Bellwether Consulting Market Recap 2020-06-30

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Bellwether Consulting Market Recap 2020-06-30 Your Quarterly Update on the Financial Markets June 30, 2020 Market Recap The US Economy: “Stocks Lap the Real Economy” The economic contraction for Q2 has yet to be measured, but Annualized Real GDP Growth there is a strong consensus that the number will be astound- ing. Among the more widely followed statistical models, the 6/15 6/18 3.5% 3/20 3.0% -5.0% Atlanta Fed’s GDPNow projection bottomed on June 4th with a 6/20 (e) Q2 annualized growth rate of -53.8%. That unofficial forecast -36.8% improved steadily through June, as data began to reflect both 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 gradual reopening activities and adaptive behaviors. Following the July 1st release of the ISM Manufacturing Report, the GDPNow model stood at -36.8%. No one knows where the final GDP number will land, but a few things are clear. First, an enormous amount of real value was destroyed by the initial COVID-19 shutdown. Second, that initial event appears to have found a trough at the end of May. However, threats remain from continued propagation of wave 1 through the southern, central, and western US, along with some US Institute for Supply Management (ISM) Indices major population densities worldwide. The probability of 6/20 57.1% subsequent waves remains considerable. 52.6% Against this backdrop, the US stock market posted torrid gains for the quarter, paring year-to-date losses to -3.08%. Index >50 = Expansion 4/20 41.8% Many have pointed out the disconnect, for which there are a 41.5% number of contributing explanations, but truly unprecedent- US Money Supply (M2) 4/20 +6.7% ed monetary expansion by the Federal Reserve is the prima- (Monthly % Change) ry cause. Fundamentally, the stock of a company is worth 5/20 +5.0% the present value of all future earnings of that company. Earnings are depressed now and in the foreseeable future – Previous record: January 1983 +2.8% Data through June 22nd but stock prices are also impacted by the discount rate used 6/20 (e) to translate future earnings to present value. The (some- +2.1% what) unintended consequence of monetary expansion is to 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 lower that discount rate, inflating the stock market. The mathematics of discounting determines how much in future earnings is recognized in today’s value and how much will be recognized in future years through additional returns. As the discount rate falls, more future earnings accrue to current shareholders. That’s particularly good for tech firms and other high-growth companies, who expect a greater pro- portion of their earnings to occur in the future. However, all other things being equal, a lower discount rate means that less future earnings will accrue to shareholders in subsequent years. In the long run, only real earnings matter. Said differently, you cannot create value by changing inter- Federal Reserve Survey Pre- and Post-Correction est rates, you can only alter how value is distributed be- 2020 Median Longer Run Median tween present and future investors. Valuation gains 12/19 6/20 ∆ 12/19 6/20 ∆ “borrowed” through rate reductions will be “paid back” Change in Real GDP 2.0 -6.5 -8.5 1.9 1.8 -0.1 through forgone returns in the future. In contrast, demand Unemployment 3.5 9.3 +5.8 4.1 4.1 0.0 destruction due to the pandemic represents a real, actual PCE Inflation 1.9 0.8 -1.1 2.0 2.0 0.0 loss of value. The Fed’s bet, apparently, is that the real im- Fed Funds Rate 1.6 0.1 -1.5 2.5 2.5 0.0 pact of the virus on growth and interest rates is temporary (note the lack of change in their long-term projections). Actual/Projected Real GDP Growth This suggests the best-case scenario for stocks is restora- 12/21 tion of real earnings growth (e.g., via a vaccine) accompa- 5.0% nied by rising rates in 2021 – which means most of the 12/14 12/19 Long Run value of a vaccine has already accrued to today’s share- 2.9% 2.3% 1.8% holders. With rates near zero, the ability to borrow addi- tional returns in the event of a contingency is limited. 12/20 -6.5% 2 MARKET RECAP June 2020 The US Bond Market th On May 7 , the 2-year key rate hit its new historical low of 3% US Treasury Yield Curve 0.13%. The previous low of 0.16% was set in September 2011, as markets began to accept a lower-for-longer outlook. The curve is now perfectly flat between the 3-month and 2-year ma- 2% turities, both closing the quarter at 0.16%. Longer-term rates retain a more normal slope, perhaps comforting those who place stock in the predictive power of an inverted curve. The 30-year 1% yield has held in there, resisting a Q2 push back towards its his- torical low of 0.99% set in March. By one perspective, the posi- tive slope and incrementally higher yield versus Q1 point to a 0% more optimistic economic outlook or resumption in risk appe- 3m 2y 5y 10y 30y tites. By a more honest perspective, there is little optimism in a 30-year rate that stands one-and-a-quarter percentage points lower than its prior historical low, established in 2008. With rates, as with the pandemic, there is no light yet at the end of this tunnel. US Bond Index Returns US government debt indices enjoyed positive, but modest gains for the quarter. Meanwhile, credit spreads contracted violently through the first week of June, continuing the trajectory Blmbrg Barclays 2Q20 set in the last week of March. AA spreads declined by nearly 100 bps. June brought some sta- Aggregate 2.90% Short Gov't 0.13% bility to fixed income markets, though high yield spreads widened moderately as signs of in- Interm. Gov't 0.55% creasing coronavirus infections emerged, AA corporate spreads traded below 1% throughout Long Gov't 0.28% the month. The Federal Reserve’s aggressive measures to restore liquidity seem to have had TIPS 4.24% the intended effect. Municipal 2.72% With a large number of “fallen angels” absorbed into below-investment-grade, high yield Interm. Credit 6.67% managers are having to study up on a lot of new names. Along with the spike in issuer credit Long Credit 11.08% downgrades, bankruptcy filings are piling up. Hertz, Gold’s Gym, Neiman Marcus, J.C. Penney, High Yield 10.18% Whiting Petroleum, and J. Crew are among the first major corporate casualties of the pan- (CS) Lev. Loan 9.71% demic. Investors face numerous pitfalls with various industries trading at steep discounts. MBS 0.67% Debt from any retailer is certainly suspect; many started underwater before drowning in the pandemic. However, homebuilders, retailers, lodging, oil producers, live entertainment, and many other industries are teetering as the pandemic draws on without end in clear sight. The common themes are manifold: those sensitive to the pandemic in the narrow sense of relying on foot traffic, in the broad sense of being sensitive to cyclical demand, or simply unable to tolerate such a massive interruption in their operations or supply chain. Outside of issuers that fall victim to those themes, plus the usual smattering of unrelated implosions, many companies have enjoyed a combination of tailwinds this year. Culling the herd in any industry can benefit the survivors. Restaurants that survive the pandemic will likely see demand return to normal before competition does. Retailers however may find the pandemic is simply a catalyst for their eventual demise, much like the Great Recession proved to be for newspapers. Fiscal and monetary stimulus has benefitted many companies that were impervious to, or even helped by, the pandemic. This year, investment grade corporate debt has been issued at more than double the pace of last year. A record of monthly high yield issuance came to market in June. The rise in supply has been driven by a confluence of liquidity needs from companies under stress, an apparent bottoming out in rates, and a resumption in risk appetites. The Secondary Market Corporate Credit Facility (SMCCF) Corporate Yields by Credit Quality started purchasing corporate bond exchange-traded funds AA BBB B 12.39% th (ETFs) on May 12 . In the first week, the SMCCF pur- 10.18% chased $1.6 billion of 15 different ETFs, about one-quarter 8.45% 6.74% of which was high yield. As of June 16th, the facility held 7.05% $6.8 billion in ETFs, with 12% being high yield. An update 3.87% to the program, as expected, expanded these purchases to 2.68% include individual corporate bonds starting June 16th. Only 2.74% 1.56% the first two days of transactions have been disclosed, and Jul-2015 Jun-2016 Jun-2017 Jun-2018 Jun-2019 Jun-2020 they totaled $429 million split among more than 80 issuers, with only 3% high yield. The SMCCF is designed to purchase up to $250 billion in debt, so it is just getting started. The doubly-large Primary Market Corporate Credit Facility (PMCCF) began its purchases on June 29th. 3 MARKET RECAP June 2020 The US Stock Market The US stock market continued its trend of record-setting quarters. US Stock Indices - Total Returns Propelled by unprecedented Fed asset purchases, the S&P 500, the Large-cap Stocks 2Q20 Mid-cap Stocks 2Q20 Dow Jones Industrial Average and the Nasdaq Composite all posted S&P 500 20.54% S&P Midcap 400 24.07% their best quarters in over 20 years amid a broad-based rally.
Recommended publications
  • The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction By
    “The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction” Speech given by Charles Bean, Deputy Governor for Monetary Policy and Member of the Monetary Policy Committee, Bank of England Given at the Schumpeter Lecture, Annual Congress of the European Economic Association, Barcelona 25 August 2009 I am grateful for the assistance of Adrian Penalver. The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of either the Bank of England or the Monetary Policy Committee. 1 All speeches are available online at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/default.aspx Summary Charles Bean, the Bank of England’s Deputy Governor, Monetary Policy, was invited to deliver the Schumpeter lecture at the Annual Congress of the European Economic Association. The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction, looks back at the causes of the financial crisis and subsequent recession. He argues that much of what went wrong can be analysed using standard economic tools. The Great Moderation was a period of unusually stable macroeconomic activity in advanced economies. This was partly thanks to good luck, including the integration of emerging market countries into the global economy, and partly a dividend from structural economic changes and better policy frameworks. The longer this stability persisted, the more markets became convinced of its permanence and risk premia became extremely low. Real short and long term interest rates were also low due to a combination of loose monetary policy, particularly in the US, and strong savings rates in a number of surplus countries. Low interest rates and low apparent risk created strong incentives for financial institutions to become highly geared.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tale of Two Great Crises
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Fratianni, Michele; Giri, Federico Working Paper The tale of two great crises FinMaP-Working Paper, No. 51 Provided in Cooperation with: Collaborative EU Project FinMaP - Financial Distortions and Macroeconomic Performance, Kiel University et al. Suggested Citation: Fratianni, Michele; Giri, Federico (2015) : The tale of two great crises, FinMaP-Working Paper, No. 51, Kiel University, FinMaP - Financial Distortions and Macroeconomic Performance, Kiel This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/125823 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu The Tale of Two Great Crises Michele Fratianni∗ Federico Giriy December 14, 2015 Abstract The great depression of 1929 and the great financial crisis of 2008 have been the two big events of the last 75 years.
    [Show full text]
  • What Is Past Is Prologue: the History of the Breakdown of Economic Models Before and During the 2008 Financial Crisis
    McCormac 1 What is Past is Prologue: The History of the Breakdown of Economic Models Before and During the 2008 Financial Crisis By: Ethan McCormac Political Science and History Dual Honors Thesis University of Oregon April 25th, 2016 Reader 1: Gerald Berk Reader 2: Daniel Pope Reader 3: George Sheridan McCormac 2 Introduction: The year 2008, like its predecessor 1929, has established itself in history as synonymous with financial crisis. By December 2008 Lehman Brothers had entered bankruptcy, Bear Sterns had been purchased by JP Morgan Chase, AIG had been taken over by the United States government, trillions of dollars in asset wealth had evaporated and Congress had authorized $700 billion in Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) funds to bailout different parts of the U.S. financial system.1 A debt-deflationary- derivatives crisis had swept away what had been labeled Alan Greenspan’s “Great Moderation” and exposed the cascading weaknesses of the global financial system. What had caused the miscalculated risk-taking and undercapitalization at the core of the system? Part of the answer lies in the economic models adopted by policy makers and investment bankers and the actions they took licensed by the assumptions of these economic models. The result was a risk heavy, undercapitalized, financial system primed for crisis. The spark that ignited this unstable core lay in the pattern of lending. The amount of credit available to homeowners increased while lending standards were reduced in a myopic and ultimately counterproductive credit extension scheme. The result was a Housing Bubble that quickly turned into a derivatives boom of epic proportions.
    [Show full text]
  • Lessons from the Great American Real Estate Boom and Bust of the 1920S
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LESSONS FROM THE GREAT AMERICAN REAL ESTATE BOOM AND BUST OF THE 1920S Eugene N. White Working Paper 15573 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15573 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2009 For their comments and suggestions, I would especially like to thank Lee Alston, Michael Bordo, Richard Grossman, Kris Mitchener, Carolyn Moehling, John Landon-Lane, Hugh Rockoff, Kenneth Snowden, Peter Temin, and the participants of seminars at Columbia University, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Free University of Brussels, the German Historical Institute (Washington, D.C.), the Harvard Business School, the NBER Summer Institute, Rutgers University, the Universitat Pompeu Fabra, the University of Oslo, and the XVth World Economic History Conference, Utrecht. The view expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2009 by Eugene N. White. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Lessons from the Great American Real Estate Boom and Bust of the 1920s Eugene N. White NBER Working Paper No. 15573 December 2009 JEL No. E5,G01,G18,G21,N12,N22 ABSTRACT Although long obscured by the Great Depression, the nationwide “bubble” that appeared in the early 1920s and burst in 1926 was similar in magnitude to the recent real estate boom and bust.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Market Bubbles and Crashes
    Financial Market Bubbles and Crashes One would think that economists would by now have already developed a solid grip on how financial bubbles form and how to measure and compare them. This is not the case. Despite the thousands of articles in the professional literature and the millions of times that the word “bubble” has been used in the business press, there still does not appear to be a cohesive theory or persuasive empirical approach with which to study bubble and crash conditions. This book presents what is meant to be a plausible and accessible descriptive theory and empirical approach to the analysis of such financial market conditions. It advances this framework through application of standard econometric methods to its central idea, which is that financial bubbles reflect urgent short side – rationed demand. From this basic idea, an elasticity of variance concept is developed. The notion that easy credit provides fuel for bubbles is supported. It is further shown that a behavioral risk premium can probably be measured and related to the standard equity risk–premium models in a way that is consistent with conventional theory. Harold L. Vogel was ranked as top entertainment industry analyst for ten years by Institutional Investor magazine and was the senior entertainment industry analyst at Merrill Lynch for seventeen years. He is a chartered financial analyst (C.F.A.) and served on the New York State Governor’s Motion Picture and Television Advisory Board and as an adjunct professor at Columbia University’s Graduate School of Business. He also taught at the University of Southern California’s MFA (Peter Stark) film program and at the Cass Business School in London.
    [Show full text]
  • Regulatory Reform and the Federal Reserve by Allan H. Meltzer the Allan H. Meltzer University Professor of Political Economy A
    Regulatory Reform and the Federal Reserve By Allan H. Meltzer The Allan H. Meltzer University Professor of Political Economy and Visiting Scholar at the American Enterprise Institute Testimony, July 9, Subcommittee on Monetary Policy, House Committee on Financial Services Thank you for the opportunity to present my appraisal of the administration’s proposal for regulatory changes. I will confine most of my comments to the role of the Federal Reserve as a systemic regulator and will offer an alternative proposal. I share the belief that change is needed and long delayed, but appropriate change must protect the public, not bankers. During much of the past 15 years, I have written three volumes entitled A History of the Federal Reserve. Working with two assistants we have read virtually all of the minutes of the Board of Governors, the Federal Open Market Committee, and the Directors of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. We have also read many of the staff papers and internal memos supporting decisions. I speak from that perspective. Two findings are very relevant to the role of the Federal Reserve. First, I do not know of any clear examples in which the Federal Reserve acted in advance to head off a crisis or a series of banking or financial failures. We know that the Federal Reserve did nothing about thrift industry failures in the 1980s. Thrift failures cost taxpayers $ 150 billion. AIG, Fannie and Freddie will be much more costly. Of course, the Fed did not have responsibility for the thrift industry, but many thrift failures posed a threat to the financial system that the Fed should have tried to mitigate.
    [Show full text]
  • Moral Hazard Misconceptions: the Case of the Greenspan Put∗
    Moral Hazard Misconceptions: the Case of the Greenspan Put∗ Gideon Bornstein Guido Lorenzoni Northwestern University Northwestern University December 2017 Abstract Policy discussions on financial regulation tend to assume that whenever a correc- tive policy is used ex post to ameliorate the effects of a crisis, there are negative side effects in terms of moral hazard ex ante. This paper shows that this is not a gen- eral theoretical prediction, focusing on the case of monetary policy interventions ex post. In particular, we show that if the central bank does not intervene by monetary easing following a crisis, an aggregate demand externality makes borrowing ex ante inefficient. If instead the central bank follows the optimal discretionary policy and intervenes to stabilize asset prices and real activity, we show examples in which the aggregate demand externality disappears, reducing the need for ex ante intervention. ∗For very useful comments we thank Eduardo Davila, Olivier Jeanne, the editor, and two referees. 1 1 Introduction Many economists and commentators have remarked that the conduct of interest policy by the central bank can affect the incentives of the financial sector. In particular, a com- mon complaint is that the so called “Greenspan put” encourages excessive leverage and risk taking by banks. The argument goes as follows. Suppose that when an adverse shock drives down asset prices, the central bank intervenes systematically by lowering interest rates. This becomes an implicit commitment to prop up asset prices in times of distress and encourages banks and other financial players to borrow more and take on more risk ex ante.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Bank Activism Duke Law Journal, Vol
    Central Bank Activism Duke Law Journal, Vol. 71: __ (forthcoming) Christina Parajon Skinner † ABSTRACT—Today, the Federal Reserve is at a critical juncture in its evolution. Unlike any prior period in U.S. history, the Fed now faces increasing demands to expand its policy objectives to tackle a wide range of social and political problems—including climate change, income and racial inequality, and foreign and small business aid. This Article develops a framework for recognizing, and identifying the problems with, “central bank activism.” It refers to central bank activism as situations in which immediate public policy problems push central banks to aggrandize their power beyond the text and purpose of their legal mandates, which Congress has established. To illustrate, the Article provides in-depth exploration of both contemporary and historic episodes of central bank activism, thus clarifying the indicia of central bank activism and drawing out the lessons that past episodes should teach us going forward. The Article urges that, while activism may be expedient in the near term, there are long-term social costs. Activism undermines the legitimacy of central bank authority, erodes its political independence, and ultimately renders a weaker central bank. In the end, the Article issues an urgent call to resist the allure of activism. And it places front and center the need for vibrant public discourse on the role of a central bank in American political and economic life today. © 2021 Christina Parajon Skinner. Draft 2021-05-27 20:46. † Assistant Professor, The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania. This article benefited from feedback provided by workshop or conference participants at The Wharton School, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York .
    [Show full text]
  • Lessons from the Great American Real Estate Boom and Bust of the 1920S
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LESSONS FROM THE GREAT AMERICAN REAL ESTATE BOOM AND BUST OF THE 1920S Eugene N. White Working Paper 15573 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15573 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2009 For their comments and suggestions, I would especially like to thank Lee Alston, Michael Bordo, Richard Grossman, Kris Mitchener, Carolyn Moehling, John Landon-Lane, Hugh Rockoff, Kenneth Snowden, Peter Temin, and the participants of seminars at Columbia University, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Free University of Brussels, the German Historical Institute (Washington, D.C.), the Harvard Business School, the NBER Summer Institute, Rutgers University, the Universitat Pompeu Fabra, the University of Oslo, and the XVth World Economic History Conference, Utrecht. The view expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2009 by Eugene N. White. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Lessons from the Great American Real Estate Boom and Bust of the 1920s Eugene N. White NBER Working Paper No. 15573 December 2009 JEL No. E5,G01,G18,G21,N12,N22 ABSTRACT Although long obscured by the Great Depression, the nationwide “bubble” that appeared in the early 1920s and burst in 1926 was similar in magnitude to the recent real estate boom and bust. Fundamentals, including a post-war construction catch-up, low interest rates and a “Greenspan put,” helped to ignite the boom in the twenties, but alternative monetary policies would have only dampened not eliminated it.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding the Greenspan Standard by Alan S. Blinder And
    Understanding the Greenspan Standard by Alan S. Blinder and Ricardo Reis Princeton University September 12, 2005 Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City symposium, The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the Future, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 25-27, 2005. The authors are grateful for helpful discussions with Donald Kohn, Gregory Mankiw, Allan Meltzer, Christopher Sims, Lars Svensson, John Taylor, and other participants at the Jackson Hole conference—none of whom are implicated in our conclusions. We also thank Princeton’s Center for Economic Policy Studies for financial support. I. Introduction Alan Greenspan was sworn in as Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System almost exactly 18 years ago. At the time, the Reagan administration was being rocked by the Iran-contra scandal. The Berlin Wall was standing tall while, in the Soviet Union, Mikhail Gorbachev had just presented proposals for perestroika. The stock market had not crashed since 1929 and, probably by coincidence, Prozac had just been released on the market. The New York Mets, having won the 1986 World Series, were the reigning champions of major league baseball. A lot can change in 18 years. Turning to the narrower world of monetary policy, central banks in 1987 still doted on money growth rates and spoke in tongues—when indeed they spoke at all, which was not often. Inflation targeting had yet to be invented in New Zealand, and the Taylor rule was not even a gleam in John Taylor’s eye. European monetary union seemed like a far-off dream. And the world-famous Jackson Hole conference was not yet world-famous.
    [Show full text]
  • The End of the Great Moderation
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive How better monetary statistics could have signaled the financial crisis Barnett, William A. and Chauvet, Marcelle University of Kansas 15 June 2010 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/24721/ MPRA Paper No. 24721, posted 31 Aug 2010 04:18 UTC How Better Monetary Statistics Could Have Signaled the Financial Crisis By William A. Barnett, University of Kansas and Marcelle Chauvet, University of California at Riverside June 15, 2010 ABSTRACT: This paper explores the disconnect of Federal Reserve data from index number theory. A consequence could have been the decreased systemic-risk misperceptions that contributed to excess risk taking prior to the housing bust. We find that most recessions in the past 50 years were preceded by more contractionary monetary policy than indicated by simple-sum monetary data. Divisia monetary aggregate growth rates were generally lower than simple-sum aggregate growth rates in the period preceding the Great Moderation, and higher since the mid 1980s. Monetary policy was more contractionary than likely intended before the 2001 recession and more expansionary than likely intended during the subsequent recovery. KEY WORDS: Measurement error, monetary aggregation, Divisia index, aggregation, monetary policy, index number theory, financial crisis, great moderation, Federal Reserve. JEL CLASSIFICATION CODE: E40, E52, E58, C43, E32 1. Introduction 1.1. The Great Moderation and the Current Crisis Over the past couple of decades, there has been an increasingly widely accepted view that monetary policy had dramatically improved. In fact, some attribute this as the cause of the “Great Moderation” in the economy‟s dynamics, by which output volatility had decreased substantially since the mid 1980s.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tale of Two Great Crises
    The Tale of Two Great Crises Michele Fratianni∗ Federico Giriy February 1, 2016 Abstract The great depression of 1929 and the great financial crisis of 2008 have been the two big events of the last 75 years. Not only have they produced serious economic consequences but they also changed our view of economics and policymaking. The aim of this work is to compare these two great crises and highlight similarities as well as differences. Monetary policy, the exchange rate system and the role of the banks are our fields of investigation. Our findings are that two big events have more similarities than dissimilarities. Keywords: Great Depression, Great Financial Crisis, gold standard, Eurozone, money multiplier, shadow banking. JEL classification : E5, E31, E42, G21. ∗Indiana University, Universit`aPolitecnica delle Marche and MoFiR, email:[email protected] yUniversit`aPolitecnica delle Marche, email: [email protected]. 1 I. Introduction The Great Depression of 1929-1933 (GD) and the Great Financial Crisis of 2008-2009 (GFC) have not only been colossal and worldwide events, but have challenged our \consensus" view of economics. Policymakers as well have had to learn new lessons and adopt, at times improvising, new strategies in response to events. The GD started 86 years ago and has been studied, interpreted and re-interpreted by an army of scholars. It never seems to go out of fashion. The GFC, being barely seven years old, cannot claim the pedigree of the GD nor its monumental literature. Yet, sufficient time has passed since 2008 to justify a comparative exercise, perhaps historically an early one, of the GD and GFC.
    [Show full text]