ABOUT STATIONARITY and REGULARITY in VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS 1. Introduction the Paper Investigates Extremality, Stationarity and R

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

ABOUT STATIONARITY and REGULARITY in VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS 1. Introduction the Paper Investigates Extremality, Stationarity and R 1 ABOUT STATIONARITY AND REGULARITY IN VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS 2 ALEXANDER Y. KRUGER To Boris Mordukhovich on his 60th birthday Abstract. Stationarity and regularity concepts for the three typical for variational analysis classes of objects { real-valued functions, collections of sets, and multifunctions { are investi- gated. An attempt is maid to present a classification scheme for such concepts and to show that properties introduced for objects from different classes can be treated in a similar way. Furthermore, in many cases the corresponding properties appear to be in a sense equivalent. The properties are defined in terms of certain constants which in the case of regularity proper- ties provide also some quantitative characterizations of these properties. The relations between different constants and properties are discussed. An important feature of the new variational techniques is that they can handle nonsmooth 3 functions, sets and multifunctions equally well Borwein and Zhu [8] 4 1. Introduction 5 The paper investigates extremality, stationarity and regularity properties of real-valued func- 6 tions, collections of sets, and multifunctions attempting at developing a unifying scheme for defining 7 and using such properties. 8 Under different names this type of properties have been explored for centuries. A classical 9 example of a stationarity condition is given by the Fermat theorem on local minima and max- 10 ima of differentiable functions. In a sense, any necessary optimality (extremality) conditions de- 11 fine/characterize certain stationarity (singularity/irregularity) properties. The separation theorem 12 also characterizes a kind of extremal (stationary) behavior of convex sets. 13 Surjectivity of a linear continuous mapping in the Banach open mapping theorem (and its 14 extension to nonlinear mappings known as Lyusternik-Graves theorem) is an example of a regularity 15 condition. Other examples are provided by numerous constraint qualifications and error bound 16 conditions in optimization problems, qualifying conditions in subdifferential calculus, etc. 17 Many more properties which can be interpreted as either stationarity or regularity have been 18 introduced (explicitly and in many cases implicitly) and investigated with the development of op- 19 timization theory and variational analysis. They are important for optimality conditions, stability 20 of solutions, and numerical methods. 21 There exist different settings of optimization and variational problems: in terms of single-valued 22 and multivalued mappings and in terms of collections of sets. It is not surprising that investigating 23 stationarity and especially regularity properties of these objects has attracted significant attention. 24 Real-valued functions and collections of sets were examined respectively in [18, 21, 27{30, 33] and 25 [3,5{7,14,21,26{32,34,39,41{43,48]. Multifunctions represent the most developed class of objects. 26 A number of useful regularity properties have been introduced and investigated - see [1, 2, 9, 12, 27 13,20{22,24,28{30,36{40,44{47] and the references therein - the most well recognized and widely 28 used being that of metric regularity. 29 In this paper, which continues [30{32], an attempt is maid to present a classification scheme for 30 such concepts and to show that, in accordance with the cited above words by Borwein and Zhu, 31 properties introduced for objects from different classes can be treated in a similar way. Further- 32 more, in many cases the corresponding properties appear to be equivalent. 2000 Mathematics Subject Classification. 90C46, 90C48, 49K27; Secondary: 58C, 58E30. Key words and phrases. subdifferential, normal cone, optimality, extremality, stationarity, regularity, multifunc- tion, slope, Asplund space. 1 2 ALEXANDER Y. KRUGER 33 First of all, stationarity and regularity properties are mutually inverse. For example, the equality 0 34 f (¯x) = 0 for a real-valued differentiable atx ¯ function f is a stationarity condition, while the 0 35 inequality f (¯x) 6= 0 can be considered as a regularity criterion. Thus, such properties always go 36 in pairs. Given one condition (stationarity or regularity), its negation automatically describes its 37 opposite counterpart. 38 It seems natural to distinguish between primal space properties and those defined in terms of dual 39 space elements. Metric conditions are primal space properties while their characterizations in terms 40 of normal cones or coderivatives are dual conditions. In some cases primal and dual conditions 41 are equivalent, and dual conditions provide complete characterizations of the corresponding primal 42 space properties. However, there are cases when equivalences do not hold, and one has necessary 43 or sufficient conditions. 44 Another natural way of classifying stationarity and regularity properties is to distinguish between 45 basic (\at a point") and more robust strict (\near a point") conditions. In the latter case one 46 can speak about approximate stationarity and uniform regularity. For instance, dual conditions 47 formulated in terms of usual Fr´echet derivatives or Fr´echet subdifferentials/normals belong to 48 the first group, while conditions in terms of strict derivatives or limiting subdifferentials/normals 49 belong to the second one. Metric regularity of multifunctions is a typical example of a primal space 50 uniform regularity property. 51 The properties can be defined in terms of certain constants which in the case of regularity prop- 52 erties provide also some quantitative characterizations of these properties. It will be demonstrated 53 in the subsequent sections that such constants are convenient when establishing interrelations 54 between the properties. 55 Obviously not all existing stationarity and regularity properties are discussed in the paper. 56 Only those typical properties have been chosen which better illustrate the classification scheme 57 described above. The content of this paper is not expected to surprise those working in the area of 58 variational analysis. However, the author believes that some relations presented in it can be useful 59 when dealing with specific problems. 60 The remaining three sections are devoted to our three main objects of interest: real-valued 61 functions, collections of sets, and multifunctions respectively. 62 In Section 2, we consider stationarity and regularity properties of real-valued functions. The 63 main feature of this class of objects compared to the two others is that, in the nondifferentiable 64 case, one can (and should) distinguish between properties of functions \from below" (from the point 65 of view of minimization) and \from above" (from the point of view of maximization). The terms 66 inf-stationarity and inf-regularity are used in the paper in the first instance, and sup-stationarity 67 and sup-regularity in the second one. The \combined" properties are considered as well. A number 68 of stationarity and regularity properties as well as constants characterizing them are introduced. 69 The relations between these constants are summarized in Theorem 2. It can be interesting to 70 note that while two different basic primal space constants are in use, the corresponding strict 71 constants coincide for lower semicontinuous functions on a complete metric space. If, additionally, 72 the space is Asplund, they coincide with the appropriate dual space strict constant. This result 73 (Theorem 2(ix)) improves [33, Theorem 4]. Special attention is given to the differential and convex 74 cases when most of the constants and properties coincide. 75 In Section 3, collections of sets are considered. The stationarity properties discussed here ex- 76 tend the concept of locally extremal collection introduced in [34] while the relation between the 77 corresponding primal and dual constants formulated in Theorem 4(vi) extends the extremal prin- 78 ciple [34, 41]. This result improves [30, Theorem 1]. The corresponding regularity properties are 79 discussed as well as their relations with other properties of this kind: metric inequality (local linear 80 regularity) [4, 19, 20, 43, 48] and Jameson's property (G) [5, 42]. 81 The last Section 4 is devoted to multifunctions with the main emphasis on their regularity 82 properties. The constants characterizing these properties are defined along the same lines. Metric 83 regularity is treated as an example of a uniform primal space regularity property corresponding to 84 similar properties of real-valued functions and collections of sets. The relations between different 85 constants, including the equality of primal and dual strict constants, are summarized in Theorem 6. 86 Finally, relations are established between the multifunctional regularity/stationarity constants and 87 the corresponding constants defined in the preceding sections for the other two main classes of 88 objects of the current research { real-valued functions and collections of sets. ABOUT STATIONARITY AND REGULARITY IN VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS 3 89 Mainly standard notations are used throughout the paper. Br(x) denotes a closed ball in a 90 metric space with centre at x and radius r. A closed unit ball in a normed space is denoted by 91 B. If Ω is a set then int Ω and bd Ω are respectively its interior and boundary. If not explicitly 92 specified otherwise, when considering product spaces we assume that they are equipped with the 93 maximum-type distances or norms: d (x1; y1); (x2; y2) = max d(x1; x2); d(y1; y2) , k(x; y)k = 94 max(kxk ; kyk). Sometimes, in products of normed spaces, the following norm depending on a 95 parameter γ > 0 will be used: k(x; y)kγ = max(kxk ; γ kyk). 96 2. Real-Valued Functions 97 2.1. Extremality, stationarity, and regularity. The classical criterion characterizing extremum 98 points of real-valued functions is given by the famous Fermat theorem. 99 Theorem 1 (Fermat). If a differentiable function f has a local minimum or maximum at x¯ then 0 100 f (¯x) = 0. 0 101 This assertion provides a dual (f (¯x) is an element of the dual space!) necessary condition for 102 a local minimum or maximum. It is well known that it actually characterizes a weaker property 103 called stationarity.
Recommended publications
  • Monotonic Transformations: Cardinal Versus Ordinal Utility
    Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 10: Quasiconcave and Pseudoconcave Functions Note 10 is based on Madden (1986, Ch. 13, 14) and Simon and Blume (1994, Ch. 21). Monotonic transformations: Cardinal Versus Ordinal Utility A utility function could be said to measure the level of satisfaction associated to each commodity bundle. Nowadays, no economist really believes that a real number can be assigned to each commodity bundle which expresses (in utils?) the consumer’slevel of satisfaction with this bundle. Economists believe that consumers have well-behaved preferences over bundles and that, given any two bundles, a consumer can indicate a preference of one over the other or the indi¤erence between the two. Although economists work with utility functions, they are concerned with the level sets of such functions, not with the number that the utility function assigns to any given level set. In consumer theory these level sets are called indi¤erence curves. A property of utility functions is called ordinal if it depends only on the shape and location of a consumer’sindi¤erence curves. It is alternatively called cardinal if it also depends on the actual amount of utility the utility function assigns to each indi¤erence set. In the modern approach, we say that two utility functions are equivalent if they have the same indi¤erence sets, although they may assign di¤erent numbers to each level set. For instance, let 2 2 u : R+ R where u (x) = x1x2 be a utility function, and let v : R+ R be the utility function ! ! v (x) = u (x) + 1: These two utility functions represent the same preferences and are therefore equivalent.
    [Show full text]
  • The Ekeland Variational Principle, the Bishop-Phelps Theorem, and The
    The Ekeland Variational Principle, the Bishop-Phelps Theorem, and the Brøndsted-Rockafellar Theorem Our aim is to prove the Ekeland Variational Principle which is an abstract result that found numerous applications in various fields of Mathematics. As its application to Convex Analysis, we provide a proof of the famous Bishop- Phelps Theorem and some related results. Let us recall that the epigraph and the hypograph of a function f : X ! [−∞; +1] (where X is a set) are the following subsets of X × R: epi f = f(x; t) 2 X × R : t ≥ f(x)g ; hyp f = f(x; t) 2 X × R : t ≤ f(x)g : Notice that, if f > −∞ on X then epi f 6= ; if and only if f is proper, that is, f is finite at at least one point. 0.1. The Ekeland Variational Principle. In what follows, (X; d) is a metric space. Given λ > 0 and (x; t) 2 X × R, we define the set Kλ(x; t) = f(y; s): s ≤ t − λd(x; y)g = f(y; s): λd(x; y) ≤ t − sg ⊂ X × R: Notice that Kλ(x; t) = hyp[t − λ(x; ·)]. Let us state some useful properties of these sets. Lemma 0.1. (a) Kλ(x; t) is closed and contains (x; t). (b) If (¯x; t¯) 2 Kλ(x; t) then Kλ(¯x; t¯) ⊂ Kλ(x; t). (c) If (xn; tn) ! (x; t) and (xn+1; tn+1) 2 Kλ(xn; tn) (n 2 N), then \ Kλ(x; t) = Kλ(xn; tn) : n2N Proof. (a) is quite easy.
    [Show full text]
  • On Nonconvex Subdifferential Calculus in Banach Spaces1
    Journal of Convex Analysis Volume 2 (1995), No.1/2, 211{227 On Nonconvex Subdifferential Calculus in Banach Spaces1 Boris S. Mordukhovich, Yongheng Shao Department of Mathematics, Wayne State University, Detroit, Michigan 48202, U.S.A. e-mail: [email protected] Received July 1994 Revised manuscript received March 1995 Dedicated to R. T. Rockafellar on his 60th Birthday We study a concept of subdifferential for general extended-real-valued functions defined on arbitrary Banach spaces. At any point considered this basic subdifferential is a nonconvex set of subgradients formed by sequential weak-star limits of the so-called Fr´echet "-subgradients of the function at points nearby. It is known that such and related constructions possess full calculus under special geometric assumptions on Banach spaces where they are defined. In this paper we establish some useful calculus rules in the general Banach space setting. Keywords : Nonsmooth analysis, generalized differentiation, extended-real-valued functions, nonconvex calculus, Banach spaces, sequential limits 1991 Mathematics Subject Classification: Primary 49J52; Secondary 58C20 1. Introduction It is well known that for studying local behavior of nonsmooth functions one can suc- cessfully use an appropriate concept of subdifferential (set of subgradients) which replaces the classical gradient at points of nondifferentiability in the usual two-sided sense. Such a concept first appeared for convex functions in the context of convex analysis that has had many significant applications to the range of problems in optimization, economics, mechanics, etc. One of the most important branches of convex analysis is subdifferen- tial calculus for convex extended-real-valued functions that was developed in the 1960's, mainly by Moreau and Rockafellar; see [23] and [25, 27] for expositions and references.
    [Show full text]
  • OPTIMIZATION and VARIATIONAL INEQUALITIES Basic Statements and Constructions
    1 OPTIMIZATION and VARIATIONAL INEQUALITIES Basic statements and constructions Bernd Kummer; [email protected] ; May 2011 Abstract. This paper summarizes basic facts in both finite and infinite dimensional optimization and for variational inequalities. In addition, partially new results (concerning methods and stability) are included. They were elaborated in joint work with D. Klatte, Univ. Z¨urich and J. Heerda, HU-Berlin. Key words. Existence of solutions, (strong) duality, Karush-Kuhn-Tucker points, Kojima-function, generalized equation, (quasi -) variational inequality, multifunctions, Kakutani Theo- rem, MFCQ, subgradient, subdifferential, conjugate function, vector-optimization, Pareto- optimality, solution methods, penalization, barriers, non-smooth Newton method, per- turbed solutions, stability, Ekeland's variational principle, Lyusternik theorem, modified successive approximation, Aubin property, metric regularity, calmness, upper and lower Lipschitz, inverse and implicit functions, generalized Jacobian @cf, generalized derivatives TF , CF , D∗F , Clarkes directional derivative, limiting normals and subdifferentials, strict differentiability. Bemerkung. Das Material wird st¨andigaktualisiert. Es soll Vorlesungen zur Optimierung und zu Vari- ationsungleichungen (glatt, nichtglatt) unterst¨utzen. Es entstand aus Scripten, die teils in englisch teils in deutsch aufgeschrieben wurden. Daher gibt es noch Passagen in beiden Sprachen sowie z.T. verschiedene Schreibweisen wie etwa cT x und hc; xi f¨urdas Skalarpro- dukt und die kanonische Bilinearform. Hinweise auf Fehler sind willkommen. 2 Contents 1 Introduction 7 1.1 The intentions of this script . .7 1.2 Notations . .7 1.3 Was ist (mathematische) Optimierung ? . .8 1.4 Particular classes of problems . 10 1.5 Crucial questions . 11 2 Lineare Optimierung 13 2.1 Dualit¨atund Existenzsatz f¨urLOP . 15 2.2 Die Simplexmethode .
    [Show full text]
  • 2011-Dissertation-Khajavirad.Pdf
    Carnegie Mellon University Carnegie Institute of Technology thesis Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy title Convexification Techniques for Global Optimization of Nonconvex Nonlinear Optimization Problems presented by Aida Khajavirad accepted by the department of mechanical engineering advisor date advisor date department head date approved by the college coucil dean date Convexification Techniques for Global Optimization of Nonconvex Nonlinear Optimization Problems Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Mechanical Engineering Aida Khajavirad B.S., Mechanical Engineering, University of Tehran Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA August 2011 c 2011 - Aida Khajavirad All rights reserved. Abstract Fueled by applications across science and engineering, general-purpose deter- ministic global optimization algorithms have been developed for nonconvex nonlinear optimization problems over the past two decades. Central to the ef- ficiency of such methods is their ability to construct sharp convex relaxations. Current general-purpose global solvers rely on factorable programming tech- niques to iteratively decompose nonconvex factorable functions, through the introduction of variables and constraints for intermediate functional expres- sions, until each intermediate expression can be outer-approximated by a con- vex feasible set. While it is easy to automate, this factorable programming technique often leads to weak relaxations. In this thesis, we develop the theory of several new classes of cutting planes based upon ideas from generalized convexity and convex analysis. Namely, we (i) introduce a new method to outer-approximate convex-transformable func- tions, an important class of generalized convex functions that subsumes many functional forms that frequently appear in nonconvex problems and, (ii) derive closed-form expressions for the convex envelopes of various types of functions that are the building blocks of nonconvex problems.
    [Show full text]
  • A Microlocal Characterization of Lipschitz Continuity
    A microlocal characterization of Lipschitz continuity Benoˆıt Jubin∗† November 3, 2017 Abstract We study continuous maps between differential manifolds from a microlocal point of view. In particular, we characterize the Lipschitz continuity of these maps in terms of the microsupport of the constant sheaf on their graph. Furthermore, we give lower and upper bounds on the microsupport of the graph of a continuous map and use these bounds to characterize strict differentiability in microlocal terms. Contents Introduction 1 1 Background material 4 2 Microsupports associated with subsets 11 3 Whitney cones of maps 14 4 Conormals of maps 19 5 Real-valued functions 24 6 Main results 29 7 Topological submanifolds 37 A Appendix: Lipschitz continuity and strict differentiability 39 B Appendix: tangent cones 40 arXiv:1611.04644v2 [math.AG] 2 Nov 2017 Introduction Microlocal analysis is the study of phenomena occurring on differential manifolds via a study in their cotangent bundle; for instance, the study of the singularities of solutions of a partial differential equation on a manifold M via the study of their wavefront set in T ∗M. A general setting for microlocal analysis is the microlocal theory of sheaves, developed by M. Kashi- wara and P. Schapira (see [KS90]). In [Vic], N. Vichery used this theory to study from a microlocal viewpoint continuous real-valued functions on differential manifolds, and to define for these functions a good notion of subdifferential. We extend this study to continuous maps ∗Key words: microlocal theory of sheaves, Lipschitz maps, Dini derivatives. †MSC: 35A27, 26A16, 26A24. 1 between differential manifolds. We study simultaneously the tangent aspects of the subject to emphasize the parallelism between the tangent and cotangent sides.
    [Show full text]
  • Radial Duality Part I: Foundations
    Radial Duality Part I: Foundations Benjamin Grimmer∗ Abstract Renegar [11] introduced a novel approach to transforming generic conic optimization prob- lems into unconstrained, uniformly Lipschitz continuous minimization. We introduce radial transformations generalizing these ideas, equipped with an entirely new motivation and devel- opment that avoids any reliance on convex cones or functions. Perhaps of greatest practical importance, this facilitates the development of new families of projection-free first-order meth- ods applicable even in the presence of nonconvex objectives and constraint sets. Our generalized construction of this radial transformation uncovers that it is dual (i.e., self-inverse) for a wide range of functions including all concave objectives. This gives a powerful new duality relat- ing optimization problems to their radially dual problem. For a broad class of functions, we characterize continuity, differentiability, and convexity under the radial transformation as well as develop a calculus for it. This radial duality provides a strong foundation for designing projection-free radial optimization algorithms, which is carried out in the second part of this work. 1 Introduction Renegar [11] introduced a framework for conic programming (and by reduction, convex optimiza- tion), which turns such problems into uniformly Lipschitz optimization. After being radially trans- formed, a simple subgradient method can be applied and analyzed. Notably, even for constrained problems, such an algorithm maintains a feasible solution at each iteration while avoiding the use of orthogonal projections, which can often be a bottleneck for first-order methods. Subsequently, Grimmer [8] showed that in the case of convex optimization, a simplified radial subgradient method can be applied with simpler and stronger convergence guarantees.
    [Show full text]
  • On a Variant of a Theorem of Schmeidler
    STX BEBR FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 1306 On a Variant of a Theorem of Schmeidler M. AH Khan College of Commerce and Business Administration Bureau of Economic and Business Research University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign BEBR FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 1306 College of Commerce and Business Administration University of Illinois Urbana-Champaign November 1986 On a Variant of a Theorem of Schmeidler M. Ali Khan, Professor Department of Economics Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2012 with funding from University of Illinois Urbana-Champaign http://www.archive.org/details/onvariantoftheor1306khan On a Variant of a Theorem of Schmeidlert by M. Ali Khan* August 1986 Revised: November 1986 Abstract . We report generalizations of a theorem of Mas-Colell on the existence of a Cournot Nash equilibrium distribution for games in which the strategy space is not necessarily metrizable and separable and the pay-off functions are not necessarily continuous. tl am grateful to Ye Neng Sun for finding a gap in the proof of Theorem 3.1 in the first version of this paper and to Tapan Mitra for several helpful discussions. Errors are, of course, solely mine. This research was presented at the Mathematical Economics Workshop at Indiana University and was supported in part by the Bureau of Business and Economic Research at the University of Illinois and in part by an NSF grant. Both sources of support are gratefully acknowledged. *Department of Economics, University of Illinois, 1206 S. Sixth St., Champaign, IL 61820. 1. Introduction Mas-Colell (1984) presents a reformulated version of Schraeidler's (1973) results on the existence of Cournot-Nash equilibria in games with a continuum of players.
    [Show full text]
  • Mathematics Mathematics Neelam Patel
    CONSTRAINT QUALIFICATIONS , LAGRANGIAN DUALITY & SADDLE POINT OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS A Dissertation Submitted For The Award of the Degree of Master of Philosophy in Mathematics Neelam Patel School of Mathematics Devi Ahilya Vishwavidyalaya, (((NACC(NACC Accredited Grade “A”“A”)))) Indore (M.P.) 20122012----20132013 Contents Page No. Introduction 1 Chapter-1 2-7 Preliminaries Chapter-2 8-21 Constraint Qualifications Chapter-3 22-52 Lagrangian Duality & Saddle Point Optimality Conditions References 53 Introduction The dissertation is a study of Constraint Qualifications, Lagrangian Duality and saddle point Optimality Conditions. In fact, it is a reading of chapters 5 and 6 of [1]. First chapter is about preliminaries. We collect results which are useful in subsequent chapters, like Fritz-John necessary and sufficient conditions for optimality and Karush-Kuhn-Tucker necessary and sufficient conditions for optimality. In second chapter we define the cone of tangents and show that F 0 T = is a necessary condition for local optimality is the cone of tangents. The constraint ∩ ∅ qualification which are defined are Abidie ′s, Slater ′s, Cottle ′s, Zangvill ′s, Kuhn- Tucker ′s and linear independence constraint qualification. We shall prove LICQ ⇒ CQ ⇒ ZCQ KT CQ ⇒ AQ ⇒ SQ ⇑ We derive KKT conditions under various constraint qualifications. Further, We study of various constraint qualifications and their interrelationships. In third chapter, we define the Lagrangian dual problem and give its geometric interpretation. We prove the weak and strong duality theorems. We also develop the saddle point optimality conditions and its relationship with KKT conditions. Further, some important properties of the dual function, such as concavity, differentiability, and subdifferentiability have been discussed.
    [Show full text]
  • Differentiability Properties of a Parametric Consumer Problem
    Differentiability Properties of a Parametric Consumer Problem V.T. Huong,∗ J.-C. Yao,y and N.D. Yenz April 30, 2018 Abstract. We study the budget map and the indirect utility function of a parametric consumer problem in a Banach space setting by some advanced tools from set-valued and variational analysis. The Lipschitz- likeness and differentiability properties of the budget map, as well as for- mulas for finding subdifferentials of the infimal nuisance function, which is obtained from the indirect utility function by changing its sign, are established. Our investigation is mainly based on the paper by Mor- dukhovich [J. Global Optim. 28 (2004), 347{362] on coderivative analysis of variational systems and the paper of Mordukhovich, Nam, and Yen [Math. Program. 116 (2009), 369{396] on subgradients of marginal func- arXiv:1804.10377v1 [math.OC] 27 Apr 2018 tions. Economic meanings of the obtained subdifferential estimates are explained in details. ∗Graduate Training Center, Institute of Mathematics, Vietnam Academy of Science and Technology, 18 Hoang Quoc Viet, Hanoi 10307, Vietnam; email: [email protected]; [email protected]. yCenter for General Education, China Medical University, Taichung 40402, Taiwan; email: [email protected]. zInstitute of Mathematics, Vietnam Academy of Science and Technology, 18 Hoang Quoc Viet, Hanoi 10307, Vietnam; email: [email protected]. 1 2 Keywords: Parametric consumer problem, Banach space setting, budget map, indirect utility function, subdifferential. 2010 Mathematics Subject Classification: 91B16, 91B42, 91B38, 46N10, 49J53. 1 Introduction Various stability properties and a result on solution sensitivity of a consumer problem were obtained in our recent paper [8].
    [Show full text]
  • Arxiv:1605.03456V6 [Math.OC] 8 Jun 2018 Abstract
    A UNIFIED APPROACH TO EXTENDED REAL-VALUED FUNCTIONS by PETRA WEIDNER1 Research Report Version 6 from June 8, 2018 Extended Version of Version 1 from November 16, 2015 Abstract. Extended real-valued functions are often used in optimization theory, but in different ways for infimum problems and for supremum problems. We present an approach to extended real-valued functions that works for all types of problems and into which results of convex analysis can be embedded. Our approach preserves continuity and the Chebyshev norm when extending a functional to the entire space. The basic idea also works for other spaces than R. Moreover, we illustrate that extended real-valued functions have to be handled in another way than real-valued functions and characterize semicontinuity, convexity, linearity and related properties of such functions. Keywords: Extended real-valued function; Semicontinuity; Convex function; Linear function; Sublevel set; Epigraph; Indicator function Mathematics Subject Classification (2010): 90C25, 90C30, 90C48, 54C30, 58C05 arXiv:1605.03456v6 [math.OC] 8 Jun 2018 1 HAWK Hochschule Hildesheim/Holzminden/G¨ottingen, University of Applied Sciences and Arts, Faculty of Natural Sciences and Technology, D-37085 G¨ottingen, Germany, [email protected]. 1 2 1. Introduction In this report, we present basic notations and properties for functions which attain values in R := R ∪ {−∞, +∞}, the extended set of real numbers. Of course, such a function may also be real-valued, but infima, suprema, limits, im- proper integrals or some measure can result in function values −∞ or +∞. Such values can also result from the extension of a function to the entire space or from the addition of an indicator function expressing certain restrictions in convex analysis.
    [Show full text]
  • Title on a Relationship Between Ekeland's Algorithm and Infimal
    On a Relationship between Ekeland's Algorithm and Infimal Title Convolutions(Nonlinear Analysis and Convex Analysis) Author(s) TANAKA, TAMAKI Citation 数理解析研究所講究録 (1995), 897: 73-79 Issue Date 1995-02 URL http://hdl.handle.net/2433/84472 Right Type Departmental Bulletin Paper Textversion publisher Kyoto University 数理解析研究所講究録 第 897 巻 1995 年 73-79 73 On a Relationship between Ekeland’s Algorithm and Infimal Convolutions $*$ $R_{\overline{B|J}}\star\mp fE^{P}\mp^{-}-\#$ $ffl*$ $\ovalbox{\tt\small REJECT}$ (TAMAKI TANAKA)\dagger Abstract. The aim of this paper is to give a study on a relationship between Eke- land’s variational principle and infimal convolution. By help of graphic interpretation of infimal convolution, Ekeland’s variational principle can be regarded as an algorithm similar to the proximal point algorithm for a problem of minimizing a lower semicon- tinuous proper convex function on a Hilbert space. Key Words. Ekeland’s variational principle, infimal convolution, convex analysis, optimization. 1. INTRODUCTION Recently, good books related to optimization theory have been published; [2, 10, 14], in which Ekeland’s variational principle and fixed point theorems are observed, but not devoted to relationship between the variational principle and infimal convolution. Hence, the aim of this paper is to give a study on a relationship between Ekeland’s variational principle and infimal convolution. By help of graphic interpretation of infimal convolution, Ekeland’s variational principle can be regarded as an algorithm similar to the proximal point algorithm for a problem of minimizing a lower semicontinuous proper convex function on a Hilbert space; see $[7^{\backslash }, 9,11]$ .
    [Show full text]