THE Law of Difgnishihg RETURNS in THEORY and HRACTICE of -T- V

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

THE Law of Difgnishihg RETURNS in THEORY and HRACTICE of -T- V ,;V- J.H. BURNS m THE lAW OF DIfGNISHIHG RETURNS IN THEORY AND HRACTICE Of -t- V .. I /, .r Cam. ecsonomic laws be classed vrith scientific lavTS? The answer is no, just as we must answer in. the negative any svich question, ast la economics a science? There is, after all, no such thing as an excep tion to a scientific law; whereas half the difficulty in understand ing the laws of political econonrr lies in the consideration of excep tions, modifications and qualifications. Even in the unreal psexjdo- scientific atmosphere of pure theory these exceptions beset tis» How much worse are they when we attempt to apply the theoretical prin ciples to the actual facts. But these difficulties need not make us doubt the usefulness of economic laws. If we forget the attempted "scientificization" of ec onomics, if we forget to call these principles "laws" at all, and rather regard them as statements of general tendencies, we shall find solid practical truth embodied in them. In the particular instance imder discvission, there are other dif ficulties off phraseology: •jpirst, "retvim" is apt to convey the idea of monetary profit, Ifhile in fact what is meant is the amount of pro duce in proportion to the productive power applied. Secondly, there is the all-inportant word diminishing. To attempt to give a final statement of the law would be most difficult, but it majr be noted here that retijms are said to diminish in that they don not increase in pro portion to the amount of labour and capital applied. In dealing with the theory of diminishing returns, it seems ad visable to consider not only the j^rinciple, •v#iich has remained essent ially the same, but its history, and the way in which various auth ors have dealt with it. At first sight, nothing seems to be more easily placed in hist ory than the law of diminishing returns. It seems to appear quite suddenly about 1814, a time when controversy about agricultural mat ters was rife. But in his "Review of Economic Theory" Gannan quotes from a little-knovm work by Turgot, which enunciates the idea; again, Marx, in one of the bully footnotes to "Das Kapital" says the law was first published by James Anderson in the time of Adam Smith; and in his recently published "English Economic History mainly since 1700", C.R. Pay speaks of the law's being foreshadowed in a Royal Societjr questionnaire of 1664i. He goes on to say; "In 1814-15 Maithus, Ricardo and Edward West made the three- cornered pronouncement^rom which it is usual to date the laws of rent and diminishing returns in agricultmre. .. .and it is symptomatic of the imscientific natire of economics itself that this trinity disputed for priority in the discovery of something wiiich derives plainly from a queationnaire of 150 years back." Nevertheless, it can truly be said that the lav/ was not estab lished as a definite part of economicc "S-octrine till the time of the aforesaid "trinity". Por one thing, yhe phrase "law of diminishing ret urn" was coined by Edward West. And with Ricardo, we find practically all that coxald be said on the law of diminishing returns in agricult- \u?e. What Ricardo said was practically what John Stuart Mill said after him, and indeed, as far as agricultiire is concerned, -vi^at every % one h.as ) one has said since. The statement was quite simply that lander static coiaditions and ai'ter a certain point, additional units of pTOducti^e power applied to land, or additional areas of land taken under cult ivation would yield a diminishing ret\ma. On the other hand, under what we now call dynamic conditions, this law does not apply. That is, improvements in agrictilture, or, as Mill said in a characteristic phraae, "the progress Of civilisation", may make increased returns possible - but only for a time. That was, and in all essentials is, the theory. Ricardo enunc iated it coiTiT^letely, and Hill repeated it at much greater length, add ing little new material except his famous dictum to the effect that the law was the most impottant in political economy. Its practical applic ations and truth m'ust be discussed at a latei- stagej meanwiiile we muist follow the extension of the idea beyond tlie agricultural field. Mill, as has been said, added nothingt to the principle as applied to agricvilture. But he did fa.ce up to another aspect of the problem — the question oil diminishing returns in mining and other industries. Ricardo indeed included in his "Principles" a short chapter on the rent of mines; but he mad.e no definite statement about the returns ffom min It" ^; ing. The Classical School regarded mining as cognal-e with aigriculture, since both TOre concerned directly with the produce of the earth. This parallel is by no means exact. But Mill's remarks about mines are sound: He says, in effect that returns to minig diminish even more rap idly than in farming, but that improvements talce place to a greater deg ree. Yfith regard to manufactures. Mill believed that as much of their Vaw material is derived from agriculture, vdiich is sub.iect to dimin- Jibing returns, they also must be subject to that principle. That is not perhaps a well-founded argument. But he goes on to say that im- provements take place to such an extent in industry that the forces in- to diminished returns are far more than balanced by those tend- i ng ;o increased returns. Tnese views of the law of diminishing returns in agriciolture and industry have been held almost consistently since the days of Mill. But modern theorists have in some cases been more dogtaatic about the principle's application to manufactixres. Both Carman and Seli^nan, for instance, regard the law as universal: the first because of his idea of a point of ma:?:im'um returns in all industries, beyond which, ex h-gpothesj, returns will diminish; And the second because he relates the law of diminishing r'etums to the universal law of diminishing utility. On the whole it is perhaps most accurate to regard the law as a tendency which sooner or later operates in all industries, under static conditions. Practical consmderations oblige us to CaJce the law as a tendency, and it is these that must now be discussed. ¥e may ask first vdiether actual agricultural experience bears out the idea of diminishing returns to additional units of productive poiver. And the natural inclination is to fall back on reductio ad absurdum, sayingt the principle is obviously true in practice because otherwise no farm need be increased beyond one acre; this area, with sufficient productive powei- appdied, would, produce all that was necessary. Birt on consideration, roductio ad dbnurdun But on consideration, reductio ad absurdum seems, as always, an unfaif nuBthod of resoning. It is based on carrying a thing to its log ical conclusion - a dangerous practice* Apart from such unrealities, how. ever, experience shows the f'undaraental truth of the law of diminish ing returns. I say experience, not experiment, PolT thou^ experiments in this subject have been made at Rothamsted ans elsewiiere, thes$ in my opinion. Are just as far removed from reality as the ratiocinations of theor ists, Experimental farming is not, cannot be, normal practical farm ing, It may become so in the futmre, but it can tell us nothing of ex isting conditions, ¥/hen we turn to these everyday conditions, we find one fact of enormous importance: It has been stated that experience bears out the law, but this fact must al?/ays be bome in raind - the law applies only \mder statie conditions. And in the long run, conditions are not stat ic but dynamic. For example, a century and a iquarAer ago itjwas quite clear to all save the pessimistic political economists thatretums to British agriculture inthe preceding century had not dimini^ed but greatly increased. Only a little consideration sufficed to demonstrate the absurdity of any such idea as that the law of diminishing returns had been "in force" from the dawn of civilization; and Mill eagerly dis sociated himself from this notion. On the other hand, the qualification that conditions must be static is far from invalidating the general idea of the law. Dynamic con ditions do indeed prevail on the long view; but improvements in agri culture do not in general take place rapidly or at frequent inter vals, and there are, as a result, many periods when conditions may be taken as static. It is in such static and compscratively short periods that we find the law of diminishing returns to be a practical truth. It is quite clear, for example, that British farmland could be more intensively cultivated than it actually is. The devotion of the Chinese peasant to "the good earth" and the almost incredible care with which he tills it are -well-known phenome na. And naturally, if the same care were bestopred on British land, the amounjr of produce would be vastly increased. But in fact such care is not besto-wed on our land, and for an excellent reason - it would not be profitable. Why then is it profitable for the Chinese peasant? The ans-wer to this lies in the fundamental difference bet-ween the Chinese and the British farm. The ordinary Ohinese farmer is producing his own food - he is carrying on subsistence agric\ilt-ure. The ordinary British farm, on the other hand,, is a profit-making concern (or at least a concem that attempts to make profit), Tjp,us the Chinaman, vdiose holding of laM is small, but whose family isgenerally large, and -whose requirements in food, even -with a low living-standard, are consequently large also, must cult ivate his land intensiveljr (and it may be noted that the extensive principle also applies —all land, if accessible, must be usedj^ no mat ter how infertile it is),The British farmer, on the contrary, -will only expend on his land just as moh as he hopes to be able to recover by selling the produce.
Recommended publications
  • The Ricardian Law of Diminishing Returns. a Ew Interpretation
    The Ricardian Law of Diminishing Returns. A ew Interpretation . Leveraging productivity to drive globalization. Lucy Badalian — Victor Krivorotov 11501 Maple Ridge Rd Reston VA 20190 Millennium Workshop, USA [email protected] Abstract . The 2009 IMF report found notable differences between the pre- and post-1985 busts in their ratios of capital/labor. According to historical trends it cited, the recent extreme financialization may cloud our mid-term recovery prospects. The Market Pendulum Model (further MPM) stresses the importance and fluidity of interrelationship between traditional factors of production: land, labor, capital and entrepreneurship. MPM shows the difference between productivity-factors during demand shocks, such as today, and supply shocks (the 1970s-80s). It traces the causal roots of the financialization in market’s compensation for failing fundamentals, the direct result of the Ricardian Law of Diminishing Returns (further RLDR). Keywords : Ricardian Law of Diminishing Returns, financialization, financial crisis, demand shocks/demand shortages, supply shocks/supply shortages, ratio of capital/labor. JEL codes: E1, E20. E5, E6. 1. Introduction. The Interrelationship between Various Factors of Production as a Potential Predictive Tool. The October 2009 report of the IMF showcased the importance of the hitherto under- researched area of the inter-relationship between factors of production, which, in its opinion, holds significant predictive power as to the length and severity of the unfolding recession. It found that the growth in productivity since 1985 was accompanied by a rapid rise in the ratios of capital to labor. Earlier research noted other specific patterns of labor productivity. Among them, the wavelike behavior of multifactor productivity growth, which peaked in 1928-50 and slowed gradually, both when moving back to 1870-91 and forth to 1972-96 (Gordon 2004).
    [Show full text]
  • MARGINAL PRODUCT of LABOR and CAPITAL Assume Q = F(L, K) Is the Production Function Where the Amount Produced Is Given As a Func
    MARGINAL PRODUCT OF LABOR AND CAPITAL Assume Q = f(L, K) is the production function where the amount produced is given as a function of the labor and capital used. For example, for the Cobb-Douglas production function Q = f(L, K) = ALa Kb. Q For a given amount of labor and capital, the ratio is the average amount of production for one unit of K capital. On the other hand the change in the production when the labor is fixed and the capital is changed from K to K + ∆K is ∆Q = f(L, K + ∆K) − f(L, K). Dividing this quantity by ∆K gives the change in the production per unit change in capital, ∆Q f(L, K + ∆K) − f(L, K) = . ∆K ∆K Usually, we take the limit with infinitesimal changes in capital, or taking the limit as ∆L goes to zero we get ∂Q , ∂K which is called the marginal product of capital. The term “marginal” is used because it measures the change of production with a small change of capital. In the same way, ∂Q , ∂L which is called the marginal product of labor. For the Cobb-Douglas production function ∂Q b Q = b A La Kb−1 = and ∂K K ∂Q a Q = a A La−1 Kb = . ∂L K Thus, for the Cobb-Douglas production function, the marginal product of capital (resp. labor) is a constant times the average product of capital (resp. labor). These marginal rates depend on the units used for measuring the quantities. The ratio of the amount of change to the amount held does not depend on the units, ∆Q/Q, and can be interpreted as the “percentage change” of the quantity.
    [Show full text]
  • Medium-Term Determinants of Oecd Productivity
    OECD Economic Studies No . 22. Spring 1994 MEDIUM-TERM DETERMINANTS OF OECD PRODUCTIVITY A . Steven Englander and Andrew Gurney TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction ................................................ 50 1. Recent perspectives on productivity growth .................... 51 A . Investment and physical capital .......................... 52 B. Infrastructure capital .................................. 56 C . Education and human capital ........................... 57 D . Research and development (R&D) ....................... 61 E . Trade and competition ................................. 61 F. Cyclical influences on medium-term growth ................. 64 G . Energy, demography, labour market unrest. regulation ........ 66 H. Rent-seeking and structural rigidities ...................... 66 1 . Review of selected empirical work ....................... 67 II. Empirical analysis of OECD productivity growth ................. 69 A . Aggregate analysis ................................... 69 B. Industry level analysis ................................. 81 111. Policies to promote productivity growth ....................... 87 A . General considerations ................................ 87 B. Specific policy options ................................. 89 Bibliography ................................................ 95 Annex 7: Simultaneity bias in estimating the contribution of infrastructure to productivity growth ................................ 99 Annex 2: Applying new growth regressions to the OECD ............ 101 Annex 3: Industry aggregations:
    [Show full text]
  • Are There Diminishing Returns to R&D?
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Madsen, Jakob B. Working Paper Are there Diminishing Returns to R&D? EPRU Working Paper Series, No. 2006-05 Provided in Cooperation with: Economic Policy Research Unit (EPRU), University of Copenhagen Suggested Citation: Madsen, Jakob B. (2006) : Are there Diminishing Returns to R&D?, EPRU Working Paper Series, No. 2006-05, University of Copenhagen, Economic Policy Research Unit (EPRU), Copenhagen This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/82093 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu EPRU Working Paper Series Economic Policy Research Unit Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Studiestræde 6 DK-1455 Copenhagen K DENMARK Tel: (+45) 3532 4411 Fax: (+45) 3532 4444 Web: http://www.econ.ku.dk/epru/ Are there Diminishing Returns to R&D? Jakob B.
    [Show full text]
  • Intermediate Microeconomics
    Intermediate Microeconomics PRODUCTION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY Definitions Production: turning inputs into outputs. Production Function: A mathematical function that relates inputs to outputs. ◦ e.g., = ( , ), is a production function that maps the quantities of inputs capital (K) and labor (L) to a unique quantity of output. Firm: An entity that transforms inputs into outputs, i.e., engages in production. Marginal Product: The additional output that can be produced by adding one more unit of a particular input while holding all other inputs constant. ◦ e.g., , is the marginal product of capital. Two input production Graphing a function of more than 2 variables is impossible on a 2-dimensional surface. ◦ Even graphing a function of 2 variables presents challenges—which led us to hold one variable constant. In reality we expect the firm’s production function to have many inputs (arguments). Recall, if you have ever done so, doing inventory at the place you work: lots of things to count. ◦ Accounting for all of this complexity in an Economic model would be impossible and impossible to make sense of. So the inputs are grouped into two categories: human (labor) and non-human (capital). This enables us to use the Cartesian plane to graph production functions. Graphing a 2 input production function There are two ways of graphing a production function of two inputs. 1.Holding one input fixed and putting quantity on the vertical axis. E.g., = ( , ). 2.Allowing both inputs to vary and showing quantity as a level set. ◦This is analogous to an indifference curve from utility theory.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics Students Will Know… Unit 1
    Economics [email protected] Students will know… Unit 1 - Economics - Basic Economic Concepts & Our American Economic System 1. People exchange voluntarily because of the perceived benefits. 2. Scarcity causes people to make choices about how to allocate their resources. 3. The factors of production are land, labor, capital, and management. 4. Land (natural resources) is considered the natural resources used in production. 5. Labor is the human inputs used in the production process. 6. Capital is considered to be the tools used in the production process. 7. Entrepreneurship involves taking risks and combing the factors in production in the most efficient manner. 8. Management decides how to use land, labor, and capital in the production process. 9. Opportunity cost looks at decisions by analyzing costs and benefits of alternatives. 10. The basic economic question looks at the allocation of scarce resources (What should be produced? How should it be produced? How much should be produced, and Who should receive it?). 11. The three types of market systems are traditional, command, and market. 12. Traditional markets answer the basic economic question based on customs and history. 13. Command economies answer the basic economic question through a central authority. 14. Market economies are where the buyers and sellers answer the basic economic question by themselves. 15. The United States economic system is a mixed system, but is based on free market concepts. 16. The pillars of our economic system revolve around private property, limited government, market competition, and entrepreneurship. 17. Private property is the principle that individuals own the means of production.
    [Show full text]
  • Can Cryptocurrencies Fulfil the Functions of Money?
    Columbia University Center on Capitalism and Society Working Paper No. 92, August 2016 Can cryptocurrencies fulfil the functions of money? Dr. Saifedean Ammous1 Abstract This paper analyzes five cryptocurrencies’ monetary supply growth, credibility, and stability, to evaluate whether these currencies have a viable monetary role as a medium of exchange, store of value, and unit of account. While all cryptocurrencies can theoretically serve as a medium of exchange, they are inherently too unstable to be used as a unit of account. Of the five, only Bitcoin could potentially serve as a store of value, due to its strict commitment to low supply growth, credibly backed by the network’s distributed protocol and very large processing power. Other cryptocurrencies’ low processing power, centralized control, and use as tokens for specific applications make them unlikely to fulfil any monetary function. JEL classification: E42, E51 1 Assistant Professor of Economics, Lebanese American University. Foreign Member, Center on Capitalism and Society, Columbia University. Email: [email protected] 1. Introduction In 2008, pseudonymous programmer Satoshi Nakamoto introduced the design of a distributed peer-to-peer digital cash named Bitcoin. It was put into operation on the third of January 2009, as an obscure experiment among cryptography enthusiasts who transacted and mined the then-worthless tokens until they were listed on an exchange for a price of $0.000764. On May 22, 2010, the first real transaction was recorded in which Bitcoin served the function of a medium of exchange, at a rate of $0.0025 (Coindesk 2014). Since then, more than 140 million transactions have taken place with bitcoin, and the purchasing power of the currency has risen significantly, to around $600 per bitcoin at the time of writing, giving the total coin supply a market value around $10 billion.
    [Show full text]
  • Monotone Methods for Equilibrium Selection Under Perfect Foresight Dynamics
    Theoretical Economics 3 (2008), 155–192 1555-7561/20080155 Monotone methods for equilibrium selection under perfect foresight dynamics Daisuke Oyama Graduate School of Economics, Hitotsubashi University Satoru Takahashi Department of Economics, Princeton University Josef Hofbauer Department of Mathematics, University of Vienna This paper studies a dynamic adjustment process in a large society of forward- looking agents where payoffs are given by a supermodular normal form game. The stationary states of the dynamics correspond to the Nash equilibria of the stage game. It is shown that if the stage game has a monotone potential maximizer, then the corresponding stationary state is uniquely linearly absorbing and glob- ally accessible for any small degree of friction. A simple example of a unanimity game with three players is provided where there are multiple globally accessible states for a small friction. Keywords. Equilibrium selection, perfect foresight dynamics, supermodular game, strategic complementarity, stochastic dominance, potential, monotone potential. JEL classification. C72, C73. 1. Introduction Supermodular games capture the key concept of strategic complementarity in various economic phenomena. Examples include oligopolistic competition, the adoption of new technologies, bank runs, currency crises, and economic development. Strategic complementarity plays an important role in particular in Keynesian macroeconomics Daisuke Oyama: [email protected] Satoru Takahashi: [email protected] Josef Hofbauer: [email protected] This paper has been presented at the Universities of Tokyo, Vienna, and Wisconsin–Madison, and con- ferences/workshops in Heidelberg, Kyoto, Marseille, Prague, Salamanca, San Diego, Tokyo, Urbino, and Vienna. We are grateful to the audiences as well as to Drew Fudenberg, Michihiro Kandori, Akihiko Mat- sui, Stephen Morris, William H.
    [Show full text]
  • Diminishing Returns to Improvement in Financial Development
    Financial Dependence and Growth: Diminishing Returns to Improvement in Financial Development Leilei Shen ∗ Kansas State University April 7, 2013 Abstract This paper examines how much financial development facilitates economic growth by nonpara- metrically estimating the effect of financial development on reducing the costs of external finance to firms. The data reveal substantial evidence of diminishing returns to improvement in financial development. Keywords: Financial Dependence, Growth, Semiparametric Estimation. JEL Classifications: F3, O4. ∗Leilei Shen, Department of Economics, 214 Waters Hall, Kansas State University, Manhattan, KS,66506, USA. Phone: (785) 532-4580. Fax: (785) 532-6919. Email: [email protected] Diminishing Returns to Improvement in Financial Development Leilei Shen 1. Introduction There has been a growing literature on financial institutions and growth. Dating as far back as Schumpeter (1911), development of a country's financial institutions has a positive influence on the rate of growth of its per capita income. In addition, Rajan and Zingales (1998) show that this effect is more pronounced in the financially dependent industries. The basic specification in this paper is a semiparametric growth rate function where the in- teraction between external financial dependence of an industry and financial development of a country enters nonparametrically and the remaining variables are parametric. This paper provides evidence that the effect of financial development and external dependence on finance is non-linear and increasing at a decreasing rate. In other words, parametric estimation of this interaction effect significantly overestimates the interaction when it is small and underestimates it when it is large. In addition, for an improvement in financial development, the parametric estimation assumes the return to financial improvement only varies with industry, whereas the semiparametric specification is able to capture diminishing returns to financial improvement in addition to industry variance.
    [Show full text]
  • Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6)
    Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Lectures 09-10 Feb 06/09 2017 Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Production The theory of the firm describes how a firm makes cost- minimizing production decisions and how the firm’s resulting cost varies with its output. The Production Decisions of a Firm The production decisions of firms are analogous to the purchasing decisions of consumers, and can likewise be understood in three steps: 1. Production Technology 2. Cost Constraints 3. Input Choices Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.1 THE TECHNOLOGY OF PRODUCTION ● factors of production Inputs into the production process (e.g., labor, capital, and materials). The Production Function qFKL= (,) (6.1) ● production function Function showing the highest output that a firm can produce for every specified combination of inputs. Remember the following: Inputs and outputs are flows. Equation (6.1) applies to a given technology. Production functions describe what is technically feasible when the firm operates efficiently. Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.1 THE TECHNOLOGY OF PRODUCTION The Short Run versus the Long Run ● short run Period of time in which quantities of one or more production factors cannot be changed. ● fixed input Production factor that cannot be varied. ● long run Amount of time needed to make all production inputs variable. Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.2 PRODUCTION WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT (LABOR) TABLE 6.1 Production with One Variable Input Amount Amount Total Average Marginal of Labor (L) of Capital (K) Output (q) Product (q/L) Product (∆q/∆L) 0 10 0 — — 1 10 10 10 10 2 10 30 15 20 3 10 60 20 30 4 10 80 20 20 5 10 95 19 15 6 10 108 18 13 7 10 112 16 4 8 10 112 14 0 9 10 108 12 -4 10 10 100 10 -8 Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.2 PRODUCTION WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT (LABOR) Average and Marginal Products ● average product Output per unit of a particular input.
    [Show full text]
  • The Law of Diminishing Returns in Clinical Medicine: How Much Risk Reduction Is Enough?
    J Am Board Fam Med: first published as 10.3122/jabfm.2010.03.090178 on 7 May 2010. Downloaded from SPECIAL COMMUNICATION The Law of Diminishing Returns in Clinical Medicine: How Much Risk Reduction is Enough? James W. Mold, MD, MPH, Robert M. Hamm, PhD, and Laine H. McCarthy, MLIS The law of diminishing returns, first described by economists to explain why, beyond a certain point, addi- tional inputs produce smaller and smaller outputs, offers insight into many situations encountered in clinical medicine. For example, when the risk of an adverse event can be reduced in several different ways, the im- pact of each intervention can generally be shown mathematically to be reduced by the previous ones. The diminishing value of successive interventions is further reduced by adverse consequences (eg, drug-drug, drug-disease, and drug-nutrient interactions), as well as by the total expenditures of time, energy, and re- sources, which increase with each additional intervention. It is therefore important to try to prioritize inter- ventions based on patient-centered goals and the relative impact and acceptability of the interventions. We believe that this has implications for clinical practice, research, and policy. (J Am Board Fam Med 2010;23: 371–375.) Keywords: Risk Reduction, Clinical Decision-Making, Evidence-Based Medicine In economics, the law of diminishing returns states The abstract of his paper begins with the following that, as “quantities of one variable factor are in- statement: “In the quest for diagnostic certainty, copyright. creased, while other factor inputs remain constant, one can be led into a false sense of accomplishment all things being equal, a point is reached beyond by the results of sensitive, specific, and well-exe- which the addition of one more unit of the variable cuted diagnostic tests that provide little or no di- factor will result in a diminishing rate of return and agnostic information.
    [Show full text]
  • Increasing Returns and Unemployment Equilibrium
    Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/increasingreturnOOweit working paper department of economics INCREASING RETURNS AND UNEMPLOYMENT EQUILIBRIUM M.L. Weitzraan Number 291 October, 1981 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 INCREASING RETURNS AND UNEMPLOYMENT EQUILIBRIUM M.L. Weitzman Number 291 October, 1981 For their useful comments I am grateful to R.M. Solow, D.D. Hester J. Tobin, F.H. Hahn, J.J. Rotemberg, M. Bruno, and A.K. Dixit. AUG 1 6 1983 Increasing Returns and Unemployment Equilibrium Summary Current approaches to macroeconomic theory divide, roughly, into two basic schools of thought. One approach, typically associated with "rational expectations", views the economy as basically at or near market clearing equilibrium, in which case it becomes very hard to convincingly explain away the undeniable persistence, at times, of involuntary unemployment. Another approach views the underemployed economy as being in a state of temporary disequilibrium, in which case, even leaving aside suspicions that the essence of effective demand failures might not have to do with prices fixed at "wrong" values, there is a lot of rationalizing to be done about why adjustments are so slow. This paper argues that it is possible, and even plausible, to have something like a consistent theory of steady state unemployment in the more or less usual sense of general equilibrium; that is, individual economic agents have no incentive to change their optimizing behavior under conditions which their very behavior sustains, and yet there is persistent involuntary unemployment.
    [Show full text]