1 + 0.045(90/365)) -1 [$ 5.72] =(0.98903)($5.72) = $5.66 Example - problem 2.4: forward pricing and valuation Prob 2.4: S(0) = $45. Non-dividend paying asset contract maturity is 100 days simple interest rate is 4.75% ; daycount is actual/365. a) find current forward price f(0,100/365) f(0,100/365) = $45.00(1+ 0.0475(100/365)) = $45.59 b) You are long 100 day forward to buy asset at $50.25. If you sell a 100 day forward at current price, what is payoff at T? At maturity: long: S(T) - $50.25 short -[ S(T) - $45.59] net: $45.59 - $50.25 = - $4.66. c) what is the present value of your net position? PV = B(t,T)[ f(t,T) - f(0,T)] = [1/(1+0.0475(100/365)](-4.66) = (0.9872)(-4.66) = -$4.60 Assets with known cash flows Example: Zero-coupon yield curve 12 month T-note (simple interest) par = $1000. month T is(T) B(0,T) Coupon=10% semi-annual 6 1/2 7.18% 0.9653 $50 $1050 9 9/12 7.66% 0.9456 12 1 7.90% 0.9267 0 ! 1 Spot bond price Bc(0,12) = $50.00 B(0,6) + $1050.00 B(0,12) = $50.00(.9653) + $1050.00(.9268) = $48.27 + $ 973.12 = $1021.39 Forward contract does not receive coupon at T=6 months Forward pricing: assets with known cash flows Strategy 1: cost now t1 =6 months at T=9 months a) buy bond 1021.39 + 50.00 Bc(9,12) b) borrow PV(coupon) - 50.00 B(0,6) - 50.00 total 1021.39 - 48.27 0 Bc(9,12) [S(0) - d(t1)B(0,t1)] Strategy 2: cost now t1= 6 months at T=9 months a) enter long forward 0 0 Bc(9,12) - f (0,9) b) lend PV( f (0,9)) f (0,9) B(0,9) 0 f (0,9) (buy bill ) total f (0,9) B(0,9) 0 Bc(9,12) Each strategy has same payoff: must have same cost to avoid arbitrage f (0,9) B(0,9) = $1021.39 -28.27 = $973.12 f (0,9) = $ 973.12/0.9457 = $1029.03 in general: f (0,T)B(0,T) = S(0) - d(t1)B(0,t1) General forward pricing for assets with known cash flows Strategy 1: cost now at t1 at T a) buy asset S(0) + d(t1) S(T) b) borrow PV(d(t1)) - d(t1) B(0,t1) - d(t1) total S(0) - d(t1)B(0,t1) 0 S(T) Strategy 2: cost now at t1 at T a) enter long forward 0 0 S(T) - f (0,T) b) lend PV( f (0,T)) f (0,T) B(0,T) 0 f (0,T) (buy bill ) total f (0,T) B(0,T) 0 S(T) Each strategy has same payoff: must have same cost to avoid arbitrage in general: f (0,T)B(0,T) = S(0) - d(t1)B(0,t1) for N known flows: N f (0,T)B(0,T) = S(0) - S d(ti)B(0,ti) i=1 Example: forward pricing - asset pays dividends Problem #2.7 S(0) = 63 * = $63.375 Bill prices: stock pays dividends: $1.50 in 1 month 1 month: 0.9967 $2.00 in 7 months 7 month : 0.9741 12 month: 0.9512 Find price of one-year forward contract written on stock. Use: f (0,T) B(0,T) = S(0) - PV(dividends) f (0,12) B(0,12) = S(0) - d(1)B(0,1) - d(7)B(0,7) f (0,12) (0.9512) = $63.375 - $1.50(0.9967) - $2.00(0.9741) f (0,12) = $59.93/(0.9512) f (0,12) = $63.01 Assets with continuous payouts (index, currency) for N known flows: N f (0,T)B(0,T) = S(0) - S d(t )B(0,t ) i=1 i i = S(0) - PV(cash payout to time T) if asset pays continuous yield then PV(dividends to time T) = S(0)[ 1 - exp(-dyT)] (J&T ch 2 appendix - note typo ) so that f (0,T)B(0,T) = S(0) - [ S(0) [ 1 - exp(-dyT)]] f (0,T)B(0,T) = S(0) exp(-dyT) write B(0,T) as continuous discount factor: B(0,T) = exp(-rT) then f (0,T) = S(0) exp ( (r-dy)T) Example: Index forward pricing Problem #2.9: S&P500 Index = 495.00 div yield = 2.50% continuous (365 day year) a) Given 95-day discount rate =5.75% (360 day year), find f (0,95 days) B(0,95) = 1 - 0.0575(95/360) = 0.984826 exp(-dyT) = exp(-0.025(95/365)) = 0.993514 f (0,95)B(0,95) = S(0)exp(-dyT) f (0,95) = 495.00 (0.993514) / (0.98426) = 499.37. b) One day later index is at 493. 94-day discount is 5.75%. What is the value of the contract in part (a)? B(0,94) = 1 - 0.0575(94/360) = 0.984986 exp(-dyT) = exp(-0.025(94/365)) = 0.993582 f (0,94) = 493.00(0.993582)/(0.984986) = 497.20 value of prior contract = B(0,94) ( 497.20 - 499.37) = 0.984986 (-2.17) = -2.04 Commodity Forwards: Storage cost Storage: Define: G = cost of storing asset for (0,T) (per unit); paid time 0. “Cost of carry” strategy: cost now value at date T buy asset at cost S(0), pay storage S(0) + G S(T) borrow asset cost and storage cost -[S(0) + G] -[S(0)+G](1+isT) sell forward at f(0,T) 0 -[ S(T) -f(0,T)] Total 0 f(0,T) - [S(0) +G](1+isT) f (0,T)B(0,T) = S(0) + G Example: 180-day Gold forward (100 troy oz.) Spot Gold S(0) = $368 / oz. cost of storage for 180 days = 2.25 / oz., paid at time 0. 180 days simple interest rate = 3.875% annualized (actual/actual). f (0,180) = (368 + 2.25)(1 + 0.03875(180/365)) = 370.25(1.01911) = $377.33 / oz. If storage cost G is defined to be paid at T, then f(0,T)B(0,T) = S(0) + G B(0,T) so f (0,180) = 368(1+0.03875(180/365)) + 2.25 = $377.28 / oz. Commodity Forwards: Convenience yield Convenience yield: Define: Y(0,T) = present value (time 0) of benefits provided by holding asset.
Recommended publications
  • Forward Contracts and Futures a Forward Is an Agreement Between Two Parties to Buy Or Sell an Asset at a Pre-Determined Future Time for a Certain Price
    Forward contracts and futures A forward is an agreement between two parties to buy or sell an asset at a pre-determined future time for a certain price. Goal To hedge against the price fluctuation of commodity. • Intension of purchase decided earlier, actual transaction done later. • The forward contract needs to specify the delivery price, amount, quality, delivery date, means of delivery, etc. Potential default of either party: writer or holder. Terminal payoff from forward contract payoff payoff K − ST ST − K K ST ST K long position short position K = delivery price, ST = asset price at maturity Zero-sum game between the writer (short position) and owner (long position). Since it costs nothing to enter into a forward contract, the terminal payoff is the investor’s total gain or loss from the contract. Forward price for a forward contract is defined as the delivery price which make the value of the contract at initiation be zero. Question Does it relate to the expected value of the commodity on the delivery date? Forward price = spot price + cost of fund + storage cost cost of carry Example • Spot price of one ton of wood is $10,000 • 6-month interest income from $10,000 is $400 • storage cost of one ton of wood is $300 6-month forward price of one ton of wood = $10,000 + 400 + $300 = $10,700. Explanation Suppose the forward price deviates too much from $10,700, the construction firm would prefer to buy the wood now and store that for 6 months (though the cost of storage may be higher).
    [Show full text]
  • Pricing of Index Options Using Black's Model
    Global Journal of Management and Business Research Volume 12 Issue 3 Version 1.0 March 2012 Type: Double Blind Peer Reviewed International Research Journal Publisher: Global Journals Inc. (USA) Online ISSN: 2249-4588 & Print ISSN: 0975-5853 Pricing of Index Options Using Black’s Model By Dr. S. K. Mitra Institute of Management Technology Nagpur Abstract - Stock index futures sometimes suffer from ‘a negative cost-of-carry’ bias, as future prices of stock index frequently trade less than their theoretical value that include carrying costs. Since commencement of Nifty future trading in India, Nifty future always traded below the theoretical prices. This distortion of future prices also spills over to option pricing and increase difference between actual price of Nifty options and the prices calculated using the famous Black-Scholes formula. Fisher Black tried to address the negative cost of carry effect by using forward prices in the option pricing model instead of spot prices. Black’s model is found useful for valuing options on physical commodities where discounted value of future price was found to be a better substitute of spot prices as an input to value options. In this study the theoretical prices of Nifty options using both Black Formula and Black-Scholes Formula were compared with actual prices in the market. It was observed that for valuing Nifty Options, Black Formula had given better result compared to Black-Scholes. Keywords : Options Pricing, Cost of carry, Black-Scholes model, Black’s model. GJMBR - B Classification : FOR Code:150507, 150504, JEL Code: G12 , G13, M31 PricingofIndexOptionsUsingBlacksModel Strictly as per the compliance and regulations of: © 2012.
    [Show full text]
  • Monte Carlo Strategies in Option Pricing for Sabr Model
    MONTE CARLO STRATEGIES IN OPTION PRICING FOR SABR MODEL Leicheng Yin A dissertation submitted to the faculty of the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Department of Statistics and Operations Research. Chapel Hill 2015 Approved by: Chuanshu Ji Vidyadhar Kulkarni Nilay Argon Kai Zhang Serhan Ziya c 2015 Leicheng Yin ALL RIGHTS RESERVED ii ABSTRACT LEICHENG YIN: MONTE CARLO STRATEGIES IN OPTION PRICING FOR SABR MODEL (Under the direction of Chuanshu Ji) Option pricing problems have always been a hot topic in mathematical finance. The SABR model is a stochastic volatility model, which attempts to capture the volatility smile in derivatives markets. To price options under SABR model, there are analytical and probability approaches. The probability approach i.e. the Monte Carlo method suffers from computation inefficiency due to high dimensional state spaces. In this work, we adopt the probability approach for pricing options under the SABR model. The novelty of our contribution lies in reducing the dimensionality of Monte Carlo simulation from the high dimensional state space (time series of the underlying asset) to the 2-D or 3-D random vectors (certain summary statistics of the volatility path). iii To Mom and Dad iv ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS First, I would like to thank my advisor, Professor Chuanshu Ji, who gave me great instruction and advice on my research. As my mentor and friend, Chuanshu also offered me generous help to my career and provided me with great advice about life. Studying from and working with him was a precious experience to me.
    [Show full text]
  • Forward and Futures Contracts
    FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 Forward and Futures Contracts These notes explore forward and futures contracts, what they are and how they are used. We will learn how to price forward contracts by using arbitrage and replication arguments that are fundamental to derivative pricing. We shall also learn about the similarities and differences between forward and futures markets and the differences between forward and futures markets and prices. We shall also consider how forward and future prices are related to spot market prices. Keywords: Arbitrage, Replication, Hedging, Synthetic, Speculator, Forward Value, Maintainable Margin, Limit Order, Market Order, Stop Order, Back- wardation, Contango, Underlying, Derivative. Reading: You should read Hull chapters 1 (which covers option payoffs as well) and chapters 2 and 5. 1 Background From the 1970s financial markets became riskier with larger swings in interest rates and equity and commodity prices. In response to this increase in risk, financial institutions looked for new ways to reduce the risks they faced. The way found was the development of exchange traded derivative securities. Derivative securities are assets linked to the payments on some underlying security or index of securities. Many derivative securities had been traded over the counter for a long time but it was from this time that volume of trading activity in derivatives grew most rapidly. The most important types of derivatives are futures, options and swaps. An option gives the holder the right to buy or sell the underlying asset at a specified date for a pre-specified price. A future gives the holder the 1 2 FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS obligation to buy or sell the underlying asset at a specified date for a pre- specified price.
    [Show full text]
  • What's Price Got to Do with Term Structure?
    What’s Price Got To Do With Term Structure? An Introduction to the Change in Realized Roll Yields: Redefining How Forward Curves Are Measured Contributors: Historically, investors have been drawn to the systematic return opportunities, or beta, of commodities due to their potentially inflation-hedging and Jodie Gunzberg, CFA diversifying properties. However, because contango was a persistent market Vice President, Commodities condition from 2005 to 2011, occurring in 93% of the months during that time, [email protected] roll yield had a negative impact on returns. As a result, it may have seemed to some that the liquidity risk premium had disappeared. Marya Alsati-Morad Associate Director, Commodities However, as discussed in our paper published in September 2013, entitled [email protected] “Identifying Return Opportunities in A Demand-Driven World Economy,” the environment may be changing. Specifically, the world economy may be Peter Tsui shifting from one driven by expansion of supply to one driven by expansion of Director, Index Research & Design demand, which could have a significant impact on commodity performance. [email protected] This impact would be directly related to two hallmarks of a world economy driven by expansion of demand: the increasing persistence of backwardation and the more frequent flipping of term structures. In order to benefit in this changing economic environment, the key is to implement flexibility to keep pace with the quickly changing term structures. To achieve flexibility, there are two primary ways to modify the first-generation ® flagship index, the S&P GSCI . The first method allows an index to select contracts with expirations that are either near- or longer-dated based on the commodity futures’ term structure.
    [Show full text]
  • Term Structure Lattice Models
    Term Structure Models: IEOR E4710 Spring 2005 °c 2005 by Martin Haugh Term Structure Lattice Models 1 The Term-Structure of Interest Rates If a bank lends you money for one year and lends money to someone else for ten years, it is very likely that the rate of interest charged for the one-year loan will di®er from that charged for the ten-year loan. Term-structure theory has as its basis the idea that loans of di®erent maturities should incur di®erent rates of interest. This basis is grounded in reality and allows for a much richer and more realistic theory than that provided by the yield-to-maturity (YTM) framework1. We ¯rst describe some of the basic concepts and notation that we need for studying term-structure models. In these notes we will often assume that there are m compounding periods per year, but it should be clear what changes need to be made for continuous-time models and di®erent compounding conventions. Time can be measured in periods or years, but it should be clear from the context what convention we are using. Spot Rates: Spot rates are the basic interest rates that de¯ne the term structure. De¯ned on an annual basis, the spot rate, st, is the rate of interest charged for lending money from today (t = 0) until time t. In particular, 2 mt this implies that if you lend A dollars for t years today, you will receive A(1 + st=m) dollars when the t years have elapsed.
    [Show full text]
  • Forward and Future Implied Volatility
    May 24, 2011 10:49 WSPC/S0219-0249 104-IJTAF SPI-J071 S0219024911006590 International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance Vol. 14, No. 3 (2011) 407–432 c World Scientific Publishing Company DOI: 10.1142/S0219024911006590 FORWARD AND FUTURE IMPLIED VOLATILITY PAUL GLASSERMAN Columbia Business School [email protected] QI WU∗ Department of APAM Columbia University 200 S.W. Mudd Building New York, NY 10027, USA [email protected] Received 14 June 2010 Accepted 12 January 2011 We address the problem of defining and calculating forward volatility implied by option prices when the underlying asset is driven by a stochastic volatility process. We exam- ine alternative notions of forward implied volatility and the information required to extract these measures from the prices of European options at fixed maturities. We then specialize to the SABR model and show how the asymptotic expansion of the bivariate transition density in Wu (forthcoming) allows calibration of the SABR model with piecewise constant parameters and calculation of forward volatility. We then inves- tigate empirically whether current option prices at multiple maturities contain useful information in predicting future option prices and future implied volatility. We under- take this investigation using data on options on the euro-dollar, sterling-dollar, and dollar-yen exchange rates. We find that prices across maturities do indeed have pre- dictive value. Moreover, we find that model-based forward volatility extracts this pred- icative information better than a standard “model-free” measure of forward volatility and better than spot implied volatility. The enhancement to out-of-sample forecasting accuracy gained from model-based forward volatility is greatest at longer forecasting horizons.
    [Show full text]
  • Forward Price • the Payoff of a Forward Contract at Maturity Is
    Forward Price ² The payo® of a forward contract at maturity is ST ¡ X: ² Forward contracts do not involve any initial cash flow. ² The forward price is the delivery price which makes the forward contract zero valued. { That is, f = 0 when X = F . °c 2011 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 384 Forward Price (concluded) ² The delivery price cannot change because it is written in the contract. ² But the forward price may change after the contract comes into existence. { The value of a forward contract, f, is 0 at the outset. { It will fluctuate with the spot price thereafter. { This value is enhanced when the spot price climbs and depressed when the spot price declines. ² The forward price also varies with the maturity of the contract. °c 2011 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 385 Forward Price: Underlying Pays No Income Lemma 9 For a forward contract on an underlying asset providing no income, F = Ser¿ : (32) ² If F > Ser¿ : { Borrow S dollars for ¿ years. { Buy the underlying asset. { Short the forward contract with delivery price F . °c 2011 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 386 Proof (concluded) ² At maturity: { Deliver the asset for F . { Use Ser¿ to repay the loan, leaving an arbitrage pro¯t of F ¡ Ser¿ > 0. ² If F < Ser¿ , do the opposite. °c 2011 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 387 Example ² r is the annualized 3-month riskless interest rate. ² S is the spot price of the 6-month zero-coupon bond. ² A new 3-month forward contract on a 6-month zero-coupon bond should command a delivery price of Ser=4.
    [Show full text]
  • Implied Volatility Surface by Delta Implied Volatility Surface by Delta
    Implied Volatility Surface by Delta Implied Volatility Surface by Delta................................................................................................................ 1 General........................................................................................................................................................ 1 Difference with other IVolatility.com datasets........................................................................................... 2 Application of parameterized volatility curves........................................................................................... 3 Application of Delta surface ...................................................................................................................... 3 Why Surface by Delta ? .............................................................................................................................. 3 Methodology and example.......................................................................................................................... 4 Implied volatility parameterization......................................................................................................... 4 Delta surface building............................................................................................................................. 5 Example .................................................................................................................................................. 6 Document describes IVolatility.com
    [Show full text]
  • Swaption Volatility Surface Construction Tutorial | Finpricing
    How to Construct Swaption Volatility Surfaces Michael Taylor FinPricing https://finpricing.com/lib/IrVolIntroduction.html Swaption Volatility An implied volatility is the volatility implied by the market price of an option based on the Black-Scholes option pricing model. An interest rate swaption volatility surface is a four-dimensional plot of the implied volatility of a swaption as a function of strike and expiry and tenor. The term structures of implied volatilities which provide indications of the market’s near- and long-term uncertainty about future short- and long-term swap rates. A crucial property of the implied volatility surface is the absence of arbitrage. Swaption Volatility Summary ▪ Swaption Volatility Surface Introduction ▪ The Summary of Volatility Surface Construction Approaches ▪ Arbitrage Free Conditions ▪ The SABR Model ▪ Swaption Volatility Surface Construction via The SABR Model Swaption Volatility Swaption Volatility Surface Introduction ▪ An implied volatility is the volatility implied by the market price of an option based on the Black-Scholes option pricing model. ▪ An swaption volatility surface is a four-dimensional plot of the implied volatility of a swaption as a function of strike and expiry and tenor. ▪ The term structures of implied volatilities provide indications of the market’s near- and long-term uncertainty about future short- and long- term swap rates. ▪ Vol skew or smile pattern is directly related to the conditional non- nomality of the underlying return risk-neutral distribution. ▪ In particular, a smile reflects fat tails in the return distribution whereas a skew indicates return distribution asymmetry. ▪ A crucial property of the implied volatility surface is the absence of arbitrage.
    [Show full text]
  • MANAGING SMILE RISK 1. Introduction. European Options Are
    MANAGING SMILE RISK PATRICK S. HAGAN¤, DEEP KUMARy ,ANDREWS.LESNIEWSKIz , AND DIANA E. WOODWARDx Abstract. Market smiles and skews are usually managed by using local volatility models alaDupire. We discover that the dynamics of the market smile predicted by local vol models is opposite of observed market behavior: when the price of the underlying decreases, local vol models predict that the smile shifts to higher prices; when the price increases, these models predict that the smile shifts to lower prices. Due to this contradiction between model and market, delta and vega hedges derived from the model can be unstable and may perform worse than naive Black-Scholes’ hedges. To eliminate this problem, we derive the SABR model, a stochastic volatility model in which the forward value satis…es ¯ dF^ =^aF^ dW1 d^a = º^adW2 and the forward F^ and volatility ^a are correlated: dW1dW2 = ½dt. We use singular perturbation techniques to obtain the prices of European options under the SABR model, and from these prices we obtain explicit, closed-form algebraic formulas for the implied volatility as functions of today’s forward price f = F^(0) and the strike K. These formulas immediately yield the market price, the market risks, including vanna and volga risks, and show that the SABR model captures the correct dynamics of the smile. We apply the SABR model to USD interest rate options, and …nd good agreement between the theoretical and observed smiles. Key words. smiles, skew, dynamic hedging, stochastic vols, volga, vanna 1. Introduction. European options are often priced and hedged using Black’s model, or, equivalently, the Black-Scholes model.
    [Show full text]
  • IFM-01-18 Page 1 of 104 SOCIETY of ACTUARIES EXAM IFM
    SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES EXAM IFM INVESTMENT AND FINANCIAL MARKETS EXAM IFM SAMPLE QUESTIONS AND SOLUTIONS DERIVATIVES These questions and solutions are based on the readings from McDonald and are identical to questions from the former set of sample questions for Exam MFE. The question numbers have been retained for ease of comparison. These questions are representative of the types of questions that might be asked of candidates sitting for Exam IFM. These questions are intended to represent the depth of understanding required of candidates. The distribution of questions by topic is not intended to represent the distribution of questions on future exams. In this version, standard normal distribution values are obtained by using the Cumulative Normal Distribution Calculator and Inverse CDF Calculator For extra practice on material from Chapter 9 or later in McDonald, also see the actual Exam MFE questions and solutions from May 2007 and May 2009 May 2007: Questions 1, 3-6, 8, 10-11, 14-15, 17, and 19 Note: Questions 2, 7, 9, 12-13, 16, and 18 do not apply to the new IFM curriculum May 2009: Questions 1-3, 12, 16-17, and 19-20 Note: Questions 4-11, 13-15, and 18 do not apply to the new IFM curriculum Note that some of these remaining items (from May 2007 and May 2009) may refer to “stock prices following geometric Brownian motion.” In such instances, use the following phrase instead: “stock prices are lognormally distributed.” November 2020 correction: Question 1 was edited to correct an error in the earlier version. Copyright 2018 by the Society of Actuaries IFM-01-18 Page 1 of 104 Introductory Derivatives Questions 1.
    [Show full text]