Currents Within Thevalue Controversy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Currents Within Thevalue Controversy chapter 5 Currents within the Value Controversy This chapter provides an overview and critical assessment of the controversy among Marxist and neo-Marxist theorists concerning the content, probity and implications of Marx’s theory of value beyond its ‘first phase’, as reviewed in the last chapter. As with many other controversies that developed following the revival of Marxism in the 1960s and 1970s, the ‘second-phase’ of the value controversy has testified to the willingness of Marxist intellectuals to entertain a variety of interpretations of Marx’s theoretical legacy and to part company with him on issues of the utmost importance. Unfortunately it has also testified to their ability to debate such issues in a fashion that renders them relatively inaccessible to the non-specialist. In consideration of this problem, I shall try to ‘interpret’ Marx’s value theory and the ongoing debates surrounding it in such a way as to highlight what I take to be the key postulates of the capitalist law of labour value. This will, I hope, contribute not only to a better understanding of some of the contested issues, but also to a clarification of what is at stake in this controversy, something which is too rarely discussed by its participants. The principal idea developed here as well as in the next chapter is that Marx’s theory of value constitutes the unity of a qualitative treatment of the value-form (exchange-value/money-price) and a quantitative concern with the ‘substance of value’. Its conceptual nexus is considered to be ‘abstract labour’ – a category that bridges the divide between value’s ‘particular’ and ‘universal’ aspects. Key to this interpretation is an extension of the ontological reversals described by Marx in his discussion of the value-form to include the relation between abstract labour, understood as a real social structure, and commod- ities, as sensuously concrete particulars. Such a conceptualisation furnishes a much-needed ontological and methodological basis for sustaining the key pos- tulates of what I call the ‘fundamentalist’ approach to Marxian value theory as against a ‘neo-orthodox’ approach that strips Marx’s value theory of much of its ‘operational’ significance. These fundamentalist postulates, I argue, pertain to the laws of motion of the capitalist economy as a whole, and it is there- fore a mistake for those who defend them to pursue a theoretical agenda that tilts Marx’s value theory in the direction of accounting for ‘relative equilibrium prices’, a project having little to do with disclosing the historical-structural lim- its of capitalism. © koninklijke brill nv, leiden, 2019 | doi:10.1163/9789004312203_006 98 chapter 5 1 The Second Phase of the Value Controversy The origins of the second phase of controversy surrounding Marx’s theory of value, a phase now a half-century old, is easily specified. First, by the 1960s, the critique of neoclassical economic theory undertaken by the Cambridge School of Piero Sraffa, Joan Robinson, Nicholas Kaldor et al. had constituted itself as a major ‘neo-Ricardian’ challenge to some central tenets of marginalism and was doing much to encourage the rehabilitation of some characteristic con- cerns of classical and Marxian political economy: in particular, the problem of the source, measurement and distribution of an economic surplus. Second, the renewed interest in Marx’s thought resulting from the New Left/student radicalisation of the 1960s focused increasingly upon Marx’s ‘economics’ as the world capitalist economy experienced worsening dislocation and malaise after 1970 (the collapse of the Bretton Woods monetary agreement, falling rates of profit in several of the advanced capitalist countries, and the worldwide reces- sion of 1974–75). Third, interest in Marx’s theory of capitalist crisis was spurred during the 1970s by the apparent exhaustion of Keynesian macro-economic policy, which had manifestly failed to anticipate the specific features of the emerging economic crisis of Western capitalism as popularly encapsulated in the notion of ‘stagflation’. These economic, political and intellectual developments provide the socio- historical backdrop to our discussion. By way of introduction to the latter’s principal themes, a brief characterisation of each of its main ‘camps’ or ‘cur- rents’ will help to further specify the context and significance of this second major phase of debate surrounding Marx’s theory of value. 1.1 Neo-Ricardianism and the Ricardian-Marxist Orthodoxy The neo-Ricardianism that initially came to the fore in the 1970s encompasses both a ‘left wing’ that considers itself Marxist in some circumscribed sense and a right wing that has been primarily concerned with what Latouche aptly called the ‘reswitching of dominant ideologies’ within the economics profes- sion.1 Our concern here is strictly with ‘left neo-Ricardianism’, that is, with the varied attempts of Marxist or neo-Marxist economists to either reconcile Piero Sraffa’s critique of neoclassicism with Marxian political economy or to substan- tially revise the latter in light of the former. 1 Latouche 1976. By the twenty-first century, this more conservative wing of neo-Ricardianism had substantially merged with post-Keynesian and ‘institutionalist’ schools of thought on the boundaries of ‘mainstream’ and ‘heterodox’ economics..
Recommended publications
  • Value's Law, Value's Metric
    Values Law Values Metric by P Co ckshott A Cottrell Research Rep ort RR Novemb er Values Law Values Metric W Paul Co ckshott and Allin F Cottrell septemb er Abstract It is argued that the metric space of exchanging commo dities is noneuclidean and characteristic of a system governed by a conservation law The p ossible can didates for what is conserved in commo dity exchange are reviewed with reference to inverted inputoutput matrices of the British economy Strong evidence is pre sented that the conserved substance is lab our The arguments of Mirowski and others regarding the appropriateness of such physicalist arguments are discussed What is meant by the law of value The phrase law of value is little used by Marx but p opular among his followers It has no precise denition of the typ e that one would exp ect for a scientic law Laws such as Ho okes law or Boyles law have a concise denition that any chemist or physicist could rep eat but it is doubtful if anywhere in the Marxist literature there exists a comparable denition of the law of value On the basis of what Ricardo and Marx wrote on the theory we would advance the following as a reasonable denition The law of value states that value understood as the labour time social ly necessary to produce a commodity is conserved in the exchange of commodities The advantages of this denition are that it is cast in the normal form of a sci entic law it is empirically testable it has a precise meaning and it emphasizes the fundamental Marxian prop osition that value cannot arise in circulation
    [Show full text]
  • Advertising and the Creation of Exchange Value
    University of Massachusetts Amherst ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst Doctoral Dissertations Dissertations and Theses Summer November 2014 Advertising and the Creation of Exchange Value Zoe Sherman University of Massachusetts Amherst Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umass.edu/dissertations_2 Part of the Economic History Commons, Political Economy Commons, and the Public Relations and Advertising Commons Recommended Citation Sherman, Zoe, "Advertising and the Creation of Exchange Value" (2014). Doctoral Dissertations. 205. https://doi.org/10.7275/5625701.0 https://scholarworks.umass.edu/dissertations_2/205 This Open Access Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by the Dissertations and Theses at ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. It has been accepted for inclusion in Doctoral Dissertations by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ADVERTISING AND THE CREATION OF EXCHANGE VALUE A Dissertation Presented by ZOE SHERMAN Submitted to the Graduate School of the University of Massachusetts Amherst in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY September 2014 Economics © Copyright by Zoe Sherman 2014 All Rights Reserved ADVERTISING AND THE CREATION OF EXCHANGE VALUE A Dissertation Presented by ZOE SHERMAN Approved as to style and content by: ______________________________________ Gerald Friedman, Chair ______________________________________ Michael Ash, Member ______________________________________ Judith Smith, Member ___________________________________ Michael Ash, Department Chair Economics DEDICATION Dedicated to the memory of Stephen Resnick. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I have had many strokes of good fortune in my life, not least the intellectual and emotional support I have enjoyed throughout my graduate studies. Stephen Resnick, Gerald Friedman, Michael Ash, and Judith Smith were the midwives of this work.
    [Show full text]
  • The Emergence of the Law of Value in a Dynamic Simple Commodity Economy
    Review of Political Economy, Volume 20, Number 3, 367–391, July 2008 The Emergence of the Law of Value in a Dynamic Simple Commodity Economy IAN WRIGHT Faculty of Social Sciences, The Open University, Milton Keynes, UK ABSTRACT A dynamic computational model of a simple commodity economy is examined and a theory of the relationship between commodity values, market prices and the efficient division of social labour is developed. The main conclusions are: (i) the labour value of a commodity is an attractor for its market price; (ii) market prices are error signals that function to allocate the available social labour between sectors of production; and (iii) the tendency of prices to approach labour values is the monetary expression of the tendency of a simple commodity economy to allocate social labour efficiently. The model demonstrates that, in the special case of simple commodity production, Marx’s law of value can naturally emerge from multiple local exchanges and operate ‘behind the backs’ of actors solely via money flows that place budget constraints on their local evaluations of commodity prices, which are otherwise subjective and unconstrained. 1. Introduction Marx, following Ricardo, held a labour theory of the economic value of reprodu- cible commodities. The value of a commodity is determined by the prevailing technical conditions of production and measured by the socially necessary labour-time required to produce it (Marx, 1867). The value of a commodity is to be distinguished from its price, which is the amount of money it fetches in the market. According to Marx, although individual economic actors may differ in their subjective evaluations of the worth or ‘value’ of commodities, market prices are nevertheless determined by labour values due to the operation of the ‘law of value’, an objective economic law that emerges as an unintended consequence of local and distributed market exchanges.
    [Show full text]
  • Makoto Itoh P
    On the Value and Exchange-Value of Money Referring to the Definition of Value of Money in the 'New Interpretation' Makoto Itoh Professor, Kokugakuin University, Tokyo 1 1 The Significance of Value of Money in the 'New Interpretation' A 'new interpretation' on the transformation problem concerning Marx's theory of transforming values into prices of production was presented by D.K.Foley(1982, 1986) and G.Duménile(1983) among others and became influential among a certain number of contemporary Marxian political economists. The 'new interpretation' is based on a particular definition of value of money as the monetary expression of labor time. More concretely, the value of money is conceived as 'the ratio of the net domestic product at current prices to the living productive labor expended in an economy over a period of time' (Foley, 2000,p.21), and thus it represents the average amount of expended labor time obtainable by a unit of money, say a dollar. For example, in the USA in the early 1980s, the aggregate national value added was about $3 trillion, while about 100 million of employed workers expended 200,000 million hours (each 2,000 hours) a year. Therefore, 1 hour of labor contributed $15 of value added, and the value of a dollar was 1/15 hour (4 minutes) of social labor (Foley, 1986, p.14-15). This notion of value of money is different from Marx's notion of value of money commodity as embodied labor time in a unit of money commodity. It is, however, conceived as a useful notion in solving the traditional treatment of the transformation problem.
    [Show full text]
  • Exchange-Value and the Concealment of Theft and Violence
    Continental Thought & Theory CT&T A journal of intellectual freedom Volume 1 | Issue 2: Debt and Value 269-291 | ISSN: 2463-333X Exchange-Value and the Concealment of Theft and Violence Jeta Mulaj Abstract: Exploring the phantom-like objectivity of exchange-value, this paper seeks to analyze the ways in which capitalist exchange relations conceal theft, violence, and exploitation. This paper begins with a critical analysis of Marx’s account of the phantom-like objectivity of exchange-value. Then, the paper elucidates the exchange between the worker and capital as an exchange of non-equivalents, while exploring the ways in which exchange-relations and the wage system conceal unpaid labour inside and outside the working day. Finally, drawing on the work of Silvia Federici and Massimo De Angelis, I argue that exchange-value and the wage system conceal violence and exploitation on at least three levels: unpaid surplus-labour, unpaid reproductive labour, and the permanence of primitive accumulation. Keywords: Exchange-value, primitive accumulation, surplus-value, Marx, Silvia Federici http://ctt.canterbury.ac.nz CONTINENTAL THOUGHT & THEORY: A JOURNAL OF INTELLECTUAL FREEDOM Volume 1, Issue 2: Debt and Value Karl Marx’s Capital is filled with ghosts, phantoms, monsters, “peculiar natures,” and hauntings. From the first chapter of Capital Volume I Marx expresses his concern with the peculiarity of the commodity. This peculiarity deepens and becomes more troubling as the relations between use-value and exchange- value, social relations of production, primitive accumulation, and wage-labor are exposed. At the center of all these relations stands exchange-value. Unlike use- value, which includes the sensuous and material characteristics of the object, exchange-value is not a thing that belongs to the object.
    [Show full text]
  • Keywords—Marxism 101 Session 1 Bourgeoisie
    Keywords—Marxism 101 Session 1 Bourgeoisie: the class of modern capitalists, owners of the means of social production and employers of wage labour. Capital: an asset (including money) owned by an individual as wealth used to realize a fnancial proft, and to create additional wealth. Capital exists within the process of economic exchange and grows out of the process of circulation. Capital is the basis of the economic system of capitalism. Capitalism: a mode of production in which capital in its various forms is the principal means of production. Capital can take the form of money or credit for the purchase of labour power and materials of production; of physical machinery; or of stocks of fnished goods or work in progress. Whatever the form, it is the private ownership of capital in the hands of the class of capitalists to the exclusion of the mass of the population. Class: social stratifcation defned by a person's relationship to the means of production. https://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/b/bf/Pyramid_of_Capitalist_System.png Class struggle: an antagonism that exists within a society, catalyzed by competing socioeconomic interests and central to revolutionary change. Communism: 1) a political movement of the working class in capitalist society, committed to the abolition of capitalism 2) a form of society which the working class, through its struggle, would bring into existence through abolition of classes and of the capitalist division of labor. Dictatorship of the Proletariat: the idea that the proletariat (the working class) has control over political power in the process of changing the ownership of the means of production from private to collective ownership as part of a socialist transition to communism.
    [Show full text]
  • Abstract Labor: Substance Or Form
    ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM? A CRITIQUE OF THE VALUE-FORM INTERPRETATION OF MARX’S THEORY by Fred Moseley Universidad Autonoma Metropolitana (Mexico City) Mount Holyoke College (Massachusetts) May 1997 Our analysis has shown that the form of value, that is the expression of the value of a commodity, arises from the nature of commodity value, as opposed to value and its magnitude arising from their mode of expression as exchange-value. Marx (C. I. 152) It is not money that renders commodities commensurable. Quite the contrary. Because all commodities, as values, are objective human labor and therefore themselves commensurable, their values can be communally measured in one and the same commodity. Mon ey is the necessary form of appearance of the measure of value immanent in commodities - labor-time. Marx (C.I. 188) ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM? A CRITIQUE OF THE VALUE-FORM INTERPRETATION OF MARX’S THEORY In the Introduction to our first book, I wrote: All the authors agree that Marx attempted in Section 1 of Chapter 1 of Capital to derive abstract labor as the "substance of value," which exists prior to exchange - although it is not observable - and which determines the exchange values of com modities. But there is significant disagreement over the validity file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/mhcuserxp/Desktop/VALUEFRM.htm (1 of 15)10/15/2005 2:29:42 PM ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM and necessity of Marx’s derivation. Indeed this disagreement is probably the most significant one amount the authors. This controversy has a long history beginning with Boehm-Bawerk.
    [Show full text]
  • A Defence of Co-Constitutive Value-Form Theory
    chapter 15 Avoiding Bad Abstractions: A Defence of Co-constitutive Value-Form Theory We see then that commodities are in love with money, but that ‘the course of true love never did run smooth’.1 ∵ Marxian value theory is a value-form theory. Since it was by asserting this that I came to be invited to participate in the present symposium, I will begin here.2 Speaking in a general way, one could say that value-form theory encompasses any theory of the value form, where the value form is the expression of value, namely, exchange value. That Marx is a value-form theorist in this general sense is apparent from any number of facts, the most striking is that he devotes Sec- tion Three of the first chapter of Capital to ‘The Value-Form, or Exchange-Value’. Marx discusses two theorists of the value form in this general sense, Aristotle and Samuel Bailey. Marx identifies Aristotle as ‘the great investigator who was the first to analyse the value-form, like so many other forms of thought, society and nature’.3 Aristotle recognised (1) that it takes the equating of two commod- ities to express value, though he did not notice the necessarily polar nature of the expression of value nor, consequently, did he analyse the peculiarities of either the relative or equivalent value forms; (2) ‘that the money-form of the commodity is only the further developed figure [die weiter entwickelte Gestalt] of the simple form of value’;4 (3) that the equalities expressed in the form of 1 Marx 1976a, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Marx's Theory of Value and Money
    MARX’S THEORY OF VALUE AND MONEY: A CRITIQUE OF REUTEN’S ‘VALUE-FORM’ INTERPRETATION OF PART 1 OF VOLUME 1 OF CAPITAL by Fred Moseley [email protected] How then is the magnitude of value to be measured? By means of the ‘value-forming substance’, the labour, contained in the article. The quantity is measured by its duration, and the labour-time itself is measured on the particular scale of hours, days, etc. (C.I. 129). Socially necessary labour-time is the labour-time required to produce any use-value under the conditions of production normal for a given society and with the average degree of skill and intensity of labour prevalent in that society. (C.I. 129) A given quantity of any commodity contains a definite quantity of human labour. Therefore the form of value must not only express value in general, but also quantitatively determined value; i.e. the magnitude of value… The equation 20 yards of linen = 1 coat, or 20 years of linen are worth 1 coat, presupposes the presence in 1 coat of exactly as much of the substance of value as there is in 20 yards of linen, implies therefore that the quantities in which the two commodities are present have cost the same amount of labour or the same quantity of labour-time. (C.I. 144) It is not money that renders commodities commensurable. Quite the contrary. Because all commodities, as values, are objectified human labour and therefore themselves commensurable, their values can be communally measured in one and the same commodity.
    [Show full text]
  • Futures of the Lumpenproletariat
    Lumpen: Vagrancies of a Concept from Marx to Fanon (and on) by Bennett Dempsey Carpenter Program in Literature Duke University Date:_______________________ Approved: ___________________________ Roberto Dainotto, Supervisor ___________________________ Wahneema Lubiano ___________________________ Anne Garréta ___________________________ Nancy Armstrong Dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate Program in Literature in the Graduate School of Duke University 2019 i v ABSTRACT Lumpen: Vagrancies of a Concept from Marx to Fanon (and on) by Bennett Dempsey Carpenter Graduate Program in Literature Duke University Date:_______________________ Approved: ___________________________ Roberto Dainotto, Supervisor ___________________________ Wahneema Lubiano ___________________________ Anne Garréta ___________________________ Nancy Armstrong An abstract of a thesis/dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate Program in Literature in the Graduate School of Duke University 2019 Copyright by Bennett Dempsey Carpenter 2019 Abstract This dissertation, Lumpen: Vagrancies of a Concept from Marx to Fanon (and on), tracks the concept of the lumpenproletariat from its coinage by Karl Marx through its reworking by Franz Fanon, the Black Panthers and others in the context of the colonial liberation and Black Power movements, and onwards into contemporary debates about populism, identity, politics, and the end
    [Show full text]
  • Value-Form and the Mystery of Money
    Capital & Class 1 –20 Value-form and the © The Author(s) 2019 Article reuse guidelines: mystery of money sagepub.com/journals-permissions https://doi.org/10.1177/0309816818817540DOI: 10.1177/0309816818817540 journals.sagepub.com/home/cnc Kiyoshi Nagatani Shinshu Daigaku, Japan Abstract Value-form is a theory Marx first developed in Capital vol.1 to solve the mystery of money. He seemed convinced that he had finally solved the mystery of money by reducing the money-form to the general value-form. However, his explanation of the transition from the latter to the former with the phrase ‘by social custom’ is not satisfactory. I consider that, as long as a logical derivation of the money- form from the general value-form is unsuccessful, the mystery of money is not yet completely solved. I attempt first to rehabilitate the simple value-form, comparing it with real value expression in price (money-form), emphasizing the distinction between the expression of value and the measure of value, and the asymmetry of the value-form. Thereby, I explain that Marx’s complicated exposition of the value- form stems from his postulate of the labor substance of value in the first chapter of Capital vol.1, which can be proved and developed later in the production process of capital. Rehabilitation of the value-form can expose a fundamental difference between the general value-form and the money-form, and provide a logical derivation of the money-form. To achieve this aim, it is necessary to reformulate the logical structure of the theory of commodity based on the concept ‘the world of commodities’, which comes to appear more frequently as Marx’s theory of value-form advances.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Marx's Explanation of Money's Functions: Overturning the Quantity
    1 Marx’s Explanation of Money’s Functions: Overturning the Quantity Theory Martha Campbell At the beginning of the Chapter on Money in the Grundrisse, Marx discusses the operation and effects of ‘modern credit institutions’, touching on several of the questions he will later consider in Capital, Vol. III. An argument he will later present in Capital, Vol. II is implicit in his rhetorical question: would ‘large scale modern industry’ be possible ‘without the concentration of credit …created’ by “our present banks’? Referring to the great variety of financial instruments generated by the credit system, he states that ‘the thousand forms of circulating paper…are as much the preconditions as the product of modern commerce and modern industry’.1 It is clear from this that Marx knows that capitalist money is not gold and, moreover, that capitalism could not have developed as it did without the credit system. The obvious question, then, is, if he knows it is unrealistic to assume that money is gold, why does he do this throughout Capital? There is the obvious ‘expositional’ advantage that gold money gives Marx a way of presenting money and value so that he can proceed to the concept of capital, which presupposes both; banking, by contrast, presupposes not only capital but the division into different kinds of capital.2 Another expositional convenience is that Marx uses gold money throughout Capital, Vol. I as the measure, or expression of value, in order to explain, for example, the origin of surplus value and the factors that influence its quantity. By treating gold 1 All quotations from Marx 1939: 122.
    [Show full text]