An Unprecedented Short History of Fed Independence

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

An Unprecedented Short History of Fed Independence Macro Wrap-Up: An Unprecedented Short History of Fed Independence July 27, 2018 After last week’s Wrap-Up on the Powell Fed, we got a lot of questions on executive interference in U.S. monetary policy and currency markets. 1The questions were mostly along the lines of: “Are President Trump’s criticisms of the Fed unprecedented?” The answer is straightforward: they are completely precedented. 2In fact, the comments criticizing the Fed’s rate hikes may be the most precedented thing the administration has done. It’s understandable that young folks may not remember all of the past conflicts over Fed independence because the past three administrations have, for the most part, let the Fed set monetary policy as it wished. 3However, by the standards of the 1960s, 1970s and 1980s, Trump’s comments were very tame. Modern Fed independence dates back to the post-World War II period. 4The U.S. government borrowed enormous amounts to finance its participation in the War and then used the Fed to monetize the debt by mandating low yield targets. 5This led to double digit inflation in the late 1940s. Many Fed members, including Chair Marriner Eccles, objected. In 1948, President Truman responded by replacing Eccles.6 Tensions between the Fed and the Treasury were finally resolved by the famous 1951 Accord, which granted the Fed autonomy over monetary policy. 7The Accord allowed the Fed to set rates based on economic considerations rather than using it as a financing tool. But even though independence was the official policy, it was challenged numerous times in the following thirty years. For the most part, governing parties wanted lower rates to stimulate the economy with the not-so-hidden agenda of improving their electoral chances. 8There were some colorful confrontations between politicians and the Fed. Three weeks after the Accord, William McChesney Martin Jr. took the helm at the Fed. He gained a reputation as a solid inflation fighter, but after a few years he was caught in President Johnson’s crosshairs. 9After Martin cast the deciding vote for a 50bps rate increase, Johnson called him to his Texas ranch. According to reports, Johnson grabbed Martin by the arm and threw him against a wall. “Martin, my boys are dying in Vietnam and you won’t print the money I need” he said.1 0Richard Nixon was equally creative in his approach to the Fed.11 During the run-up to the 1972 election, Nixon and his advisor George Shultz pressured Martin’s successor Arthur Burns to increase the monetary supply. Nixon was very blunt about how a stronger economy would help his campaign and referred to the “myth of the autonomous Fed.” In an effort to be even more persuasive, Nixon also leaked false stories about Burns requesting a pay increase. We don’t know how much the not-so-subtle pressure affected monetary policy, but it probably wasn’t a coincidence that these incidents were followed by periods of rising inflation. By the late 1970s, inflation had gotten so high that Jimmy Carter had little choice but to allow Paul Volcker to raise rates to previously unseen levels. After defeating Carter in the 1980 election, Ronald Reagan reappointed Volcker. However, when Volcker voted for continued tight policy, despite more moderate inflation levels, Reagan replaced him with Alan Greenspan. 1 2Greenspan did not loosen monetary policy immediately. Some economists think that he may have purposely kept rates high to prove his independence and to establish his inflation fighting credentials. It was not long before the stock market crashed in October of 1987. That may have been a coincidence. The market eventually recovered, but Greenspan later faced harsh criticism from George H.W. Bush for not cutting rates more aggressively prior to the 1992 election. “I reappointed him and he disappointed me” H.W. poetically lamented.1 3His son, George W. Bush did not interfere in monetary policy at all during his term, nor did President Obama. By Greenspan’s account, W. believed in monetary policy independence. It’s more difficult to know what Obama thought on the issue because the Fed was so aggressive with its easy money policies that there wasn’t much for him to ask.1 4Now that rates are rising, it shouldn’t be too surprising that a President wants easier policy. Some have argued that Powell will respond like Greenspan and tighten rates more quickly. Others have argued that he will cave in as Burns and Martin are alleged to have done. The more likely outcome is that he just ignores the pressure and hikes rates slowly. That would be truly independent. If we do start to see a more meaningful erosion of Fed independence, it is reasonable to expect a sustained rise in inflation and low real rates. The past experiences are not conclusive but they point in that direction. Trump’s comments on the dollar are different, in part because the strong dollar policy in its current form only dates back to the Clinton administration. It doesn’t carry the weight of Fed independence nor does it have the history of being trampled on. The strong dollar policy is really only rhetoric, but in foreign exchange, rhetoric can move markets. If the administration were to commit to a weaker dollar policy, it could be successful. Of course, it could trigger reactions from other countries and could lead to a round of competitive devaluations. Fortunately, we’re not there yet. Soon after Trump’s comments, Treasury Secretary Mnuchin said the U.S. was committed to the strong dollar policy.1 5This seems to be the pattern with the administration and the dollar. You could even say it was precedented. What We Are Watching Bank of Japan Meeting (Tuesday) The Bank of Japan’s monetary policy meeting will take place amid recent speculation of potential 1 adjustments to the bank’s monetary easing framework. The speculation was ignited by news, citing undisclosed sources, indicating that “unusually active discussions” are taking place within the BoJ ahead of the July meeting “with changes to [the central bank’s] interest-rate targets and stock-buying techniques on the table.”1 6The sources noted that discussions were contingent on the board members’ inflation forecasts to be updated in the upcoming meeting. Any changes that can be perceived as a withdrawal of stimulus would pose a communication challenge for the BoJ given persistently low inflation in Japan.1 7The market will be particularly focused on potential changes to the yield curve control scheme and the ETF-buying program. FOMC Meeting (Wednesday) - Bank of England Meeting (Thursday) Market pricing for both the FOMC and BoE meetings implies no changes in policy rates next week. On the FOMC front, Chairman Powell’s prepared remarks to Congress last week reiterated the committee’s expectation of continued strength in the labor market and inflation stability near 2% over the next several years.1 8Powell also noted that the effects on the economy of the current discussions over trade policy are still uncertain. On the BoE front, Governor Carney recently expressed increased confidence that the softness of U.K. activity in Q1 was largely due to weather factors. He noted that should the economy perform in line with his expectations, “ongoing tightening of monetary policy over the next few years would be appropriate,” without specifying the timing of a hike.1 9With rates unlikely to change, market focus will be on language changes in both central banks. U.S. Employment Report (Friday) The July employment report in the U.S. will be released on August 3. While job creation has been remarkably strong this year, rising from 182,000 jobs per month in 2017 to 215,000 jobs created in 2018 on average, wage inflation has remained unchanged relative to December 2017 at 2.7%.2 0Wage growth has been muted despite the unemployment rate falling 0.5% below the FOMC’s 4.5% estimate of the long-term unemployment rate.2 1Perhaps contributing to the lack of wage inflation, labor force participation among workers aged 25 to 54 years has been trending higher steadily since late 2015, rising from 80.6% to 82% in June.22 Market focus will likely be on wage inflation, job creation, and the unemployment rate. [1 ] For the key comments from Trump’s CNBC interview last week, see CNBC: “Trump lays into Federal Reserve, says he’s ‘not thrilled’ about interest rate hikes,” 7/19/18. [2 ] Or perhaps “Presidented.” My spellcheck is saying “precedented” is not a word either. Then what’s the opposite of unprecedented, spellcheck?? [3 ] Old folks may not remember either. [4 ] Prior to the Fed, Andrew Jackson fought with the President of the Second Bank of the U.S., Nicholas Biddle. Jackson won that fight and the Bank of the U.S. was ultimately dissolved. [5 ] This was one of the earlier examples of yield curve control. For a summary of the policy and the economic backdrop, see: Bank of Japan: “History and Theories of Yield Curve Control,” 1/11/17. [6 ] Eccles was able to stay on the Fed, just not as Chairman. Eccles is considered a hero by many economic historians and the main office of the Board of Governors in Washington D.C. carries his name today – the Marriner S. Eccles Federal Reserve Board Building. [7 ] The 1951 Accord, also known as the Treasury-Fed Accord, only came about after President Truman falsely told the press in early 1951 that the FOMC had agreed to support the Treasury’s interest rate peg. Eccles released the FOMC minutes showing otherwise.
Recommended publications
  • Jerome H Powell: Challenges for Monetary Policy
    For release on delivery 10:00 a.m. EDT (8:00 a.m. local time) August 23, 2019 Challenges for Monetary Policy Remarks by Jerome H. Powell Chair Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System at “Challenges for Monetary Policy,” a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Jackson Hole, Wyoming August 23, 2019 This year’s symposium topic is “Challenges for Monetary Policy,” and for the Federal Reserve those challenges flow from our mandate to foster maximum employment and price stability. From this perspective, our economy is now in a favorable place, and I will describe how we are working to sustain these conditions in the face of significant risks we have been monitoring. The current U.S. expansion has entered its 11th year and is now the longest on record. 1 The unemployment rate has fallen steadily throughout the expansion and has been near half-century lows since early 2018. But that rate alone does not fully capture the benefits of this historically strong job market. Labor force participation by people in their prime working years has been rising. While unemployment for minorities generally remains higher than for the workforce as a whole, the rate for African Americans, at 6 percent, is the lowest since the government began tracking it in 1972. For the past few years, wages have been increasing the most for people at the lower end of the wage scale. People who live and work in low- and middle-income communities tell us that this job market is the best anyone can recall.
    [Show full text]
  • What Have We Learned Since October 1979?
    Panel Discussion I Moderation.” Recessions have become less fre- What Have We Learned Since quent and milder, and quarter-to-quarter volatility October 1979? in output and employment has declined signifi- cantly as well. The sources of the Great Moderation Ben S. Bernanke remain somewhat controversial, but, as I have argued elsewhere, there is evidence for the view he question asked of this panel is, that improved control of inflation has contributed “What have we learned since October in important measure to this welcome change in 1979?” The evidence suggests that we the economy (Bernanke, 2004). Paul Volcker and have learned quite a bit. Most notably, his colleagues on the Federal Open Market Com- Tmonetary policymakers, political leaders, and mittee deserve enormous credit both for recogniz- the public have been persuaded by two decades ing the crucial importance of achieving low and of experience that low and stable inflation has stable inflation and for the courage and persever- very substantial economic benefits. ance with which they tackled America’s critical This consensus marks a considerable change inflation problem. from the views held by many economists at the I could say much more about Volcker’s time that Paul Volcker became Fed Chairman. In achievement and its lasting benefits, but I am sure 1979, most economists would have agreed that, that many other speakers will cover that ground. in principle, low inflation promotes economic Instead, in my remaining time, I will focus on growth and efficiency in the long run. However, some lessons that economists have drawn from many also believed that, in the range of inflation the Volcker regime regarding the importance of rates typically experienced by industrial countries, credibility in central banking and how that credi- the benefits of low inflation are probably small— bility can be obtained.
    [Show full text]
  • Reforming the Rules That Govern the Fed
    Reforming the Rules That Govern the Fed Charles W. Calomiris Abstract The Fed has achieved both of its central objectives – price stability and financial stability – in only about a quarter of its years of operation. What reforms would be likely to improve that performance? This article focuses on two problems that have plagued the Fed throughout its history: adherence to bad ideas, especially to influence from intellectual fads in macroeconomics, which have produced major policy errors; and politicization of the Fed, which leads it to pursue objectives other than price stability and financial stability. Several reforms are proposed to the structure and governance of the Fed, and its policy mandates, which would promote greater diversity of thought and independence from political pressures, which in turn would insulate the Fed from political pressures and make its thinking less susceptible to intellectual fads. Taking Stock The Fed is celebrating its 100th birthday. The celebration has been muted, sometimes even somber, and for good reason: the Fed has achieved both of its central objectives – price stability and financial stability – in only about a quarter of its years of operation. There is one Fed leader, however, whose record receives universal accolades. In one Fed cartoon prepared for high school students, Paul Volcker is lovingly portrayed as a superhero wearing a red cape. Few would object to that characterization. Over the 100-year history of Fed monetary policy, Mr. Volcker’s combination of integrity, judgment, and courage stand alone. Integrity because, prior to his appointment, he leveled with President Carter about his intention to attack inflation aggressively.
    [Show full text]
  • What Have We Learned Since October 1979? by Alan S. Blinder Princeton
    What Have We Learned since October 1979? by Alan S. Blinder Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. 105 April 2005 “What Have We Learned since October 1979?” by Alan S. Blinder Princeton University∗ My good friend Ben Bernanke is always a hard act to follow. When I drafted these remarks, I was concerned that Ben would take all the best points and cover them extremely well, leaving only some crumbs for Ben McCallum and me to pick up. But his decision to concentrate on one issue—central bank credibility—leaves me plenty to talk about. Because Ben was so young in 1979, I’d like to begin by emphasizing that Paul Volcker re-taught the world something it seemed to have forgotten at the time: that tight monetary policy can bring inflation down at substantial, but not devastating, cost. It seems strange to harbor contrary thoughts today, but back then many people believed that 10% inflation was so deeply ingrained in the U.S. economy that we might to doomed to, say, 6-10% inflation for a very long time. For example, Otto Eckstein (1981, pp. 3-4) wrote in a well-known 1981 book that “To bring the core inflation rate down significantly through fiscal and monetary policies alone would require a prolonged deep recession bordering on depression, with the average unemployment rate held above 10%.” More concretely, he estimated that it would require 10 point-years of unemployment to bring the core inflation rate down a single percentage point,1 which is about five times more than called for by the “Brookings rule of thumb.”2 In the event, the Volcker disinflation followed the Brookings rule of thumb rather well.
    [Show full text]
  • Alphachatterbox: the Life and Times of Paul Volcker Cardiff Garcia First of All, Thanks for Talking to Us
    Alphachatterbox: the life and times of Paul Volcker Cardiff Garcia First of all, thanks for talking to us. Appreciate it. Paul Volcker You're welcome. We'll see how it goes. Cardiff Garcia Here's where I want to start. When you were studying economics, those were pretty exciting times for the profession. Hayek and Keynes were still debating, Bretton Woods had been established in the mid­1940s, central bank independence was still kind of a contentious topic. Who were some of the early influences on the way you think about monetary economics? Who were some of the thinkers that influenced your points of view? Paul Volcker I'm supposed to have some thinkers that influenced me. I don't remember any standing out in particular. For some reason, I took the advanced economic theory course when I was either a freshman or a sophomore at Princeton from a guy named Oskar Morgenstern, who was part of the Jewish intellectuals that moved to the United States before the war. And he was Austrian, so you got a full exposure to the Austrian school of economics. To the best of my memory, and maybe my memory is wrong, I could sit through all those economics classes in Princeton, I don't think the word Keynes was ever mentioned. Cardiff Garcia The word...? [overtalking] Paul Volcker Keynes. John Maynard Keynes. Because the money and banking professor, a guy by the name of [Friedrich] Lutz, another Austrian émigré... they were not Keynesian. And in those days, most professors I guess were not yet Keynesian, or at least it was controversial.
    [Show full text]
  • What Have We Learned Since October 1979? (Central Bank Articles And
    Ben S Bernanke: Panel discussion: what have we learned since October 1979? Remarks by Mr Ben S Bernanke, Member of the Board of Governors of the US Federal Reserve System, to the Conference on Reflections on Monetary Policy 25 Years after October 1979, Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis, St Louis, Missouri, 8 October 2004. The references for the speech can be found on the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System’s website. * * * The question asked of this panel is, “What have we learned since October 1979?” The evidence suggests that we have learned quite a bit. Most notably, monetary policy-makers, political leaders, and the public have been persuaded by two decades of experience that low and stable inflation has very substantial economic benefits. This consensus marks a considerable change from the views held by many economists at the time that Paul Volcker became Fed Chairman. In 1979, most economists would have agreed that, in principle, low inflation promotes economic growth and efficiency in the long run. However, many also believed that, in the range of inflation rates typically experienced by industrial countries, the benefits of low inflation are probably small - particularly when set against the short-run costs of a major disinflation, as the United States faced at that time. Indeed, some economists would have held that low-inflation policies would likely prove counterproductive even in the long run, if an increased focus on inflation inhibited monetary policy-makers from responding adequately to fluctuations in economic activity and employment. As it turned out, the low-inflation era of the past two decades has seen not only significant improvements in economic growth and productivity but also a marked reduction in economic volatility, both in the United States and abroad, a phenomenon that has been dubbed “the Great Moderation.” Recessions have become less frequent and milder, and quarter-to-quarter volatility in output and employment has declined significantly as well.
    [Show full text]
  • Arthur Burns and G. William Miller: the Hapless Inflators
    Excerpt from Fed Watching for Fun and Profit Edward Yardeni March 2020 Chapter 3 Arthur Burns and G. William Miller: The Hapless Inflators Fueling the Great Inflation Arthur Burns served as Fed chair from February 1, 1970 to January 31, 1978 under Presidents Richard Nixon, Gerald Ford, and Jimmy Carter. Burns was an academic, and the first PhD macroeconomist to head the Fed. He taught economics at both Rutgers University (starting in 1927) and Columbia University (1945), having earned his PhD at the latter. As a doctoral student at Columbia, Burns studied under Wesley Clair Mitchell, a founder of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) and its chief researcher. Mitchell brought Burns into the NBER, where Burns began his lifelong research into the business cycle. Together, in 1946, they published Measuring Business Cycles, which introduced the characteristic NBER methods of analyzing business cycles empirically.32 It was Burns who started the NBER’s academic tradition of determining recessions—a role that has been continued by the organization’s Business Cycle Dating Committee. The NBER remains the preeminent authority on dating recessions.[33] Burns served as president and chair of the NBER at points throughout his teaching career. He also chaired the Council of Economic Advisers (CEA) from 1953 to 1956 under President Dwight Eisenhower. The CEA was established by the Employment Act of 1946, which stated that it is the responsibility of the federal government to create “conditions under which there will be afforded useful employment for those able, willing, and seeking work, and to promote maximum employment, production, and purchasing power.” The CEA was created to help President Eisenhower and successive Presidents make sure another Great Depression would never happen.
    [Show full text]
  • FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM the First 100 Years
    FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM The First 100 Years A CHAPTER IN THE HISTORY OF CENTRAL BANKING FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM The First 100 Years A Chapter in the History of Central Banking n 1913, Albert Einstein was working on his established the second Bank of the United States. It new theory of gravity, Richard Nixon was was also given a 20-year charter and operated from born, and Franklin D. Roosevelt was sworn 1816 to 1836; however, its charter was not renewed in as assistant secretary of the Navy. It was either. After the charter expired, the United States also the year Woodrow Wilson took the oath endured a series of financial crises during the 19th of office as the 28th President of the United and early 20th centuries. Several factors contributed IStates, intent on advocating progressive reform to the crises, including a number of bank failures, and change. One of his biggest reforms occurred which generated waves of bank panics and on December 23, 1913, when he signed the Federal economic instability.2 Reserve Act into law. This landmark legislation When Jay Cooke and Company, the nation’s created the Federal Reserve System, the nation’s largest bank, failed in 1873, a panic erupted, leading central bank.1 to runs on other financial institutions. Within months, the nation’s economic problems deepened as silver A Need for Stability prices dropped after the Coinage Act of 1873 was Why was a central bank needed? The nation passed, which dampened the interests of U.S. silver had tried twice before to establish a central bank miners and led to a recession that lasted until 1879.
    [Show full text]
  • What Does Jerome Powell Know That William Mcchesney Martin Didn’T—And What Role Did Academic Research Play in That?
    What does Jerome Powell know that William McChesney Martin didn’t—and what role did academic research play in that? by Alan S. Blinder, Princeton University Griswold Center for Economic Policy Studies Working Paper No. 259, September 2019 Keynote lecture at the Money Macro and Finance Research Group’s 50th Anniversary Conference, London School of Economics, September 4-6, 2019. Forthcoming in The Manchester School. I thank Roger Ferguson, Chris Sims, and Janet Yellen for helpful conversations, but none of them is implicated in the opinions expressed here. It is indeed a pleasure for an old LSE alumnus like me (M.Sc., 1968) to return to help mark the 50th anniversary of the Money Macro and Finance Research Group. I actually have on my bookshelf a copy of Harry Johnson’s 1972 book, Macroeconomics and Monetary Theory (Johnson, 1972), which was based on his lectures at LSE during the 1969-1970 academic year. I presumably heard some of these lectures as a student two years earlier. But fifty years is a long time and memory fails. The world changes in 50 years. In 1969, the New York Jets won the Superbowl of American football and the New York Mets won the World Series of baseball—two huge upsets in the same year! The former has never reoccurred; the latter has been repeated only once. The year 1969 is perhaps most famous for astronaut Neil Armstrong’s walk on the moon—a remarkable feat that was accomplished five more times, but not since 1972. However, some aspects of the world don’t change much in a half-century.
    [Show full text]
  • Great Deformation: the Corruption of Capitalism in America
    4/C PROCESS + PANTONE 8402 GRITTY MATTE UV 100#PAPER. ECONOMICS / BUSINESS $35.00 / $38.00 can IN THE WORDS OF DAVID STOCKMAN THE GREAT DEFORMATION is a searing look at Washington’s craven response to the recent myriad of financial crises and fiscal cliffs. It counters conven- ER D “ At the heart of the Great Deformation is a rogue central bank tional wisdom with an eighty-year revisionist history of how LAN G N E that has abandoned every vestige of sound money.” the American state—especially the Federal Reserve—has fallen ARYL ARYL C prey to the politics of crony capitalism and the ideologies of fiscal stimulus, monetary central planning, and financial bail- DAVID A. STOCKMAN was elected as a “ In the years after 1980, America had undergone the equivalent of outs. These forces have left the public sector teetering on the Michigan congressman in 1976 and joined the Reagan White a national leveraged buyout...[and was] now saddled with edge of political dysfunction and fiscal collapse and have caused House in 1981. Serving as budget director, he was one of the America’s private enterprise foundation to morph into a spec- more in combined public and private debt.” key architects of the Reagan Revolution plan to reduce taxes, $30 trillion ulative casino that swindles the masses and enriches the few. cut spending, and shrink the role of government. He joined Defying right- and left-wing boxes, David Stockman Salomon Brothers in 1985 and later became one of the early The Corruption of Capitalism provides a catalogue of corrupters and defenders of sound partners of the Blackstone Group.
    [Show full text]
  • The Honorable Jerome H. Powell Chair, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 20Th St
    The Honorable Jerome H. Powell Chair, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 20th St. and Constitution Ave. NW Washington, DC 20551 Comptroller Joseph M. Otting Office of the Comptroller of the Currency 400 7th Street, SW Washington, DC 20219 SUBMITTED VIA FEDEX August 8, 2018 Re: Comments regarding the eSLR and Volcker Rule Dear Chair Powell and Comptroller Otting, This letter offers the comments of the Systemic Risk Council (SRC) on the proposals of the Federal Reserve Board (Fed) and the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) (together, “the Regulators”) to relax (a) the leverage ratio applying to banks and banking groups, and (b) the so-called ‘Volcker Rule’ constraints on using insured deposits to fund speculative trading and investments. The SRC has serious reservations about both proposals, as they would make the US banking system less resilient and so expose the American people to unnecessary risks. In this Comment Letter, we set out our concerns and offer some possible mitigating measures if the Fed and OCC continue on their charted course. Relaxing the leverage constraint The enhanced supplementary leverage ratio (eSLR) applies to (and only to) banking groups that have been designated as global systemically important banking organizations (GSIBs). It is currently 6% for insured depository institutions (i.e., operating banks) that are subsidiaries of such GSIBs; and 5% for the consolidated group holding company. Summary of the proposals The Regulators have proposed that the ratios be reduced to 3% (the standard leverage requirement for all banks) plus 50% of the surcharge that is applied to a particular GSIB’s risk-based capital requirement.
    [Show full text]
  • President Trump's Pick for Fed Chair
    JOHN L. BELLOWS, PhD Portfolio Manager / Research Analyst POLICY MATTERS August 2017 President Trump’s Pick for Fed Chair Executive Summary “[Yellen] is not a Republican. When her time is up, I would most likely replace her because of the fact that I • Fed Chair Janet Yellen’s term think it would be appropriate.” ends in February 2018, with no clear successor yet identified. “[Yellen] is a low-interest-rate person, she’s always been a low-interest-rate person, and let’s be honest, I’m a low-interest-rate person.” • President Trump has made it clear he is interested in keeping interest rates low and ~Donald J. Trump, CNBC Interview, May 5, 2016 leans toward selecting a fellow Republican. With Janet Yellen’s term ending in February 2018, the sweepstakes for Federal Reserve (Fed) Chair is heating up. Media stories about who is favored are appearing with increasing frequency and attracting a lot of attention. • One possible choice, not Potential candidates are trying to raise their profiles and thereby increase their chances. Furthermore, our clients currently on most investors’ radars, would be Jerome regularly ask us for our view on who President Donald Trump will pick. Our honest answer is “We don’t know, nor Powell whose views on does anybody else.” That stated, we can make some informed observations. While we may or may not get the accommodative policy and name exactly right, our thought process, detailed below, may be a helpful guide to watching the contest heat up political affiliation meet the over the coming months.
    [Show full text]