Reference: 20150441

12 November 2015

Thank you for your Official Information Act request, received on 14 October 2015. You requested the following:

“This request for information is made under the Official Information Act. It relates to any work undertaken by The Treasury in relation to economic, financial and regulatory policy advice in the area of sugar . The request seeks: 1. Copies of any Working Papers, commissioned by The Treasury relating to the issue of a sugar and or sugar sweetened beverages (SSB) tax for the 2014 and 2015 year to date. 2. Copies of any Analytical Papers of data and research undertaken or commissioned from internal or external authors by The Treasury on a sugar tax and or SSB tax for the same period. 3. Copies of any Policy Perspective Papers on a sugar tax and or SSB tax for the same period. 4. Copies of any communications received by The Treasury that seeks The Treasury’s modelling on a sugar tax and or SSB tax for the same period.”

Information Being Released

Please find enclosed the following documents:

Item Date Document Description Decision

1. February 2014 Treasury Intern Research Report: Withhold junior official’s Regulatory Responses to address details under s9(2)(g)(i). the growing problem in New Zealand 2. 16 December Treasury Report: Options for Withhold junior official’s 2014 regulatory responses to the details under s9(2)(g)(i) and growing obesity problem personal contact details under s9(2)(a).

3. February 2015 (Incomplete Draft) Treasury Intern Withhold junior official’s Research Report: A Conceptual details under s9(2)(g)(i). Basis and Evidence Base for Health Tax

I have decided to release the documents listed above, subject to information being withheld under one or more of the following sections of the Official Information Act, as applicable:

• personal contact details of officials, under section 9(2)(a) – to protect the privacy of natural persons, including deceased people, and

• names and contact details of junior officials and certain sensitive advice, under section 9(2)(g)(i) – to maintain the effective conduct of public affairs through the free and frank expression of opinions.

It is worth noting that documents 1 and 3 are not Treasury opinion and that document 3 is an incomplete draft. The Treasury internship programme requires interns to produce a report on a topic supplied by the policy team they are assigned to. Alongside a mentor, they undertake their own research and engagements to feed into this report. The reports are high level and are sometimes not finished in the three-month time period they are limited to. Therefore, the reports do not represent a Treasury position and should not be taken as such.

In making my decision, I have considered the public interest considerations in section 9(1) of the Official Information Act.

Please note that this letter (with your personal details removed) and enclosed documents may be published on the Treasury website.

This fully covers the information you requested. You have the right to ask the Ombudsman to investigate and review my decision.

Yours sincerely

Ben McBride Manager, Health

2

Information Being Released OIA 20150441

Doc 1 Page 1 Doc 2 Page 44 Doc 3 Page 53

Doc 1 Page 1 of 76 Released

y r u s

e a r T

a n d l

e a Regulatory responses to address Z

the growing obesity problem in New w Zealand e N Withheld under s9(2)(g)(i)

February 2014

i

Doc 1 Page 2 of 76 Released

i

Doc 1 Page 3 of 76 Released

I NTERNSHIP R ESEARCH Regulatory responses to address the growing obesity problem in P RO J E CT New Zealand

M O N T H / Y E A R February 2014

NZ TREASURY New Zealand Treasury PO Box 3724 Wellington 6015 NEW ZEALAND Email [email protected] Telephone 64-4-472-2733 Website www.treasury.govt.nz

DISCLAIMER The views, opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this Policy Perspectives Paper are strictly those of the author(s). They do not necessarily reflect the views of the New Zealand Treasury. The Treasury takes no responsibility for any errors or omissions in, or for the correctness of, the information contained in these Policy Perspectives Papers. The paper is presented not as policy, but to inform and stimulate wider debate. Acknowledgements: Ministry of Health, Ministry of Primary Industries, Boyd Swinburn, Elaine Rush, Geoff Simmons, Tony Blakely, Jim Mann, and Louise Signal for their contributions to the paper.

ii

Doc 1 Page 4 of 76 Released

Table of Contents

List of Figures iv

1 Executive Summary 1

2 Introduction 3

3 Overview of the problem 4

3.1 Obesity in New Zealand 4 3.2 Factors seen to underpin the problem 6 3.3 Costs and impacts on Living Standards 7

4 Actions currently undertaken 11

5 Regulatory measures 13

5.1 Regulatory options considered 13 5.2 Criteria for assessing regulatory measures 14 5.3 Interpretive front of pack labelling 14 5.4 Regulation of marketing to children 17 5.5 Pricing mechanisms 19 5.5.1 Sugar-sweetened beverage tax 20 5.5.2 Saturated fat tax 22 5.5.3 Removal of GST from fruit and vegetables 25

6 Recommendations 28

6.1 Recommended approach 28 6.2 Areas of further work 29 6.2.1 Sugar-sweetened beverage tax 29 6.2.2 Regulation of marketing to children 29 6.2.3 Front of pack labelling 29

7 Appendix 30

8 Reference List 34

iii

Doc 1 Page 5 of 76 Released

List of Figures

Figure 1: Overweight and Obesity in the OECD (Sassi, 2010) 4 Figure 2: Obesity trends in New Zealand 2006-2013 (Ministry of Health, 2013). 5 Figure 3: Attributable burden for selected risk factors 2006 (Ministry of Health, 2013). 8 Figure 4: Treasury Living Standards Framework (Treasury, 2014) 9 Figure 5: Policy options, goals and desired outcomes 13 Figure 6: Example of Traffic Light labelling UK (Food Standards Agency Scotland, 2013). 15

iv

Doc 1 Page 6 of 76 Released

1 Executive Summary

This report assesses the regulatory responses appropriate for New Zealand to employ in order to address the growing problem of obesity.

In 2013 the New Zealand adult obesity rate was 31 per cent, with a further 35 per cent overweight (Ministry of Health, 2013). This rate has increased threefold since 1977 representing an escalating problem. Obesity has significant impacts upon health and productivity costs, with the growing problem having serious implications for future economic growth and sustainability. It is important to understand how improvements in health outcomes can provide benefits to population wellbeing.

Obesity is a complex problem with a number of inter-related causes, which are still not completely understood. The current problem in New Zealand is generally seen to stem from an obesogenic environment: an environment that facilitates and promotes weight gain.

The current policy approach to obesity in New Zealand focuses on initiatives that aim to support and encourage individuals to lead healthier lifestyles and encourage the food industry to provide healthier products and inform consumers.

The purpose of this paper is to investigate the role and effectiveness of a range of regulatory measures that the government could implement in response to the growing obesity crisis. The options considered are:

• An interpretive front of pack labelling system

• Regulation of marketing to children

• A sugar-sweetened beverage tax

• A saturated fat tax

• Removal of GST from fruit and vegetables.

The options focus on targeting the price and information aspects of the obesogenic environment. The tax and GST options have been analysed from a health policy perspective, rather than focusing on the precise mechanism (for example, tax vs. ). Each measure has been selected due to international application and substantive evidence.

From analysis, it is evident that promising areas for further work include a sugar-sweetened beverage tax, an interpretive front of pack labelling system, and regulation of marketing to children.

A sugar-sweetened beverage tax would lead to a reduction in the consumption of sugar- sweetened beverages. According to Briggs et al. (2013) a 20 per cent tax on sugar- sweetened beverages could reduce consumption by 16 per cent. A UK study found a 20 per

1

Doc 1 Page 7 of 76 Released

cent tax on sugar-sweetened beverages in the UK would have a 1.3 per cent reduction in the prevalence of obesity (Briggs et al., 2013). It would also have a number of health benefits, with a particular benefit on rates and dental health. There are concerns that the tax would have greater financial implications for lower socio-economic groups. However, some have suggested that this would be progressive in terms of health outcomes as low socio-economic groups have a higher incidence of obesity. There are a number of areas for further work, such as the mechanism by which the tax could be introduced, and a number of policy formulation and implementation issues to consider.

Interpretive front of pack labelling is a policy that would provide the population with greater information about food composition and would therefore drive behavioural change among consumers to reduce consumption of products high in sugar, fat and salt. Evidence shows there can also be an effect on producers in the space of product reformulation. The main drawback of this policy is the impact on producers. A strong industry push back is to be expected due to producer losses, product reputation and reduced sales of foods; however, the gains in health impacts are seen to outweigh the costs. An area requiring further work in this policy is defining the optimal interpretive system of front of pack labelling for New Zealand, such as the ‘Health Star Rating’ or ‘Traffic Light’ systems. In addition, further work into the possible implementation issues and costs to the producer would be required.

Finally, placing restrictions on marketing to children is a regulatory measure that would reduce exposure to advertising for unhealthy foods, which could ultimately reduce demand for these products and have benefits upon consumption. An issue of this approach is the various media that are used by firms; regulations would have to consider an approach to target a range of advertising media, which is likely to be complicated for some. There are several issues that require further work namely policy formulation issues, such as the most effective way to introduce the restrictions. It would be important to avoid unintended consequences such as those that arose in Britain, where the policy increased children's exposure to marketing as the restrictions were poorly targeted and implemented (elaborated on p.18).

Whilst a sugar-sweetened beverage tax appears as a consideration for further work, a saturated fat tax has not been considered due to a number of significant economic implications, which have been seen from the experience. This is largely attributed to implementation issues. In addition, the effect upon consumption is viewed as ambiguous; this is mainly due to difficulties in specification and administration, the potential for increase in other food consumption (e.g. salty foods) due to cross price elasticities, and push back from powerful dairy and meat industries.

Another policy that has not been recommended is the removal of GST from fruit and vegetables. This policy represents a loss of key government income, would compromise GST efficiency, and has an unclear impact on obesity. Higher intakes of fruit and vegetables are likely to have a health benefit; however, there are issues regarding efficiency and equity in using GST to achieve this increase (elaborated in section 5.5.3). Other mechanisms that could be used to achieve an increase in fruit and vegetable consumption without compromising the GST efficiency should be investigated.

2

Doc 1 Page 8 of 76 Released

2 Introduction

Obesity is a complex health issue, affecting a significant proportion of New Zealanders. In 2013 the obesity rate for New Zealand adults was 31 per cent, representing a threefold increase since 1977.

The current problem in New Zealand is generally attributed to an obesogenic environment: an environment that facilitates and promotes weight gain. If left unaddressed obesity is predicted to rise, resulting in increased mortality, morbidity, financial pressure on health care systems and productivity, as well as broader impacts on living standards.

This report assesses a range of regulatory responses that may be appropriate for New Zealand to employ in order to address the growing problem of obesity. Options to improve labelling, restrict marketing, and change the price of food products were considered and evaluated against a set of criteria.

Research and international experience relating to each of the relevant approaches is discussed, presenting the costs and benefits of each measure. The information is drawn together in the final section, which presents the recommended approaches for New Zealand and identifies a number of areas for further work.

3

Doc 1 Page 9 of 76 Released

3 Overview of the problem

3.1 Obesity in New Zealand

In the past 30 years New Zealand has been experiencing an increase in obesity. New Zealand has one of the highest rates of obesity in all age groups when compared with similar developed countries (Health Committee, 2013). While overweight and obesity rates have been increasing relentlessly in all industralised countries, including a number of lower income countries, New Zealand has the third highest rate of overweight and obese adults in the OECD (Figure: 1) (Sassi, 2010). In 2013 the New Zealand obesity rate was 31 per cent, with a further 35 per cent overweight (Ministry of Health, 2013).

Overweight and obesity are defined as abnormal or excessive accumulation of weight that may impair health (World Health Organisation, 2013). Body mass index (BMI) is a simple measure that is commonly used to classify overweight and obesity in adults (World Health Organisation, 2013). The World Health Organisation (2013) defines overweight and obesity in adults as:

• a BMI greater than or equal to 25 as overweight

• a BMI greater than or equal to 30 as obesity.

Figure 1: Overweight and Obesity in the OECD (Sassi, 2010)

4

Doc 1 Page 10 of 76 Released

In 1977 the rate of obesity in New Zealand was 10 per cent (Ministry of Health, 2013). This has continued to rise for the last thirty years with the adult obesity rate reaching 31 per cent in 2013 (Ministry of Health, 2013).

The burden of obesity in New Zealand falls disproportionately on Maori and Pacific Island populations, socio-economically disadvantaged populations, and those living in areas of high deprivation. Among New Zealand’s multicultural society there are some clear ethnic disparities throughout the country. In 2013, 68 per cent of Pacific adults and 48 per cent of Maori adults were obese (Figure: 2) (Ministry of Health, 2013).

Figure 2: Obesity trends in New Zealand 2006-2013 (Ministry of Health, 2013).

One particular concern is the growing child obesity rate. In 2013, obesity among New Zealand children reached 11 per cent with a further 21 per cent of children classified as overweight (Ministry of Health, 2013). Childhood obesity continues to rise (Health Committee, 2013). This is problematic because nutrition and physical activity patterns in childhood are likely to influence adult behaviours with emerging evidence that health during childhood affects health into adulthood (Health Committee, 2013). Whilst many other countries are experiencing decreasing obesity rates, this is not the case for New Zealand (Sassi, 2010).

5

Doc 1 Page 11 of 76 Released

3.2 Factors seen to underpin the problem

Obesity is a complex problem with a number of inter-related causes, which are still not completely understood. The basic cause of obesity is defined as an individual regularly taking in more calories than required (Harvard School of Public Health, 2013). Heredity plays a role in obesity; however, the rapid increase in prevalence suggests that it is unlikely that genes are the main source of the epidemic (Harvard School of Public Health, 2013). Instead the dramatic increase in population body mass distribution is attributed to exposure to an ‘obesogenic’ environment: that is an environment that facilitates and promotes weight gain (Jenkin et al., 2011). This term was coined by Swinburn in 1997, and has attained international recognition as the basis of the obesity problem (Sassi, 2010). An ‘obesogenic’ environment includes physical, social, economic, and policy aspects, which have contributed to higher obesity rates in the last 30 years (Sassi, 2010; Waikato District Health Board, 2011). A prevalent theme across the range of factors is the current nature of lifestyles, and the high proportion of energy dense foods consumed.

Obesity has been described as people responding normally to the environment they find themselves in (Waikato District Health Board, 2011). Marmot (2011) notes that the behavioural choices we make as individuals are embedded in our social and economic circumstances; individuals born into more advantageous situations find adopting a healthier lifestyle easier than socially disadvantaged individuals (Waikato District Health Board, 2011). The literature suggests there are a number of factors that may encourage people to become obese. These factors are summarised as:

Information

• Lack of information about healthy products, exacerbated by an inability to cook (Swinburn et al., 2004).

• An increase of fats and sugars in the composition of foods, which is difficult to identify due to an inability to understand the current labelling system (Health Committee, 2013).

Environmental

• High concentration of fast food outlets, particularly in high deprivation areas (Swinburn et al., 2004).

• Urbanisation: urban environments encourage sedentary lifestyles (Waikato District Health Board, 2011).

• Impact of technology through use of labour-saving devices, including transport (Swinburn et al., 2004).

Price

• Low cost of unhealthy food, which may promote greater consumption of unhealthy products (Swinburn et al., 2004).

6

Doc 1 Page 12 of 76 Released

Lifestyle

• Heavy marketing to children and adults, which may increase the demand for unhealthy food products (Health Committee, 2007).

• Increased eating out: food prepared away from the home is higher in total energy, fats, cholesterol and sodium (Swinburn et al., 2004).

• Larger portion sizes (Swinburn et al., 2004).

• Increased snacking: snack foods tend to be energy dense and encourage weight gain (Swinburn et al., 2004).

• Sedentary jobs with non-active forms of recreation, which encourage inactive lifestyles (Waikato District Health Board, 2011).

• Reduced time to prepare home-prepared meals (Swinburn et al., 2004).

3.3 Costs and impacts on Living Standards

Obesity has significant impacts on health and productivity costs, with the growing problem having serious implications for future economic growth and sustainability.

The Ministry of Health (2001) defines the economic cost of obesity as being made up of three components:

• Direct costs to the individual and the healthcare service provider.

• Opportunity costs to the individual, i.e. the social and personal loss associated with obesity generally arising from premature death or morbidity.

• Indirect costs usually measured as lost productivity due to absenteeism from work and premature death.

Costs

Obesity is a major public health concern because it is a key risk factor in a range of chronic diseases, which are costly to individuals and the health system. Type 2 diabetes is closely linked to obesity (Sassi, 2010). High cholesterol and high blood pressure are more common as an individual’s BMI increases; this relationship means that heart disease, , and are more prone to develop (Sassi, 2010). A link between obesity and cancer has also been identified (Health Committee, 2007). Quality of life and length is significantly impacted by these conditions (Sassi, 2010).

In addition to chronic non-communicable diseases obesity can cause debilitating conditions and psychological problems. These conditions include: osteoarthritis, gallbladder disease, respiratory difficulties, infertility, skin problems and clinical depression (Waikato District Health Board, 2011).

Figure 3 displays the relationship between obesity (high body mass index) and health conditions. It shows that in 2006 high BMI was the second highest risk to health, at 7.9 per 7

Doc 1 Page 13 of 76 Released

cent Disability Adjusted Life Years (DALYs). By 2016 health loss from high BMI is expected to be greater than that from (Ministry of Health, 2013)

Figure 3: Attributable burden for selected risk factors 2006 (Ministry of Health, 2013).

According to the World Health Organisation (2000), the economic costs of obesity range from 2 to 7 per cent of total health care costs, with obesity health care expenditure expected to grow in future years (Waikato District Health Board, 2011). In 1991 the direct costs from obesity were conservatively estimated to be NZ$135m per year and 2.5 per cent of health care expenditure (Health Committee, 2007). In 2006 Lal et al. (2012) estimated health care costs attributed to obesity equated to 4.5 per cent of total health care expenditure, calculated at NZ$686m. 10.5 per cent and 18.5 per cent of total obesity costs were attributed to Maori and Pacific Island populations (Lal et al., 2012). Due to higher rates of obesity presently compared with 2006 it can be assumed these health costs have also increased. An obese person incurs health care expenditure at least 25 per cent higher than someone of a normal weight (Sassi, 2010).

The ageing population and high prevalance of obesity represents a challenge for New Zealand health care expenditure. This suggests that understanding and minimising liabilities from obesity should be a priority, especially in the context of growing demand for limited health care resources.

Opportunity costs

In addition to health costs, an obese individual may suffer other costs such as psychological distress and employment issues. According to the OECD (Sassi, 2010), the obese are likely to earn less than people of a normal weight; research has suggested wage penalties of up to 18 per cent. An obese person is more likely to be unemployed compared to an individual of a normal weight (Sassi, 2010). The OECD suggests obesity is a factor in job discrimination and social stigmatisation, and is found to have an increased prevalence in bullying (Sassi, 2010).

8

Doc 1 Page 14 of 76 Released

Indirect costs

Obesity has detrimental impacts for economic growth and productivity. Overweight and obese individuals generate productivity costs estimated to be between NZ$98m and NZ$225m, using 2006 data (Lal et al., 2012). These costs are created through absenteeism, premature death, or recruitment and training of replacement staff. It is also suggested that an obese individual may work at less than full capacity (Lal et al., 2012). If an individual is unable to work due to obesity, there may be costs to the welfare system. Impacts upon the transport industry would also be important to consider, as greater resources are required for larger individuals.

As the obesity problem worsens it is predicted that these economic, health and social costs will escalate creating further problems.

Impacts on Living Standards

The Treasury’s goal of increasing the living standards of all New Zealanders is reflected in its 'Living Standards Framework' (Treasury, 2014). This framework (see Figure 4) represents a unique policy tool that identifies the key dimensions that need to be considered when addressing particular issues of concern (Treasury, 2014). In this paper the Treasury Living Standards framework has been considered to gain a greater sense of the impacts of the obesity problem, and the impacts of regulatory measures that could help address it.

Figure 4: Treasury Living Standards Framework (Treasury, 2014)

9

Doc 1 Page 15 of 76 Released

The table below identifies possible impacts of the obesity problem in New Zealand using the Living Standards Framework.

Living standards dimension Application to problem of obesity in New Zealand

Economic growth A healthy population supports greater productivity and ultimately stronger economic growth. Obesity compromises productivity and labour market participation as it prevents individuals from working, impacts longevity of life, and reduces productivity.

Health spending represents a significant proportion of government expenditure. As obesity increases this puts pressure on spending with potential implications for taxation and deadweight economic costs.

Sustainability for the future If health spending increases there are implications for the Government’s other spending priorities.

A sustainable diet is considered a ; if individuals are consuming an unhealthy diet this may place pressure on the sustainability of food provision.

Reducing risks Obesity is a fiscal risk for the future, as there are many health costs associated with obesity as well as potential risks to productivity and GDP. Higher welfare and a weaker economy present a risk for the New Zealand macro economic outlook.

Increasing equity Low socio-economic groups have a higher prevalence of obesity. If it is not addressed this will exacerbate existing inequalities.

Social infrastructure An effective health system is an important part of New Zealand’s social infrastructure. Trust in the health system may be weakened if it fails to respond to the growing obesity problem.

10

Doc 1 Page 16 of 76 Released

4 Actions currently undertaken

The current policy approach to obesity in New Zealand focuses on initiatives that aim to support and encourage individuals to lead healthier lifestyles and the food industry to provide healthier products and inform consumers. In 2001 the Ministry of Health published a strategy that placed obesity as an important health priority; this included a stock take of obesity prevention programmes and an evidence-based review of successful international programmes (Ministry of Health, 2001). Since 2001 there have been a number of mostly short-term preventive initiatives at national, regional and local levels directly targeting prevention and management of obesity. However, no dedicated regulatory measures have been implemented, e.g. by changing the price of food. Many critics argue that there is no organised strategy and an organised strategy should be the first priority in targeting the core of the problem. There are calls for work to be completed in this field to impact on the New Zealand obesity problem. New Zealand has also engaged internationally in efforts to reduce global obesity rates.

Today obesity is seen as overwhelmingly a societal issue given its prevalence and costs. Existing programmes provide part of the solution. In 2007 and 2013 the Health Committee investigated the obesity and diabetes problem in New Zealand, suggesting a number of regulatory approaches. The 2013 Health Committee paper reported that the obesity problem will not be solved by targeting individuals in isolation but must reflect their food environment, family, cultural background and financial constraints (Health Committee, 2013).

The current initiatives to improve nutrition and increase physical activity include but are not restricted to (important to note the intention of these policies in many cases is not based on obesity):

Diet:

• The Health Promotion Agency organises campaigns such as ‘Breakfast Eaters’ (Ministry of Health, 2013).

• Public health contracts are in place to promote nutrition and physical activity promotion, including product reformulation (Ministry of Health, 2013).

• Fruit in Schools programme provides fruit to children in low-decile schools (Ministry of Health, 2013).

• The 5 plus a day programme promotes consumption of fruit and vegetables (Ministry of Health, 2013).

• In 2006 Counties Manukau DHB “Let’s Beat Diabetes” programme prompted the initiation of a joint venture with McDonalds and Coca- to substitute sugar-free for the full sugar beverage (Food Industry Group, 2006).

• The food industry, including manufacturers such as McDonalds, Coca-Cola, FRUCOR, KFC, New World and , has made pledges to reformulate products, review and refine marketing practices and provide opportunities for communication, information and education (Food Industry Group, 2006).

11

Doc 1 Page 17 of 76 Released

• The Ministry of Primary Industries has made efforts to modify the composition of food products by working with industry to reformulate in the areas of sodium and trans-fat. It has also completed work strengthening rules around food labelling (Ministry of Health, 2013). In 2007 the Australia New Zealand Collaboration on Trans Fats was created with the goal of reducing trans-fats in the food supply (Food Standards Australia New Zealand, 2013).

Education:

• The Pacific Innovation Fund helps Pacific Island people to improve their health and wellbeing. Three of the five current initiatives directly target obesity (Ministry of Health, 2013).

Physical Activity:

• The National Transport Agency encourages user friendly walking (Ministry of Health, 2013).

• DHB Green Prescriptions issued by GPs or practice nurses to encourage physical activity (Ministry of Health, 2013).

One initiative that has been in place for a number of years and has promising results for children is the Project Energize programme in Waikato (Rush et al., 2013).

Project Energize

The Energize programme began in 2005 funded by the Waikato District Health Board. It is a health programme focusing on health literacy and physical activity (Rush et al., 2013). Currently the programme is in place in 233 schools in the Waikato District, reaching 10 per cent of the child population of New Zealand. When evaluated in 2011 children in the Energize program ran 550m 13 per cent faster and their BMI was 3 per cent lower in younger (6-8 years) and 2.4 per cent lower in older (9-11 years) children than those in the comparison group (Rush et al., 2013). In 2010 $1.9m was spent to deliver the programme – a cost of $44.96/child/year (Rush et al., 2013). If rolled out to the whole New Zealand child population the programme is estimated to cost $20 million per year.

Given the continuing rise in obesity, there may be a role for regulatory measures to play in reducing the New Zealand obesity rate. Regulatory measures are viewed as complementary to community-based approaches; however, neither approach can be expected to reverse the obesity problem individually. Regulatory change is an important tool in changing attitudes towards societal issues. The introduction of the New Zealand Smoke Free Environments Act has helped shaped some of the social norms held presently towards smoking, from this experience it can be assumed regulations may play a role in shaping norms towards obesity.

12

Doc 1 Page 18 of 76 Released

5 Regulatory measures

5.1 Regulatory options considered

Figure 5 shows a range of measures that could be adopted to address obesity. This paper focuses on the following regulatory options:

• Interpretive front of pack labelling

• Regulation of marketing to children

• Pricing mechanisms:

o Sugar-sweetened beverage tax

o Saturated fat tax

o Removal of GST from fruit and vegetables

These options are the most widely considered and commonly implemented internationally. However, due to the complexity of the problem there is scope for further research into other regulatory measures including minimum pricing, planning restrictions and banning of goods. These are shown on the continuum below, along with voluntary measures (see Figure 5).

Figure 5: Policy options, goals and desired outcomes

13

Doc 1 Page 19 of 76 Released

5.2 Criteria for assessing regulatory measures

The following criteria will be used to assess the regulatory options:

• Impact on consumption

• Efficiency and cost-effectiveness

• Acceptability: Stakeholder support

• Costs

• Feasibility

• Effects on equity

• Positive and negative impacts

The Treasury Living Standards framework has been considered where appropriate (as seen from Figure 4):

• Economic Growth

• Sustainability for the Future

• Increasing Equity

• Social Infrastructure

• Reducing Risks.

The discussion of each regulatory option sets out the main issues to consider against the options. A full analysis against all the criteria is in the Appendix (page 34).

5.3 Interpretive front of pack labelling

An interpretive front of pack labelling system would require the food industry to distribute food products with a user-friendly label displaying key nutrients on the front of product

packets, including: fats, saturates, sugars and salt for 100g of the product. This would clearly display easy to read nutritional content. The system may include use of colour such as green, amber and red (traffic light system) or symbols such as stars (health star rating system) to portray messages to the consumer. The analysis throughout this paper is from a broad front of pack labelling policy perspective. Details on the precise mechanism would be an area for further work .

Rationale An interpretive front of pack labelling system should provide nutritional information in a format that is easy for consumers to interpret and should help aide healthier food choices through interpretation. This could reduce the level of obesity in New Zealand by encouraging

14

Doc 1 Page 20 of 76 Released

consumers to choose healthier foods to the benefit of the individual and their family. It has the additional benefit of providing incentives to producers to improve the health of their products through product reformulation. Consumer research on the current nutrition label suggests that the Nutrition Information Panel (NIP) on the back of food packages in Australia and New Zealand is viewed by consumers as confusing and technical (Signal et al., 2012). Of particular concern is evidence that individuals from low socio-economic groups experience difficulties interpreting the current label (Signal et al., 2012). Recent consumer studies in Australia found that 49 per cent of consumers misinterpreted the current nutrition information (Lanumata et al., 2008). This suggests there is scope to improve understanding of current labels with potential for a positive impact on eating patterns.

The dominant ideology surrounding the issue of obesity is based on commercial freedom and personal responsibility (Magnusson, 2010). An interpretive labelling system informs consumers about the nutrient profiling and allows them to make judgements. It allows the consumer to make informed decisions about food products, which may be seen as a better fit with this approach.

International application

The UK is one of the only countries to have introduced a voluntary front of pack labelling system. In 2006 a voluntary traffic light front of pack labeling system for food manufacturers was implemented (see Figure 6). More recently Ecuador and Mexico have introduced mandatory regulations on food products.

Figure 6: Example of Traffic Light labelling UK (Food Standards Agency Scotland, 2013).

More than 100 companies of all sizes in the UK are now using the traffic light system consistently on a voluntary basis. Labels are on the front of more than 20,000 product lines (Department of Health & Devolved Administrations, 2013).

Analysis of an interpretive front of pack labelling in New Zealand

Evidence of effectiveness

Front of pack labelling encourages changes in consumer behaviour. The visual system aids consumers with greater information about food products, enabling them to make informed decisions about what products they consume (Signal et al., 2012).

Surveys have found a shift in consumer purchasing behaviour to healthier food products in response to the traffic light system and a push from supermarkets to reformulate their products (World Cancer Research Fund, 2012). Studies in New Zealand found that the traffic light system was effective in deterring consumers from unhealthy foods encouraging healthier eating in comparison to the Nutrition Information Panel (Veer, 2014). US research

15

Doc 1 Page 21 of 76 Released

found significant shifts in sales towards healthier food products with the support of front of pack labelling (Sacks et al., 2010).

It is understood that this policy in the UK has been accepted by consumers, who have found it easy to understand and have shifted to healthier food options (Health Committee, 2007). Further research into this system has found that front of pack labelling is used, liked by and performs well for lower socio-economic groups (Department of Health & Devolved Administrations, 2013). There is additional evidence that an interpretive front of pack labelling system has resulted in higher comprehension of food composition by low socio- economic groups (Department of Health & Devolved Administrations, 2013). This is important as overweight and obesity are more prevalent in low socio-economic groups and comprehension of the current nutrition information panels in New Zealand is low (World Cancer Research Fund, 2012).

Sacks et al. (2010) believe the introduction of an interpretive nutrition labelling system would act as a stimulus for food companies to improve the nutrition of their standardised offerings, creating a healthier food environment for consumers. Interpretive front of pack labelling incentivises producers to reformulate food products in order to obtain a favorable label. An example of reformulation from labelling has been reported when the Heart Foundation Tick was introduced resulting in food companies throughout New Zealand to exclude 33 tonnes of salt due to reformulation (Hawley et al., 2012). In the US a number of producers reduced the level of trans-fats when the Food and Drug Association mandated the listing of trans-fat content on product packaging (Hawley et al., 2012). Even if an interpretive front of pack labelling system produces little impact upon consumer behaviour there could still be considerable public health benefits and it supports consumers’ rights to know what is in the food they are consuming (Hawley et al., 2012).

Economic implications for producers

Support from the food industry is likely to be low for an interpretive front of pack labelling system, however this is mainly restricted to large processed food manufacturers. A number of producers would gain unfavourable nutrition labels for their product lines and fear this would reduce demand for their products (Hawley et al., 2012). All submissions from food manufacturers to the Australia and New Zealand Food Regulation Council in regard to an interpretive front of pack labelling system opposed a traffic light front of pack labelling system (Signal et al., 2012). This led the Panel to put consideration of the traffic light system ‘on hold’, but efforts to develop an interpretive system have continued (Signal et al., 2012). A mandatory system would also have a number of economic implications for manufacturers that would be forced to alter their packaging to incorporate the front of pack label, potentially resulting in an additional cost to production. However, if introduced with a long enough lead- in time the costs may be minimised. Further work into the implications of these economic costs would need to be conducted to determine how the costs could be minimised or to establish whether or not additional government support should be introduced. There could be scope to help minimise costs through phasing in of the regulations or enabling producers to combine the change with other planned changes to their packaging.

Policy formulation issues

Critics of interpretive front of pack labelling systems report the system as too simplistic and potentially unhelpful (Consumer NZ, 2014). They believe that the system incorrectly labels

16

Doc 1 Page 22 of 76 Released

food products providing some healthy food products with a detrimental label (Consumer NZ, 2014). To maximise health benefits there may have to be further consideration of the quantity at which food is assessed. It has been argued that giving labels to 100g quantities of food is misleading and confusing to consumers who may consume larger or smaller quantities of the product (Consumer NZ, 2014). Equally, if labels are according to serving size, it can be difficult to compare products that consider one serving to be of a different size to a similar product. These are issues with policy formulation, but they can be minimised with a focus on effective implementation.

Summary

Interpretive front of pack labelling is a policy that would provide the population with greater information in regard to food composition. It would drive consumer behavioural change to reduce consumption of products high in sugar, salt and fat. Evidence shows that there would be an effect on producers that may encourage product reformulation, which is positive for population health outcomes. The main downfall to this policy is the impact on producers, with strong industry push back expected; however, the gains in health impacts are considered to outweigh the costs. For some producers in the industry there will be favourable impacts with consumers subsituting to their products. There are a number of areas requiring further work (see 6.2), namely the best interpretive labelling system for New Zealand, such as the star or traffic light systems. In addition, further work into possible policy formulation issues and economic costs to the producers would be required.

5.4 Regulation of marketing to children

This policy would restrict advertising of unhealthy food products during children’s frequent viewing times and other prominent advertising mediums. It would have the goal of reducing children’s exposure to unhealthy food products, therefore reducing demand for and consumption of unhealthy food products.

Rationale

The rights of children are commonly exploited as children are viewed as a vulnerable and lucrative market to target. This needs to be curtailed. Marketing to children has been clearly shown to influence parents’ and children’s preferences and food choices and drives ‘pester power’, which can influence consumer behaviour (Health Committee, 2013). A UK study showed that 73 per cent of children asked their parents to purchase things that they had seen advertised on television (Diabetes New Zealand Inc et al., 2003). A recent Australian survey examining children’s exposure to television advertising of ‘unhealthy’ food reported an association of heavier and more frequent consumption of such foods from increased television exposure (Jenkin et al., 2009).

Currently in New Zealand, children are exposed to advertisements for snack foods, sweet snacks, drinks and fast foods, with 70 per cent of advertising in children’s viewing times promoting unhealthy food products (Shaw, 2009). If exposure to these advertisements was reduced it is suggested that obesity among children would decline (Jenkin et al., 2009). One rigorous review commissioned by the Institute of Medicine concluded that “television advertising influences the food preferences, purchase requests, and diets, at least of children under age 12 years, and is associated with increased rates of obesity among 17

Doc 1 Page 23 of 76 Released

children and youth” (Jenkin et al., 2009). In 2007 the fast food industry spent $12.94 per person on advertising in New Zealand; the amount spent on healthy food advertising was only $1.44 per person (Waikato District Health Board, 2011).

Currently New Zealand has an almost entirely self-regulatory system for television marketing, with the Advertising Standards Authority (ASA) acting as a voluntary industry body (Shaw, 2009). The current ASA reponse to regulating unhealthy advertising is seen as flawed (Shaw, 2009). From the current evidence it is clear that the self-regulatory system in place has failed to decrease children’s exposure to advertising of unhealthy foods (Shaw, 2009). Internationally self-regulatory systems are failing to protect children, suggesting a statutory mechanism is required. The current situation could be defined as a market failure and strengthens the argument for intervention; children are viewed as powerless to their exposure. In terms of other mediums such as the internet, there are currently no regulations in place restricting exposure to children and this is considered very complicated to implement.

International application

In 2007 the UK regulator Ofcom introduced regulations banning the advertisement of foods high in fat, salt and sugar during children’s programming on television (Adams, 2012). Several countries in Europe, such as Sweden, Norway, Poland and Greece, and Quebec in Canada have banned advertising to children through a number of mediums (Shaw, 2009).

Analysis of regulation of television advertising to children in New Zealand

Evidence of effectiveness

Regulations on advertising to children have been associated with reductions in exposure to, and therefore demand for, unhealthy foods such as soft drinks. Evidence from Poland has reported that a ban on television and radio marketing to children significantly reduced product sales, notably of soft drinks (Diabetes New Zealand Inc et al., 2003).This represents an association between a number of food products and advertising, suggesting that reductions in exposure can have effects upon consumption behaviour. If restrictions were implemented in New Zealand, children’s exposure to marketing could be reduced resulting in positive consumer behaviour patterns.

Industry impacts

There may be issues with industry acceptability if the regulations were only enforced upon television, raising issues about regulating other marketing mediums. For advertisers there may be a shift to other types of media such as the internet or to adult viewing times. It would be important to consider and monitor industry responses to ensure the policy worked as intended. Further implications could be experienced by broadcasters who may be subjected to reduced revenue; this would need to be monitored. Further work on regulations upon other industries may be required in order to develop a well targeted policy.

Policy formulation issues

If the regulations are not well formulated they may not provide any gains for the child audience. Lessons can be learnt from the UK; research following the UK restrictions on

18

Doc 1 Page 24 of 76 Released

television advertising found that children were exposed to the same level of marketing as before the ban, because children watched shows not specifically targeted to their audience and which were not affected by the regulations (Adams, 2012). One of the Public Health Research Centres of Excellence funded through the UK Clinical Research Collaboration (UKCRC) has found evidence showing that restricting unhealthy advertising to viewing times after 9pm would reduce children’s exposure by 82 per cent (Adams, 2012). The regulations would need an effective monitoring body so that the progress in the New Zealand context can be accurately measured (Shaw, 2009). In order to effectively regulate this industry a regulatory body would have to be established or the Advertising Standards Authority (ASA) given greater powers. The policy design is likely to be complicated in order to include mediums other than television and radio.

Summary

Restriction of marketing to children could reduce children’s exposure to advertising and reduce demand for unhealthy foods. There are several issues that require further work namely policy formulation issues, for example, the most efficient way to implement the restrictions and the medium in which the restrictions can be applied. This policy would support the basic principle of society’s responsibility to protect children from known harms and exploitation. Overall this policy represents a promising approach that could have benefits for child nutrition and welfare.

5.5 Pricing mechanisms

Price is an important determinant in food choices and diet. Economic theory assumes as the price of the item rises, according to the law of demand the consumption of that item will typically fall. For governments, increasing the price of undesirable products through taxation should reduce the consumption of the taxed foods. Economists generally agree that government intervention is justified when the market fails to provide the optimum amount of a product for the good of society; this argument is applied in the case of taxing tobacco and alcohol (Mytton et al., 2012). A pricing mechanism is not an absolute tool but can be used as a multi-tailored response to the obesity problem.

Price elasticity

Price elasticity of food consumption measures the level of responsiveness of demand for food consumption to changes in food prices relative to prices of other commodities (O’Dea et al., 2009). It is also likely that industry may alter the pricing of other products such as diet drinks so that pricing matches the tax. Price elasticity is important to consider when evaluating consumer behaviour in response to a tax.

The higher the level of elasticity of demand the greater the likelihood of substitution and decreased consumption of a product. When increasing the price of one product, related products such as substitutes (diet coke for coke) may be affected in response to the price change (Mytton et al., 2012).

19

Doc 1 Page 25 of 76 Released

Elasticities of demand are interpreted as follows:

0 = Perfectly inelastic demand

-1< 0= Inelastic or relatively inelastic demand

-1 = Unit elasticity

1 > = Elastic or relatively elastic demand

Demand is:

• relatively inelastic when the percentage change in quantity demanded is less than the percentage change in price

• unit elasticity demand when the percentage change in quantity demanded is equal to the percentage change in price

• relatively elastic when the percentage change in quantity demanded is greater than the percentage change in price.

Pricing mechanisms

There are a number of different goods that can be targeted by a tax on sugar, fat and/or salt content for example. This paper focuses on three pricing mechanisms:

• Sugar-sweetened beverage tax

• Saturated fat tax

• Removal of GST from fruit and vegetables

In addition to the variety of products that could be targeted, there are a number of different ways of designing pricing regulations, including an excise tax, sales tax, minimum pricing and . Each approach may have different impacts. Nutrient profiling is a promising area for taxation; it would provide greater effectiveness in targeting ‘unhealthy’ products. The purpose of this report is to understand the potential impact on consumption from a health policy perspective, rather than focusing on the exact mechanism.

5.5.1 Sugar-sweetened beverage tax

A sugar-sweetened beverage tax would tax beverages containing added sugar. Sugar- sweetened beverages include carbonated soft drinks, sports drinks, fruit drinks, flavoured waters, sweetened teas, ready-to-drink coffees, and other non-alcoholic drinks containing added sugars .

Rationale

There is evidence that taxes on foods with high sugar content can reduce consumption, provided that the rate of tax is sufficiently high. Particular interest has been placed in sugar- sweetened beverages because of their strong association with obesity, diabetes and dental health.

20

Doc 1 Page 26 of 76 Released

Sugar-sweetened beverages deliver little to no nutrition, are heavily marketed to children, contribute to poor diet, and carry the risk of obesity, diabetes and other diseases (Brownell & Friedman, 2012). The Global Burden of Disease panel estimates 0.6 per cent of deaths worldwide per year can be attributed to diets high in sugar-sweetened beverages (Blakely et al., 2014). By reducing consumption of these beverages through taxation, it is assumed calorie intake will fall as people will be incentivised to reduce consumption. They may also substitute these beverages for healthier alternatives, reducing sugar intake.

International application

Internationally a number of countries have introduced sugar-sweetened beverage taxes, including France, Mexico, Finland and a number of US states (Landon & Graff, 2012). In 2011 Hungary introduced a sugar-sweetened beverage tax, and from evidence has proven successful in reducing consumption.

Analysis of a sugar-sweetened beverage tax in New Zealand

Evidence of effectiveness

Sugar-sweetened beverage taxes have been associated with reductions in consumption. Evidence from Hungary has reported consumption of sugar-sweetened beverages was almost halved after the tax implemented in 2011 (Landon & Graff, 2012). Before the tax was levied Hungary had an average intake of 290ml per day, with young people obtaining 7 per cent of their daily energy from soft drinks (Landon & Graff, 2012). Following the introduction of the tax, soft drink consumption in Hungary fell from 117 million litres to 69 million litres in the last quarter of 2011 (Landon & Graff, 2012). A New Zealand modelling study found a decrease in consumption by 24 per cent when a 10 per cent tax was applied to sugar-sweetened soft drinks (Eyles et al., 2012). In a recent study, Briggs et al. (2013) found that a 20 per cent tax on sugar-sweetened beverages would reduce consumption by up to 16 per cent. Evidence from other international taxes is still yet to be published.

Evidence from the Briggs et al. (2013) study suggested elasticity for sugar-sweetened beverages was between 0.92 and -0.81, suggesting they are relatively elastic in nature. For the lowest socio-economic group elasticity was estimated at -1.03 suggesting the reductions would be proportionate to the increase in price (Briggs et al., 2013). This suggests a high level of substitution with diet beverages or beverages containing no sugar content.

If the tax level was high enough there would be an impact on obesity in New Zealand. A sugar-sweetened beverage tax is likely to have impacts on reduced consumption and reductions on the rate of obesity. Modelling by Briggs et al. (2013) predicted that a 20 per cent tax on sugar-sweetened beverages would reduce the prevalence of obesity in the UK by 1.3 per cent, whilst a study in India by Basu et al. (2014) estimated that a 20 per cent sugar-sweetened beverage tax would avert 4.2 per cent of the prevalence of obesity in India. It is unclear if the obesity impacts would be to the same level in New Zealand; however both represent promising indications in reductions of obesity (Blakely et al., 2014).

In addition to positive obesity outcomes there are reported benefits for diabetes, dental cavities and a number of health conditions (Brownell & Friedman, 2012). Basu et al. (2014) found that a 20 per cent sugar-sweetened beverage tax could reduce the incidence of diabetes by 2.3 per cent from 2014 to 2023 (Blakely et al., 2014).

21

Doc 1 Page 27 of 76 Released

Financial implications for low socio-economic groups

There are several concerns that a sugar-sweetened beverage tax would have greater financial implications for lower socio-economic groups. However some have suggested that this would be progressive in terms of health outcomes as poor people have a higher incidence of disease, and consume less healthy food (Briggs et al., 2013). Consequently, the greater absolute reduction in obesity would be assumed to be among poor people who have a higher prevalence of obesity.

Industry push back

Opposition to a tax is to be expected from the beverage industry due to the high profitability of sugar-sweetened beverage consumption and significant vested interests (Brownwell & Frieden, 2009). From international experience, industry has opposed sugar-sweetened beverage taxes and in many countries industry has spent large amounts of money to lobby for the abolition of the tax (Lavin & Timpson, 2013).

Policy formulation issues

In the New Zealand context, an excise tax on these products is feasible whilst other designs are likely to be complicated and ineffective. Issues with a sugar-sweetened beverage tax raise a number of issues surrounding artificial sweeteners’ and the beverages subjected in the tax. Internationally there is conflicting evidence surrounding artificial sweeteners, this would have to be further considered in the policy design stage, with scope for artificial sweeteners to be included in the tax (Fowler et al., 2008). However, it is important to consider the switch from sugar-sweetened beverages to artificially sweetened beverages as a positive shift in reducing sugar intake, although it is not as healthy as a switch to water or milk beverages. Some retailers may not pass on the tax to consumers and instead may absorb the price increases as sugar-sweetened beverages are commonly used as a ‘loss leader’ by a number of retailers.

Summary

Evidence suggests that a sugar-sweetened beverage tax would reduce consumption of sugar-sweetened beverages and caries the prevalence of obesity. It would have a number of health benefits, with a particular benefit in reducing diabetes and reducing poor dental health. The benefit is highly likely to be progressive (this has been seen in tobacco taxation), however there are concerns that the tax would have greater financial implications for lower socio-economic groups. Some have suggested that this is progressive in terms of health outcomes, and it is viewed as correctly targeting the groups with the highest prevalence of obesity. There are a number of areas for further work, such as the mechanism by which the tax could be introduced, and a number of policy formulation issues to consider.

5.5.2 Saturated fat tax

A saturated fat tax would tax food products exceeding a threshold of saturated fat. This could be applied to certain products such as meats, dairy, processed foods, cooking oils and junk foods in the form of a ‘per kilo’ charge.

22

Doc 1 Page 28 of 76 Released

Rationale

Saturated fats are the main type of fat in butter, dairy products, fatty meats, fried and take- away foods. When an individual consumes a diet high in saturated fat they store large amounts of excess fat and their risk of cardio-vascular and heart disease increases (American Heart Association, 2013). A high level of saturated fat can increase the level of bad cholesterol in the blood and is a major risk factor for heart diseases and stroke.

Australian guidelines recommend that saturated fats and trans-fats provide no more than 10 per cent of a person’s energy, due to the implications of excess consumption on obesity and cardiovascular disease (Health Committee, 2013). Currently New Zealanders are obtaining around 14 to 16 per cent of daily kilojoules from trans-fats and saturated fats; this is well above the Australian and New Zealand recommendation not to exceed consumption of 8 to 10 per cent of daily kilojoule intake. This high rate of consumption is also well above the recommendations of other OECD countries (Food Standards Australia Zealand, 2013).

If a tax was implemented, people would be incentivised to consume smaller quantities of saturated fat, which is suggested to lead to decreased obesity rates. This would improve health outcomes and improve the rates of obesity-related diseases.

An alternative approach could be a tax on trans-fatty acids. However, evidence suggests that trans-fat consumption is not a major issue in New Zealand. Food Standards Australia New Zealand’s dietary modelling found that New Zealanders obtain an average of 0.6 per cent of their daily kilojoules from trans-fats; this is below the WHO organisation recommendation of 1 per cent (Food Standards Australia Zealand, 2013). In 2007 the New Zealand and Australian Governments established Australia New Zealand Collaboration on trans-fats (Food Standards Australia Zealand, 2013). Since 2007 the intake level of trans- fats from manufactured products has declined from 70 per cent to 45 per cent in the food supply (Food Standards Australia Zealand, 2013).

International application

In 2011 Denmark introduced the first fat tax in the world. The tax targeting saturated fat products was placed on food items exceeding 2.3g/100g of saturated fat, charging NZ$3.50 for every kilogram of saturated fat (Petkantchin, 2013). This tax was applied to meat, dairy products and animal fats that are rendered or extracted in other ways, edible oils and fats, margarine and blended spreads (Smed, 2012).

Analysis of a saturated fat tax in New Zealand

Evidence of effectiveness

Price is a major factor in consumption patterns, so if a fat tax was introduced there is likely to be a fall in consumption (Smed, 2012). Evidence from Denmark suggests that consumption of products containing saturated fat fell following the introduction of the fat tax (Smed, 2012). However, a survey from the Danish Agriculture and Food Council reported that 80 per cent of households reported no change in their consumption patterns after the fat tax was introduced (Petkantchin, 2013). There is still debate on the exact figures of decreased consumption as the tax was only in place for fifteen months, but some studies

23

Doc 1 Page 29 of 76 Released

indicated decreased consumption of up to 15 per cent for some products (Petkantchin, 2013).

Internationally there is a lack of evidence regarding the effect of a saturated fat tax. From available evidence it appears there is an ambiguous effect on consumption. Further evidence would be required before judgement on the effect could be concluded. A modelling study from Auckland and Otago Universities predicted that for every one per cent price increase there would be an overall decrease of 0.02 per cent in energy intake from saturated fats (Eyles et al., 2012).

Economic implications

In Denmark, the fat tax created a number of issues for businesses and industry. Supermarkets were able to absorb the price changes and spread the burden across other food products (Petkantchin, 2013). In contrast some retailers, such as butchers, were significantly harmed by the tax. According to the Danish Agriculture and Food Council, Denmark experienced a loss of jobs due to the fat tax (Petkantchin, 2013). From the Danish experience the potential impact on jobs and economic growth are serious considerations if it were to be implemented in New Zealand (Petkantchin, 2013).

One issue raised from this tax is that a small country with an open border cannot raise their prices or they will face cross border shopping and a loss of competitiveness. However, this is unlikely to occur in New Zealand due to its geographical location. It is difficult to measure the effectiveness of the Danish fat tax as low public support and pressure from industry meant it was repealed after fifteen months, but during this time the tax did raise NZ$216 million with estimates of administration costs over NZ$44 million (Nestle, 2012). This suggests revenue could be raised from a fat tax to reinvest into obesity prevention programmes. The tax mechanism performed as desired with the price increasing and consumption falling, the failure from the tax is largely attributed to poor conception and implementation by policy makers exacerbated with a lack of public health support.

If the fat tax were implemented in New Zealand, it is likely that it would be applied to dairy and meat products, which are leading sources of income for New Zealand producers. It is likely there would be high levels of industry push back in response to such a policy, although this is dependent on producers’ reliance on the New Zealand market. If producers responded by exporting larger quantities then the economic costs would be minimised. These administration costs and economic implications would need to be balanced against the health benefits.

Impact on low socio-economic groups

As lower-income households generally spend a higher proportion of their income on food, the tax may have a greater impact on these groups (Health Committee, 2013). For these low socio-economic groups there could be issues with behavioural change, as some of these individuals may not have the resources to adapt their behaviour accordingly. It is likely that the tax may have an income effect in which the consumer will buy fewer healthy foods as well as unhealthy foods, as the basket they habitually bought is more expensive so they feel poorer (Smed, 2012). However, it could be argued that if the policy was successful in improving health outcomes, it would provide low socio-economic individuals more opportunities to participate in society.

24

Doc 1 Page 30 of 76 Released

Summary

Overall this policy could have health benefits, but it is important to consider the serious flaws of this policy. There is a serious risk that targeting products that have nutritional benefits could have negative consequences. There are a number of significant economic considerations and the effect upon consumption is unclear.

5.5.3 Removal of GST from fruit and vegetables

The removal of GST from fruit and vegetables would mean the current 15 per cent goods and services tax would be removed from fruit and vegetable products.

Rationale

There is scope for New Zealanders to increase their intake of fruit and vegetables, with potential positive impacts on health and obesity rates. In 2012/13 the Ministry of Health survey reported that 66 per cent of adults ate at least three servings of vegetables, while 58 per cent of adults ate at least two servings of fruit and vegetables presenting a lack of fulfilling daily nutritional needs (Ministry of Health, 2013).

If GST was removed from fruit and vegetables, it would incentivise households and individuals to purchase larger quantities of fruit and vegetables for a given amount of income. This could make fruit and vegetables more attractive relative to less healthy food products. This measure would benefit health outcomes, and may reduce obesity and related diseases through improving nutrition.

This analysis focuses on the removal of GST from fresh fruit and vegetables. Some critics have argued that GST should be removed from healthy foods; however, there is some ambiguity around what is defined as a healthy food product. This can be determined by nutrient profiling.

Analysis of GST removal from fruit and vegetables in New Zealand

Evidence of effectiveness

According to advocates for the removal of GST, the quantities of fruit and vegetables that consumers would be able to purchase would increase as they could use a given level of income to purchase higher quantities. According to a study published in the American Journal of Clinical Nutrition, if a 12.5 per cent GST sales tax was removed from fruit and vegetables the consumption of these products would increase by 11 per cent (Mhurchu et al., 2010). In Australia fruit and vegetables are exempt from GST; it is estimated if GST of 10 per cent was added to these products then fruit consumption would decline by 4.9 per cent and vegetable consumption by 4.8 per cent (Veerman & Cobiac, 2013). In Australia the removal of the GST exemption is expected to increase health costs and health loss by 3 per cent annually (Veerman & Cobiac, 2013). However, in New Zealand it is difficult to predict if the removal of GST at 15 per cent from fruit and vegetables would change consumption; in 2010 when the rate of GST increased to 15 per cent, rates were reduced simultaneously with the overall change in consumption ambiguous. It is also important to

25

Doc 1 Page 31 of 76 Released

consider the market situation for the pricing of these products; the exemption may allow the market to increase the price of these products.

It has also been argued that consumption of fruit and vegetables is not driven by the absolute price. Even with the exemption, research suggests low income households will still purchase unhealthy food products (Wynd & Familton, 2010). According to Drewnowski & Darmon (2005) low income individuals think quite rationally when they purchase and they wish to purchase the greatest amount of calories for the lowest value of income (Wynd & Familton, 2010). The relative prices of fresh fruit and vegetables and poor quality food is unbalanced and it is unlikely that the exemption would change the buying patterns of households (Wynd & Familton, 2010). Instead, it is likely low income households would be enabled with greater disposable income to purchase ‘unhealthy’ food products that are typically low cost (Wynd & Familton, 2010).

Further work on the relationship between obesity and fruit and vegetables would need to be completed to establish this relationship. It could be a component of the obesity strategy, but it may not have the necessary level of impact to elicit changes in the levels of obesity in New Zealand.

Loss of GST efficiency

The current GST system is viewed as a simple system which maximises the revenue received with low administration costs (National Business Review, 2013). If exemptions were added, this system would become more complex and the revenue received would decrease forcing the government to compensate for loss of income, potentially through another source of taxation (National Business Review, 2013).

Loss of key Government income

According to Treasury in 2009 the government received 21 per cent of tax income from GST. The fiscal cost of the removal has been estimated to be $250 million dollars annually, which is 2.16% of the total GST income (Wynd & Familton, 2010). New Zealand receives the highest ratio of revenue from the GST system in the OECD (see Figure: 8) (OECD, 2012). It has been suggested that the GST system should not be used as a welfare tool; instead it should be viewed as a revenue earner for the government and social welfare should compensate for welfare issues.

26

Doc 1 Page 32 of 76 Released

Figure 8: VAT revenue ratio for the OECD (OECD, 2012)

Disproportionate benefit to higher socioeconomic groups

The exemption is likely to have a disproportionate benefit for higher socio-economic rather than lower socio-economic groups. GST is regressive in nature. By removing GST from fruit and vegetables it would not make the system less regressive; all consumers would benefit from the removal of GST. However, those on higher incomes spend a higher amount of money on fruit and vegetables. As a result the exemption would provide these consumers with a greater benefit compared to those in greater need, suggesting targeting issues with the policy (Wynd & Familton, 2010).

Summary

This policy represents a loss of key government income and would compromise GST efficiency. It is likely that the consumption of fruit and vegetables would increase, however the relationship to obesity remains unclear. Further investigation into the market situation would be critical to measure how pricing of fruit and vegetable products are set and if the exemption would allow retailers to inflate these prices. Removing GST from fruit and vegetables may not be viable; however, consideration of other mechanisms is necessary. For example, a voucher system could be an effective mechanism to encourage greater consumption of fruit and vegetables.

27

Doc 1 Page 33 of 76 Released

6 Recommendations

6.1 Recommended approach

This paper suggests the most promising areas are:

• Sugar-sweetened beverage tax

• Regulations on marketing to children

• Interpretive front of pack labelling system

A sugar-sweetened beverage tax has been proposed as an area that could use further work. This regulatory option has a number of benefits namely:

• A reduction in consumption of sugar-sweetened beverages, suggested up to 16 per cent reduction in consumption from a 20 per cent tax.

• A number of health benefits, with a particular benefit on reducing diabetes, pre- diabetes and a proven effect upon obesity.

• Increased revenue that could be used to support health promotion activities to reduce obesity or prevent/treat diabetes.

Regulation of marketing to children is another policy that requires further consideration. It has a number of significant benefits for child obesity and would protect children and support parents through:

• A reduction in exposure to unhealthy food advertising.

• A reduction in pester power and demand for unhealthy food products.

The final policy that requires further consideration is an interpretive front of pack labelling. Again, this policy would have a number of positive impacts including:

• Product reformulation by producers.

• Greater information for the consumer about food composition.

• Driving consumer behavioural change to reduce consumption of products high in sugar, fat and salt.

A saturated fat tax could provide a useful mechanism to reduce consumption of unhealthy food products. However, in this paper the tax has been excluded due to a number of negative impacts including:

• Significant economic implications, loss of jobs and businesses, and harm to New Zealand primary industries.

• Implementation issues.

28

Doc 1 Page 34 of 76 Released

• Lack of consumer or producer acceptability.

• Ambiguous effect on consumption.

Another regulatory option considered in this paper was removal of GST on fruit and vegetables. Again, this paper excluded this regulatory option due to a number of financial implications and efficiency issues such as:

• Loss of key government income.

• Equity impacts, higher proportion of benefit upon higher socio-economic rather than lower socio-economic groups.

• Loss of efficiency from a current simplistic GST system.

6.2 Areas for further work

6.2.1 Sugar-sweetened beverage tax

A sugar-sweetened beverage tax has the intended goal of changing the price of sugar- sweetened products and ultimately changes in consumer behaviour. Further work would be required on the level of the taxation, inclusion criteria (e.g. powdered drinks, juices, cordials, sports drinks, energy drinks, RTDs etc) and the mechanism by which the tax is introduced. There would have to be further work on the policy formulation issues, such as further investigation into the harm of artificial sweeteners.

6.2.2 Regulation of marketing to children

Regulating marketing to children has the goal of reducing exposure to and demand for unhealthy foods. There are several issues that require further work namely policy formulation issues such as the most efficient way the restrictions would be introduced. Regulation of some media such as the internet may be difficult to implement; further investigation into the impact and the way this could be introduced is important to consider. In consideration of manufacturers, there would have to be further work on ways that could minimise producer loss from the regulations.

Another regulation highlighted for further work earlier in the paper was planning restrictions, in particular restrictions on the number and locations of fast food outlets. Again, this policy has the intention of restricting exposure to unhealthy foods. The relationship between fast food outlets and low socio-economic areas is a theme highlighted earlier in the paper and could be vital in understanding obesity causes.

6.2.3 Interpretive front of pack labelling

Front of pack labelling would increase the level of information available to the consumer. This would help consumers to make better informed decisions about the food they consume. An area requiring further work in this policy is defining the best system of front of pack labelling for New Zealand, i.e. star or traffic light systems. In addition, significant further work into the possible implementation issues and costs to the producer or consumer would be required. There would have to be considerations into minimising the costs to producers through a phasing-in period or a subsidy. 29

Doc 1 Page 35 of 76 Released

7 Appendix

Assessment Interpretive front of pack Regulation of marketing to Sugar-sweetened beverage Saturated fat tax Removal of GST from fruit against criteria labelling children tax and vegetables

Impact on • There is predicted to be a • Through less exposure there • Expected fall in • Expected fall in • The price of fruit and consumption behavioural change away is estimated to be less consumption as price consumption as price vegetables would fall and from products high in sugar, demand for and increases. increases. as result consumption will fat and salt. However this is consumption of products increase. It has been dependent on the high in sugar, fat and salt. • There may be issues of • Greater impact expected suggested this increase understanding of the system However there may be some retailers absorbing upon low socio-economic would be 11 per cent, if in place and the significance issues in policy design. the tax and spreading the groups, due to higher 12.5 per cent tax was the consumer places upon tax upon other product elasticity. This is deemed removed. the label. • Likely to have a positive lines, and so not to be progressive in terms impact upon children’s transferring the tax to of health outcomes. • However this extra • The main driver of change wellbeing and diet. consumers. income or wealth the will be seen through • There may be issues of consumer feels might be producers with the incentive • Reduction in pester power some retailers absorbing used for other food to achieve a favourable and desire to consume the tax and spreading the products. So the real label. This could help unhealthy food products. tax upon other products, increase in fruit and influence consumption of and so not transferring the vegetables would be unhealthy foods over time. tax to consumers. unknown.

Efficiency • This regulatory approach is • Restricting advertising • A sugar-sweetened • The efficiency of a fat tax • This option may be seen seen as highly efficient; it is during children’s viewing beverage tax would be may be a poor use of as inefficient as it would providing consumers with a hours may result in a shift to seen as beneficial in resources, there would be create exemptions to a higher level of information at other media such as the changing consumer several exemptions and system which is currently little to no cost to the internet and adult viewing behaviour. as seen in Denmark it efficient and simple. government. times which are more would be difficult to make difficult to regulate. As a • Sugar-sweetened sure the implemented tax • GST is not viewed as a • The labelling system is likely beverages have a high

30

Doc 1 Page 36 of 76 Released

to drive the manufacturers result children might have a level of substitution so would not overly affect tool for social welfare. to reformulate their products higher exposure such as in consumers will reduce businesses. to obtain a more favourable the UK. consumption if the tax is • Removal would see the rating. high enough. This is likely • This tax would be seen as highest benefit go to • However if the policy is well to have an impact on efficient in terms of higher socio-economic formulated there could be obesity rates and have administration costs, but groups as they buy the significant health benefits. positive health benefits. there are some boundary highest proportion of fruit issues that would need to and vegetables. • There may be issues in be considered. defining the classification of defining the food products.

Acceptability: Public : High public acceptability. Public: High public acceptability. Public: High public acceptability. Public: Low public acceptability. Public : Dependent on other taxes Public and i.e. income taxes increase, would Producer Producer : Low producer acceptability. Producer : Low producer acceptability. Producer: Low producer Producer: Low producer result in low public acceptability. Support acceptability. acceptability. Producer: Likely to be high producer acceptability.

Costs • Likely to have little to no • Likely to have little to no • Administration costs need • Administration costs need • One estimate has costs for the government. costs for the government. to be considered. to be considered. indicated cost of $250 However the revenue that However the revenue that million , 2.16 • Consideration of • Monitoring harm to the tax would generate the tax would generate per cent of GST revenue. manufacturer costs would broadcasters would be would offset any losses. would offset any losses. This is income that the be required, including ways necessary; some government would have to offset the costs. intervention could be • Policy would place higher to generate from another required. economic burdens upon source i.e. income taxes. manufacturers in terms of internal administration costs.

Impact on Economic growth : Likely to have a Sustainability for the future: Likely Sustainability for the future: Likely Economic growth : Likely to have a Economic growth : Likely to have a Living negative impact. to have a positive impact. to have positive impact. negative impact. negative impact.

31

Doc 1 Page 37 of 76 Released

Standards • Some manufacturers of food • Limiting exposure from a • Have positive health • Some retailers may • The government would products will be harmed as young age will encourage benefits, with significant experience significant experience reduced GST their products may be children to live healthier improvements in heart harm, which could result income and would have to assessed as unfavourable. lifestyles which would have disease. in job losses and business fund this cost from As a result demand for positive benefits for society failure. another source. these products may fall. and the level of obesity. • Likely to have an impact upon the rate of obesity in • The fat tax may apply to • Reduced GST income • Would have economic Increasing Equity: Likely to have a New Zealand. significant New Zealand may put pressure on implications for positive impact. industries such as dairy spending for other manufacturers that will have Increasing Equity: Likely to have and meat products; this priorities. to alter their packaging to • Advertising to children is impacts either way. would decrease incorporate the mandatory seen as inequitable as they consumption and could • The exemptions added to • The regressive nature of requirements. are vulnerable consumers. harm producers. the GST system would By restricting marketing to the tax places economic reduce the simplicity and Sustainability for the future: Likely children it is limiting their constraints on low socio- Sustainability for the future: Likely effectiveness of the to have a positive impact. exposure and provides economic groups. to have a positive impact. system. greater opportunities for • From an equity • Have positive health these children to live healthy • Have positive health Sustainability for the future: Likely perspective the tax may benefits, with individuals lifestyles. benefits, with significant to have a positive impact . aware of the nutritional provide greater improvements in heart value of products they opportunities. disease. • Have positive health consume. outcomes. • Likely to have an impact upon the rate of obesity in Increasing Equity: Likely to have a New Zealand. negative impact. • Producers are likely to reformulate to obtain a Increasing Equity: Could have • The exemption is favourable label. This would impacts either way. regressive in nature, have a positive nutritional favouring higher socio- benefit for all consumers. • The regressive nature of economic groups. the tax places economic Increasing Equity: Likely to have a constraints on low socio-

32

Doc 1 Page 38 of 76 Released

positive impact. economic groups.

• Provides greater information • From an equity to the consumer so they can perspective the tax may make informed decisions in provide greater regard to their food choices. opportunities for individuals at risk of experiencing obesity to participate in society.

33

Doc 1 Page 39 of 76 Released

8 Reference list

Adams, J., Tyrrell, R., Adamson, A.J., & White, M. (2012). Effect of Restrictions on Television Food Advertising to Children on Exposure to Advertisements for ‘Less Healthy’ Foods: Repeat Cross-Sectional Study. PLoS ONE , 7(2). doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0031578 .

American Heart Association. (2013). Obesity Information . Retrieved from http://www.heart.org/HEARTORG/GettingHealthy/WeightManagement/Obesity/Obesity- Information_UCM_307908_Article.jsp

Blakely, T., Wilson, N., & Kaye-Blake, B. (2014). Taxes on Sugar-sweetened Beverages to Curb Future Obesity and Diabetes Epidemics. PLoS Med , 11(1). doi: 10.1371/journal.pmed.1001583.

Briggs, A., Mytton, O., Kehlbacher, A., Tiffin, R., Rayner, M., & Scarborough, P. (2013). Overall and income specific effect on prevalence of overweight and obesity of 20% sugar-sweetened drink tax in UK: econometric and compartive risk assessment modelling study. British Medical Journal , 347:f6189. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1136/bmj.f6189

Brownell, K., & Frieden, T. (2009). Ounces of Prevention – The Public Policy Case for Taxes on Sugared Beverages. New England Journal of Medicine , 360(18), 1805-1808.

Brownell, K. & Friedman, R. (2012). Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Taxes: An Updated Policy Brief . New Haven, CT: Yale Rudd Center for Food Policy & Obesity.

Child Poverty Action Group Inc. (2010). Will removing GST on fresh fruit and vegetables achieve its stated aim? Auckland, New Zealand: Wynd, D., & Familton, A.

Consumer NZ. (2010). Traffic-light food label changes. Retrieved from https://www.consumer.org.nz/articles/traffic-light-food-label-changes.

Department of Health & Devolved Administrations. (2013). Front of pack Nutrition Labelling: Joint Response to Consultation . London, UK: Department of Health.

Diabetes New Zealand Inc. & Fight the Obesity Epidemic Inc. (2003). The POD Report – Prevention of Obesity and Type 2 Diabetes in New Zealand Children. The Facts. Retrieved from http://www.foe.org.nz/wp-content/plugins/wp-publications- archive/openfile.php?action=open&file=20

Drewnowski, A., &. Darmon, N. (2005). The Economics of Obesity: dietary energy density and energy cost. American Journal of Clinical Nutrition , 82(1) 265S-273S.

Eyles, H., Mhurchu, C., Nghiem, N., & Blakely, T. (2012). Food Pricing Strategies, Population Diets, and Non- Communicable Disease: A Systematic Review of Simulation Studies. PLoS Med , 9(12) e1001353. doi: 10.1371/journal.pmed.1001353

34

Doc 1 Page 40 of 76 Released

Food Standards Agency Scotland. (2013). Front-of-pack nutrition labelling . Retrieved from https://www.food.gov.uk/scotland/scotnut/signposting

Food Standards Australia New Zealand. (2013). Trans fatty acids. Retrieved from http://www.foodstandards.govt.nz/consumer/nutrition/transfat/Pages/default.aspx.

Fowler, S., Williams, K., Resendez, R., Hunt, K., Hazuda, H., & Stern, M. (2008). Fueling the Obesity Epidemic? Artificially Sweetened Beverage Use and Long-term Weight Gain. Obesity , 16(8), 1894-1900. doi: 10.1038/oby.2008.284

Harvard School of Public Health. (2013). Obesity Prevention Source . Retreived from http://www.hsph.harvard.edu/obesity-prevention-source/

Hawley, K., Roberto, C., Bragg, M., Liu, P., Schwartz, M., & Brownell, K. (2012). The science on front-of-package food labels. Public Health Nutrition. 16(3), 430-439. doi:10.1017/S1368980012000754

Health Committee. (2013). Inquiry into improving child health outcomes and preventing child abuse, with a focus on preconception until three years of age. Wellington, New Zealand: House of Representatives.

Health Committee. (2007). Inquiry into Obesity and Type 2 Diabetes in New Zealand. Wellington, New Zealand: House of Representatives.

Jenkin, G., Signal, L., & Thomson, G. (2011). Framing obesity: the framing contest between industry and public health at the New Zealand inquiry into obesity. Obesity Reviews , 12(12), 1022-1030. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-789X.2011.00918.x.

Jenkin, G., Wilson, N., & Hermanson, N. (2009). Identifying 'unhealthy' food advertising on television: a case study applying the UK Nutrient Profile model. Public Health Nutrition , 12(5), 614-623. doi: 10.1017/S1368980008003029.

Lal, A., Moodie, M., Ashton, T., Siahpush, M., & Swinburn, B. (2012). Health care and lost productivity costs of overweight and obesity in New Zealand. Australian and New Zealand Journal of Public Health , 36(6), 550-556. doi: 10.1111/j.1753- 6405.2012.00931.x.

Lanumata, T., Heta, C., Signal, L., & Haretuku, R. (2008). Front of Pack Labelling from the Perspectives of Maori, Pacific and Low-income New Zealanders. Dunedin, New Zealand: Health Promotion and Policy Research Unit, University of Otago.

Lavin, R., & Timpson, H. (2013). Exploring the Acceptability of a Tax on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages , UK: Centre for Public Health Liverpool, Liverpool John Moores University.

Magnusson. R. (2010). Obesity prevention and personal responsibility: the case of front-of- pack food labelling in Australia. BMC Public Health , 10(662). doi:10.1186/1471-2458- 10-662.

Mhurchu, C., Blakely, T., Jiang, Y., Eyles, H.C., & Rodgers, A. (2010). Effects of price discounts and tailored nutrition education on supermarket purchases: a randomized controlled trial. American Journal of Clinical Nutrition , 91(3), 736-747.

35

Doc 1 Page 41 of 76 Released

Ministry of Health. (2013). Annual Report. Wellington, New Zealand: Ministry of Health.

Ministry of Health. (2001). DHB Toolkit. Wellington, New Zealand: Ministry of Health.

Ministry of Health. (2013). Health Loss in New Zealand . Wellington, New Zealand: Ministry of Health.

Ministry of Health. (2001). Health Strategy. Wellington, New Zealand: Ministry of Health.

Ministry of Health. (2013). New Zealand Health Survey 2012/13. Wellington, New Zealand: Ministry of Health.

Mytton, O., Clarke, D., & Rayner, M. (2012). Taxing unhealthy food and drinks to improve health. British Medical Journal , 344:e2931. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1136/bmj.e2931

National Heart Forum. (2012). What is the role of health-related food duties? London, UK: Landon, J., & Graff, H.

Nestle. M. (2012). The Danish fat tax: reflections on its demise . Retrieved from http://www.foodpolitics.com/2012/11/the-danish-fat-tax-reflections-on-its-demise/

O’Dea, D., Gorton, D., & Mhurchu, C. (2009). Thin Subsidies and Fat Taxes: Economic Instruments for addressing Food Inadequacy and Nutrition Issues . Wellington, New Zealand: NZ Association of Economists conference.

OECD. (2012). Trends 2012: VAT/GST and Excise Rates, Trends and Administration Issues , Paris, France: OECD Publishing.

Petkantchin, V. (2013). “Nutrition” taxes: the costs of Denmark’s fat tax. Institut Économique Molinari. Retrieved from http://www.institutmolinari.org/nutrition-taxes-the-costs- of,1522.html

Rush, E., McLennan, S., Obolonkin, V., Vandal, A., Hamlin, M., Simmons, D., & Graham, D. (2014). Project Energize: whole-region primary school nutrition and physical activity programme; evaluation of body size and fitness 5 years after the randomised controlled trial. British Journal of Nutrition , 111(2), 363-371. doi: 10.1017/S0007114513002316

Sacks, G., Veerman, J., Moodie, M., & Swinburn, B. (2010). ‘Traffic-light’ nutrition labelling and ‘junk-food’ tax: a modelled comparison of cost-effectiveness for obesity prevention. International Journal of Obesity , 35(7), 1001-1009. doi: 10.1038/ijo.2010.228.

Sassi, F. (2010). Obesity and the Economics of Prevention: Fit not Fat . Paris, France: OECD Publishing.

Shaw, C. (2009). (Non)regulation of marketing of unhealthy food to children in New Zealand. New Zealand Medical Journal , 122(1288), 76-86.

Signal, L., Lanumata, T., Mhurchu, C., & Gorton, D. (2012). Front-of-pack nutrition labelling in New Zealand: an exploration of stakeholder views about research and implementation. Health Promotion Journal of Australia , 23(1), 48-51.

36

Doc 1 Page 42 of 76 Released

Smed, S. (2012). Financial penalties on foods: the fat tax in Denmark. Nutrition Bulletin , 37(2), 142-147.

Swinburn, B.A., Caterson, I., Seidell, J.C., James, W.P. (2004). Diet, nutrition and the prevention of excess weight gain and obesity. Public Health Nutrition , 7(1A), 123-146.

The Food Industry Group. (2006). 2nd Annual Report to the Minister of Health. Retrieved from http://www.fig.org.nz/5/downloads

The National Business Review. (2010). GST removal from healthy food gets a 'no' . Retrieved from http://www.nbr.co.nz/article/gst-removal-healthy-food-gets-a-no-126510.

Toomath, R. (2006). Obesity in children. New Zealand Family Physician , 33(3), 203-205.

University of Canterbury. (2014). Current food labelling not good enough . Retrieved from http://www.scoop.co.nz/stories/GE1401/S00025/current-food-labelling-not-good- enough.htm

Veerman, J., & Cobiac, L. (2013). Removing the GST exemption for fresh fruits and vegetables could cost lives. Medical Journal of Australia , 199(8), 534-535.

Waikato District Health Board. (2011). Obesity, diabetes and fast food – the impact of marketing to childen . Hamilton, New Zealand: Waikato District Health Board.

World Cancer Research Fund. (2012). Traffic light labelling – helping people make healthy choices . London, UK: World Cancer Research Fund.

World Health Organization. (2013). Obesity and overweight . Retrieved from http://www.who.int/mediacentre/factsheets/fs311/en/

37

Doc 1 Page 43 of 76 Released

38

Doc 2 Page 44 of 76 Released

Doc 2 Page 45 of 76 Released IN-CONFIDENCE

Treasury Report: Options for regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem

Executive Summary

This paper explores regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem. Regulatory measures to combat obesity have been implemented internationally and there are often calls for similar approaches to be implemented in New Zealand in the media and among academics. The statistics on obesity in New Zealand have been worsening despite the voluntary initiatives that have been implemented in recent years to combat the problem. This has encouraged us to investigate potential regulatory responses that could be implemented in New Zealand.

A third of New Zealand’s population is obese today and another third is overweight. Obesity is expected to overtake tobacco use as the number one risk factor for health within the next two years. Obesity is a key risk factor for a number of chronic diseases and has links with diabetes, heart disease, stroke and coronary artery disease. The rising rates of childhood obesity are of particular concern.

The environment we live in today has a huge impact on our lifestyles and is contributing to the high rates of obesity. This environment, which facilitates and promotes weight gain, has been named an ‘obesogenic’ environment. If this obesogenic environment is left unaddressed, obesity rates, and subsequent health costs, are predicted to rise further.

The current approach to combat obesity involves a number of voluntary initiatives, which are not underpinned by a coordinating strategy. Some regulatory and/or mandatory measures may be required as an addition to the current initiatives to reverse the rising rates of obesity. Based on international evidence and our engagement with academics in this field, we consider that the most promising regulatory approaches to explore further are a sugar- sweetened beverage tax, regulation of marketing to children and a mandatory front of pack food labelling system. However, further work is needed to determine whether there is a robust policy justification for each specific intervention, to clarify the -offs, and to consider implementation issues.

Obesity is a complex problem and requires multiple initiatives to reverse the current trend. Obesity has impacts on labour market participation, productivity and quality of life and therefore cuts across several government sectors. A cross-government approach may be an effective way to approach the issue. We consider that an obesity target, perhaps in the form of an additional BPS target, could help to encourage cross-government collaboration and make this growing problem a priority area for collaborative action. A target could also be used to focus on the connection between child obesity rates and poverty.

: Options for regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem - revised Page 2

IN-CONFIDENCE Doc 2 Page 46 of 76 Released IN-CONFIDENCE

Recommended Action

We recommend that you: a note that obesity is about to overtake tobacco use as the number one risk factor for health and that regulatory interventions may need to be considered, alongside voluntary initiatives, to address this problem b note that a sugar-sweetened beverage tax, regulation of marketing to children and mandatory front of pack labelling show promise as possible regulatory measures, although further work is needed to determine whether there is a robust policy justification for each specific intervention, to clarify the trade-offs, and to consider implementation issues c indicate if you would like to discuss this report with Treasury officials, and

Yes/No d refer a copy of this report to the Minister of Health.

Refer/not referred.

Ben McBride Manager, Health

Hon Bill English Minister of Finance

: Options for regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem - revised Page 3

IN-CONFIDENCE Doc 2 Page 47 of 76 Released IN-CONFIDENCE

Treasury Report: Options for regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem

Purpose of Report

1. This report is to advise you of some options for regulatory responses that the Government could consider to respond to the rising obesity rates in New Zealand in the future.

2. Regulatory interventions to improve health outcomes involve trade-offs between conflicting objectives, including improved health outcomes on the one hand and individual choice and freedoms on the other. The net fiscal and economic impacts are uncertain. Regulatory action to tackle obesity is most likely to be justified if individuals currently lack the information necessary to make optimal decisions or face difficulty making such decisions even in the presence of good information, or if obesity gives rise to large externalities (including social, fiscal and economic costs).

3. This report does not provide a detailed analysis of specific interventions in terms of this framework. Nor does it make recommendations. Instead, it:

• Describes the high and rising levels of obesity in New Zealand and notes that regulatory interventions may need to be considered as part of a package of measures if the Government wishes to make progress in reversing these trends;

• Provides a brief overview of three regulatory responses that have shown some promise based on international evidence and academic research. It also notes that an additional BPS target could help to drive cross-government action on the problem of obesity.

4. If Ministers wished seriously to consider regulatory measures alongside voluntary programmes, then further policy work would be needed to provide a balanced assessment of the different options.

Obesity is a growing problem in New Zealand

5. Obesity is a complex health issue affecting significant numbers of people. Approximately a third of the New Zealand population is obese today. A further third is overweight. New Zealand now has the third highest rate of overweight and obese adults in the OECD, after only the United States and Mexico (see figure 1).

6. Obesity disproportionately affects Maori and Pacific Island populations and socio- economically disadvantaged populations, which reinforces ethnic disparities in the New Zealand health system. In 2013, 68 percent of Pacific adults and 48 percent of Maori adults were obese. The growing child obesity rate is also concerning. In 2013, obesity among New Zealand children reached 11 percent with a further 21 percent classified as overweight. There is also a strong connection between child obesity rates and poverty: the NZ health survey indicates that children living in the most deprived areas are three times as likely to be obese as children living in the least deprived areas (after adjusting for sex, age and ethnicity).

7. These figures are particularly alarming since obesity is a key risk factor in a range of chronic diseases. For example, type 2 diabetes is closely linked to obesity, as are high cholesterol and blood pressure, which can increase the likelihood of heart disease, stroke and coronary artery disease developing. Obesity (or high body mass index) was

: Options for regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem - revised Page 4

IN-CONFIDENCE Doc 2 Page 48 of 76 Released IN-CONFIDENCE

the second highest risk to health in 2006 (see Figure 2) and is expected to overtake tobacco use as the number one risk factor to health in the next couple of years (see Figure 3).

Figure 1: Obesity among adults, 2012 or nearest year (OECD, 2014)

Figure 2: Attributable burden for selected risk factors 2006 (Ministry of Health, 2013)

: Options for regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem - revised Page 5

IN-CONFIDENCE Doc 2 Page 49 of 76 Released IN-CONFIDENCE

Figure 3: Trends and projections in health loss attributable to tobacco and high BMI, total population, 2006 to 2016 (Ministry of Health, 2013)

8. Calculating the fiscal and economic costs associated with obesity is not straightforward. There is little doubt that obesity-related conditions account for a material proportion of healthcare expenditure, although estimates vary depending partly on differences in methodology and because co-morbidities make it difficult to attribute costs to specific conditions. One 2010 OECD report cited an estimate that an obese person has healthcare costs around 30 percent higher than someone of a normal weight; this estimate is based on a meta analysis drawing on a range of studies with different methodologies and timeframes. McKinsey (2014) estimated that obesity accounts for between 2 and 7 percent of all health care spending in developed economies. For New Zealand, Lal et al. (2012) estimated that spending related to obesity in 2006 was equal to 4.5 percent of total health expenditure (or $686m). There are also a number of obesity-related costs that fall outside the health sector – for example, reduced productivity, inability to work, and reduced quality of life, which can lead to other social problems – although these costs are difficult to quantify.

9. Obesity-related interventions may thus be a cost effective way of improving population health. This does not mean that they are necessarily cost saving in fiscal terms. The evidence on this point is inconclusive. A number of older studies suggest that the lifetime health costs of obese individuals are higher than those for people of normal weight. However, a more recent paper has argued that reductions in obesity-related costs are offset by higher expenditure on other diseases during additional life years gained. More broadly, it is open to question how far healthcare expenditure is driven by objective need rather than other factors, including supplier-induced and income-driven demand and unit cost growth. Addressing one source of morbidity, while improving health outcomes, may therefore displace rather than reduce demand.

10. Similarly, while improved population health may contribute to improved productivity and economic growth, there are likely to be trade-offs in terms of the deadweight economic costs associated with the taxes needed to fund public healthcare systems. There is some empirical support for the view that reallocating government spending towards infrastructure, education and (to a lesser degree) health is positive for economic growth (Gemmell et al., 2009; 2014). Whether the effect of health spending on growth overall is positive or negative once taxes are taken into account is not clear, particularly for countries with advanced health systems which may face diminishing marginal returns to expenditure.

: Options for regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem - revised Page 6

IN-CONFIDENCE Doc 2 Page 50 of 76 Released IN-CONFIDENCE

Regulatory measures could complement existing voluntary initiatives

11. In recent years there have been several initiatives that have aimed to combat the problem of obesity in New Zealand. These initiatives have generally been voluntary in nature and focussed on encouraging individuals to make healthier choices rather than trying to change or regulate the ‘obesogenic environment’ – that is, an environment that facilitates and promotes weight gain – the individuals are living in.

12. Some of these initiatives include:

• Green Prescriptions issued by GPs or practice nurses to encourage physical activity. • The Fruit in Schools programme for low-decile schools and the 5 Plus a Day programme to promote consumption of fruit and vegetables. • The “Let’s Beat Diabetes” programme in Counties Manukau, which led to a joint venture with McDonalds and Coca-Cola to substitute sugar-free lemonade for the full sugar version. • Project Energize in Waikato (now in 233 schools in Waikato reaching 10% of New Zealand’s child population), which focuses on health literacy and physical activity.

13. Earlier this year the Government agreed to introduce two new initiatives: Healthy Families NZ and a front of pack labelling system. Healthy Families NZ is a community based initiative to encourage healthy choices and healthy lifestyles. Front of pack labelling is intended to enable consumers to make healthier food choices. These are both voluntary measures.

14. In 2001, the Ministry of Health published a Health Strategy document, which included a stocktake of some obesity prevention programmes in New Zealand as well as an evidence-based review of successful international programmes. Since then there have been individual voluntary initiatives implemented like those mentioned above.

15. Regulatory measures could complement the range of existing voluntary measures. A recent report by McKinsey (2014) argued that, while education and personal responsibility were critical elements of any programme to reduce obesity, these were not sufficient on their own and must be supplemented by interventions that “reset the defaults” to make healthy behaviours easier. The report recommended a systemic, sustained portfolio of initiatives, both government and non-government, delivered at scale, to address the health burden associated with obesity.

Some regulatory options show promise

16. The obesity epidemic is a growing problem internationally. There are international examples of regulatory measures being implemented to combat the problem and recently there have been calls for such measures to be implemented in New Zealand. The Treasury Health Team has undertaken an initial review of a range of regulatory measures that have been implemented internationally and identified in academic research.

17. The options that show promise include a sugar-sweetened beverage tax, regulations on marketing to children and a mandatory interpretive front of pack labelling system. These options are discussed below. Similar regulatory options are proposed in the recent New Zealand Medical Association (NZMA) policy briefing, Tackling Obesity , which recommends a sugar-sweetened beverages tax, marketing regulation, front of pack labelling and licensing of fast food premises.

: Options for regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem - revised Page 7

IN-CONFIDENCE Doc 2 Page 51 of 76 Released IN-CONFIDENCE

Fiscal mechanism: Sugar-sweetened beverages tax

18. Sugar-sweetened beverages (SSB) deliver little to no nutrition, are heavily marketed to children, contribute to poor diet and carry the risk of obesity, diabetes and other diseases, as well as poor dental health.

19. A SSB tax has the intended goal of changing the price of sugar-sweetened products and ultimately changing consumer behaviour. Taxes on SSB have been introduced in a number of countries, including France, Mexico, Finland, Hungary and a number of US states. Some international evidence has shown these taxes to be effective in reducing consumption, for example, in France and Hungary (National Heart Forum, 2012). The policy logic is that a reduction in consumption of these beverages will have an impact on obesity rates as well as reducing diabetes and poor dental health, although the evidence on this point is mixed. Some studies have suggested that consumers may shift to other high-calorie products, with no impact on population weight.

20. A SSB tax may be a viable option for New Zealand in principle, but further work would be required initially to ensure that a SSB tax is the most appropriate and effective policy lever to help reduce obesity rates and to determine that there is a strong rationale for targeting these products in particular through taxation. There would then be policy trade-offs and design issues to work through before a decision to proceed was made.

21. One concern about a SSB tax is that it may have negative distributional impacts because the financial implications will be more significant for lower socio-economic groups. However, this might also have a progressive impact on health outcomes given that there is a higher incidence of obesity-related disease within lower socio-economic groups and they generally consume more unhealthy foods.

22. If additional work determined that there was a rationale for introducing a SSB tax, design and implementation issues would then need to be considered. Further work and analysis would be required on the level of the tax and inclusion criteria (e.g. powdered drinks, juices, cordials, sports drinks, energy drinks, RTDs, etc.). There are likely to be additional compliance costs for business and administration costs for government, which would also need to be considered.

23. Some opposition to a SSB tax could be expected from the beverage industry and we have seen examples of this internationally. This is something to be considered as part of further work on a SSB tax and this should involve working with and consulting industry.

24. Other fiscal mechanisms to combat obesity include a saturated fat tax and removal of GST from fruit and vegetables. International evidence has shown these regulatory measures to be less effective and more complex to implement than a SSB tax.

Regulation of marketing to children

25. Marketing to children has been clearly shown to influence parents’ and children’s food preferences and choices and also drives ‘pester power’ that can influence consumer behaviour. Currently, children in New Zealand are exposed to advertisements for many unhealthy snack foods, drinks and fast foods and 70 percent of advertising in children’s viewing times promotes unhealthy food products.

26. Regulations on advertising to children can reduce exposure to, and therefore demand for, unhealthy foods. International evidence has shown that regulating or banning television and radio marketing to children can lead to reduced product sales. For example, a ban on television advertising directed at children in Poland was associated with reduced soft drinks sales. The NZMA policy briefing also recommends protecting

: Options for regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem - revised Page 8

IN-CONFIDENCE Doc 2 Page 52 of 76 Released IN-CONFIDENCE

children from marketing of unhealthy foods, but argues that the regulatory regime must address all forms of marketing. Such policies need to avoid unintended consequences, as shown by the UK experience in which children were still exposed to the same amount of advertising because they watched television shows outside of the viewing times targeted by the regulations. This would be an area for further work.

Mandatory front of pack labelling

27. Cabinet agreed in June to implement a voluntary interpretive front of pack labelling system consistent with the system that has been implemented in Australia. This is a ‘Health Star Rating’ system, which will display the amounts of salt, sugar, saturated fat and energy in the food product.

28. As well as improving consumers’ ability to interpret the nutritional information on food products, interpretive front of pack labelling may also have the desirable effect of encouraging food producers to reformulate their products to reduce the sugar, salt and/or fat content. This is more likely to occur if the front of pack labelling is a mandatory requirement for producers. The system Cabinet agreed to in June is voluntary, so it may not be as effective as intended in influencing product reformulation and, subsequently, obesity rates. Further work on the policy could consider making the labelling system mandatory. Any further work on this would need to involve working with stakeholders to establish an effective system that works for industry and consumers.

A BPS target could help drive a cross-government approach

29. Reducing obesity will require changes to social factors/behaviours and changes to environmental conditions to achieve success. There are multiple possible interventions. Regulatory measures of the kind discussed above alongside educational initiatives may be worth exploring, as this may be a way to raise the overall level of impact on obesity rates. A coordinated, evidence-based strategy for obesity is required to coordinate the various initiatives needed to tackle this multi-faceted problem. The effects of obesity are not limited to the health sector, so such a strategy should involve government agencies and NGOs in several sectors, particularly Health, Education, and Sport and Recreation.

30. We consider that a BPS obesity target could help to encourage cross-government work and promote the development of a cross-government obesity strategy. Additionally, given there is a strong connection between poverty and child obesity rates, an obesity target could be a way to address the practical consequences of deprivation for children’s longer term outcomes. We consider that an obesity target is more appropriate than a diabetes target, because it would address the source of the problem and would reduce the time lag to deliver action and results.

Consultation with the Ministry of Health

31. We have consulted with the Ministry of Health on this report and we have been informed of the obesity-related work currently happening in the Ministry.

32. The immediate focus for the Ministry of Health will be advice around a possible target for childhood obesity and assessing the effectiveness of existing obesity initiatives. The Ministry will also be kicking off a work stream looking at a broader framework and approach to obesity/non-communicable diseases (NCDs), which is to be developed in the medium term (approximately next 6-12 months). This should be informed in part by the results of the WHO Commission on Ending Childhood Obesity.

: Options for regulatory responses to the growing obesity problem - revised Page 9

IN-CONFIDENCE Doc 3 Page 53 of 76 Released

THIS IS AN INCOMPLETE DRAFT DOCUMENT

A Conceptual Basis and Evidence Base for Health Tax

A overview of conceptual rationales and evidence based rationales for the imposition of food and drink related taxes for health reform

Withheld under s9(2)(g)(i) Tax Strategy

Doc 3 Page 54 of 76 Released

THIS IS AN INCOMPLETE DRAFT DOCUMENT

N Z T R E A S UR Y W O RK I N G A Conceptual Basis and Evidence Base for Health Tax P A PE R

M O N T H / YE AR February 2015

N Z T R E A S UR Y New Zealand Treasury PO Box 3724 Wellington 6008 NEW ZEALAND

Email [email protected] Telephone 64-4-472 2733 Website www.treasury.govt.nz

Withheld under s9(2)(g)(i) ACKN O W L E D G E M E N T S Sian Roguski and Suzy Morrison – Managers Tax Strategy Team, GPS, Treasury Health Team, BPS, Treasury

D I S C L A I M E R The views, opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this Working Paper are strictly those of the author(s). They do not necessarily reflect the views of the New Zealand Treasury or the New Zealand Government. The New Zealand Treasury and the New Zealand Government take no responsibility for any errors or omissions in, or for the correctness of, the information contained in these working papers. The paper is presented not as policy, but with a view to inform and stimulate wider debate.

2

Doc 3 Page 55 of 76 Released

Table of Contents

1. Executive Summary 4

2. Introduction 5

3. Problem Definition and Purpose 6

3.1 Obesity in New Zealand 7 3.2 International Health Reforms through Taxation 8

4. Conceptual Basis for Health Taxes 10

4.1 Case for Market Failure 11 4.2 Rationales for Health Taxes 12

5. Evidence Ba se for Health Taxes 15

5.1 Saturated Fat and 16 5.2 Sugar and Sugar Sweetened Beverage 17 5.3 Analysis 18

6. Design Considerations 19

7. Summary of Findings and Final Outcomes 20

8. Conclusion 21

9. References 22

3

Doc 3 Page 56 of 76 Released

Executive Summary

Obesity, Diabetes, Heart Attacks have all become increasingly common in the past few years. The change in lifestyle and shifts in preferences towards; fast processed foods high in sugar and fat has been a key factor in the.

The project builds evaluates the rationales and the evidence base for such health taxes.

Obesity has risen from 10% of New Zealand in 1977 to 31%. Currently in New Zealand only Tobacco and Alcohol are taxed on a Health rationale. There have been increasing attention in the media to the harm of unhealthy food and drink and the excess consumption of fat and sugar.

There is a global concern about the rise in lifestyle diseases; with Denmark raising a tax on saturated fat, Mexico imposing taxes on soft drinks and Berkeley California in the US became the first city in the world to impose a tax on soft drinks per ounce of sugar.

The project has been analysed on two aspects;

 Conceptual rationales for a health tax

 Evidence base for a health tax.

Conceptual rationales

This evaluated the market failures that would warrant government’s interventions are evaluated.

The excess consumption of these foods and drinks can impose negative externalities on the New Zealand economy.

Other rationales:

 Information Failures

 Behavioural Biases.

o Addictive Quality

o Time inconsistent failures

Tax as an instrument for health reform has been widely debated, Tax crude tool whereby you are effectively forcing people to reduce their consumption. There is also an issue of the poor targeting of tax here, where you are taxing everyone but only a portion of the population, [albeit increasing] are the main targets for such policies.

The evidence base for health taxes; evaluated the elasticity’s for these goods and the relative health outcomes that could be achieved.

The literature is mixed. The elasticity towards these goods was mostly found to be relatively elastic and overall, a tax imposed will have some form of reduction.

4

Doc 3 Page 57 of 76 Released

A rate of 15% or higher would be needed to have the effective reduced rates of consumption. The high rate would be economically regressive on lower income groups.

The major concern is little understanding we have of people’s substitution patterns after the imposition of a tax. This may be a cause for concern as some studies has shown worsened outcomes from substitution to unhealthier but cheaper alternatives.

An example of the harm of substitution effects is; where a tax is raised on soft drinks which would raise the price of average soft drinks like coke. But even after tax; an 89cent 1.25lt bottle of cola from the Warehouse would still be relatively cheaper but the higher sugar content would mean an increased consumption of sugar and a higher rate of lifestyle related diseases.

In summary the call for a tax to unhealthy foods and drink is getting stronger, especially as the concern for lifestyle diseases increases. There is definitely an increasing interest in this area worldwide and it would be interesting to see the dynamics in other countries where such taxes are in place. There is still a need for greater understanding of the elasticity’s and substitution patterns especially due to the potential reversed effects that could occur.

5

Doc 3 Page 58 of 76 Released

Introduction

It is important when making decisions that affect daily lives; the basic reasons of its necessity, its outcomes and actions for moving forward. This project looks at the reasons for why New Zealand would impose a tax on unhealthy foods and drinks high in sugar and fat and if there is a sufficient supporting evidence for these rationales.

The project is an exploration into ‘Health Taxes’ - or tax on foods high in sugar, fat and other unhealthy substances. Both the conceptual insights and evidence base are analysed to understand and evaluate such a tax. The project has an overlying tax policy perspective rather than a health perspective, though such considerations have been made.

The project has insights into what is happening in New Zealand and also considers the international context, where other countries have implemented health taxes.

The conceptual base looks at the market failures that would warrant government’s intervention into the market. These failures are the catalyst for less than optimal decisions made by individuals. Here the decision to consumer regularly unhealthy food and drink is analysed. Also considered are the rationales for why government would impose such a tax.

Also the evidence base considers the literature on consumer responses to ‘Health Taxes’ and the relevant health outcomes that could be achieved.

The alarming rise in lifestyle diseases is a pressing problem on society today and steps towards finding solutions for such a tricky problem is critical. This project aims to only act as a building block for further evaluation and analysis on ‘Health Taxes’.

6

Doc 3 Page 59 of 76 Released

Problem Definition and Purpose

The global obesity epidemic is gaining increasing attention. Even in New Zealand the threat of rising obesity rates loom large, with one of the highest obesity rates compared to other developed nations (Health Commitee, 2013)).

The obesity rate has risen by over 67% since 1977, with 31% now being classified as obese 1. Lal et al, holds an estimates $8 billion to be spent over the next decade on obesity, $2 billion loss in productivity due to absenteeism and premature death in business and society and for 2006 their estimated annual cost of obesity to be $847million and with obesity’s 2% annual rise; this is likely to be higher today.

The problem however is not limited to obesity, as the rate of other lifestyle-related diseases such as diabetes, rheumatic fever, hypertension, cardiovascular diseases and kidney diseases have all been increasing in recent years.

These trends have resulted in health professionals, institutions, the public, and media calling for greater government intervention. Many of the conditions highlighted above have been linked to the excess consumption of unhealthy foods and drinks, with attention being focused on products that have large amounts of fat, sugar and other substances. This issue is especially prevalent in lower income groups, where these foods and drinks tend to be consumed more regularly due to their inexpensive nature.

Sugar has become especially topical, with many studies and documentaries linking the prevalence of sugar in the modern diet to rising health problems in society, including extensive coverage by the New Zealand media, especially in New Zealand psychologists Nigel Latta’s expose on sugar. There has been recurring attention in the media articles or reports being made on an almost weekly basis on the effect of these products. American journalist Katie Couric’s documentary ‘FedUp’ and Nigel Latta’s documentary on sugar have increased in the public profile of food and drink related taxes as a means combating such health problems.

Many other countries like, France, Hungary and Mexico have introduced such taxes and many others have had policy debates on the introduction of health taxes. In addition, increasing numbers of health professionals are campaigning for the imposition of health-related consumption taxes.

As a result, the purpose of this report is to explore the rationales and evidence base for health-related consumption taxes (hereafter referred to as “health taxes”). New Zealand is regarded as having one of the most efficient tax systems in the world. This means that changes to the tax system need to be clearly reasoned and coherent.

1 [Definition]

7

Doc 3 Page 60 of 76 Released

Background

Consumption taxes in New Zealand

In New Zealand, alcoholic beverages and tobacco are currently taxed under the excise regime, which is levied as a unit tax . That is, tax is levied at a fixed dollar amount on a predefined unit of consumption. In the case of alcoholic beverages the unit of taxation is the per liter level of pure alcohol content; whereas for tobacco products it is the per kilo level of tobacco content.

A key feature of this approach is that the relevant unit of taxation is chosen so as to be highly correlated with expected the level of harm. This means that we expect the tax to be ‘well-focused’ in the sense that the burden of the tax is matched to the harmful aspects of consumption.

Separate to the excise regime, most consumer goods and services in New Zealand are subject to Goods and Services Tax (GST), which is a proportionate tax (sometimes referred to as an ) that is currently levied at a flat rate of 15%. New Zealand’s broad GST base means that there are no exemptions for food and drink related goods. In other words, all food and drink items, whether perceived to be ‘healthy’ or ‘unhealthy’, are taxed at the 15% rate under the GST regime. This includes alcohol and tobacco, for which GST is levied after including of the costs of excise tax.

However, there have been calls to exempt fresh fruit and vegetables from GST. [Summary of recent Lab party and Green policies].

A snapshot of excise and GST

8

Doc 3 Page 61 of 76 Released

International context

Consumption taxes are used worldwide; principally as a means of raising revenue, but sometimes also to advance specific social policy objectives. Alcohol and tobacco taxation are the most common example of the latter, with most countries levying separate taxes on these goods (i.e. separate to the local GST/VAT regime) to help curb excessive consumption. These are typically implemented as a unit tax through the excise regime; the same way as in New Zealand. As shown in [Figure 1] however, rates [vary widely, in accordance with national policy priorities.]

Fig 1: Alcohol and tobacco excise rates [charts will need some work]

Most countries also administer a general consumption tax (often called GST or VAT) which is similar, at least in principle, to New Zealand’s GST. However the precise details of these taxes, in particular the breadth of the tax base; vary considerably from country to country. Few if any countries maintain a tax base as broad as New Zealand’s.

In terms of food and drink related consumption, a number of countries permit exemptions or “zero-rating” within their GST/VAT regimes for items such as fresh fruit and vegetables [and other food/drink items]2. Such countries include […].

Whilst exemptions from GST/VAT are not uncommon, it is less common to see narrow taxes with a specific policy goal (such as health taxes or environmental taxes) implemented through the GST/VAT regime. Such taxes are normally collected through a separate regime (such as excise) or a purpose-built sales tax. The reasons for this are explored further below.

Recently however, there has been growing global interest in health-motivated food and drink taxes, such as “soft-drinks taxes”, “fat taxes” and “sugar taxes”. In particular, a number of countries have begun to experiment with various forms of “health taxes”. For example, in 2011 Finland introduced excise on sweets, ice cream and soft drinks; Hungary introduced a public health food tax aimed at foods and drinks that are judged to carry a proven health risk, and Denmark introduced the world’s first tax on saturated fat in certain foods (although this tax was abolished in 2013) (Jacobson & Brownell, 2000).

France followed in 2012 with a high-profile tax on sugar and non-sugar sweetened beverages; and Mexico in 2013 with taxes on junk foods (those high in saturated fat, sugar and salt) and sugary drinks (Jacobson & Brownell, 2000). In the US, Berkeley California introduced the nation’s first soda tax in 2015 (with a 75% majority of

2 [Quick fn on the difference between exemptions and zero-rating]

9

Doc 3 Page 62 of 76 Released

Berkeley voters) (Gargliardi, 2014). A similar measure in neighboring San Francisco received 54% of the vote, but fell short of the threshold required to pass.

Such taxes have also been proposed and debated in a number of other countries (including most Ireland, Italy and others), and have received endorsement from a number of intergovernmental organisations and think tanks. For example, the 2011 UN High-level Meeting on non-communicable diseases noted the role that food taxes and subsidies could play in health reform; while WHO’s Global NCD Action Plan (2013-2020) recommends the use of taxes and subsidies which may create incentive for behaviours associated with improved health and healthier food consumption.

As a result, health-motivated food and drink taxes are gaining considerable policy attention, and it is important to develop a well-considered position on these issues.

Box summarizing key features of global health taxes (bases, rates and rationales)

10

Doc 3 Page 63 of 76 Released

Conceptual Basis for Health Taxes

Taxation alters the prices that individuals face when making choices. In doing so, it alters or ‘distorts’ the comparisons we make between alternative decisions. Across the economy as a whole, this influences what is produced and consumed. As such, it is potentially a very powerful policy instrument. Used incorrectly however, this can cause major distortions in the allocation of resources.

New Zealand follows a broad-base low-rate (BBLR) approach to tax policy, which means that on the whole, we try to tax economic decisions as evenly as possible. This approach is favored because it is considered to minimize the distortions that taxation introduces when people choose between different goods and services. This is a key reason, for example, for why we have a flat rate of GST for nearly all goods and services.

Our commitment to the BBLR approach doesn’t mean that everything has to be taxed this way, but it does mean that the case for exceptions needs to be very strong. In other words there needs to be a strong rationale for intervention. This section develops a framework for assessing the rationale for health taxes.

Allocative Efficiency in Economics

A central insight from economics is that, under certain conditions , free markets (i.e. the free interaction of buyers and sellers) results in an efficient allocation of resources. Loosely stated, if:

• markets are competitive (i.e. there are many competing sellers); • individuals know what they want and are well informed about their possible choices; and • there are no market failures ;

… then markets are said to be allocatively efficient . That is, only those goods are produced that are most valued, and they are allocated to those that value them the most. This is an important insight, and provides much of the basis for our modern faith in the free market mechanism. As evident from the way it is stated however, it relies on a number of important conditions.

11

Doc 3 Page 64 of 76 Released

Possible Market Failures

Firstly, the efficiency of markets relies on the absence of market failures. As the name suggests, market failures prevent market processes from optimizing the flow of resources. Although there are several potential sources of market failure, the most relevant one from the point of view of health taxes is externalities.

Market transactions are only efficient when all the costs and benefits that arise from the transaction are borne by the buyer and seller. These costs and benefits are then said to be internalized . That is, buyers and sellers fully account for the effects of the transaction.

Externalities arise when some of the costs or benefits arising from the transaction are borne by participants outside (i.e. external to) the transaction. As these participants do not have a say in the transaction, the market fails to take some peoples’ values into account when allocating resources. Examples include economic decisions that cause pollution or congestion.

In the case of food and drink consumption, it would seem that most of the costs and benefits from consumption are borne by the consumer. Specifically, consumers bear the retail cost of the purchase decision (which should fully compensate suppliers for all production costs), and the health costs (or benefits) of consumption. Offsetting these costs however, consumers also experience the benefits of consumption – that is, the satisfaction that arises from consuming products of their choice.

In these terms it would appear that the costs and benefits of food and drink consumption are fully internalized, and so we should expect the market mechanism to work well. That is, it should deliver outcomes that people want. In this setting, people may well choose to consume unhealthy foods in relatively large quantities. However, this would be the result of conscious decision-making made by well- informed informed consumers who weigh-up all the costs and benefits of consumption. Essentially, in this world consumers would prefer to trade-off increased health risks for the satisfaction of other wants.

However, externalities can arise in economic decisions that have health impacts because of the provision of free (or publicly subsidized) health care. Specifically, the government provision of health care means that some of the costs from poor health are shared across society rather than being borne directly by the consumer. This creates an externality as some of the costs of food and drink consumption are being borne by society as a whole, rather than by the individual that makes consumption decisions.

12

Doc 3 Page 65 of 76 Released

Information Failures

While the above health effects are worrying, such information is not relatively common public knowledge. The reasonable consumer is unlikely to fully appreciate the links between consumption of these foods and drinks and the relative consequences. The consumer therefore is likely to make decisions based on imperfect information. In markets saturated with persuasive ad campaigns for these food and drinks, consumer decisions are even more skewed.

Behavioral Biases

Addiction biases

Fast food, fizzy drinks and foods high in sugar and fat, are known to have an addictive quality. When eating something containing sugar the brain releases a large amount dopamine in an area of the brain called the Nucleus Accumbens which neutralises damaging effects but on the next large consumptions of sugar, the dopamine is weakened as there are fewer dopamine receptors left (Lustig, Schmidt, & Brindis, 2013). Sugar and other junk foods due to their massive effects to the reward centres of the brain have similar effects to that of cocaine or nicotine, dominating the brains chemistry to make people crave and be addicted to these foods (Lustig, Schmidt, & Brindis, 2013). Such effects would result in an inelastic demand for these products. The addictive nature of these products may impose a regression effect on tax. This would be due to lower income earners having an increases in comparison to higher income earners.

Time Inconsistent Preferences

Decisions by consumers are influenced by time inconsistent preferences where there is short term satisfaction but resultant long term detriment. This is especially seen in children adolescents, who have been found to place higher value on short term satisfaction without full/or negligent regard for future consequences. This is especially the concerning in terms of food and drink that can have drastic long term health effects if consumed heavily.

13

Doc 3 Page 66 of 76 Released

Rationales for Health Taxes

There is an alarming rise in obesity and other lifestyle diseases, correlated to the unhealthy consumption of food and drink heavy in sugar and fat. This has been the centre of global contention, perpetuating countries to introduce “fat taxes” on the basis of health concerns, on the consumption of sugar and fat.

The case for the intervention pigovian taxes is usually based on the market failure of consumers being unable to make healthy choices. This would be enforced with the following rationales

• Reduce Health effects due to Consumption • Reduce Negative externalities to society through consumption • Raise Revenue • Increase Productivity of Workforce [with resultant economic gain] • Reduce Inequality • Promote Healthy living and Healthy New Zealand Image

1. Reduce Health effects of consumption

Imposing “fat taxes”, may be proactive step to reduce the consumption of foods high in fat, sugar and other harmful substances. The reduced consumption would help to stifle consequent negative health effects from overconsumption, such as; obesity, diabetes, hypertension, hepatitis and other health disorders that are on the rise.

There are differing views if this policy outcome would be achieved. Opposing research has found that there is differing elasticity’s to different consumers. A rise in price of sugary/fatty drinks or food would motivate a reduction in consumption from moderate consumers (with elastic demands) of such products but have little effect on heavy consumers of such products

2. Reduce Public Health expenditure of consumption

Raised taxes on food and drinks may help to reduce lifestyle epidemics like obesity and diabetes. This would lead to decreased costs to the public health system as decreased health issues would result in decreased expenditure on consumption related health issues.

3. Raise Revenue

Raising taxes of health taxes on would provide relatively efficient tax revenue. As similar to excise on tobacco and alcohol, sugar and fat have a reasonably inelastic demand. This would provide an efficient revenue base for collecting tax.

14

Doc 3 Page 67 of 76 Released

4. Increase Productivity of Workforce

Introduction of taxes deters buyers from unhealthy foods; therefore people are healthier; due to reduced consumption of such foods and spend less time on sick leave or on doctor’s fees. As people are healthier, they are able to work to their full potential and do work more efficiently.

5. Reduce Inequality

Reduction in health issues may lead to higher gains. Lower socio-economic groups are likely to have greater elasticity to a given change in price. The reduced consumption of these foods and drinks may lead to decreased health fatigues like diabetes, rheumatic fever, cardiovascular diseases, etc. that are widespread in these groups. Also if there are increases health benefits in these groups, work productivity may increases leading to wider economic gain in lower socio-economic groups. Maori and Pasifika are noted to have the most to gain from this policy. Lifestyle disorders like diabetes and rheumatic fever are rising in these groups, and a reduced consumption of these unhealthy foods may help to deter such harmful health consequences.

15

Doc 3 Page 68 of 76 Released

Evidence Base for Health Taxes

Evidence based policies has risen to preference overtime. These are policies that have been scrupulously calculated through the use of trials and data to determine the most probable outcome(s). The research is supported through analysis of statistical surveys of people’s preferences or probability of certain outcomes. The use of such matters helps to give a more realistic insight into the outcomes that would be achieved.

In consideration of the evidence base, the main points explored were based on; Consumer Responses to Health Taxes and Health Outcomes to a Health Tax.

• Consumer Response to a Health Tax

Consumer Response here has mainly been reviewed through the use of the price elasticity of demand of consumers to Health tax. Price Elasticity of Demand measures the responsiveness of a consumers demand for a good or service, for a given change in price.

• Health Outcomes from a Health Tax

Health outcomes have been reviewed through the literature from the relationship of a given consumer response’s impact in the change in a person’s health. Many studies have been based on the relative reduced consumption of certain foods impact on the reduction of conditions like obesity, cancer and cardiovascular diseases.

16

Doc 3 Page 69 of 76 Released

Saturated Fat and Junk Food

Many studies have evaluated the elasticity of the imposition of a health tax in concern of fat. Price elasticity’s are greatly varied due to the numerous types of food which contain fat and resultant differing elasticity’s.

Nnoaham et al, surveyed the impact of a tax on major sources of saturated fat and unhealth foods. The study analysed four different scenarios; taxation of sources of saturated fat, taxation of ‘unhealthy foods’, a combination of an unhealthy food tax and 17.5% fruits and vegetable subisidy and another combination of a 64% subsidy on fruits. The four scenarios were modelled on the impact to cardiovascular diseases and cancer.The study worryingly holds that, while the imposition of saturated fats tax may reduce consumption it is unlikely to reduce cardiovascular diseases and cancer mortality rates and may even increase likelihoods.

Also the taxing ‘unhealthy foods’, were found to increase rates of cardiovascular diseases and cancer. The combinations of unhealthy food taxes and fruit and vegetables subsidies were found to be more effective in reducing the concerned diseases (Nnoaham, Sacks, Rayner, Mytton, & Gray, 2009). However the percentage tax needed to be imposed and subsisdiy raised to achieve results would be economically regressive and have very little positive change on lower income groups, where the need is more prominent (OECD, Obesity Update , 2012).

Food high in fat is usually assumed to be more elastic, as it may be cheaper. This assumption does not always hold. An example is low fat ice creams, which may be considered by consumers to be worth more, (due to being healthier) and are willing to pay more for the health benefits. Manufacturers may find it expensive to produce low fat ice cream at the same taste quality and upon imposition of a tax, shift the tax burden onto consumers. This would then shift consumers to regular ice creams and cause an increase in fat and sugar consumption; rising levels of obesity (Clark & Dittrich, 2010)

Taxation to fat and unhealthy foods have varying elasticity’s and reverse effects in most major studies. Fat taxes therefore are unlikely to achieve any positive health outcomes and rather may cause negative effects.

17

Doc 3 Page 70 of 76 Released

Sugar/Sugar Sweetened Beverages

The Price elasticity of a tax on sugar sweetened beverages is differing and at wide ranges in many studies but Andreyeva et al, holds it at -0.8 and -1.0. This denotes a relatively elastic demand for goods. The disparity in the literature is likely due to the numerous biases that need to be accounted for when considering the elasticity of a good.

Briggs et al, finds a 20% tax on sugar-sweetened beverage tax would greatly help to decrease obesity levels, especially among young people. The study holds that a 20% goods and services tax on sugar sweetened drinks will reduce consumption of concentrated and non-concentrated sugar sweetened beverages. This leads to an increase in substitutes to such drinks like tea and coffee, milk and fruit juice. These alternatives help to achieve positive health outcomes like reduced obesity rates. And other lifestyle related diseases. Also an estimated 18000 people would have reduced risks of obesity (in the United Kingdom). This shows a very positive health impact from the imposition of health taxes. The study however may not fully explore the effect of substitutes and finds no greater effects on lower income groups

Differing studies however, note the weak information on tax elasticity in concern of soda taxes and the substitution patterns between soft drinks and other beverages (Fletcher, Frisvold, & Tefft, 2010). This creates an alarming concern about the unintended consequences that may occur and therefore neutralize the effectiveness of a tax

Lusk and Schroeter, find taxes on soda to be unlikely to increase consumer welfare. Another study (Smith, Lin, & Lee, 2010) note that taxes on sugar sweetened beverages do decrease consumption, but such outcomes are not effective at 1 - 2% as imposed in other countries like Denmark and Hungary, and rather at 18% and above. The study’s insights into substitution patterns find individuals to switch from soft drinks to whole milk and fruit juices. This makes no change in the caloric intake [therefore no weight changes] into the body as the greater consumption of milk has a similar magnitude of the effects. This is also held to make little change in obesity in children and adolescents.

In shift to fruit drinks, while nutrient levels may be increased, the amount of sugar in these drinks are equal or even greater to soft drinks and aims to curb obesity or other lifestyle-related diseases would be ineffective or more damaging (Fletcher, Frisvold, & Tefft, 2010).

There is disparity in the evidence base on health taxes. Consumer response is difficult to measure as price elasticity has several biases; differing age, gender, income level, and effect of substitution patterns and the differing values people put on food per content of fat, sugar, which skew results.

18

Doc 3 Page 71 of 76 Released

Analysis of Evidence Base

Generally to achieve conjoint consumer responses and health outcomes a high percentage of tax (at least at 20%) must be imposed to have the relevant health outcomes achieved. Because substitution patterns are not fully understood here, there is cause for weariness of the expected results.

Taxes on soft drinks may deter consumers from drinking well known brands but supermarket brands that charge $0.89 for a 1.25L bottle of soft drinks are hardly going to be out of the relative price range at a 20% tax on these goods. These cheaper alternatives have higher sugar contents and an increase in consumption of these goods would lead to increased obesity and other lifestyle related diseases rates.

A imposed at 20% would also be highly regressive; with the tax incidence falling harder on lower income groups. An OECD report on ‘Fat Taxes’ found that a fat tax would need to be well designed, covering all possible bases and substitutes, to be effective (OECD, Obesity Update, 2012). The benefits would fall disproportionally, as many of the conceptual arguments have put forward, that lower income groups the most to gain from such taxes but the substitution and consumer preference patterns are difficult to gauge and it is most likely to have a greater negative externality imposed on such groups

19

Doc 3 Page 72 of 76 Released

This section is still in progress and will be further developed after consultation with Tax experts…

Tax Policy Design Considerations

A tax is achieved through a complex methodology of considerations to its implementation, collection and administration. As you are imposing increased costs to people, is important that the tax is upheld to the theoretical canons of taxation.

There are certain considerations that need to be made, design wise in the case for consumption related –‘Health Taxes’. Some of these are: • Integrity Of Tax • Boundary Issues • Substitution and Gaming • Exemptions on GST • Difference between proportionate tax and unit tax

 Integrity of a ‘Health Tax’

 Boundary Issues Denmark example

 Substitution and Gaming

 Exemptions on GST

 Differences between proportionate tax and unit tax

To be further developed after consultation with Tax team.

20

Doc 3 Page 73 of 76 Released

Summary of Findings

A tax on unhealthy food and drink is something that is very topical at the moment and increasing efforts globally combined with domestic efforts by lobby groups making it a very persuasive policy to implement.

In analysis of the conceptual basis, there are real rationales that exist. There are market failures that exist here ;

 Information Failures  Behavioral Biases

These are important factors which warrant government intervention as consumers cannot make optimal decisions.

On the evidence base, the literature is mixed and it is hard to infer a general direction. However common threads that exist are;

 There is a relatively elastic demand to the price of such foods and drinks.  An imposition of a tax on such food and drinks will have at least some resultant reduction.  The tax is likely to be economically regressive  The substitution patterns are not fully understood and there is a threat of substitution to unhealthier alternatives, resulting in worsened health outcomes.

Overall there are disparities in the literature of the consumer response to Health Taxes and the relative health outcomes achieved.

21

Doc 3 Page 74 of 76 Released

Conclusion

The rise in lifestyle diseases is alarming and there is a critical need for government’s strategy towards such a difficult issue. It is important that we understand the relevant outcomes and effects of such a problem to discover relevant solutions.

A ‘Health Tax’ or tax on unhealthy food and drink has been implemented in other countries and it would be interesting to see how these play out in these countries and relevant data and research that would be gained.

The role of tax as an instrument for health reform has been widely debated. Tax may perhaps be effective to attempt in reduce consumption but tax is a crude tool whereby you are effectively forcing people into making a decision. Also there is the issue of the poor targeting of tax, whereby a tax would impose costs on society as a whole, while the issue of obesity is limited to a portion of society. These foods and drink also do not have the same addictive nature or level of harm as tobacco.

Overall there is a great contention worldwide over health taxes and if considered need to be evaluated carefully. There is generally not enough of a clear direction in whether a tax would be an effective solution, especially in the substitution patterns. The lack of understanding of substitution is a critical issue as the substitution to cheaper unhealthier alternatives may result in worsened outcomes and ineffective policy. This reversed outcome is worrying and warrants further work into this area.

22

Doc 3 Page 75 of 76 Released

References Andreyeva, T., Long, M., & Brownell, K. (2010). 2010. American Economic Journal , 216-22.

Brownell, K. D., Farley, T., Willett, W. C., Popkin, B., Chaloupka, F. J., Thompson, J. W., & Ludwig, D. S. (2009). The Public Health and Econmic Benefits of Taxing Sugar- Sweetened Beverages. The New England Journal of Medicine , 1599-605.

Clark, J. S., & Dittrich, O. L. (2010). Alternative Fat Taxes to Control Obesity. International Atlantic Economic Society , 388-394.

Coalition, S. (2013). The history of tobacco control in New Zealand . Retrieved December 10, 2014, from The Smokefree Coalition - Te Ohu Auahi Kore: http://www.sfc.org.nz/infohistory.php

Denmark introduces world's first food fat tax . (2011, October 1). Retrieved December 8, 2014, from BBC: http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-europe-15137948

Eyles, H., Cliona, M. N., Nghiem, N., & Blakely, T. (2012). Food Pricing Strategues, Population Diets and Non Communicable Disease: A systematic review of simulation studies. PLOS| Medicine .

Fastenburg, D. (2010, September 21). Not-So-Sweet Tooth: Finland to Tax Chocolate . Retrieved December 8, 2014, from Time Inc: http://newsfeed.time.com/2010/09/21/not-so-sweet-tooth-finland-to-tax-chocolate/

Fletcher, J. M., Frisvold, D. E., & Tefft, N. (2010). The effects of soft drink taxes on child and adolsecent consumption and wieght outcomes. Journal of Public Economics , 967- 974.

Fletcher, J. M., Frisvold, D. E., & Tefft, N. (2014). Non-Linear Effects of Soda Taxes on Consumption and Weight Outcomes. Health Economics .

Gargliardi, N. (2014, May 11). Approval Of Soda Tax In Berkeley Is Scary Precedent For Food Industry . Retrieved from FORBES: http://www.forbes.com/sites/nancygagliardi/2014/11/05/berkeley-makes-history-on- the-soda-tax/

Health, & Commitee. (2013). Inquiry into improving child health outcomes and preventing child abuse, with a focus on preconception until three years of age. Wellington: House of Representatives.

Jacobson, M. F., & Brownell, K. D. (2000). Small Taxes on Soft Drinks and Snack Foods to Promote Health. American Journal of Public Health , 854-857.

Lal, A., Moodie, M., Ashton, T., Siahpush, M., & Swinburn, B. (2012). Health care and lost productivity costs of overweight and obesity in New Zealand. Austrailian and New Zealand Journal of Public Health, 36 (6), 550-56.

Lusk, J., & Schroeter, C. (2012). When do Fat Taxes increase Consumer Welfare. Health Economics , 1367-1374.

23

Doc 3 Page 76 of 76 Released

Lustig, R. H., Schmidt, L. A., & Brindis, C. D. (2013). Public Health; The toxic truth about sugar. Nature, 482 (7383), 27-29.

Marlow, M., & Abdukadirov, S. (2012). Can Behaviourial Economics Combat Obesity? Health & Medicine .

Nnoaham, K. E., Sacks, G., Rayner, M., Mytton, O., & Gray, A. (2009). Modelling income group differences in the health and economic impacts of trageted food taxes and subsidies. International Journal of Epidemology , 1324-1333.

O'Dea, D., Gorton, D., & Ni Mhurchu, C. (2009). Thin Subsidies and Fat Taxes, Economic Instruments for addressing Food Inadequacy and Nutrition Issues. NZ Association of Economists. Wellington.

OECD. (2012). Obesity Update .

OECD. (2014). Consumption Tax Trends.

OECD. (2014). Obesity and the Economics of Prevention: Fit not Fat - France Key Facts. OECD.

OECD. (2014). Obesity Update.

Powell, M. L., Chriqui, J. F., Khan, W. R., & Chaloupka, J. F. (2013). Assessing the potential effectiveness of food and beverage taxes and subsidies for improving public health: a systematic review of prices, demand and body weight outcomes. Obesity Reviewa , 110-128.

Sharma, A., Hauck, K., Hollingsworth, B., & Siciliani, L. (2014). The Effects of Taxing Sugar- Sweetend Beverages Across Different Income Groups. Health Economics , 1159- 1184.

Smith, T., Lin, B.-H., & Lee, J. Y. (2010). The effects of a sugar-sweetened beverage tax: Consumption, calorie intake, obesity, and tax burden by income. Agricultural and Applied Economic Association.

Tiffin, R., & Arnoult, M. (2009). The Public Health Impacts of a Fat Tax.

24