Working Paper No. 76 Taxation in Latin America in the Last Decade

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Working Paper No. 76 Taxation in Latin America in the Last Decade CENTER FOR RESEARCH ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND POLICY REFORM Working Paper No. 76 Taxation in Latin America in the Last Decade by Vito Tanzi* December 2000 Stanford University John A. and Cynthia Fry Gunn Building 366 Galvez Street | Stanford, CA | 94305-6015 * International Monetary Fund and Carnegie Endowment TO BE REVISED Taxation in Latin America in the Last Decade1 By Vito Tanzi2 Abstract This paper presents a broad view of progress and challenges in tax policy in Latin America, which, in the last decade, experienced a high degree of activism and several reforms and reform attempts. It first identifies the most influential factors affecting tax developments in the region: (i) The debt crises of the early 1980s reduced the ability to finance public spending through foreign borrowing and increased the costs of servicing the debt forcing. (ii) High inflation throughout the 1980s and early 1990s, eroded real tax revenues due to the collection lag, “the Tanzi effect.” (iii) Trade liberalization lowered tariff revenues. (iv) Capital account liberalization forced reductions in tax rates to maintain competitiveness. The main body of the paper is devoted to describing major tax policy developments. (a) The fall in trade taxes has been compensated by the rising importance of the Value-Added Tax (VAT). The VAT has become the workhorse tax in Latin America but there is still heterogeneity in its collection productivity. (b) With few exceptions, Latin American countries continue to have difficulties implementing income taxes, especially the individual income taxes. The paper then argues that fiscal needs have introduced interesting experimentation with new taxes and new approaches to taxation, such as the gross asset taxes, taxes on bank debits, and simplified regimes for small taxpayers. The paper also discusses achievements and reform challenges in tax administration. Finally, it concludes that although tax systems in Latin America have made important headway, improvements in tax equity, efficiency of tax administration, and obstacles posed by fiscal federalism remain important challenges that need to be overcome in the future. 1Paper prepared for the conference on "Fiscal and Financial Reforms in Latin America," held at Stanford University, on November 9-10, 2000. Valuable advice and assistance received from Carlos Silvani, Juan Toro, and Howell Zee was much appreciated. Asegedech Woldemariam was helpful in collecting some of the statistical information. 2 International Monetary Fund and Carnegie Endowment 1 I. INTRODUCTION Next to the weather, taxes must rank as one of the most discussed topics of conversation. This is true universally but it is especially true for Latin America which, in the last decade, has experienced a high degree of tax activism and several attempts aimed at reforming the countries' tax systems. Most governments have come into office promising to improve the tax systems to make them simpler to administer, easier to comply with, and more equitable. Most governments, however, have quickly resigned themselves to tinkering with the tax systems rather than truly reforming them. Strong political opposition to reform and administrative difficulties have been obstacles that governments have found difficult or even impossible to remove. Yet, as we shall show in this paper, gradually some important changes have taken place so that the tax systems of today are significantly different from those of a decade or more ago. Many of the Latin American countries that have faced macroeconomic difficulties and that have chosen to go to the IMF for Fund-supported programs have given particular importance to the objective of raising revenue. However, at times, this objective has been pursued or achieved at the cost of simplification or of equity improvement. Several Latin American countries have been only partially successful in raising the level of taxation in neutral and equitable ways. However, as we shall show, many countries succeeded in raising their tax levels. This paper will survey some of the major developments in taxation that occurred in Latin America over the last decade. Given the number of countries involved and the many changes that have taken place, only the most important changes can be discussed. Furthermore, more attention will be given to developments in larger countries. In Section II we identify the major factors that have influenced tax developments in Latin America. In Section III we identify major developments in tax systems. In Section IV we discuss distinctive features of the Latin American tax reform efforts. In Section V we discuss some developments in tax administration. Section VI draws some conclusions. II. MAIN INFLUENCES ON TAX DEVELOPMENTS Although most governments inherit tax systems that do not fully conform with their desires or goals, and that they would, thus, like to change, there are often more immediate or fundamental influences that at times force governments to take action. In this section we identify 2 the most important for the Latin American countries among these although, undoubtedly, there were additional factors or influences that, in particular countries, might have been as important. The Debt Crisis of the 1980s Perhaps the first influence worth mentioning is the Debt Crisis which started in Mexico in 1982 and spread to most other Latin American countries. The debt crisis reduced the ability of these countries to finance their public spending through foreign borrowing and, because of the increase in the cost of servicing the debt, it forced most Latin American countries to cut public spending or to increase the level of taxation. These countries were faced with the need to increase their primary surplus (the difference between ordinary revenue and non-interest expenditures) in order to service their debt. This situation, per se, would have created strong incentives for governments to increase the level of taxation especially when, for political or legal reasons, non-interest spending could not be reduced. As it was, capital spending was often reduced thus, in part, contributing to the reduction of the rate of growth through the 1980s but, more immediately, increasing the primary surpluses of these countries. The fact that many of these countries negotiated adjustment programs with the IMF exposed them to additional pressures to improve their fiscal accounts. The Fund often provided technical assistance in the tax area, assistance that aimed at strengthening the tax systems so that they would become more efficient. It is important to stress two points in this context. First, that Fund or no Fund the fiscal situation needed to be strengthened because of the macroeconomic situation. Thus, the argument often heard, that these countries were forced by the Fund to cut spending or increase taxes, ignores reality. Second, that whenever possible the Fund's advice was to strengthen the tax administration and to widen the tax bases, rather than simply to increase the rates or to cut expenditure as some Fund critics have argued. The Inflationary Context The Debt Crisis was accompanied by economic developments that had strong influences on the tax systems of these countries. One such development was inflation. Many factors contributed to inflation but, surely, inflationary financing of public spending (i.e., recourse to monetary expansion) must have been the most important. Throughout the 1980s and until the mid-1990s Latin America experienced strong inflationary pressures which in some countries 3 reached very high levels. In 1990, the average increase in the cost of living index for the Western Hemisphere reached 461.1 percent per year. In Argentina it reached 3080 percent in 1989. In Bolivia it reached almost 12,000 percent in 1985. In Brazil it reached almost 13,000 percent in 1990 and around 2,000 percent in 1993-94. In Mexico it reached 58 percent in 1985. The period after 1995 has seen much lower rates of inflation for most countries. When inflation reaches very high levels and the collection lags are significant, the positive impact of the "fiscal drag" on tax revenue is overwhelmed by the negative impact of what came to be called the Tanzi effect.3 This effect stipulates that the longer is the collection lag and the higher is the rate of inflation, the larger will be the proportional, negative effect on tax revenue. However, the absolute effect depends also on the initial level of the average tax ratio. The higher is the initial average tax ratio, the greater will be the absolute fall in tax revenue given the average collection lag for the whole tax system and the rate of inflation.4 Because income taxes generally have longer lags than other taxes, their relative contribution to total tax revenue generally falls during the period of inflation. The countries tried to react to the impact of inflation on their tax revenue by: (a) attempting to reduce the collection lags through administrative changes;5 (b) by relying more on taxes with shorter collection lags such as value-added taxes and excises; (c) by anticipating tax payments through withholding; and (d) in extreme cases (Brazil and Chile) by indexing the tax liabilities for the period of the lag. The indexation factor was supposed to reflect the rate of inflation over the period of the delay. Through this latter mechanism Brazil significantly reduced, but did not completely neutralize, the negative impact of inflation on its tax revenue. See Gianbiagi, 1987. The impact of inflation on the tax system was very important especially for high inflation countries such as Argentina, Bolivia, Nicaragua, Peru, and some others. While the acceleration of inflation until the early 1990 reduced the average tax ratios, the deceleration of inflation in the 3 The collection lag is the time that elapses between an event that creates a tax liability and the time when the government receives the payment. 4 For the technical details the reader is sent to Tanzi (1977 and 1989).
Recommended publications
  • Hyperinflation in Venezuela
    POLICY BRIEF recovery can be possible without first stabilizing the explo- 19-13 Hyperinflation sive price level. Doing so will require changing the country’s fiscal and monetary regimes. in Venezuela: A Since late 2018, authorities have been trying to control the price spiral by cutting back on fiscal expenditures, contracting Stabilization domestic credit, and implementing new exchange rate poli- cies. As a result, inflation initially receded from its extreme Handbook levels, albeit to a very high and potentially unstable 30 percent a month. But independent estimates suggest that prices went Gonzalo Huertas out of control again in mid-July 2019, reaching weekly rates September 2019 of 10 percent, placing the economy back in hyperinflation territory. Instability was also reflected in the premium on Gonzalo Huertas was research analyst at the Peterson Institute foreign currency in the black market, which also increased for International Economics. He worked with C. Fred Bergsten in July after a period of relative calm in previous months. Senior Fellow Olivier Blanchard on macroeconomic theory This Policy Brief describes a feasible stabilization plan and policy. Before joining the Institute, Huertas worked as a researcher at Harvard University for President Emeritus and for Venezuela’s extreme inflation. It places the country’s Charles W. Eliot Professor Lawrence H. Summers, producing problems in context by outlining the economics behind work on fiscal policy, and for Minos A. Zombanakis Professor Carmen Reinhart, focusing on exchange rate interventions. hyperinflations: how they develop, how they disrupt the normal functioning of economies, and how other countries Author’s Note: I am grateful to Adam Posen, Olivier Blanchard, across history have designed policies to overcome them.
    [Show full text]
  • World Bank Document
    Wps it &> POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER Wes-1267 Public Disclosure Authorized The Tax Base in Transition Economies in transition may be better off not imitating the The Case of Bulgaria tax structures of mature westernmarket economies Public Disclosure Authorized V Lower taxes and strong Zeljko Bogetic administration with well- Arye 1.. Hdiliman publicized penalties for evasion may be the best route to a broader, more equitable tax base that increases revenue without reducing incentives for private enterprise Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized The World Bank Europeand CentralAsia, Countrt DepartmentI Country Operations I Divixion March 1994 IPOLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1267 Summaryfindiings The transition from socialismcharacteri.tically reducts * Be simple,not complex or oversophisticated. existingtax revenuesat the same time that it increases * Be administrativelyimplementable with current the need for governmentspending. An increasingneed resources. for revenuecombined with an eroding tax basecreates a * Imposea low tax burden on all economicagents. transition-relatedfiscal gap and a challengefor tax * Rely on broad tax bases with minimumexemptions. policy. * Beginthe long-termimprovement of tax The solution,say Bogetil5andHillman, is not to lay a administration. heaviertax burden on new private firms. The issue is * Limitthe severityof tax penaltiesin the transition how to meet revenue needswithout inhibitingprivate from an authoritarian to a democraticregime. sector development.Large-scale tax evasionin the In theory, reduciaigthe cost of complianceand privatesector - the de facto outcome in Bulgariaand in increasingthe expectedcost of noncomplianceshould many other transitionaleconomies - may be a good reduce tax evasionand increasetax revenues.In practice, incentivefor developmentof private enterprise,but it is small businessesand self-employedcitizens tend to evade illegaland inequitableto wage-earnersand salaried taxes, providing an effectivezero tax base.
    [Show full text]
  • Taxable Capacity and Effort of Ghana's Value-Added Tax
    Andoh: Taxable capacity and effort of Ghana's value-added tax African Review of Economics and Finance | ISSN 2042-1478 | Volume 9 | Issue 2 | December 2017 Taxable capacity and effort of Ghana's value-added tax FRANCIS KWAW ANDOH Department of Economics, University of Dar es Salaam, Tanzania / Department of Economics, University of Cape Coast, Ghana [email protected] / [email protected] Abstract Value-added tax (VAT) has not only brought dynamism in Ghana’s revenue mobilisation landscape but also occupies a centre stage in the country’s fiscal consolidation efforts. Interestingly, the VAT regime has undergone a number of discretionary reforms in a bid to generate as much revenue as possible for its fiscal mandate. However, the trends show that VAT’s contribution to total tax revenue has consistently remained below 30 percent over the past one and a half decades. Could it be that the scope for further VAT revenue expansion is reaching its limit? This study uses the regression approach to estimate and examine the taxable capacity and collection efforts of Ghana’s VAT. The paper discovers that the VAT regime is characterised by both periods of underexploited and overexploited taxable capacities. However, on the whole, there appears to be little scope for further revenue expansion, given the existing base. The study, therefore, argues that the recent over concentration on VAT may endanger the country’s quest for fiscal adequacy. Consequently, an appropriate tax mix is highly recommended. JEL classification: H20; H25; E62; 017. Keywords: Tax effort; Tax capacity; VAT; Tax collection; Shadow economy. 255 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Taxation and Equitable Economic Development: a Historical Note*
    LATIN AMERICAN PROGRAM Taxation and Equitable Economic Development: A Historical Note* LATIN AMERICAN PROGRAM Vito Tanzi** Former Director, Fiscal Affairs Department, IMF November 2014 Introduction LATIN AMERICAN PROGRAM The end of World War Two was followed by the creation of the United Nations and the Bretton Woods Institutions (International Monetary Fund and World Bank). The United Nations established an office that was responsible for generating econom- ic statistics for member countries and which started producing, for the first time, comparable statistics on countries’ national and per capita incomes. Because of these statistics, economists and policymakers became fully aware of the enormous differences that existed, in per capita incomes and in standards of living—between rich and poor countries. They also became aware of the need to raise per capita incomes, especially in poor countries. The United Nations became a vocal champion of “growth” and “development.” Although the difference that exists *Paper prepared for presentation at the Fedesarrollo and Woodrow Wilson Center’s Conference on “Hacia una Nueva Reforma Tributaria,” Bogotá, Colombia, 28 August 2014. **The author has been Head of the Tax Policy Division (1974-81) and Director of the Fiscal Affairs Department (1981-2000) at the IMF, President of the International Institute of Public Finance (1990-94) and State Secretary for Economy and Finance in the Italian Government (2001-03). between growth (that lends itself more easily to measurement) and development (that does not) was always recognized and development was always considered the superior objective, growth became the key, operational objective in most dis- cussions. It was, however, understood that development required, as a major com- ponent, the participation of all classes in the growth process; in other words, the pursuit of growth could not ignore the way in which income was distributed.
    [Show full text]
  • World Bank Document
    P.ONYRsseweI / 5 WORKING PAPFRS CountrOpera LatinAmerica and the Caribbean CountryDepartment IV TheWorld Bank Septmber 1993 Public Disclosure Authorized WPS1192 Effects of Tax Reform on Argentina's Revenues Public Disclosure Authorized Jacques Morisset and Alejandro Izquierdo Public Disclosure Authorized In Argentina,changes in tax legislation,tax administration,and individualtaxpayers' attitudestoward tax evasion improvedtax Public Disclosure Authorized revenues.Here is a method to measurehow much. PaWyRRWaogPq tdiu=rnAfindiw.pinpui and i .dachngf idme Banamaffad &D1y*Airvew-ba.ldb.weudntuecbmy1dmbfWbnt8R.chinUAdeeu3iyOWmmLthiVdaCim so beanumW tot W=IdBDha ke BmdofDitZ. i mmgmormyof i4 aau,__mbw Country Opwldons WPS1192 This paper - a product of the CountryOperations Division, Latin Americaand the Caribbean,Country DepartmentIV - is part of a larger effort in the departmentto understandfiscal reforms in Argentina. Copiesof the paper are availablefree from the WorldBank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington,DC 20433. Please contactGerald Carter, room 16-020,extension 30603 (September1993, 23 pages). Too often, a good tax policy proposalis consid- * The admin;strativedimension of tax reform ered sufficientto improve the tax system- too is at the heart of Argentina's recent fiscal little consideraticiiis given to weaknessesin tax adjustment.Since 1991, tax effort is an average administration,perhaps because of measurement 80 percenthigher than during the preceding problems.Analyzing legal and administrative (temporary)successful adjustment period
    [Show full text]
  • Argentina, Brazil, and Peru
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Reform, Recovery, and Growth: Latin America and the Middle East Volume Author/Editor: Rudiger Dornbusch and Sebastian Edwards, eds. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-15745-4 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/dorn95-1 Conference Date: December 17-18, 1992 Publication Date: January 1995 Chapter Title: Stopping Three Big Inflations: Argentina, Brazil, and Peru Chapter Author: Miguel A. Kiguel, Nissan Liviatan Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c7663 Chapter pages in book: (p. 369 - 414) 12 Stopping Three Big Inflations: Argentina, Brazil, and Peru Miguel A. Kiguel and Nissan Liviatan 12.1 Introduction The recent hyperinflations in Argentina, Brazil, and Peru defy much of the widely accepted views regarding the origins and ends of hyperinflations. These “classical” views essentially state that hyperinflations have clear causes, excep- tionally large budget deficits financed by money creation, and are brought to a sudden end, through a comprehensive stabilization program. In addition, the stabilization is achieved without much cost in terms of growth and unemploy- ment. Sargent (1982) provides convincing empirical evidence for these propo- sitions based on the European hyperinflations in the midtwenties. The more recent hyperinflation and stabilization in Bolivia by and large conforms with this view.’ In contrast, in two of the more recent hyperinflations, Argentina and Brazil, the origins are less clear. Prior to the hyperinflation, deficits, while large, did not reach enormous proportions while seigniorage levels were not higher than in the previous two decades.
    [Show full text]
  • The Behavior of Poverty and Inequality in Brazil in the Last Forty Years
    The Behavior of Poverty and Inequality in Brazil in the Last Forty Years Theo Ribas Palomo, Bruno Kawaoka Komatsu, Naercio Menezes Filho Policy Paper | Nº 60 CENTRO DE GESTÃO E Julho, 2021 POLÍTICAS PÚBLICAS The Behavior of Poverty and Inequality in Brazil the in Last Forty Years Theo Ribas Palomo Bruno Kawaoka Komatsu Naercio Menezes Filho Theo Ribas Palomo Insper Instituto de Ensino e Pesquisa Cátedra Ruth Cardoso Rua Quatá, nº 300 04546-042 – São Paulo, SP – Brasil [email protected] Bruno Kawaoka Komatsu Insper Instituto de Ensino e Pesquisa Cátedra Ruth Cardoso Rua Quatá, nº 300 04546-042 – São Paulo, SP – Brasil [email protected] Naercio A. Menezes Filho Insper Instituto de Ensino e Pesquisa Cátedra Ruth Cardoso Rua Quatá, nº 300 04546-042 – São Paulo, SP – Brasil [email protected] Copyright Insper. Todos os direitos reservados. É proibida a reprodução parcial ou integral do conteúdo deste documento por qualquer meio de distribuição, digital ou impresso, sem a expressa autorização do Insper ou de seu autor. A reprodução para fins didáticos é permitida observando-se a citação completa do documento. The Behavior of Poverty and Inequality in Brazil the in Last Forty Years Theo Ribas Palomo Bruno K. Komatsu † Naercio Menezes-Filho ‡ Abstract This paper documents the evolution of poverty and inequalities over the last four decades using consistent data from the Brazilian Household Surveys (PNADs). We show that poverty declined substantially over the period, because of growth, economic stabilization, education and the minimum wage. We then describe the behavior of inequality, focusing on three income strata: the poor, middle class and the rich.
    [Show full text]
  • The Austral Plan
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Developing Country Debt and Economic Performance, Volume 2: The Country Studies -- Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Mexico Volume Author/Editor: Jeffrey D. Sachs, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press, 1990 Volume ISBN: 0-226-73333-5 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/sach90-1 Conference Date: September 21-23, 1987 Publication Date: January 1990 Chapter Title: The Austral Plan Chapter Author: Rudiger Dornbusch, Juan Carlos de Pablo Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c8927 Chapter pages in book: (p. 91 - 114) 91 ArgentindChapter 5 inevitable because the inflation tax, with sufficient financial adaptation, can be almost entirely evaded and hence the budget deficit cannot be financed. The Olivera-Tanzi effect, the shortening of contracts, and financial adaptation all react in a perverse way (from the point of view of stabilization) in that they widen the deficit and accelerate explosively the inflation process. 4.4 Concluding Remarks: Why Stabilization Is Difficult The preceding discussion has an immediate bearing on the fact that stabiliza- tion is difficult and, more often than not, takes more than one attempt to succeed. In the process of high inflation all institutions melt. When stabilization is undertaken, there is neither immediate, spontaneous resumption of longer adjustment periods for wages and prices, nor an instant increase of real money demand to noninflationary levels. As a result, more sizable adjustments in the budget are required and more dramatic measures are necessary to create the confidence that stabilization will last.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Fiscal and Monetary Policies in the Brazilian
    The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 62 (2016) 41–55 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/qref The role of fiscal and monetary policies in the Brazilian economy: Understanding recent institutional reforms and economic changes José Roberto Afonso a,b,∗, Eliane Cristina Araújo c,d, Bernardo Guelber Fajardo e a Brazilian Institute of Economics at Getulio Vargas Foundation (FGV-IBRE), Brazil b Brasiliense Institute of Public Law (iDP), Brazil c State University of Maringá (UEM), Brazil d National Council for Scientific and Technological Development (CNPq), Brazil e Brazilian School of Public and Business Administration (EBAPE/FGV), Brazil article info abstract Article history: Monetary and fiscal institutions have played a decisive role in the stabilisation of the Brazilian economy Received 22 July 2015 since the mid-1990s. In Brazil institutional reforms were predominantly made in response to a succession Received in revised form 15 July 2016 of internal and, particularly, external crises. Brazil’s experience of designing and managing institutions Accepted 19 July 2016 to this end is likely to be of interest to other emerging and low- or middle-income economies. As such, Available online 28 July 2016 the Brazilian experience offers many lessons to be learned, both in the sense of what could be done and what is better avoided. JEL classification: © 2016 The Authors. Published by Elsevier Inc. on behalf of Board of Trustees of the University of 5.005: E5 – Monetary Policy, Central Illinois. This is an open access article under the CC BY license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/ Banking, and the Supply of Money and 4.0/).
    [Show full text]
  • Comparative Analysis of the Value Added Tax (VAT) and Retail Sales
    Value Added Tax (VAT) and Retail Sales Tax (RST): A Comparative Analysis on the Two Tax Methodologies in the U.S. Marcos Aurélio Pereira Valadao Resumo: O artigo aponta as diferenças entre o imposto sobre o valor agregado (IVA) e o imposto sobre vendas no varejo (IVV), considerando a possibilidade da adoção de um imposto sobre o consume na esfera federal nos Estados Unidos da América (EUA), e suas repercussões nacionais e internacionais. Tanto o IVA quando o IVV são tributos indiretos sobre o consumo, que podem ser cobrados de diversas maneiras com diferentes conseqüências legais e econômicas. Primeiramente o artigo distingue as diferenças entre imposto sobre a renda e imposto sobre o consumo considerando os seus aspectos mais importantes (cobrança, lançamento, origem ou destino, tributação de serviços, alíquota zero, imposição federal, estadual ou local, aspectos e auditagem e cumprimento da legislação). O artigo então discute esses aspectos para fazer uma análise das vantagens e desvantagens do IVA e do IVV, assumindo a possibilidade de implementação de tributação indireta sobre o consumo nos EUA. Ao final, o artigo conclui que a melhor opção é o IVA, e mesmo que o IVA não vá substituir o imposto sobre a renda ou outro imposto qualquer, o IVA deveria ser implementado deforma a aumentar a eficiência do sistema tributário por permitir que o Governo simplifique as outras formas de tributação (e também diminuendo as alíquotas) Empregando mais modalidades tributárias, o Governo pode simplificar cada tipo de tributo individualmente. Palavras-chaves: Imposto sobre valor agregado. OVA. Imposto sobre vendas no varejo. Reforma tributária. Simplificação do sistema tributária.
    [Show full text]
  • Ability to Pay Principle 66, 71, 95, 159 Ad Rem Tax 159 Administrative Costs
    JOBNAME: Tanzi PAGE: 1 SESS: 3 OUTPUT: Thu Feb 22 13:11:06 2018 Index ability to pay principle 66, 71, 95, capital 8, 17 159 capital accumulation 93, 94 ad rem tax 159 capital incomes 56, 68 administrative costs 29, 102 capital–labor ratio 55 agents of tax complexity 31 capital mobility 63 digression on lobbies 32–5 capital output ratios 94 Alliance for Progress 116 carried trade 55, 56 American Economic Association 48 “Center for Environmental Innovation Anglo-Saxon countries 56, 68, 69 in Roofing” 34 Annual Report to Congress 2005, ceteris paribus 101, 119, 148, 155 39 Chicago School 84 Australia 36–8, 40, 41 class warfare 70 Australian federal tax system 37 classical economics 14 Avi-Yonah, Reuven 77 Coase, Ronald 15 Cobham, Alex 77 Bakija, Jon 41, 165 collection lags 87 bank share price 62 command economy 15 bankers 69 commons 20 banking secrecy 78 compensating value added tax (CVAT) basic commodities 14 162 Becker, Gary 31, 35, 37 competence 113 Belgium 16, 23, 81, 148 complex tax system 39 benefit received principle 98, 157 compliance costs 29, 36, 41, 42, 102, “The Best Laws Money Can Buy” 126 34 compliance, regressive nature 40 “Beveridge Report” 17 Congressional Budget Office 56, 69 Bird, Richard 162 Congressional Joint Committee on Bloomberg News 66 Taxation 57 bonuses 61, 62, 69, 99 Cornia, Giovanni Andrea 123 Boskin, Michael 52, 56 corporate income tax 118 British tax system 37 cost–benefit evaluation 102 Brittan, Samuel 26 crony capitalism 60, 75 Buchanan, James 30, 84 cross-country trade 19 bureaucrats 28 cross institutional externalities 97 bursting bubbles, tax effect 87, 91 debts 85 “Can Complexity Unmake deflation 83 Civilization?” 26 democratic deficit 137, 143 Canada 23, 38, 90 democratization 132 169 Vito Tanzi - 9781788116879 Downloaded from Elgar Online at 09/30/2021 06:58:11PM via free access Columns Design XML Ltd / Job: Tanzi-Ecology_of_tax_systems / Division: Index /Pg.
    [Show full text]
  • Corruption, Complexity and Tax Evasion* by Vito Tanzi**
    Corruption, Complexity and Tax Evasion* By Vito Tanzi** *Paper written for presentation at the “Tax and Corruption Symposium”, Organized by the UNSW Business School, Sydney, 19-20, April, 2017. ** Vito Tanzi, an economist, is Honorary President of the International Institute of Public Finance. He served as Head of the Tax Policy Division and as Director of the Fiscal Affairs Department at the International Monetary Fund. He was also Undersecretary for Economy and Finance in the Italian Government and President of the International Institute of Public Finance. 1 I. Introduction Corruption is an old human activity. References to it go back thousands of years. In the distant past, corruption had not always been considered an illegitimate or undesirable activity, and some modern societies continue to be relatively indifferent, or at least more tolerant, of it than others. It was during the high days of the Roman Republic, when a modern legal system started to be created, that made corruption an undesirable and illegitimate activity. Centuries later, Dante, the great, Italian, medieval poet, in his literary masterpiece, Inferno, would place corrupt people in the deepest and most painful levels of Hell. The term comes from the Latin verb “to break”, because it is assumed that corruption breaks some widely accepted norms. The term seems to have entered the English language at about Dante’s time, in the 13th-14th Centuries. A few centuries later, the American Constitution made corruption, together with treason, one of two explicitly - mentioned crimes that could lead to the impeachment of an American president. Over the years there have been various and different definitions of corruption, some more morally- based and some more legally-based than others.
    [Show full text]