Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity By AVINASH K. DIXIT AND JOSEPH E. STIGLITZ* The basic issue concerning production in potential commodity involves some fixed welfare economics is whether a market solu- set-up cost and has a constant marginal tion will yield the socially optimum kinds cost. Modeling the desirability of variety and quantities of commodities. It is well has been thought to be difficult, and several known that problems can arise for three indirect approaches have been adopted. broad reasons: distributive justice; external The Hotelling spatial model, Lancaster's effects; and scale economies. This paper is product characteristics approach, and the concerned with the last of these. mean-variance portfolio selection model The basic principle is easily stated.' A have all been put to use.3 These lead to re- commodity should be produced if the costs sults involving transport costs or correla- can be covered by the sum of revenues and tions among commodities or securities, and a properly defined measure of consumer's are hard to interpret in general terms. We surplus. The optimum amount is then therefore take a direct route, noting that the found by equating the demand price and the convexity of indifference surfaces of a con- marginal cost. Such an optimum can be ventional utility function defined over the realized in a market if perfectly discrim- quantities of all potential commodities al- inatory pricing is possible. Otherwise we ready embodies the desirability of variety. face conflicting problems. A competitive Thus, a consumer who is indifferent be- market fulfilling the marginal condition tween the quantities (1,0) and (0,1) of two would be unsustainable because total profits commodities prefers the mix (1/2,1/2) to would be negative. An element of monopoly either extreme. The advantage of this view would allow positive profits, but would is that the results involve the familiar own- violate the marginal condition.2 Thus we and cross-elasticities of demand functions, expect a market solution to be suboptimal. and are therefore easier to comprehend. However, a much more precise structure There is one case of particular interest on must be put on the problem if we are to which we concentrate. This is where poten- understand the nature of the bias involved. tial commodities in a group or sector or in- It is useful to think of the question as one dustry are good substitutes among them- of quantity versus diversity. With scale selves, but poor substitutes for the other economies, resources can be saved by pro- commodities in the economy. Then we are ducing fewer goods and larger quantities of led to examining the market solution in re- each. However, this leaves less variety, lation to an optimum, both as regards which entails some welfare loss. It is easy biases within the group, and between the and probably not too unrealistic to model group and the rest of the economy. We ex- scale economies by supposing that each pect the answer to depend on the intra- and intersector elasticities of substitution. To demonstrate the point as simply as possible, *Professors of economics, University of Warwick we shall aggregate the rest of the economy and Stanford University, respectively. Stiglitz's re- into one good labeled 0, chosen as the search was supported in part by NSF Grant SOC74- 22182 at the Institute for Mathematical Studies in the numeraire. The economy's endowment of it Social Sciences, Stanford. We are indebted to Michael is normalized at unity; it can be thought of Spence, to a referee, and the managing editor for com- as the time at the disposal of the consumers. ments and suggestions on earlier drafts. ISee also the exposition by Michael Spence. 2A simple exposition is given by Peter Diamond and 3See the articles by Harold Hotelling, Nicholas Daniel McFadden. Stern, Kelvin Lancaster, and Stiglitz. 297 298 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1977 The potential range of related products is varieties, or as diversification on the part labeled 1,2,3,.... Writing the amounts of of each consumer. the various commodities as x0 and x = (xl, X2, X3 ..., we assume a separable utility 1. Constant-ElasticityCase function with convex indifference surfaces: A. Demand Functions (1) u = U(xO, V(x1,x2,X3..)) The utility function in this section is In Sections I and II we simplify further (2) ( {x} I/P) by assuming that V is a symmetric function, and that all commodities in the group have For concavity, we need p < 1. Further, equal fixed and marginal costs. Then the since we want to allow a situation where actual labels given to commodities are im- several of the xi are zero, we need p > 0. We material, even though the total number n also assume U homothetic in its arguments. being produced is relevant. We can thus The budget constraint is label these commodities 1,2, ..., n, where n the potential products(n + 1), (n + 2), ... (3) xO + Pi= I are not being produced. This is a restrictive assumption, for in such problems we often where pi are prices of the goods being pro- have a natural asymmetry owing to grad- duced, and I is income in terms of the uated physical differences in commodities, numeraire, i.e., the endowment which has with a pair close together being better been set at I plus the profits of the firms mutual substitutes than a pair farther apart. distributed to the consumers, or minus the However, even the symmetric case yields lump sum deductions to cover the losses, as some interesting results. In Section III, we the case may be. consider some aspects of asymmetry. In this case, a two-stage budgeting pro- We also assume that all commodities cedure is valid.4 Thus we define dual quan- have unit income elasticities. This differs tity and price indices from a similar recent formulation by Michael Spence, who assumes U linear in xo, so that the industry is amenable to (4) y = {?, q= p partial equilibrium analysis. Our approach allows a better treatment of the intersectoral whereA = (I - p)/p, which is positive since substitution, but the other results are very O< p < 1. Then it can be shown5 that in the similar to those of Spence. first stage, We consider two special cases of (1). In s(q) Section I, V is given a CES form, but U is (S) y - I xo = I(1 - s(q)) allowed to be arbitrary. In Section II, U is q taken to be Cobb-Douglas, but V has a for a function s which depends on the form more general additive form. Thus the for- of U. Writing a(q) for the elasticity of sub- mer allows more general intersector rela- stitution between xo and y, we define 0(q) as tions, and the latter more general intra- the elasticity of the function s, i.e., qs'(q)/ sector substitution, highlighting different s(q). Then we find results. = - $1 - < 1 Income distribution problems are ne- (6) 0(q) 11 o(q)} s(q)} glected. Thus U can be regarded as repre- but 0(q) can be negative as a(q) can ex- senting Samuelsonian social indifference ceed 1. curves, or (assuming the appropriate aggre- gation conditions to be fulfilled) as a mul- tiple of a 4Sec p. 21 of John Green. representative consumer's utility. 5These details and several others are omitted to save Product diversity can then be interpreted space, but can be found in the working paper by the either as different consumers using different authors, cited in the references. VOL. 67 NO. 3 DIXIT AND STIGLITZ: PRODUCT DIVERSITY 299 Turning to the second stage of the prob- downward. The conventional condition that lem, it is easy to show that for each i, the dd curve be more elastic is seen from (9) and (12) to be (7) = (13) + (q)>? where y is defined by (4). Consider the effect of a change in pi alone. This affects xi di- Finally, we observe that for i + j, rectly, and also through q; thence through y as well. Now from (4) we have the elasticity (14) xi Pi ] (8)dlg =(q d logpi Pi Thus 1/(1 - p) is the elasticity of substitu- tion between any two products within the So long as the prices of the products in the group. group are not of different orders of mag- nitude, this is of the order (I/n). We shall B. Market Equilibrium assume that n is reasonably large, and ac- It can be shown that each commodity is cordingly neglect the effect of each Pi on q; produced by one firm. Each firm attempts thus the indirect effects on xi. This leaves us to maximize its profit, and entry occurs un- with the elasticity til the marginal firm can only just break () logx_ -I -(I + Oi) even. Thus our market equilibrium is the (9) =- .. familiar case of Chamberlinian monopolis- dlogpi (I -P) tic competition, where the question of In the Chamberlinian terminology, this is quantity versus diversity has often been the elasticity of the dd curve, i.e., the curve raised.6 Previous analyses have failed to relating the demand for each product type consider the desirability of variety in an ex- to its own price with all other prices held plicit form, and have neglected various constant. intra- and intersector interactions in de- In our large group case, we also see that mand. As a result, much vague presumption for i s j, the cross elasticity d log xi/d log p1 that such an equilibrium involves excessive is negligible.
Recommended publications
  • Monopolistic Competition in General Equilibrium: Beyond the CES Evgeny Zhelobodko, Sergey Kokovin, Mathieu Parenti, Jacques-François Thisse
    Monopolistic competition in general equilibrium: Beyond the CES Evgeny Zhelobodko, Sergey Kokovin, Mathieu Parenti, Jacques-François Thisse To cite this version: Evgeny Zhelobodko, Sergey Kokovin, Mathieu Parenti, Jacques-François Thisse. Monopolistic com- petition in general equilibrium: Beyond the CES. 2011. halshs-00566431 HAL Id: halshs-00566431 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00566431 Preprint submitted on 16 Feb 2011 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. WORKING PAPER N° 2011 - 08 Monopolistic competition in general equilibrium: Beyond the CES Evgeny Zhelobodko Sergey Kokovin Mathieu Parenti Jacques-François Thisse JEL Codes: D43, F12, L13 Keywords: monopolistic competition, additive preferences, love for variety, heterogeneous firms PARIS-JOURDAN SCIENCES ECONOMIQUES 48, BD JOURDAN – E.N.S. – 75014 PARIS TÉL. : 33(0) 1 43 13 63 00 – FAX : 33 (0) 1 43 13 63 10 www.pse.ens.fr CENTRE NATIONAL DE LA RECHERCHE SCIENTIFIQUE – ECOLE DES HAUTES ETUDES EN SCIENCES SOCIALES ÉCOLE DES PONTS PARISTECH – ECOLE NORMALE SUPÉRIEURE – INSTITUT NATIONAL DE LA RECHERCHE AGRONOMIQUE Monopolistic Competition in General Equilibrium: Beyond the CES∗ Evgeny Zhelobodko† Sergey Kokovin‡ Mathieu Parenti§ Jacques-François Thisse¶ 13th February 2011 Abstract We propose a general model of monopolistic competition and derive a complete characterization of the market equilibrium using the concept of Relative Love for Variety.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Introduction 2 the Economics of Imperfect Competition
    Notes 1 Introduction 1. It should be noted that Joan Robinson might have been very angry at being so described. Marjorie Turner, in discussing Mary Paley Marshall’s reaction to The Economics of Imperfect Competition (Robinson, 1933a), points out that Joan Robinson ‘thought of her own reputation as being that of an economist and not a woman-economist’ (Turner, 1989, 12–13; see also below, 8–9. 2. Luigi Pasinetti brilliantly describes their approaches and interrelationships, and evaluates their collective contributions in his entry on Joan Robinson in The New Palgrave (Pasinetti, 1987; see also 2007). 3. The editors of the Cambridge Journal of Economics, of which she was a Patron, had been preparing a special issue in honour of her eightieth birthday. Sadly, it had to be a Memorial issue instead (see the special issue of December 1983). 4. For an absorbing account of the Maurice debates and the events and issues surrounding them, see Wilson and Prior (2004, 2006). 5. In private conversation with GCH. 6. It was widely thought at Cambridge, in pre- and post-war years, that Marjorie Tappan-Hollond was responsible for Joan Robinson never being elected to a teaching fellowship at Girton (it was only after Joan Robinson retired that she became an Honorary Fellow of Girton and the Joan Robinson Society, which met on 31 October (her birth date) each year, was started). Marjorie Turner documents that there was mutual personal affection between them and even concern on Tappan-Hollond’s part for her former pupil but that she strongly disapproved of Joan Robinson’s ‘messianic’ approach to teaching.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation
    Product differentiation Industrial Organization Bernard Caillaud Master APE - Paris School of Economics September 22, 2016 Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation The Bertrand paradox relies on the fact buyers choose the cheap- est firm, even for very small price differences. In practice, some buyers may continue to buy from the most expensive firms because they have an intrinsic preference for the product sold by that firm: Notion of differentiation. Indeed, assuming an homogeneous product is not realistic: rarely exist two identical goods in this sense For objective reasons: products differ in their physical char- acteristics, in their design, ... For subjective reasons: even when physical differences are hard to see for consumers, branding may well make two prod- ucts appear differently in the consumers' eyes Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation Differentiation among products is above all a property of con- sumers' preferences: Taste for diversity Heterogeneity of consumers' taste But it has major consequences in terms of imperfectly competi- tive behavior: so, the analysis of differentiation allows for a richer discussion and comparison of price competition models vs quan- tity competition models. Also related to the practical question (for competition authori- ties) of market definition: set of goods highly substitutable among themselves and poorly substitutable with goods outside this set Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation Firms have in general an incentive to affect the degree of differ- entiation of their products compared to rivals'. Hence, differen- tiation is related to other aspects of firms’ strategies. Choice of products: firms choose how to differentiate from rivals, this impacts the type of products that they choose to offer and the diversity of products that consumers face.
    [Show full text]
  • Classical Vs Neoclassical Conceptions of Competition
    ISSN 1791-3144 University of Macedonia Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series Classical vs. Neoclassical Conceptions of Competition Lefteris Tsoulfidis Discussion Paper No. 11/2011 Department of Economics, University of Macedonia, 156 Egnatia str, 540 06 Thessaloniki, Greece, Fax: + 30 (0) 2310 891292 http://econlab.uom.gr/econdep/ 1 Classical vs. Neoclassical Conceptions of Competition∗ By Lefteris Tsoulfidis Associate Professor, Department of Economics University of Macedonia 156 Egnatia Street, 540 06, Thessaloniki, Greece Tel. 2310 891-788, Fax 2310 891-786 Homepage: http://econlab.uom.gr/~lnt/ Abstract This article discusses two major conceptions of competition, the classical and the neoclassical. In the classical conception, competition is viewed as a dynamic rivalrous process of firms struggling with each other over the expansion of their market shares. This dynamic view of competition characterizes mainly the works of Smith, Ricardo, J.S. Mill and Marx; a similar view can be also found in the writings of Austrian economists and the business literature. By contrast, the neoclassical conception of competition is derived from the requirements of a theory geared towards static equilibrium and not from any historical observation of the way in which firms actually organize and compete with each other. Key Words: B12, B13, B14, L11 JEL Classification Codes: Classical Competition, Regulating Capital, Incremental Rate of Return, Rate of Profit, Perfect Competition. 1. Introduction This article contrasts the classical and the neoclassical theories of competition, starting with the classical one as this was developed in the writings of Smith, Ricardo, J.S. Mill and more explicitly analyzed in Marx’s Capital. The claim that this paper raises is that the classical conception of competition despite its realism was gradually replaced by the neoclassical one, according to which competition is an end state rather than a description of the way in which firms organize and actually compete with each other.
    [Show full text]
  • Distorted Monopolistic Competition Kristian Behrens, Giordano Mion, Yasusada Murata, Jens Suedekum
    No 237 Distorted Monopolistic Competition Kristian Behrens, Giordano Mion, Yasusada Murata, Jens Suedekum November 2016 IMPRINT DICE DISCUSSION PAPER Published by düsseldorf university press (dup) on behalf of Heinrich‐Heine‐Universität Düsseldorf, Faculty of Economics, Düsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), Universitätsstraße 1, 40225 Düsseldorf, Germany www.dice.hhu.de Editor: Prof. Dr. Hans‐Theo Normann Düsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE) Phone: +49(0) 211‐81‐15125, e‐mail: [email protected] DICE DISCUSSION PAPER All rights reserved. Düsseldorf, Germany, 2016 ISSN 2190‐9938 (online) – ISBN 978‐3‐86304‐236‐3 The working papers published in the Series constitute work in progress circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comments. Views expressed represent exclusively the authors’ own opinions and do not necessarily reflect those of the editor. Distorted Monopolistic Competition Kristian Behrens∗ Giordano Mion† Yasusada Murata‡ Jens Suedekum§ November 2016 Abstract We characterize the equilibrium and optimal resource allocations in a gen- eral equilibrium model of monopolistic competition with multiple asymmetric sectors and heterogeneous firms. We first derive general results for additively separable preferences and general productivity distributions, and then analyze specific examples that allow for closed-form solutions and a simple quantifica- tion procedure. Using data for France and the United Kingdom, we find that the aggregate welfare distortion — due to inefficient labor allocation and firm entry between sectors and inefficient selection and output within sectors — is equivalent to the contribution of 6–8% of the total labor input. Keywords: monopolistic competition; welfare distortion; intersectoral distor- tions; intrasectoral distortions JEL Classification: D43;D50;L13. ∗Université du Québec à Montréal (esg-uqàm), Canada; National Research University Higher School of Economics, Russian Federation; and cepr.
    [Show full text]
  • 14.581 Lecture 9: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition: Theory
    14.581 MIT PhD International Trade – Lecture 9: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition (Theory) – Dave Donaldson Spring 2011 Today’s Plan 1 Introduction to “New” Trade Theory 2 Monopolistically Competitive Models 1 Krugman (JIE, 1979) 2 Helpman and Krugman (1985 book) 3 Krugman (AER, 1980) 3 From “New” Trade Theory to Economic Geography “New” Trade Theory What ’s wrong with neoclassical trade theory? In a neoclassical world, differences in relative autarky prices– due to • differences in technology, factor endowments, or preferences– are the only rationale for trade. This suggests that: • 1 “Different” countries should trade more. 2 “Different” countries should specialize in “different” goods. In the real world, however, we observe that: • 1 The bulk of world trade is between “similar” countries. 2 These countries tend to trade “similar” goods. “New” Trade Theory Why Increasing Returns to Scale (IRTS)? “New” Trade Theory proposes IRTS as an alternative rationale for • international trade and a potential explanation for the previous facts. Basic idea: • 1 Because of IRTS, similar countries will specialize in different goods to take advantage of large-scale production, thereby leading to trade. 2 Because of IRTS, countries may exchange goods with similar factor content. In addition, IRTS may provide new source of gains from trade if it • induces firms to move down their average cost curves. “New” Trade Theory How to model increasing returns to scale? 1 External economies of scale Under perfect competition, multiple equilibria and possibilities of losses • from trade (Ethier, Etca 1982). Under Bertrand competition, many of these features disappear • (Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg, QJE 2009).
    [Show full text]
  • Principles of Microeconomics
    PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS A. Competition The basic motivation to produce in a market economy is the expectation of income, which will generate profits. • The returns to the efforts of a business - the difference between its total revenues and its total costs - are profits. Thus, questions of revenues and costs are key in an analysis of the profit motive. • Other motivations include nonprofit incentives such as social status, the need to feel important, the desire for recognition, and the retaining of one's job. Economists' calculations of profits are different from those used by businesses in their accounting systems. Economic profit = total revenue - total economic cost • Total economic cost includes the value of all inputs used in production. • Normal profit is an economic cost since it occurs when economic profit is zero. It represents the opportunity cost of labor and capital contributed to the production process by the producer. • Accounting profits are computed only on the basis of explicit costs, including labor and capital. Since they do not take "normal profits" into consideration, they overstate true profits. Economic profits reward entrepreneurship. They are a payment to discovering new and better methods of production, taking above-average risks, and producing something that society desires. The ability of each firm to generate profits is limited by the structure of the industry in which the firm is engaged. The firms in a competitive market are price takers. • None has any market power - the ability to control the market price of the product it sells. • A firm's individual supply curve is a very small - and inconsequential - part of market supply.
    [Show full text]
  • Assessing the Role of Scale Economies and Imperfect Competition in the Context of Agricultural Trade Liberalisation: a Canadian Case Study
    ASSESSING THE ROLE OF SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION IN THE CONTEXT OF AGRICULTURAL TRADE LIBERALISATION: A CANADIAN CASE STUDY Franqois Delorme and Dominique van der Mensbrugghe CONTENTS Introduction .............................................. 206 I. The implementation of scale economies in WALRAS ............ 207 A. Scale-economy parameters ............................ 209 B. Pricing strategies ................................... 21 1 II. Empirical results ....................................... 218 A. Perfect competition ................................. 220 B. Scale economies and oligopolistic behaviour ............... 222 111. Concluding remarks.. ................................... 225 Technical Annex ........................................... 230 Bibliography .............................................. 233 FranCois Delorme is an Administrator with the Growth Studies Division and Dominique van der Mensbrugghe was a Trainee with the Growth Studies Division. The authors are grateful to John P. Martin, Val Koromzay and Peter Sturm for many perceptive suggestions and substantial comments on an earlier draft. They are also indebted to Kym Anderson, Jean-Marc Burniaux, Avinash Dixit, Robert Ford, Richard Harris, lan Lienert, James Markusen, Victor Norman, J. David Richardson, Benoit Robidoux, Jeff Shafer and Anthony J. Venables for valuable discussions and comments during the course of this work. 205 INTRODUCTION One of the key characteristics of the WALRAS model [as described in Burniaux et a/. (1989)l is that it assumes that all markets are perfectly competi- tive and production takes place under constant returns to scale. In this case, supply curves are flat', although they shift as input prices change. Until recently, this modelling strategy was adopted by most applied general equilibrium (AGE) modellers, since such models are relatively easy to build and their properties are well understood. Simulations of trade liberalisation with such models tend to show rather "small" welfare gains, typically of the order of 1 per cent of GNP or less.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Structures
    Market Structures Lesson Goal: In this lesson, you will learn the characteristics of the 4 types of market ​ structures: perfect competition, monopoly, monopolistic competition, and oligopoly. You ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ will also learn how the government intervenes in the market to protect competition. Directions: Read the notes below CLOSELY for understanding, and follow the prompts ​ given to you throughout the lesson. For example, if I ask you to pause and watch a video and take notes, pause and watch the video. Open a Google Doc and take notes as you work. WHEN the whole lesson is finished, share your completed Google Doc with me. NOTES #1 Perfect Competition The simplest market structure is known as perfect competition. It is also called pure ​ ​ competition. A perfectly competitive market is one with a large number of firms all producing essentially the same product. Pure competition assumes that the market is in equilibrium and that all firms sell the same product for the same price. However, each firm produces so little of the product compared to the total supply that no single firm can hope to influence prices. The only decision such producers can make is how much to produce, given their production costs and the market price. Four Conditions for Perfect Competition While very few industries meet all of the conditions for perfect competition, some come close. For example, markets for many farm products and the stocks traded on the New York Stock Exchange meet the conditions for perfect competition. The 4 conditions are: 1. Many buyers and sellers participate in the market. 2. Sellers offer identical products.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Efficiency Aspects of Monopolistic Competition: Innovation, Variety and Transaction Costs
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Todorova, Tamara Preprint Some Efficiency Aspects of Monopolistic Competition: Innovation, Variety and Transaction Costs Suggested Citation: Todorova, Tamara (2016) : Some Efficiency Aspects of Monopolistic Competition: Innovation, Variety and Transaction Costs, ZBW - Deutsche Zentralbibliothek für Wirtschaftswissenschaften, Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft, Kiel und Hamburg This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/148367 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu SOME EFFICIENCY ASPECTS OF MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION: INNOVATION, VARIETY AND TRANSACTION COSTS Tamara Todorova American University in Bulgaria Abstract: We stress some efficiency aspects of monopolistic competition justifying it on account of its tendency to innovate and the questionable excess capacity paradigm.
    [Show full text]
  • State Owned Enterprises and the Principle of Competitive Neutrality 2009
    State Owned Enterprises and the Principle of Competitive Neutrality 2009 The OECD Competition Committee debated the application of competition rules to state owned enterprises and the principle of competitive neutrality in October 2009. This document includes an executive summary, a background note and an issues paper by Mr. Antonio Capobianco for the OECD and country contributions from Brazil, Canada, Chile, China, Czech Republic, European Commission, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, India, Indonesia, Korea, Lithuania, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Romania, Russia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Chinese Taipei, Turkey, United Kingdom, United States and BIAC, as well as two aides memoires for the discussions. Due to their privileged position SOEs may negatively affect competition and it is therefore important to ensure that, to the greatest extent possible consistent with their public service responsibilities, they are subject to similar competition disciplines as private enterprises. Although enforcing competition rules against SOEs presents enforcers with particular challenges, competition rules should, and generally do, apply to both private and state-owned enterprises, subject to very limited exceptions. Competition law alone is not sufficient in ensuring a level playing field for SOEs and private enterprises, which is why policies aimed at achieving competitive neutrality between the two play an essential role. Competitive neutrality can be understood as a regulatory framework (i) within which public and private enterprises face the same set of rules and (ii) where no contact with the state brings competitive advantage to any market participant. Presence of competitive neutrality policies is of particular importance in recently liberalised sectors, where they play a crucial role in leveling the playing field between former state monopoly incumbents and private entrants.
    [Show full text]
  • Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition (Theory) —
    Economics 266: International Trade | Lecture 8: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition (Theory) | Stanford Econ 266 (Donaldson) Winter 2016 (lecture 8) Stanford Econ 266 (Donaldson) IRTS and MC Winter 2016 (lecture 8) 1 / 36 Today's Plan 1 Introduction to \New" Trade Theory 2 Monopolistically Competitive Models 1 Krugman (JIE, 1979) 2 Krugman (AER, 1980) 3 From \New" Trade Theory to Economic Geography 4 Appendix: HO models with IRTS (Helpman and Krugman, 1985) Stanford Econ 266 (Donaldson) IRTS and MC Winter 2016 (lecture 8) 2 / 36 Today's Plan 1 Introduction to \New" Trade Theory 2 Monopolistically Competitive Models 1 Krugman (JIE, 1979) 2 Krugman (AER, 1980) 3 From \New" Trade Theory to Economic Geography 4 Appendix: HO models with IRTS (Helpman and Krugman, 1985) Stanford Econ 266 (Donaldson) IRTS and MC Winter 2016 (lecture 8) 3 / 36 \New" (c. 1980s) Trade Theory What's wrong with neoclassical trade theory? In a neoclassical world, differences in relative autarky prices|due to differences in technology, factor endowments, or preferences|are the only rationale for trade. This suggests that: 1 “Different” countries should trade more. 2 “Different” countries should specialize in \different" goods. In the real world, however, we observe that: 1 The bulk of world trade is between \similar" countries. 2 These countries tend to trade \similar" goods. Stanford Econ 266 (Donaldson) IRTS and MC Winter 2016 (lecture 8) 4 / 36 \New" (c. 1980s) Trade Theory Why Increasing Returns to Scale (IRTS)? \New" Trade Theory proposes IRTS as an alternative rationale for international trade and a potential explanation for the previous facts.
    [Show full text]