Understanding Productivity Growth in the Industrial Revolution

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Understanding Productivity Growth in the Industrial Revolution Understanding productivity growth in † the industrial revolution ∗ By NICHOLAS CRAFTS Economic History Review, 2021 Recent research relating to productivity growth during the British industrial revolution is reviewed. This confirms that there was a gradual acceleration rather than a ‘take-off’. The explanation for the speeding-up of technological progress remains controversial but the evidence base has improved considerably. In the face of a surge in population growth, slow growth of real wages during the industrial revolution may be seen as a good outcome which was underpinned by improved growth potential. Slow total factor productivity growth from the 1870s suggests that British technological capabilities at the end of the industrial revolution were still quite limited. he British industrial revolution was a landmark event in world economic T history. While it was once seen as a period of dramatic ‘take-off’, it is now generally accepted that it was an episode of gradual acceleration in labour productivity growth which eventually led to sustained increases in living standards. Even so, the unprecedented transition to modern economic growth which it entailed rightly continues to attract massive amounts of research effort, and the literature has evolved rapidly in recent years. Despite a considerable increase in the sophistication of analysis, important (and exciting) questions remain controversial. These include ‘why did productivity growth accelerate?’, ‘how soon did workers benefit from faster productivity growth?’, and ‘why did productivity growth experience a major slowdown as soon as the 1870s?’ Much progress has, however, been made and now is an opportune moment to take stock. This article will do so from a macro-economic vantage point informed by ideas from growth economics as well as economic history. Given the volume of research that has been produced, this will necessarily be a somewhat selective survey, which treats a few aspects in depth rather covering a wide terrain superficially. The article begins by setting out estimates of productivity growth derived from recent research and exploring them in a growth accounting framework. Given that the estimates of total factor productivity (TFP) growth in this period are underwhelming, it then proceeds by explaining why this is a plausible finding even though there were many famous inventions. It also explores the revised picture of sectoral growth rates that has emerged from recent research. It then reviews competing explanations for the move to faster productivity growth during the industrial revolution and the evidence for them. It also looks at the relationship ∗Author’s Affiliation: University of Sussex and University of Warwick. † I have received helpful advice and comments from Steve Broadberry, Morgan Kelly, Tim Leunig, Cormac Ó Gráda, John Styles, and John Turner. An anonymous referee made useful suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies. © Economic History Society 2021. Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. 2 NICHOLAS CRAFTS between productivity growth and real wage growth to develop some new insights into the standard of living debate. Finally, it considers why productivity growth soon declined from the rate achieved in the mid-nineteenth century at the end of the industrial revolution. The article’s main conclusions are as follows. First, improved estimates of labour quality and hours worked reinforce the conclusions of the revisionist literature of the 1980s that TFP growth during the industrial revolution was modest at least until the second quarter of the nineteenth century. Second, viewing labour productivity in terms of real GDP per hour worked highlights that there was a marked slowdown in productivity growth from the 1870s. This suggests that viewing the ‘climacteric’ as a post-1899 blip is seriously mistaken. Third, there has been much research on the hypotheses that improved productivity growth at the time of the industrial revolution was due to a ‘high-wage’ or an ‘enlightened’ economy. Neither is a fully persuasive hypothesis but viewing the industrial revolution through the lens of induced innovation in an economy with a responsive supply-side is attractive. Fourth, the pessimistic view of the impact of the industrial revolution on living standards fashionable in the last 20 years has gone too far. Slow real wage growth was a good outcome in the face of huge demographic pressure. I. Growth accounting estimates Growth accounting is a useful way to describe the proximate sources of economic growth.1 These are the growth of factor inputs (capital, labour, and land) weighted according to their importance in production and a residual contribution from TFP growth. The latter is often thought to represent the contribution of technological change but in practice will also reflect changes in efficiency and scale economies. If the industrial revolution is conceived as a great leap forward in technology with an economy-wide impact, then it might be expected that TFP growth would be very rapid, perhaps on a par with the rate achieved by the US around the mid-twentieth century.2 This would perhaps be the prior of T. S. Ashton’s famous (notorious?) schoolboy.3 The conventional growth accounting formula is: Y/Y = sKK/K + sLL/L + sNN/N + A/A (1) where Y is real GDP, K is capital, L is labour, N is land, and A/A is the rate of TFP growth which is obtained as a residual that balances the equation, while sK, sL,andsN are the factor shares of capital, labour, and land, respectively. This is the so-called ‘primal formula’ for the sources of growth but an equivalent so-called ‘dual formula’ can be derived as follows. The national income identity is: Y = πK + wL + rN (2) 1 For a detailed discussion of various refinements to and limitations of this technique as used in economic history, see Crafts and Woltjer, ‘Growth accounting’. 2 According to the estimates in Bakker, Crafts, and Woltjer, ‘Sources of growth’, tab. 3, American TFP growth peaked at 2.2% per year in 1960–73. 3 According to Ashton, Industrial revolution, p. 48, this schoolboy said that ‘a wave of gadgets swept over England’. © Economic History Society 2021 Economic History Review, 0, 0 (2021) UNDERSTANDING PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH 3 Tab l e 1 . Accounting for growth of real GDP: earlier estimates (% per year) Capital Labour Land TFP Real GDP contribution contribution contribution growth growth Feinstein 1760–1800 0.35×1.0 = 0.35 0.50×0.8 = 0.40 0.15×0.2 = 0.03 0.32 1.1 1800–30 0.35×1.4 = 0.49 0.50×1.4 = 0.70 0.15×0.4 = 0.06 1.45 2.7 1830–60 0.35×2.0 = 0.70 0.50×1.4 = 0.70 0.15×0.6 = 0.09 1.01 2.5 Crafts 1760–1800 0.35×1.0 = 0.35 0.50×0.8 = 0.40 0.15×0.2 = 0.03 0.22 1.0 1800–30 0.35×1.7 = 0.60 0.50×1.4 = 0.70 0.15×0.4 = 0.06 0.54 1.9 1830–60 0.35×2.5 = 0.88 0.50×1.4 = 0.70 0.15×0.6 = 0.09 0.83 2.5 Note: This table is constructed using the formula in equation 1. Sources: Feinstein, ‘Capital accumulation’, adjusted to 3-factor formula using land growth as in Crafts, British economic growth; Crafts, British economic growth with revisions based on Crafts and Harley, ‘Output growth’. where K is capital, π is the rate of profit, L is labour, w is the wage rate, N is land, and r is the land rental rate. So, taking logarithms and differentiating with respect to time: Y/Y = sK(π/π + K/K) + sL(w/w + L/L) + sN(r/r + N/N)(3) Rearranging equation 3 gives: Y/Y − sKK/K − sLL/L − sNN/N = sKπ/π + sLw/w + sNr/r (4) The left-hand side of equation 4 is the primal formula for TFP growth which is the rate of output growth minus the rate of growth of total factor inputs, while the right-hand side is the dual formula for TFP growth which is the sum of the factor-share-weighted factor rewards. Feinstein was an early exponent of growth accounting based on the primal formula in the context of the British industrial revolution. An adapted version of his estimates is reported in table 1.4 Also reported in that table are estimates based on the Crafts–Harley view of the industrial revolution. The main difference between them is that the latter found much lower growth of TFP in the 1800 to 1830 period compared with Feinstein. In turn, that mainly reflected a lower estimate of growth of real GDP based on a major revision of the earlier estimates made by Deane and Cole which Feinstein had used.5 Recently, the Crafts–Harley estimates of real GDP growth have been superseded by those of Broadberry et al., built up from the output side.6 Their work entails construction of new indices of real output for the agricultural, industrial, and services sectors which extend the coverage and improve the weighting of earlier estimates. Sectoral value-added weights are then used to obtain annual estimates of real GDP which had not previously been available. Broadberry et al. confirm that the earlier study by Deane and Cole, which deflated estimates of nominal income for benchmark years by an inappropriate price index, significantly overestimated 4 Feinstein, ‘Capital accumulation’. The dual formula was first employed by Antràs and Voth, ‘Factor prices’. 5 Deane and Cole, British economic growth. 6 Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton, and van Leeuwen, British economic growth. © Economic History Society 2021 Economic History Review, 0, 0 (2021) 4 NICHOLAS CRAFTS Tab l e 2 .
Recommended publications
  • Boston University Study Abroad London Economic Policy – a British Perspective CAS EC 364 a (Core Course) Spring 2016
    Boston University Study Abroad London Economic Policy – A British Perspective CAS EC 364 A (Core course) Spring 2016 Instructor Information A. Name Professor Parvin Alizadeh B. Day and Time Wednesdays and Thursdays (1.15-5.15pm). C. Location Prince Consort, 43 Harrington Gardens, SW7 4JU D. BU Telephone 020 7244 6255 E. Email [email protected] F. Office hours By appointment Overview Since the 1980s successive UK governments have legislated and implemented a series of market- oriented reforms designed to stop the long-term economic decline in the United Kingdom relative to her major trading partners in other industrialized countries. This course provides a microeconomic analysis of these reforms with a focus on aspects of privatization, deregulation of the labour market, trade performance, the UK relationship with the EU, and the current crisis in the Euro zone. The economic analysis includes comparisons, where appropriate, with other European Union economies and the United States. The course examines the roles of the market and government in determining policy outcomes. The level of microeconomics in the course is intermediate and assumes you have completed an introductory one or two semester course in microeconomics. On completion of the course, you should be able to integrate analytical and descriptive material to aid your understanding of the nature and causes of some key contemporary problems in modern advanced economies. In addition you will be familiar with the microeconomic policies used within the UK and have some knowledge of relevant source material. Teaching Strategy The course will be taught by the selective use of lectures and seminars.
    [Show full text]
  • Marshall Plan the Answer?
    The CAGE-Chatham House Series, No. 1, June 2012 Saving the Eurozone: Is a ‘Real’ Marshall Plan the Answer? Nicholas Crafts Summary points zz Renewed support for the view that austerity measures are not sufficient and that more robust policies to stimulate growth are required to help the eurozone, and especially southern Europe, survive its current crisis has triggered a debate about the merits of a ‘Marshall Plan for Europe’. zz Faster productivity growth in the euro periphery could help improve competitiveness, fiscal arithmetic and living standards; the main role of a real Marshall Plan would be to promote supply-side reforms that raise productivity growth. This would repeat the main achievement of the original Marshall Plan of 1948. zz A real Marshall Plan would have to work as a ‘structural adjustment programme’, in much the same way as its famous predecessor, namely by achieving reforms through strong conditionality in return for serious money. To be credible the funds would have to be committed, but only released when reforms had been implemented satisfactorily – similar to the deal that worked in the context of EU enlargement in 2004. zz The experience of the Gold Standard’s collapse in the 1930s suggests that seeking to keep the eurozone intact by imposing a ‘golden straitjacket’ on the policy choices of independent nation-states is not a viable option. This points to fiscal federalism with genuine democracy at the EU level as the long-run solution; a new Marshall Plan may not be a substitute for reforms of this kind, but it can certainly serve as a valuable complement.
    [Show full text]
  • Brexit Beckons: Thinking Ahead by Leading Economists of the European Union
    The 23 June 2016 Brexit referendum saw British voters reject membership Brexit Beckons: Thinking ahead by leading economists of the European Union. Now that a decision has been made, it is time to look forward and find the best solutions for the UK’s and the EU’s Brexit Beckons: future. This VoxEU eBook regroups the views of more than a dozen leading economists and specialists on a broad range of issues, from various Thinking ahead by perspectives. The topics include globalisation, trade policy, threats to the City, immigration, labour markets, implications for Ireland, the options for Scotland, and the effects on the rest of the EU. Given that the way forward is uncertain and talks may take years, the leading economists aim of this eBook is to provide a first take on the issues and options facing the UK and the EU. Edited by Richard E. Baldwin Centre for Economic Policy Research 33 Great Sutton Street A VoxEU.org Book London EC1V 0DX CEPR Press Tel: +44 (0)20 7183 8801 Email: [email protected] www.cepr.org CEPR Press Brexit Beckons: Thinking ahead by leading economists CEPR Press Centre for Economic Policy Research 33 Great Sutton Street London, EC1V 0DX UK Tel: +44 (0)20 7183 8801 Email: [email protected] Web: www.cepr.org ISBN: 978-0-9954701-0-1 Copyright © CEPR Press, 2016. Cover image by Jeff Djevdet, reproduced under the Creative Commons license. Brexit Beckons: Thinking ahead by leading economists Edited by Richard E. Baldwin A VoxEU.org eBook Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) The Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) is a network of over 1,000 research economists based mostly in European universities.
    [Show full text]
  • Top 5% Authors, Number of Downloads Through Repec Services Over the Past 12 Months, Weighted by Number of Authors, As of December 2017
    24.01.2018 Economst Rankngs, Number of Downloads through RePEc Servces over the past 12 months, Weghted by Number of Authors | IDEAS/… Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/ Top 5% Authors, Number of Downloads through RePEc Services over the past 12 months, Weighted by Number of Authors, as of December 2017 What this page is about This page is part of a larger set of rankings for research items, serial, individuals and institutions made available on this site. A FAQ is available. Additional detail specific to this particular ranking are: Only authors registered with the RePEc Author Service are considered. Only works listed on RePEc and claimed as theirs by registered authors are counted. Number of downloads in the past 12 months (January 2017-December 2017) from the various RePEc sites (IDEAS, EconPapers, Socionet, NEP). For details, see LogEc. The score of each work is divided by the number of authors. There are 51795 registered authors evaluated for all the rankings. Similar rankings Entity Full ranking Last 10 years 10 best authors Top 5% authors More Authors Short Details Short Details More Institutions Short Details Short Details Short Details All years Last 10 More Regions Short Details Short Details More Same ranking by institutions, countries and regions, and more rankings for authors, including the criteria used here. The rankings Rank Author Score 1 Jeffrey Marc Wooldridge 7630.92 Economics Department, Michigan State University, East Lansing, Michigan (USA) 2 Ben Jann 6521.58 3 Nicholas Cox 6186.5 4 Christopher F Baum 6047.7 Department of Economics, Boston College, Chestnut Hill, Massachusetts (USA) 5 Ilhan Ozturk 5162.8 İktisadi ve İdari Bilimler Fakültesi, Çağ Üniversitesi, Mersin, Turkey Joseph E.
    [Show full text]
  • The Solow Productivity Paradox in Historical Perspective
    THE SOLOW PRODUCTIVITY PARADOX IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE By Nicholas Crafts (London School of Economics) November 2001. Abstract A growth accounting methodology is used to compare the contributions to growth in terms of capital-deepening and total factor productivity growth of three general-purpose technologies, namely, steam in Britain during 1780-1860, electricity and information and communications technology in the United States during 1899-1929 and 1974-2000, respectively. The format permits explicit comparison of earlier episodes with the results for ICT obtained by Oliner and Sichel. The results suggest that the contribution of ICT was already relatively large before 1995 and it is suggested that the true productivity paradox is why economists expected more sooner from ICT. Funding from ESRC grant R000239536 is gratefully acknowledged. I am grateful to Bob Allen, Dudley Baines, Tam Bayoumi, Steve Broadberry, Bill Kennedy, Tim Leunig, Bill Martin, Mar Rubio, and Joachim Voth for constructive criticism. Earlier versions were presented to the conference "Long Term Trends in the World Economy", Copenhagen and to seminars at Cambridge, HM Treasury, LSE, Southampton and Universidade Nova de Lisboa where I have benefited from comments by participants. I am responsible for all errors. 1 1. Introduction Robert Solow's famous 1987 quip that "You can see the computer age everywhere but in the productivity statistics" still continues to provoke a great deal of research, although for the very recent past, at last, it no longer appears to be quite so apposite (Oliner and Sichel, 2000). For example, Triplett (1999) reviews no less than eight common 'explanations' for Solow's productivity paradox.
    [Show full text]
  • Gerben Bakker Associate Professor of Economic History Gerben
    Gerben Bakker Associate Professor of Economic History Gerben Bakker is an economic historian specialised in the long-run analysis of innovation within firms and industries. He has completed four award-winning research programmes on the history of the live entertainment, motion picture and music industries and on the trade in news. He is currently working on the long-run evolution of firms’ research and development outlays and on the role of particular industries in aggregate economic growth. CURRENT RESEARCH PROGRAMMES 1. Firms and Early-Stage R&D in Britain and the United States: A long-run perspective. 2. The industry origins of American economic growth, 1899-1941 (with Nicholas Crafts and Pieter Woltjer). COMPLETED RESEARCH PROGRAMMES 1. The industrialisation of the live entertainment industry between 1870 and 1940.*§• 2. The economic history of the motion picture industry.*†§• 3. The economic history of multinationals in the recorded music industry since 1945.†§• 4. The economic history of the trade in news facts from the Renaissance to the First World War.*†§ * = output(s) of these programmes have received major international academic prizes † = part of these programmes was included in research that was evaluated as ‘outstanding’ by the funders § = findings of these programmes have already been included as chapters in major handbooks • = output(s) of these programmes have been quoted in government and parliamentary policy documents IMPACT An Impact Case Study on the impact of the competed research programmes is available at: http://www.lse.ac.uk/researchAndExpertise/researchImpact/caseStudies/bakker-supporting- development-and-success-of-creative-industries.aspx CAREER Associate Professor, Department of Economic History, London School of Economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Bretton Woods, Brussels, and Beyond
    May 2018 Conventional wisdom holds that a main constraint to Brussels, and Beyond: Redesigning the Institutions of Europe Bretton Woods, reforming the European project is not a shortage of ideas or Bretton Woods, Brussels, of tools, but a lack of priorities. To put it differently, economists have discussed extensively what to do and how, but have and Beyond been broadly silent on who and when. Which institutions and rules are needed, and when? This eBook shows that such institutional questions, although seldomly raised, are Redesigning the Institutions of Europe of fundamental importance for the future of European integration. The individual chapters distil the lessons from the institutional framework underpinning Bretton Woods Edited by Nauro F. Campos and Jan-Egbert Sturm and the globalisation wave that followed it. For example, and accounting for its prominence, we ask whether a European Monetary Fund is sufficient or whether other institutions, rules, and agencies are needed, and if so, how these should be designed and implemented. ISBN 978-1-912179-14-5 Centre for Economic Policy Research A VoxEU.org Book 33 Great Sutton Street London EC1V 0DX CEPR Press Tel: +44 (0)20 7183 8801 CEPR Press Email: [email protected] www.cepr.org 9 781912 179145 Bretton Woods, Brussels, and Beyond Redesigning the Institutions of Europe CEPR Press Centre for Economic Policy Research 33 Great Sutton Street London, EC1V 0DX UK Tel: +44 (0)20 7183 8801 Email: [email protected] Web: www.cepr.org ISBN: 978-1-912179-14-5 Copyright © CEPR Press, 2018. Bretton Woods, Brussels, and Beyond Redesigning the Institutions of Europe Edited by Nauro F.
    [Show full text]
  • Annual Lecture
    Productivity at the periphery What can Wales do to compete? Julian Hodge Institute of Applied Macroeconomics Annual Lecture Nicholas Crafts Professor of Economic History, London School of Economics Thursday 21st April 2005 The Thistle Hotel, Park Place, Cardiff Nicholas Crafts is Professor Crafts publishes widely in the Professor of Economic professional journals such as The Economic History at the London Journal, Fiscal Studies and The World Economy. School of Economics His recent work includes “Globalization and (LSE). He joined the Economic Growth; an Historical Perspective”, LSE in 1995 from the British Academy Centenary Conference, 2002; University of Warwick, “Britain’s Relative Economic Performance, where he was the 1870-1999”, The Institute of Economic Affairs, Professor of Economic 2002; and “Can Europe Still Compete?”, The History for seven years. Before that he was a Human Resources Forum, 2004. Current research Fellow and Lecturer in Economics in the interests are comparative long term economic University College, Oxford from 1977-86, whilst growth, globalization in historical perspective, visiting Stanford University, California as productivity performance, and measurement of Professor of Economics in 1982-83. living standards. Julian Hodge Institute of Applied Macroeconomics In May 1999, Cardiff Business School and Julian the Economic Adviser to Julian Hodge Bank. The Hodge Bank announced a major new initiative, institute’s staff of researchers are mainly based in the establishment of the Julian Hodge Institute the school. Research activity in the area of for Applied Macroeconomics. The aim of the applied macroeconomics is already considerable; institute is to carry out research into the work on a variety of issues related to the topics behaviour of the UK economy, and to study in the new research will study has been published in particular its relationship with the other leading scientific journals and books.
    [Show full text]
  • Secular Stagnation: Facts, Causes and Cures Rates and Extraordinary Central Bank Manoeuvres
    e Six years after the Global Crisis, the recovery is still anaemic despite years of near-zero interest Secular Stagnation: Facts, Causes and Cures rates and extraordinary central bank manoeuvres. Is ‘secular stagnation’ to blame? Secular Stagnation: This eBook gathers the thinking of leading economists including Larry Summers, Paul Krugman, Robert Gordon, Olivier Blanchard, Richard Koo, Barry Eichengreen, Ricardo Caballero, Ed Facts, Causes and Cures Glaeser and a dozen others. A fairly strong consensus emerged on four points. • Secular stagnation (SecStag) means that negative real interest rates are needed to equate saving and investment at full-employment output levels. • The key worry is that SecStag will make it hard to achieve full employment with low Edited by Coen Teulings and inflation and financial stability using macroeconomic policy as it is currently structured Richard Baldwin and operated. • It is too early to tell whether secular stagnation is to blame, but uncertainty is not an excuse for inaction. Policymakers should start thinking about solutions; if secular stagnation sets in, today’s toolkit will be inadequate. • Europe has more to fear from the possibility of secular stagnation than the US, given its slower overall growth and its lack of pro-growth reforms and more constrained policy framework. The authors point to two classes of solutions: ‘Prevention’ (raising long-run growth potentials) and ‘symptomatic treatment’ (raising the inflation target to alleviate the zero lower bound problem, and using fiscal policy to
    [Show full text]
  • Nicholas Crafts
    Nicholas Crafts Current Employment: Professor of Economic History and Director of ESRC CAGE Research Centre, University of Warwick. Educated: Trinity College, Cambridge. First Class Honours, Economics Tripos, parts I & II, 1967-1970. Previous Employment 1971-2: Lecturer in Economic History, University of Exeter. 1972-7: Lecturer in Economics, University of Warwick (on leave 1974-6). 1974-6: Visiting Assistant Professor of Economics, University of California, Berkeley. 1977-86: CUF Lecturer in Economics, University of Oxford and Fellow in Economics, University College, Oxford (on leave 1982-3). 1982-3: Visiting Professor of Economics, Stanford University. 1987-8: Professor of Economic History, University of Leeds. 1988-95: Professor of Economic History, University of Warwick. 1995-2005: Professor of Economic History, London School of Economics. 2006-9: Professor of Economic History, University of Warwick. Honours Wrenbury Scholarship for Best Degree in Economics at Cambridge in 1970. Fellow of the British Academy, 1992. CBE, Queen’s Birthday Honours List, 2014. Major Grants 1992-3: 279,000 Ecus from European Commission to direct Research Network on Postwar Economic Growth, with G. Toniolo. 2001-5: £167,654 from Economic & Social Research Council for research on "Understanding the Effects of Different Generations of Large-Scale Technological Change", with T. Leunig. Project report graded "Outstanding" by ESRC. 2010-14: £3.6 million from Economic & Social Research Council for ESRC Research Centre on Competitive Advantage in the World Economy (CAGE). 2015-19: £3.47 million from Economic & Social Research Council for ESRC Research Centre on Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy (CAGE). Selected Publications British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution (Clarendon Press, 1985) Economic Growth in Europe since 1945 (Cambridge, 1996) edited with G.
    [Show full text]
  • Making Europe Great Again?
    Making Europe Great Again? Nicholas Crafts CAGE, University of Warwick February 2017 Preliminary version of paper presented to “Restoring Prosperity” Conference, Hoover Institution, Stanford University 1. Introduction Notwithstanding a few bright spots, notably including Ireland in its Celtic Tiger years, economic growth in Western Europe has been disappointing for the last 20 years. This is a far cry from the years of rapid catch-up growth during the so-called ‘Golden Age’ of the period 1950 to 1973 or even the robust labor productivity growth which continued until the mid 1990s. Years of slow growth prior to the financial crisis have been followed by the stagnation of recent years. Productivity growth, especially in Southern Europe, has been weak in most countries. Projections of future growth are in some cases quite pessimistic and suggest a future in which Europe, rather than resuming its catch-up, will actually fall further behind the United States. Table 1 reports some details of this picture. The decline over time in labor productivity growth in the EU15 from 4.9 per cent per year in 1950-1973, to 2.5 per cent in 1973-95 and 1.5 per cent in 1995-2007 is disappointing but the extrapolation of recent trends to show a further reduction to 0.8 per cent per year for the post-crisis period of 2014-23 made for the European Commission by Havik et al. (2014) is deeply unimpressive. Notably, it does not compare well with mainstream projections for the United States and would represent a return to 19th-century rates of advance.
    [Show full text]
  • The Contribution of New Technology to Economic Growth: Lessons from Economic History*
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by Universidad Carlos III de Madrid e-Archivo THE CONTRIBUTION OF NEW TECHNOLOGY TO ECONOMIC GROWTH: LESSONS FROM ECONOMIC HISTORY* NICHOLAS CRAFTS University of Warwick a ABSTRACT This paper reviews the analysis of technological change by cliometricians. It focuses on lessons about total factor productivity (TFP) from growth accounting and on aspects of social capability that are conducive to the effective assimilation of new technology. Key messages are that when TFP growth is very rapid this typi- cally involves reductions in inefficiency not just technological advance and that even really important new technologies have small initial effects on aggregate pro- ductivity. Incentive structures matter greatly for the adoption of new technology, but social capability is not independent of the technological epoch as the informa- tion and communications technology (ICT) era has emphasized to Europeans. Keywords: economic growth, growth accounting, social capability, technological change JEL Code: N70, O30, O40 RESUMEN Este artı´culo revisa el ana´lisis del cambio tecnolo´gico por clio´metras. Se centra en las lecciones acerca de la productividad total de los factores (PTF) * Received 21 December 2009. Paper based on presentation originally given as the Figuerola Lecture, Instituto Figuerola, Carlos III University, Madrid, October 2009. a Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry CV4 7AL, Warwick, UK. [email protected] Revista de Historia Econo´mica, Journal
    [Show full text]