<<

Th is work has been published by the European University Institute, Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies. © European University Institute 2018 Editorial matter and selection © Josef Hien and Christian Joerges, 2018 Chapters © authors individually 2018 doi:10.2870/83554 ISBN:978-92-9084-711-3 QM-05-18-106-EN-N Th is text may be downloaded only for personal research purposes. Any additional reproduction for other purposes, whether in hard copies or electronically, requires the consent of the author(s), editor(s). If cited or quoted, reference should be made to the full name of the author(s), editor(s), the title, the year and the publisher Views expressed in this publication refl ect the opinion of individual authors and not those of the European University Institute.

Artwork: © Albert Hien RESPONSES OF EUROPEAN ECONOMIC CULTURES TO ’S CRISIS POLITICS: THE EXAMPLE OF GERMAN-ITALIAN DISCREPANCIES

Edited by: Josef Hien and Christian Joerges TABLE OF CONTENTS

Acknowledgements 6 Introductory Explanations 6 Contributors 20

A) The Political Economy of and

The German Political Economy under the Euro – and a Comparison to the “Southern Model” Philip Manow 27 The Political Economy of Public Sector Wage-setting in Germany and Italy Donato Di Carlo 48 Geo-Politics of Exporting Too Much: Contrasting Trajectories of Germany and Japan Margarita Estévez-Abe 63 Ideational Differences between Italian and German Governments during the Crisis Frederico Bruno 74 A Cultural Political Economy Approach to the European Crisis Josef Hien 80

B) Sectors of the Political Economy of Italy and Germany

Worlds Apart: The Divergence of Southern-European Housing-Construction Economies and Northern European Export Economies Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau 99 Banking Crisis Interventions in Germany and Italy: the Unpleasant Case of the New European Bank Resolution Framework Frederik Traut 108 Comparing the German and Italian Approaches to Banking Union Lucia Quaglia 120 Maternal employment, attitudes toward gender equality and work-family policies. German-Italian Discrepancies? Agnes Blome 129

C) German and Italian Perceptions, Differences and Misgivings

Italy and Germany during the Crisis: Support for the EU and Reciprocal Views Alessandro Pellegata 140 The Political Space in Italy and Germany during the Crisis: Italian and German Populism Compared Hanspeter Kriesi 148 The political economy of recovery in Southern Europe Manos Matsaganis 157 Accommodating EU‘s influence vs protecting national sovereignty. Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula 162 European Integration and Political Ownership: Fiction and Reality behind Structural Reforms and Risk-Sharing Filippo Taddei 170

D) The Legacy of the Welfare State in Europe

An Alternative to the of the EU’s Single Market? Florian Rödl 176 Industrial Relations and Labour Law in the EU Economic Governance Mechanisms: The Cases of Italy and Germany Francesco Costamagna 182 What to expect from Germany for the European Pillar of Social Rights and beyond? Marcel Hadeed 188 The EU Political Culture of Total Optimism is not Dead: Reflections on the European Pillar of Social Rights Vladimir Bogoeski 196 A ‘more political’ leadership for the President of the Commission? A mixed-methods language-based analysis Pamela Pansardi 201

E) The Demise of Law

The EU as “Honest Broker”? German and Italian Perspectives on an Adminstrative Body Anna Katharina Mangold 215 Integration-through-crisis as a distinct integrative mode: Placing expediency ahead of democracy? Nicole Scicluna 220 Should the Specifics of National Political Cultures be Characterised as “Democratic Acquis” and Can they be Defended by Law? Beyond the Nostalgia-Controversy between JÜrgen Habermas and Wolfgang Streeck Christian Joerges 229 The End of the Universality of Norms as a Model for Europe: The Error of “Seeing like a State” (J.S. Scott) in the Postmodern Condition Karl-Heinz Ladeur 237 F) Justice Deficits and Solidarity

Is the EU Unjust? Glyn Morgan 244 A European Minister of Economy and Finance:Assessing the Commission’s proposal and Comparing the Positions of Germany and Italy Tiziano Zgaga 253 Re-solidarizing Europe and Defusing the Crisis Maurizio Ferrera and Carlo Burelli 263

Summarising Comments

Concluding Remarks: Economic Cultures and the Politics of Interdependence Visnja Vukov 269

Two Annexes

Order in the : Maurizio Ferrera and Claus Offe in Conversation Maurizio Ferrera and Claus Offe 278 Germany is Quietly Rebalancing its Economy – But This will not Fix the Eurozone’s Flaws Donato Di Carlo 282

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS We had excellent support for this project from both sides of the Alps. In particular, we want to thank the DAAD for trusting us to do something mean- I. Political Turmoil ingful with the money that we won in the frame- work of the “Hochschuldialog mit Südeuropa, When we started our preparation for this project 2018”. Second, a big thanks goes to all members only a year ago, our prime concerns were the of the ERC-funded REScEU project at the Univer- deepening of the social and economic asymme- sity of Milan, especially, the Principal Investigator tries between the North and the South under the Maurizio Ferrera, who REScEUed us from a small impact of the financial crisis, with Germany and financial disaster, and without whom all this would Italy providing an example of existential impor- have never happened.1 Third, we wish to thank tance for the EU as a whole. Both of us had resided the Villa Vigoni for providing the most fantastic in the two countries for prolonged periods in the setting, food and administrative support imagin- past, and we had never witnessed such a surge in able for the conference. Fourth, we want to thank antagonistic feelings on both sides of the Alps as Brigid Laffan at the Robert Schumann Centre of occurred during the Euro crisis. This can even be the European University Institute for giving us measured: while it had been common in Germany, a platform for publication. Fifth, we are deeply at the beginning of the crisis, to talk about the grateful to Ines Andre-Schulze for her administra- PIIGS states (, Ireland, Italy, and tive support and the third-party funding bureau ), with Italy figuring among them as an 2 at the Hertie School of Governance in Berlin. A important member, the percentage of Italians cheer for our tireless language editor Chris Engert having a positive image of Germany crashed only and to our beloved ones. from 75 to 65 per cent during the immediate crisis period, and now the majority of the Italians thinks that Germany has too much influence in Europe Josef Hien and Christian Joerges, Stockholm/ and that it uses this influence at the expense of Milan and Bremen/Berlin, October 2018 Southern Member States.3 While our application for funding was still pending, we witnessed two crucial events that increased the pertinence of our project way beyond our expectations. First, on the 24 September 2017, for the first time in post-war German history, a far right party entered the German with a victory, receiving 14 per cent of the popular vote and 100 parliamentary seats. Second, only five months later in Italy, the far-right Lega party and the Movi- mento Cinque Stelle emerged as the big winners from the Italian federal elections of the 4th of

1 The work of Josef Hien for this collection has been carried out within 2 This notion has disappeared from the public discourse; it the framework of the REScEU project (REScEU: Reconciling Econo- re-surfaced somewhat modified in Commissioner Oettingers mic and Social Europe: the role of ideas, values and politics) hosted at comments on the plans of the present Italian government; see, the University of Milan and financed by the European Research Coun- for references, the contribution of K. Mangold, F 1. cil (grant no. 340534). Josef Hien also wants to thank the Institute for 3 Olmastroni, F. / Pellegata, A. (2017): Once we were friends. Future Studies in Stockholm, Stefan Svallfors and Gustaf Arrhenius EU support and reciprocal views between Germany and Italy. who have hosted him as a guest during the late stage of this project. http://www.euvisions.eu/friends-support-reciprocal.

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 6 March 2018. Forming a previously unthinkable II. The Challenge of Euro- coalition between right-wing and left-wing popu- pean Varieties lism, they entered into government. We are not so naïve as to believe that the variety of Europe’s It is difficult to identify uncontroversial state- crises could be understood and adequately anal- ments in the crisis literature. Among them, ysed as though these were isolated events. The however, is the - at first sight - counter-intuitive course of Italy’s economic and social policy has so factum brutum that, notwithstanding the enor- obviously been affected by the migration burdens mous efforts of Europe’s crisis politics, the econ- that Italy has had to shoulder and the lack of Euro- omies and welfare systems of the EU did not pean solidarity; the bitter disappointment could converge, these differences became instead more be turned into populist critique of the constraints pronounced. We owe the most influential expla- that European rule imposes upon national poli- nations of this phenomenon to the Varieties of cies and the public announcement of disobedi- (VoC) studies initiated by the seminal ence by members of the Italian government. In a volume of Peter A. Hall and David Soskice.4 Their similar vein, the Alternative für Deutschland (AfD) message was that different countries in Europe in Germany had been founded as an anti-Euro have developed different institutional complemen- rescue party, which catalysed quickly through the tarities that give them specific economic advan- immigration crisis of 2015 into a xenophobic far- tages.5 The crisis drastically showcased a strong right populist party, sharing many positions with variety of this within the co-ordinated market the Italian Lega. While the parties and alliances in economies of Europe. VoC scholars amended both countries had capitalised very much upon their theories, underlining the differences in wage- the antagonisms between Italy and Germany and bargaining regimes or union-membership density their positions during the Euro crisis by building between Northern and Southern countries. What on nationalist sentiments, today we have reached the original VoC literature had neglected was that a true anti-climax when one observes that the all European co-ordinated market economies had intensification of tensions are accompanied by the been subject to far-reaching trends of liberalisa- founding of new alliances and a contagion towards tion since the that had been enacted to over- formerly non-populist and non-far right parties in come the low growth of the stagflation crisis of the both countries: “Europe does not want migrants, late 1970s. All countries liberalised, albeit in very it wants our money” (Luigi Di Maio); “Migration different ways which set them on very different is the Mother of all problems” (). growth paths in the and . From Both the AfD in Germany and the Lega in Italy these findings the new growth model literature share two major targets against which they direct emerged, pointing especially to the divergences their rage: European integration, especially in the between the Southern, internal demand-driven economic realm, and immigration. We refrain, growth led, and the Northern, external demand- however, from attempting to disentangle all these driven growth led Member States of the EU/Euro- interdependencies, but hope that our study of the zone. The EMU, with its hard currency approach, two exemplary cases of Italy and Germany will benefits some of these models but puts stress on provide us with some answers to the question of what led us down this road. We believe that the approach which we have pursued in our design 4 Hall, P.A., and Soskice, D. (2001): Varieties of Capitalism: The of this project provides illuminating insights of Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Oxford: lasting importance. Oxford University Press. 5 Hall, Peter A. (2014): “Varieties of Capitalism and the Euro Crisis”, West European Politics 37 (6) (August 14): 1223-1243: id., (2012): “The Economics and Politics of the Euro Crisis”, German Politics, 21:4, 355-371.

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 7 others.6 Even the Commission, traditionally a has re-erupted and become a core problem for the fierce defendant of the convergence approach, has European integration project?9 This is the query recently underlined European diversities. In its which we sought to pursue with the help of the White Paper for a multi-speed Europe, it pleads contributors to the Vigoni conference. It is a long- for differentiated integration.7 The merits of the term agenda. We could not, and did not, expect Varieties of Capitalism approach, upon which a comprehensive coverage of the many aspects the scholarly debate builds, are, in many respects, and dimensions of the diverging socio-economic undeniable. However, we distance ourselves from approaches and needs in both Southern and the one-dimensional reliance on efficiency consid- Northern Europe, or an ideational convergence of erations in the evaluation of institutional comple- the analyses which our contributors were invited mentarities.8 In a similar vein, we also think that to submit. We would, however, like to substan- the material interest kernel of the growth model tiate our own move from the varieties and growth perspective is still incomplete. We believe that model studies in order to a focus on economic more attention should be devoted to the ideational cultures. This move is anything but idiosyncratic. and cultural side of the diversities of Europe’s The concept of “economic cultures” has been organised types of capitalism. These diversities defined and defended by both economic histo- span across the fields of economic, social and legal rians10 and path-breaking comparative law schol- theory, and have evolved in iterative relation with arship.11 One important aspect which is underlined norms, institutions, politics, and cultural historical in both disciplines is the resistance of economic trajectories for centuries. The economy unfolds cultures against the imposition of changes, which not only within a set of institutions that are ratio- can render interventions meaningless or even nally trimmed to maximise profits, but these insti- destructive. Werner Abelshauser submits that the tutions themselves evolve within a cultural envi- imposition of structural reforms through which ronment composed of ideas, ideologies, traditions Europe’s crisis politics seeks to accomplish socio- and the collective sentiments of their people. economic convergence risks, instead, de-stabi- 12 Could such a broadening of analytical perspec- lising the targeted economies further. Gunther tives help us to understand better why the asym- Teubner has submitted corresponding objec- metry between the North and the South of Europe

6 Armingeon, K., Guthmann, K., and Weisstanner, D. (2015): 9 See, recently, Scharpf, F.W. (2016): “Forced Structural Conver- “How the Euro Divides the Union: The Effect of Economic gence in the Eurozone - Or a Differentiated European Mon- Adjustment on Support for Democracy in Europe”, Socio-Eco- etary Community”, MPIfG Discussion Paper 16/15, available nomic Review 14(1): 1 26. First published online: 12 November at: http://www.mpi-fg-koeln.mpg.de/pu/mpifg_dp/dp16-15. 2015. DOI: 10.1093/ser/mwv028; see, also, Armingeon, K., pdf (last accessed 21 June 2017). and Baccaro, L. (2014): “Germania: l’indomabile trading state”, Quaderni di rassegna sindacale - Lavori[check]”, 15: 2, 19-45; 10 Abelshauser, W. (2003): Kulturkampf: Der deutsche Weg in English version: Armingeon, K., and Baccaro, L. (2014): “The die Neue Wirtschaft und die amerikanische Herausforderung, Crisis and Germany: The Trading State Unleashed”, in: Eber- Berlin: Kadmos. Abelshauser, W., Gilgen, D. and Leutzsch, A. lein, B., and Schneider, V. (eds): Complex Democracy. Varieties, (eds) (2013), Kulturen der Weltwirtschaft, Göttingen: Vanden- Crisis, and Transformations, Wiesbaden: Springer VS, 165-184. hoek und Ruprecht. 7 “White paper on the future of Europe. Reflections and sce- 11 Teubner, G. (2001): “How Unifying Law Ends Up in New narios for the EU27 by 2025”, COM(2017) 2025 of 1 March Differences”, in: Hall. P.A., and Soskice, D. (eds), Varieties 2017. See, for a scholarly discussion, Schmidt, V. (2017): of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative “Inventing a New Future for Europe: Differentiated Integration Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 417-441. with more EU and more Member-States?”, Ms. Boston (on file 12 Abelshauser, W. (2018): “Europa in Vielfalt einigen. Eine with authors). Denkschrift“, in: Atkinson, A.B., Huber, P.M., James, H., 8 Streeck, W. (2005): “Requirements for a useful Concept of Scharpf, F.W. (eds), Nationalstaat und Europäische Union. Eine Complementarity”, in: Crouch, C., Streeck, W., Boyer, R., Am- Bestandsaufnahme, Baden-Baden: Nomos, 2016, 275-294, able, B., Hall, P.A., and Jackson, G., “Dialogue on ‘Institutional available at: http://wwwhomes.uni-bielefeld.de/wabelsha/ Complementarities and Political Economy’”, Socio Economic Denkschrift.pdf (last accessed 21 June 2017); id., “Viele Wege Review 3, 359-382. führen nach Rom”, FAZ, Nr. 61, 30.3.2017, 6.

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 8 tions against legal unification politics.13 Both of III. The Individual them refrain - in this respect fully in line with Contributions the messages of VoC studies - from a ranking of the models that they have discerned; they high- Our overriding concern is a renewal of the debate light their specific advantages, instead. The differ- on Europe’s diversity. The challenges are manifold. ence is that the economic cultures approach does We distinguish between thematic, conceptual, not solely focus on institutional configurations and normative dimensions. What is certainly not (VoC) and sectoral interests (growth models) but unique, but still quite innovative about our agenda also includes a distinctively historical perspective is the multi-dimensional approach to the integra- that sheds light on the political evolution of these tion process. We deal with “Europeanisation” in economies and how it is embedded in national the conventional sense of the establishment of cultures, traditions, and economic ideas.14 More- European rules, policies, and governance prac- over, while VoC research is firmly in the hands of tices. The EU, we have internalised this message political economists and sociologists, the notion since way back, is a multi-level system. We are, of economic cultures is more integrative, synthe- of course, also aware of implementation studies sising history, law, politics, , anthro- which have highlighted the failings or unevenness pology, and cognitive science. It seems to us to of the European praxis. Our focus on the German- be especially odd that law is left by the wayside Italian discrepancies highlights a phenomenon in most political and social analyses of European which the “ever more Europe” mantra of Euro- forms of capitalism. We ask ourselves, how should pean studies tends to neglect. “More Europe” has the abundance of proposals to better the socio- an discomforting destructive potential. What is economic aspects of the state of integration be put perceived as a new accomplishment of the process into practice without thinking through their legal may generate disintegrative effects.16 Indeed, practicality and implementation. Accordingly, one what we document is that our two cases, Italy and of the objectives of our conference was to build a Germany, have, in the structure of their econo- bridge between the VoC, the growth model, and mies, not converged, but rather grown apart since the economic cultures perspectives. Maastricht. What we highlight is that disintegra- What we suggest is that Europe should stop tion is not only bad within a Member State, but lamenting about its diversity. It should, instead, may also – and here the tensions between Italy and learn to take the fortunate motto of the ill-fated Germany are of exemplary importance – affect constitutional Treaty of 2004 seriously and learn the Union as a whole: the “ever closer Union” is to establish its unitas in diversitate.15 We even characterised by ever more hostility. Last, but not expect that this learning process has the potential least, we have to take into account what is left of to generate political, social and economic benefits. the political “ownership” of the Member States. We disagree with qualifications of this residual power as an obstacle to smooth implementation. We believe that it would, instead, be important to 13 N. 10 above. 14 Another leading authority in this regard is Alexander Nützen- adel, whose research includes intensive studies of the Italian 16 See, for a general debate, Annegret Eppler and Henrik economy; suffice it here to name two projects: “Programmare Scheller (eds), Europäische Desintegration in Zeiten der il miracolo economico?” Industriepolitik in Italienzwischen Krise. Zur Konzeptionalisierung europäischer Desintegra- Boom und Krise, 1958-1973”, (DFG, 2011-2013); “Experience tion, Baden-Baden: Nomos 2013; on the case of EMU, and Expectation: Historical Foundations of Economic Behav- see Fritz W. Scharpf, “The Costs of Non-disintegration: ior”, (DFG, 2015-2022); see https://www.geschichte.hu-berlin. The Case of the European Monetary Union”, in: Chalm- de/de/bereiche-und-lehrstuehle/sozial-wirtschaftsgeschichte/ ers, D., Jachtenfuchs, M., and Joerges, C. (eds), The End forschung (last accessed 21 June 2017). of the Eurocrats’ Dream: Adjusting to European Diversity, 15 CT 2ßß4 by Motto of the Draft Constitutional Treaty 2004 Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2016, 29-49.

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 9 take cultural diversities into account.17 Manow defends the German reforms against This latter observation concerns our core theo- many internal and external critics by arguing that retical message to which we will return in the it has led to “dualisation” but not to a decrease in following comments on the individual contribu- the social protection of the core of the workforce. tions. Moreover, in contrast to what the critics antici- pated, the structural reforms did not lead to a dete- A) The political economy of rioration of the well-protected core of the work- Germany and Italy force, but, instead, made it larger. Today, Germany has, together with , the second most active Today, we have a plethora of rivalling explana- workforce, and differs, in this respect, remarkably tions of why the Eurozone crisis happened.18 All of from Italy. Manow acknowledges that the trans- them agree on one point: the currency union was formation of the German model has put severe too heterogeneous for a single currency. But what stress on the Southern European political econ- is it really that makes these economies and their omies. Germany had a tradition of coping with demands to a common regulatory framework, hard currency while the demand-led regimes of market and currency so different and have they the South are penalised by the Euro. They cannot converged over time? In Part One of our collec- devaluate any longer. The introduction of the Euro tion, we unleash five political economists to come and the Eurozone crisis have cemented these two to terms with this question, by comparing the different political economic models in Europe: an Italian and German political economies. export-oriented Northern model and an internal- demand-driven Southern model. Manow sees two 19 Philip Manow gives us a meticulous account ways forward for the Eurozone: 1. Painstaking of the transformation of the German political structural reforms in the South backed through economy during the past twenty years. He argues heavy transfers form the North or, 2. The split of that the tradition of supply-side corporatism the Eurozone into two different currency zones. in Germany enabled socio-economic actors to co-ordinate wage restraint and to embark on Donato Di Carlo challenges this view and the painstaking structural reforms that, together, underlying assumptions of the growth model successfully transitioned the German economy perspective in Manow’s account. Comparing wage from its position as sick man to that of the strong development and wage-setting institutions for man of Europe during the 2000s and . Here, the public sector in Italy and Germany, he points out that it is not wage restraint and co-ordina- 17 As we will underline, the trenches between the disciplines are tion between the social partners which led to as deep as ever; there are very few lawyers who have followed the freezing of public sector wages in Germany the Variety of Capitalism studies. Among the few, the most famous is Gunther Teubner. His discovery of the resistance but the idiosyncratic wage-setting dynamics in of legal cultures against imposed unification (“Legal Irritants: German federalism. In Italy, in contrast, he argues Good Faith in British Law”, (1998) 61 Modern Law Review, 11- it is not due to un-coordinated bids by multiple 32) was re-published at the best conceivable location: see n.10 trade unions that first strongly increased and above. later cut public-sector wages, but, instead, the 18 The latest account we became aware of is Ashoka Mody’s EuroTragedy. A Drama in Nine Acts, Oxford, OUP, 2018. political geography of Italy, where parties in the Ashoka’s reconstructions reach far beyond economic oc- South must rely heavily on the votes form public- curences. His chapter 8 on Italy ( pp. 318-360) documents his sector employees, which is decisive. The implica- precise awareness of the specifics of Italy’s institutional and political constellations - and their apparently irresolvable prob- tions elaborated in Di Carlo’s study for the current lems. trend in political economy, towards the growth 19 Philip, Manow, “The German Political Economy under the model perspective, are huge: wage restraint is Euro – and a Comparison to the ‘Southern Model’”, (2018), A not part of an intelligent design. A growth model 1.

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 10 or regime does not exist; instead, unintended as ordoliberalism and Italian style Keynesianism, outcomes created through institutional configu- Bruno concludes that the influence of ideas can rations of the German polity (federalism) condi- only be understood if they are put into the context tioned parts of the new export-orientation of the of the political landscape and electoral coalitions German economy. Hence, also the accusations in both countries. Like Di Carlo, Bruno points at from Southern European countries waged against the importance of political and electoral coalitions the German export surplus fall short. The co-ordi- for Italian Eurozone positions. The focus is hereby nation power that the growth model perspec- on the political split of the country between tive ascribes to all actors does not exist. Di Carlo North and South. National traditions of economic returns to this with a second contribution in the thought matter, not as direct causal factors, but Annex.20 because they are used as cues to the electorate. Margarita Estevez-Abe, who is among the origina- What we have assembled so far are contributions tors of the Varieties of Capitalism school, provides from different analytical and methodological us with a glance form the outside helping us to angles in which institutions, interests and ideas come to terms with the controversial discussion all feature separately as explanatory variables. about the German export-led growth regime.21 This calls for synthetisation. In the last contri- Using Japan as a counterfactual allows her to bution to Part One, Josef Hien introduces the control for the impact of a unified currency zone. concept of cultural political economy to integrate Estevez-Abe shows that Germany does not only the above laid out approaches to the crisis.23 For hide behind the EU when it gets accused of trade the rest of social science, culture as an explana- deficits by the US and other international actors tory variable is (often not unfoundedly), accused but that Germany, benefited enormously form the of being a residual category that is evoked when all Euro. The Euro made German exports cheaper. other explanations fail. However, the strength of a Hence, the German role within the single currency cultural political economy is that it can integrate has not only led to tensions between North and the trichotomy between institutions, interests, South in Europe but has triggered heavy geo-polit- and ideas. As in Weber’s famous switchmen meta- ical stress. Merkel’s reply to Donald Trump cited phor, it is not interest, ideas or institutions that as the opener in Estevez-Abe’s fascinating study determine , but all of them together. When nails it: “You can’t do a trade deal with Germany, interest, institutions and ideas all point in the same only the EU.” direction, they form a self-reinforcing compound, While the first three contributions to this volume an amalgam that is very hard to overcome or to deal with economic institutions (Manow), polit- break up, even for a superpower like the EU. Hien ical institutions (Di Carlo) and economic inter- uses neo-Weberian theory to build an integrative ests (Estevez-Abe), Federico Bruno analyses in analytical framework to explain from a long-term the fourth contribution the prevalent economic historical-sociological perspective why Italy and ideas that led Italy and Germany into the forma- Germany seem to be set on different tracks. With tion of the Eurozone and guided them through a special focus on the diverging cultural back- the economic crisis.22 Assessing the explanatory ground of both countries, Hien re-constructs the value of idiosyncratic socio-economic ideas such pathways of both political economies since the 1950s, explaining how they could end up in such 20 Donato Di Carlo, “Germany is Quietly Rebalancing its Economy – But this will not Fix the Eurozone’s Flaws“ (2018). different positions today. Annex 3. All five contributions in Part One of our collection 21 “Geo-Politics of Exporting Too Much: Contrasting Trajecto- ries of Germany and Japan”. show that Italy and Germany have grown apart, 22 “Ideational differences between Italian and German govern- 23 “Cultural Foundations of the Italian and German Political ments during the crisis”. Economy.”

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 11 rather than converged, during the past 30 years. clusters of Southern-European housing-construc- Now, we will look at divergences across specific tion economies and Northern-rental-export econ- sectors of the economy in Part Two. omies on the agenda. With the banking sector, we look at another crucial B) Sectors of the Political infrastructural backbone of the Italian and German Economy of Italy and Germany economy. Frederik Traut scrutinises the interven- tions in both countries during the banking crisis.25 Part One of the present collection showed us how Somewhat unexpectedly, he finds that Germany, the divergences of the German and Italian political in staunch neglect of its supposed ordoliberal economies play out on the aggregated level, but orientation, intervened heavily once its banking we know little about how the divergences manifest sector got into trouble during the great financial across different sectors of the economy. We have crisis. In the case of IKB, a bank specialised in selected the housing-construction sectors and the lending to small and medium-size enterprises, the banking sectors as prime infrastructural back- government injected 7 bn Euros out of fear that bones of both systems. These are supplemented the failing of the bank would bring down the rest with a comparative study on family cultures and of the economy. After this and other large-scale family policy in both cases. Albeit not an economic bail-outs in Germany, the government was eager sector in the strict traditional sense (though child to promote a harsh bail-in regulation at European and elderly care employ ever more people) and a level. In Italy, due to better banking supervision, policy-field that is usually side-lined in the main- the government did not have to intervene in the stream political economy literature, we want to banking sector. However, once the financial crisis highlight its cross-sectoral implications since it gave way to a global recession, this changed due is central to the functioning of the economy as a to many non-performing loans that Italian banks whole, structuring the supply of young and skilled had given to companies now hit by the recession. workforce. Italy therefore faced a hidden, longer and time- Sebastian Kohl and Alexander Spielau target the lagged banking crisis, in contrast to Germany. “forgotten sector” of housing and construction, With the new European regulation in place that as they call it in their contribution.24 Pointing to the Germans had pushed for, the Italian govern- its impact on employment and GDP growth, they ment saw its hands tied once the slow-boiling observe that it is strange that classical political crisis became ever more evident in Italy. Traut economy sidesteps it. Kohl and Spielau point out argues, convincingly in our view, that the Italian that housing and construction differs dramatically government had no other option than to circum- between both countries and that it plays a central vent the new regulation giving its banks the same role in both economies. While the existence of a medicine that the German banks had obtained large rental stock reinforces the export led-growth from their government before, facing, however, model of Germany, the large homeownership strong criticism from Germany. Lucia Quaglia’s rates in Italy fuel into an internal demand-driven contribution corroborates Traut’s findings.26 She economy in Italy. This led to different demands and scrutinises the policy-process around the estab- requirements that both countries have towards the lishment of the banking union, pointing out single currency. In a meticulously well-informed that Germany’s and Italy’s preferences and posi- and detailed study, the authors follow the trajecto- tions were at odds, representing the North-South ries of the housing sectors of both countries from cleavage within the , in which the WW II till today, putting the thesis of distinct 25 “Banking Crisis Interventions in Germany and Italy: The Un- 24 Sebastian Kohl and Alexander Spielau, “Worlds Apart: the Di- pleasant Case of the New European Bank Resolution Frame- vergences of Southern European Housing-construction Econo- w or k .” mies and Northern European Export Economies” (2018). 26 “Comparing the German and Italian Approaches to Banking Union.”

12 INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS decisive difference was in the fact that Germany C) German and Italian Percep- had already overcome its banking crisis. Traut’s tions, Differences and Misgivings and Quaglia’s findings resonate well with Kohl and Spielau’s: the different impact and unfolding of the So far our collection shows that both countries banking crisis stems from the structural difference have grown apart since the 1990s. The differences between the banking and lending sectors in Italy in institutions, interests and culture that set both and Germany, that evolve from the differences in economies apart have a dire impact on the feeling the housing and construction sectors. of citizens towards one another. The adverse feel- The Varieties of Capitalism and growth model ings to one another and towards the EU have also perspectives neglect family policy and family re-structured the party systems in both countries. cultures, which are crucial to understand the The backdrop to these attitudinal changes is the widening gap between Italy’s and Germany’s different experience of the crisis and of the struc- socio-economic profiles. Agnes Blome sheds light tural reform process connected to it. on the staunchly diverse paths that the two coun- Alessandro Pelegatta shows how the widening gap tries have followed since the 1990s. In the early between Italy and Germany in institutions, social 1990s, Italy and Germany shared similar conser- structure and political attitudes is mirrored in the vative cultures and institutions concerning early attitudes of the citizens of both countries towards childcare and the employment of women with one another.28 This view is strongly associated children.27 In both countries, female employ- with the feelings that the citizens of both countries ment rates hovered just above 50 per cent. In the have towards the EU. Italian citizens tend to blame 2000s, Germany embarked on a reform trajectory Germany for the Euro crisis and for the bad Italian abolishing the male-breadwinner-centred family economic situation. They think that Germany is policy model that had been in place for over half abusing its power in Europe and that its behaviour a century by introducing parental leave schemes has made the crisis worse. The EU, in this sense, and early child-care coverage for under three- has become a project dominated by Germany. year-olds. Blome shows how a change in cultural Moreover, the countries have reversed their posi- values after the 1990s accelerated the German tions regarding their position towards European reform trajectory, while Italy did not experience integration. While, traditionally, Italians have such a change in values. As a result, the mothers been in favour of integration while Germans were employment rates in Italy have only moved from sceptical, the past decade saw the inversion of 54 to 56 percentage points during the past 30 years these positions. while the German mothers employment rate is Hanspeter Kriesi illuminates how this fed into with over 70 per cent, the second highest in the the new party system configurations in Italy and EU. Germany.29 He embeds the two most recent elec- We see now that both economies reacted differ- tions in Germany and Italy into the wider Euro- ently not only when one looks at them from an pean picture and the trends of party-system aggregated perspective as we did in Part One, but change, pointing to profound tensions between also across different sectors of the economy, as we the élites and the people in both countries, which showed in Part Two. This, as we will now show in have given rise to populist challenger parties. The Part Three, has impacted strongly on the attitudes flaring up of the party systems has made govern- that German and Italian citizens have towards ment formation difficult and while Germany opted each other, and how they perceive their country’s for the old grand-coalition model, Italy has now relation to the European Union. 28 “Italy and Germany during the Crisis. Support of the EU and Reciprocal Views.” 27 “Maternal employment, attitudes toward gender equal- ity and work-family policies. German-Italian Discrepan- 29 “The Political Space in Italy and Germany during the Crisis: cies”? Italian and German Populism Compared.”

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 13 an all populist government. Both, Kriesi argues, and Northern European governments. This links are unstable. The model because well into the first-hand practitioner insights that it “ain’t so grand no more”, combining only 53 per Filippo Taddei provides for the Italian case, in cent of votes. The Italian government coalition which he theorises form his experiences about the is unstable due to the tensions between the two necessity of domestic political ownership as a pre- populist parties on ideological issues. condition for a successful structural reforms in the Providing the background for the populist surge, European South. Filippo Taddei takes issue both with the term and Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula’s contribu- demand for structural reforms.30 Having been tion shows how the Europe 2020 framework is involved as practitioner in the Jobs Act reform in implemented in very different ways in national Italy, he launches a powerful argument that struc- contexts.32 The authors give us a wonderful study tural reforms, as demanded by Northern European of the contrasting implementation of poverty and states from Southern European countries in crisis, social exclusion policies in Italy and Germany can only be structural if they can marshal polit- during the first five cycles of the European semester. ical and popular consensus at home. Comparing This also shows that the differences between the Fornero Pension Reform of 2011 with the Jobs welfare-state institutions in Italy and Germany Act of 2015, two structural reforms enacted in have become broader, instead of narrower, over Italy during the crisis, Taddei concludes that “only the past two decades. Both countries fight poverty reforms investing political capital and gathering very differently under the same European provi- consensus in their scope can persist in time and sions. Germany distorted the policy framework to affect ordinary economic and social behaviour”. fit with its century old traditions and institutions He thereby provides a clue as to why the struc- of poverty relief and social exclusion policies. In tural reforms in Italy, seen by the population as Italy, in contrast, the targets and the institutions imposed from the North, have led to anti German that proposed were fully embraced since and anti-EU feelings, as described by both Pele- the country had only a weak social exclusion and gatta and Kriesi. It also explains why these reforms poverty relief policy before. The contribution not are about to be partly rolled back by the new only provides a rigid analysis of the policy process, populist government, and makes a strong case for but also theorises when and how EU programmes the counter-productivity of octruating structural are implemented or re-formulated to fit national reforms from the outside. traditions and culture. Manos Matsaganis looks at the impact of the What we have seen in Part Three of our collection European crisis and its aftermath in the European is that the structural and widening differences South with a special focus on the Italian (non-) between both countries have an impact on public recovery.31 Analysing and comparing economic opinion, party systems, and government forma- indicators both pre- and post-crisis, Manos find- tion. With the assessment of structural reforms ings are shocking. Portugal, but none of the other in Italy and the diverging ways in which the EU Southern European countries are back to pre- provisions are implemented in both countries, we crisis levels of economic performance. Besides the have also come to a first idea of about why, after 30 worst-case scenario of Greece, Italy is the second years of accelerated and forceful socio-economic worst off. Matsaganis hints at the co-evolution of integration in Europe, the two countries are still political extremism in the European South (except “worlds apart from one another”. in Portugal) with the way in which the crisis was handled in terms of structural reforms by the EU

30 “European Integration and Political Ownership: Fiction and 32 “Accommodating EU’s Influence vs Protecting National Sover- Reality behind Structural Reforms and Risk Sharing.” eignty. The Fight Against Poverty in Italy and Germany at the 31 “The Political Economy of Recovery in Southern Europe.” Time of ‘Europe 2020’.”

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 14 D) The Legacy of the Welfare are not impressed, however. Rödl lists the many State in Europe obstacles against the realisation of a common social legislative agenda and opts for a re-orien- Ever since Alan Milward’s seminal study on The tation of the conceptualisation of the function European Rescue of the Welfare State33 “Social of the economic freedoms which would inhibit Europe” and the search for a “European Social their instrumentalisation for a de-regulation of Model” keeps irritating the students of European national social accomplishments. Bogoeski reads integration – conceptually, empirically, and politi- the proclamation of the Social Pillar as an exer- cally. Milward’s rescue thesis was published in the cise in whitewashing, an example of what Giando- year which witnessed the signing of the Maastricht menico Majone has characterised as the European Treaty and the move towards a common currency. élites’ “political culture of total optimism”.41 The It is difficult to read these events as a “rescue Pillar is soft indeed. This softness contrasts mark- operation” and Bo Stråth, Milward’s successor at edly not only with the above-mentioned jurispru- the EUI History Department, had good reasons dence of the CJEU and the imposition of internal to underline that this Union was no longer the devaluation in Europe’s austerity politics, but Europe of Milward.34 And yet, in a paradoxical even, as Francesco Costamagna underlines, with sense, Milward’s thesis has regained topicality. In the implementation of the European Semester.42 his October 2014 speech to the European Parlia- His observations document that the perception ment, European Commission President elect, Jean- of a great diversity of socio-economic conditions, Claude Juncker, spoke of his wish for Europe to to which the semester responds, is counteracted be “triple-A on social issues”, putting social issues by the uniformity of neoliberal recipes which further up on the agenda.35 Pamela Pansardi36 orient the management of the semester. These shows that it was not only this speech but that tensions are an acid test for our assumptions on all his speeches are decisively more pro welfare the resilience of national economic cultures. Two in their vocabulary than those of the previous contributions are illuminating here. As Marcel Barroso Commission. What this was supposed to Hadeed, in his analysis of the Reception of the mean was codified in the European Pillar of Social “Social Pillar” shows, the weight attributed by Rights,37 and subsequently solemnly supported the German government and its Fachbürokratie by the Commission, the Council and the Euro- to this noble initiative, is “en quelque façon nul”. 43 pean Parliament.38 This is definitely a spectacular This seems, in the sphere of social policy, all the return of “the social” on the European agenda. more remarkable as Minister for Labour and Both Florian Rödl39 and Vladimir Bogoeski40 Social Affairs, , is a Social Demo- 33 Alan Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation State, New crat and by no means from the right wing of York: Routledge 1992. that party. Hadeed cites the German Finance 34 Bo Stråth, “Still the Europe of Milward? On the Need for a Minister, also a Social Democrat, assuring us that New Long-Term Historical Understanding of Today’s Europe”, UCL Working Paper No. 1/2011, 2011. “a German finance minister is a German finance 35 “A New Start for Europe”, Strasbourg, 15 July 2014, available at minister regardless of his party card”. The agenda http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_SPEECH-14-567_en.htm. of the Minister for Labour and Social Affairs is not 36 “A ‘more political’ leadership for the President of the Commis- sion? A mixed-methods language based analysis.” 41 “The Deeper Euro-Crisis or: The Collapse of the EU Political 37 Ibid. Culture of Total Optimism,” Working Paper, 2015, available at: 38 Proclamation of the European Pillar of Social Rights, Gothen- http://cadmus.eui.eu//handle/1814/35281. burg, 17 November 2017. 42 “Industrial Relations and Labour Law in the EU Economic 39 “An Alternative to the Constitution of the EU’s Single Mar- Governance Mechanisms: The Cases of Italy and Germany”. ket”? 43 “What to Expect from Germany for the European Pillar of 40 “The EU Political Culture of Total Optimism is not Dead: The Social Rights?” Case of the European Pillar of Social Rights.”

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 15 that of the conservative coalition partner, but it to confirm that this new constellation is here to is entirely German in the definition of its priori- stay and would deserve this quasi-constitutional ties. An important determinant in Germany is its importance. These new uncertainties are accom- fiscal federalism which has institutionalised a low- panied by another tectonic shift in the contest wage equilibrium. The Italian pattern is character- of disciplines. Thanks to the preoccupation of ised by conditions which favour the toleration of European élites with the financial crisis, econo- inflationary wage increases. Is it at all conceivable mists occupy the driver’s seat when it comes to that Europe can create the “institutional determi- providing practical advice. The paradigms and nants of balanced wage growth”? The fundamental rationality criteria of economics, however, are dilemma of national political autonomy is a risk distinct and not really reconcilable with those for the priorities of European governance that of the social sciences, let alone, the normative have been established. The control of these condi- concerns of lawyers, and certainly not akin to the tions, however, would require extremely complex kind of agenda which we are pursuing.45 and demanding responses. And a recipe that may Both the disciplinary composition of our partici- work for the German-Italian case, will hardly work pants and the substance of their comments mirror in the entire Union. this constellation quite faithfully. Only three econ- omist attended the conference.46 The number E) The Demise of Law of lawyers still seems considerable. There is not much left, however, of the once widespread belief A little more than two decades ago, just a few years that law would be both “the agent and the object after a, then, young post-Ernst Haas generation of of integration”.47 The contributions that we have political scientists, had (re-) discovered the inte- assembled in section F are anything but affirma- gration process as a worthwhile academic topic, tive. Katharina Mangold’s48 comments on the Christian Joerges urged these newcomers “to role of the Commission touch upon a very sensi- take the law seriously”.44 Those years witnessed tive issue of general importance. She takes issue a “golden age” of interdisciplinary studies, with with Commissioner Oettinger’s comments on legal scholarship exploring more curiously then Italian politics. This is well argued. However, the ever the operation of legal actors, the context, and Commission is, next to the ECB, the most impor- the impact of legal prescriptions; political scien- tant example for what Paul Tucker characterises tists were - often enough - inspiring such innova- as an “unelected power”.49 The Commission has to tive endeavours. By now, these times are gone. The compensate for its democratic deficit by expertise reasons or this are complex and somewhat para- and objectivity. And yet, even where it acts as a doxical. The earlier interdisciplinary co-operation rested on the implicit transdisciplinary assump- 45 The only transdisciplinary approach we are aware of is “Constitutional economics” as inspired by James tion that integration was a good thing which Buchanan and defended in particular by the “third gen- deserved to be promoted. After a decade of finan- eration” of the Freiburg school; see most prominently cial crisis, this seems no longer so unquestionable. Lars Feld, “Eine Europäische Verfassung aus polit-öko- nomischerSicht”, ORDO – Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von The prevailing attitude in other disciplines is quite Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 54 (2003), 289-317. similar. Lawyers observe and meticulously docu- 46 Frederik Traut, see Section C 3. ment the establishment of a new “crisis law”. Polit- 47 Dehousse, R., and Weiler, J.H.H., “The Legal Dimension”, ical scientists observe and document with great in: Wallace, W. (ed.), The Dynamics of European Integration, precision the growth of European powers and London: Pinter, 242-260. governance practices. Both disciplines hesitate 48 “The EU Commission as ‘Honest Broker’? German and Italian Perspectives on an Administrative Body”. 44 “Taking the Law Seriously: On Political Science and 49 Tucker, P. (2018), Unelected Power. The Quest for the Role of Law in the Process of European Integration”, Legitimacy in Central Banking and the Regulatory State, European Law Journal, 2 (1996), 105-135. Princeton NJ-Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2018.

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 16 “guardian of the Treaty”, it cannot avoid exerting of formal rules and “social norms”, which, only in power and should, precisely for this reason, act their complementarity, ensure the functioning of more prudently than Oettinger did. The other economic and political systems. His conceptuali- lawyers address more general discrepancies sation is an exercise in sociological jurisprudence between the legal design of the integration project with great affinities to Hien’s notion of economic and its actual functions and performance. Their cultures.57 And it should be apparent that there is object is the transformation of the Union in the no contradiction between such perceptions of an course of the financial crisis. They all diagnose the erosion of legalism and a disintegration of Euro- failings of the “integration through law” agenda. pean studies with the insistence of the contribu- These failings have a long history. They became tors to section D on the viability of legal protection dramatically apparent, when the Union under- against marketisation processes which threaten took its “turn to governance”, which was essentially the social existence of workers. meant to overcome the limits of European powers where the need to take action seemed urgent.50 F) Justice, Security, Finances President Mario Draghi’s proclaimed readiness and Solidarity to do “whatever it takes”51 is evidence of the same strategy.52 Nicole Scicluna53 underlines the author- Throughout all of the contributions we observe itarian and coercive mode of the European crisis concerns about the future of Europe which explic- management and adds that the imposed inte- itly or at least implicitly assume that the present gration strategy may end up in disintegration state of the Union should not be petrified as its new through the erosion of the legitimacy of the Euro- normalcy. The pertinent suggestions, however, all pean project. Both Christian Joerges54 and Karl- operate in the shadow of Hegel’s Ohnmacht des Heinz Ladeur55 address the same concerns, albeit Sollens (powerlessness of the ought). Where we in different ways. In Joerges’ understanding, the imagine the contours of a better European future, democratic deficiency of Europe’s crisis politics we are plagued by scepticism. Does it really make stems, in the last instance, from its disregard of the sense to come up with proposals which seem so legitimate political ordering of “the economic” in obviously unrealistic? We suggest that it does. We constitutional democracies.56 Ladeur’s account is believe that even “unrealistic” proposals can help less “legalistic”. He underlines the interdependence us to understand Europe’s present better; we also believe that Europe’s presence is characterised by 50 Joerges, C, “Integration through de-legislation? An irritated such high uncertainties that complacency with heckler”, European Governance Papers (EUROGOV) No. N-07-03, available at: http://www.connex-network.org/eu- regard to the presence is anything but comforting. rogov/pdf/egp-newgov-N-07-03.pdf. The three contributions in the present section F 51 Verbatim at https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/2012/ pursue very different strategies. html/sp120726.en.html. 52 Draghi wisely added that this occurred “within our mandate”. Libraries have been filled with literature on the 58 53 “Integration-through-crisis as a distinct integrative mode: democratic deficit of the EU. Glyn Morgan, Placing expediency ahead of democracy”? however, focuses on another issue, the problem 54 “The Challenge of Socio-Economic Varieties to the Law of justice. Constitutionalists tend to address this of European Integration”. issue in the context of the powers of the EU either 55 “The End of the Universality of Norms as a Model for Europe –The Error of “Seeing like a State” (J. S. Scott) in the Postmod- in the realm of labour law and welfare politics, ern Condition”. or in the context of constitutional commitments, 56 The diagnosis of a crisis of law is compatible with such as the Sozialstaatsklausel of the German Scicluna’s findings; see, also, C. Joerges and C. Kreuder- Basic Law. Both the debates on welfare politics Sonnen, “European Studies and the European Crisis: Legal and Political Science between Critique and Com- 57 A 4. placency”, European Law Journal, 23 (2017): 118-139. 58 “Is the EU Unjust”?

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 17 and the debate between Habermas and Streeck, as Zgaga’s analysis of the reasons is revealing with re-constructed by Joerges,59 testify to a difficulty respect to the importance of the cultural determi- of fundamental importance: Is a European Sozi- nants of economic policy. There is a strong touch alstaat at all conceivable or can Sozialsaatlichkeit of ordoliberalism in the German resistance, inter- be realised only by nation states? Morgan’s shift to estingly one which is not identical with party affil- “justice” bypasses this dichotomy. The European iations: “Everywhere in Europe I said: a German project, he submits, can be and should be justi- finance minister is a German finance minister…”63 fied by the security that it ensures for the citizens The distinction between justice “within” and justice of the Union. This is a defence of “deep” integra- “between” the Member States, which Morgan tion, albeit an unconventional one. Members of underlines, was of no concern in the homoge- a polity which ensures their security “owe each neous world of the old EEC. This changed with other the duty to guarantee the conditions of secu- the enlargements of the Union. What emerged as rity. This duty will have distributive implications, a concern then became dramatic after the estab- but different distributive implications than within lishment of the EMU and the discipline imposed a nation-state”. on the members of the Eurozone. We have to (re-) Tiziano Zgaga’s essay departs from a dense and solidarise Europe in order to defuse the still viru- instructive re-construction of the Commission’s lent crisis and its impact - both within and between proposal for a European Minister of Economy the Member States, argue Maurizio Ferrera and and Finance.60 Whoever remembers the remark of Carlo Burelli.64 Their finding is that EMU has the former President of the Bundesbank, Helmut created interdependencies and dynamics which Schlesinger, in the proceedings on the Maastricht are beyond our control. Their notion capturing Treaty before the Bundesverfassungsgericht “that a this state of affairs is the “complex adaptive system currency union, especially between States which (CAS)”. The tragedy is that the “properties of a are oriented towards an active economic and social CAS are not merely causally active but become policy, can ultimately only be realised in common irreducible and irreversible”. “Solidarity” is a with a political union (embracing all essential commitment enshrined in Article 2 TEU. It has to economic functions) and cannot be realised inde- be fleshed out – and then implemented in a Union pendently thereof or as a mere preliminary stage of ever deepening diversity and conflicts. on the way to it”,61 will remain impressed but disappointed. There is enormous ingenuity in the Commission’s proposals. There are also unset- tled constitutional and political issues such as the growth of ever more “unelected power”.62 Zgaga addresses these in the second section of his essay. His own views are close to Schlesinger’s position. Of particular interest in the present context is his re-construction of the German and the Italian position. Unsurprisingly, these diverge drastically.

59 F 3. 60 “A European Minister of Economy and Finance: Assessing the Commission’s Proposal and Comparing Germany’s and Italy’s Position”. 61 2 BvR 2134/92 & 2159/92, BVerfGE 89, 155. English transla- tion: Manfred Brunner and Others v. The European Union 63 Social Democrat (minister of finance) on 22 Treaty [1994] 1 Common Market Law Reports 57 (para. 92). March 2018, cited in Hadeed, D 4. 62 See n. 50 above. 64 “Re-solidarising Europe and Defusing the Crisis”.

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 18 G) Annex

We have included in this Annex, two contributions which were not presented at the Vigoni confer- ence. They represent, in our view, the spectre of options which we have to face. Claus Offe and Maurizio Ferrera’s opt for a turn to solidarity. Such a turn, they add, is unlikely to occur deliberately; Europe will nevertheless be forced into it.65 Di Carlo closes the Annex, showing how Germany is quietly re-balancing its economy.66

65 “Order in the Eurozone”. Claus Offe has elaborated his views in: Europe Entrapped, Cambridge: Polity Press, 2015, and “Europe Entrapped. Does the EU have the Political Capacity to Overcome its Current Crisis?”, European Law Journal 19 (2013): 595-611. 66 “Germany is quietly Rebalancing its Economy – But this will not Fix the Eurozone’s Flaws.”

INTRODUCTORY EXPLANATIONS 19 CONTRIBUTORS He has been faculty member of the Center for Transnational Legal Studies (Georgetown Univer- Agnes Blome is a post-doctoral fellow at the sity) and Guest Professor at the Goethe Univer- Otto-Suhr-Institute of the Free University Berlin. sity . He is currently serving as national Blome is interested in comparative welfare state expert of MoveS (Free Movement of Workers and research, women’s political representation, and Social Security Coordination), a network funded the relationship between people’s attitudes and by the European Commission. His research mainly policy-making. She received her Ph.D. from the deals with the relationship between economic Humboldt-University Berlin and worked at the integration and social protection systems in the WZB Berlin Social Science Center. Her most EU legal order, with a specific focus on the rela- discussed book is The Politics of Work-Family Poli- tionship between the European economic gover- cies in Germany and Italy. nance and the EU social dimension. Moreover, he has worked extensively on intra-EU mobility and [email protected] free movement of workers. He is the author of a Vladimir Bogoeski is a PhD Candidate at the book, articles and book chapters, both in English Hertie School of Governance and affiliated and Italian, on these and other related topics. member of the doctoral programme “Unity and [email protected] Diversity in the European Legal Area” at the Humboldt University (European Law School). His Donato Di Carlo is a Ph.D. Candidate at the Ph.D. studies are funded by the German Academic Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies, Merit Foundation (Studienstiftung des Deutschen in . He works in European comparative Volkes). He holds degrees in Law from Ss. Cyril political economy with a focus on models of capi- and Methodius University of Skopje (LLB) and talism, wage setting systems and public admin- University of Bremen (LLM). In 2018, Bogoeski istrations. In his Ph.D. he studies the political was visiting research fellow at Fordham Law and institutional determinants of public sector School in New York. His thesis focuses on the ever wage-setting in Germany and Italy, in relation to growing tension between economic and social processes of structural divergence in the EMU. rights in the enlarged EU. The research analyses He has been visiting researcher at the European judicial and legislative responses to the clashes University Institute and has obtained his MSc in between free movement rights and (national) Political Economy of Europe from the London social regulation in the aftermath of the Viking School of Economics and Political Science. His and Laval cases. most discussed article is Does Pattern Bargaining Explain Wage Restraint in the German Public [email protected] Sector? (MPIfG Discussion Paper). Federico Bruno is Ph.D. candidate at the Network [email protected] for the Advancement of Social and Political studies of the University of Milan. He has previously Margarita Estévez-Abe is political science studied at La Sapienza and Roma TRE universi- professor in Maxwell School of Citizenship ties in Rome. His research focuses on the influ- and Public Affairs, Syracuse University, and ence of the ordoliberal ideology on the reform of Co-Director of the Center of European Studies the Eurozone in the years of the crisis. at Syracuse University. Her research focuses on social policy and gender issues in advanced indus- [email protected] trial societies. She is known as the first scholar who Francesco Costamagna is Associate Professor of “gendered” the Varieties of Capitalism. Her book EU Law at the Law Department of the University of on the Japanese variety of welfare capitalism and Turin. He is Affiliate at the Collegio Carlo Alberto. its politics, Welfare Capitalism in Post-war Japan,

CONTRIBUTORS 20 was the winner of the Masayoshi Ohira Memorial The Religious Foundations of the European Crisis Award in 2009. From 2012 to 2015, she held the in the Journal of Common Market Studies. He Chair of Public Policy at Collegio Carlo Alberto edited his most recent book together with Chris- in Turin, Italy. She’s currently working on a book tian Joerges: Ordoliberalism, Law and the Rule of manuscript, Women, Immigrants and the Elderly: Economics by Hart Publishing, Oxford 2017. Politics of Demographic Aging in Germany, Italy, [email protected]; [email protected] Japan, Spain and South Korea. Matteo Jessoula is Associate Professor of Polit- [email protected] ical Science at the University of Milan. He is also Maurizio Ferrera is Professor of Political Science Director of the Welfare Laboratory, Director of at the University of Milano, Italy. His research the International Observatory on Social Cohesion focuses mainly on comparative politics and public and Inclusion, Coordinator of LPF-Comparative policy, the welfare state and European integration. Politics and Public Philosophy Lab and National He has taken part over the years in many commis- coordinator within ESPN-European Social sions and Working Groups set up by the Italian Policy Network. His current research focuses on government, the European Union, the OECD pensions, social assistance and employment poli- and the ILO and currently sits on the Exzellenz- cies, minimum income protection in compara- kommission of the Deutsche Forschungsgemein- tive perspective, European social governance. schaft (DFG). He is President of the Network for Among his publications, the volumes: Fighting the Advancement of Social and Political Studies poverty and Social Exclusion in the EU. A Chance (NASP) among the universities of Lombardy and in Europe 2020, Routledge, 2018 (co-edited with I. Piedmont and a member of the Board of Directors Madama), Labour Market Flexibility and Pension of the Centro di Ricerca e Documenzazione Luigi Reforms. Flexible Today, Secure Tomorrow?, Einaudi of Turin. Since 2004, he has been an edito- Palgrave, 2012 (co-edited with K. Hinrichs); and rialist on the Corriera della Sera. His latest book the articles: “‘Selective Flexicurity’ in Segmented in English is The Boundaries of Welfare, (Oxford Labour Markets: The Case of Italian Mid-siders”, University Press, 2005). In 2013, he received an (with P. Graziano and I. Madama) in Journal of Advanced Grant from the ERC, to carry out a five- Social Policy, 2010; and “Europe 2020 and the year project on “Reconciling Economic and Social Fight against Poverty: Beyond Competence Clash, Europe” (REScEU). Towards ‘Hybrid’ Governance Solutions?”, in [email protected] Social Policy & Administration, 2015. Josef Hien is a post-doctoral fellow at the REScEU [email protected] project. Funded through a European Research Christian Joerges is Professor em. for Law and Council advanced grant and hosted at the Univer- Society at the Hertie School of Governance in sity of Milan, REScEU aims at reconciling social Berlin and Co-Director of the Centre of European and economic Europe. Hien is interested in the Law and Politics at the University of Bremen. Until ideational and cultural foundations of European 2007, he held the chair for European Economic political economies. He received his Ph.D. from Law at the European University Institute, Florence. the European University Institute and has worked In 2009, he was awarded an honorary doctorate as a post doc at the Max Planck Institute for the from the University of Fribourg i.Ue. His research Study of Societies (Cologne), at the Collegio Carlo focuses on European and international economic Alberto (Moncalieri/Turin) and the Berlin Social law and the legitimacy problems of pertinent Science Centre (WZB, Berlin). Hien is currently government arrangements and practices. His a visiting fellow at the Institute for Future Studies most discussed book is the Darker Legacies of Law (IF) in Stockholm. His most discussed article is in Europe: The Shadow of National Socialism and

CONTRIBUTORS 21 Fascism over Europe and its Legal Traditions, (ed. sity Freiburg i.Ue. Ladeur’s research areas and inter- with Navraj Singh Ghaleigh). ests are theory of law, public law with a focus on [email protected] national, European and global administrative law, media and environmental law. He has published Sebastian Kohl is a researcher at the Max-Planck widely in all these fields. Recent publications Institute for the Study of Societies. He holds a include: “The Significance of General Adminis- Ph.D. from Sciences Po and the University of trative Law for European Administrative Law” in: Cologne. His research interests include economic Conflict of Laws and Laws of Conflict in Europe and sociology, political economy, housing, insurances Beyond, ed. by Rainer Nickel (Intersentia, 2010) and the philosophy of the social sciences. He and Public Governance in the Age of has published in Socio-economic Review, Urban (ed.) (Ashgate Publishing, 2004). Studies, Politics & Society and the Review of Inter- national Political Economy. His recent book is karl-heinz.ladeur@uni-.de Homeownership, Renting and Society: Historical Ilaria Madama is Associate Professor of Polit- and Comparative Perspectives, published with ical Science at the University of Milan, Senior Routledge. Researcher in the REScEU project, funded [email protected] through a European Research Council advanced grant and hosted at the University of Milan, Hanspeter Kriesi holds the Stein Rokkan Chair and Coordinator of the EuVisions Observa- in Comparative Politics at the European Univer- tory. Her current research focuses on the reform sity Institute in Florence. Previously, he has been of minimum income protection in comparative teaching at the universities of Amsterdam, Geneva perspective, the transformation of family policy, and Zurich. His wide-ranging research interests and European social governance. Among her include the study of various aspects of democracy, publications: Fighting Poverty and Social Exclusion political communication, political mobilisation in the EU: A Chance in Europe 2020, Routledge, and opinion formation. His recent books include 2018 (co-edited with M. Jessoula); “The Right(s) (together with Edgar Grande, Swen Hutter and and Minimum Income in Hard Times: Southern colleagues), Politicizing Europe. Integration and and Compared”, in European Soci- Mass Politics (2016), Political Conflict in Western eties, 2018 (with M. Natili, M. Jessoula and M. Europe (2012), and West European Politics in Matsaganis); “Beyond Continuity? Italian Social the Age of Globalization (2008), (together with Assistance Policies between Institutional Oppor- Monica Ferrìn and colleagues), How Europeans tunities and Agency”, in International Journal of View and Evaluate Democracy (2016), (together Social Welfare, 2013. with Takis S. Pappas and colleagues), European Populism in the Shadow of the Great Recession [email protected] (2015), (together with Pablo Beramendi, Silja Anna Katharina Mangold is a associate professor Häusermann, Herbert Kitschelt and colleagues), (Privatdozentin) and Schumpeter Fellow (VW The Politics of Advanced Capitalism (2015), and Foundation) at Goethe-University Frankfurt/ (together with Lisheng Dong, Daniel Kübler and Main. The Schumpeter project analyses colleagues), Urban Mobilizations and New Media legitimation strategies for anti-discrimination law. in Contemporary China. Mangold works in public law, including European [email protected] Union law, in legal philosophy, contemporary legal history and feminist legal theory. She received Karl-Heinz Ladeur is Professor (Emeritus) at her Dr. jur. from the Albert-Ludwigs-University the Faculty of Law in Hamburg. In 2011, he was Freiburg/Brsg. and has delivered her habilitation awarded an honorary doctorate from the Univer- thesis docent at Goethe-University Frankfurt aM.

CONTRIBUTORS 22 Currently, Mangold works as an interim professor Study of Europe at Boston University. His current for public law at the University of Konstanz. Her research focuses on the distributional implica- most discussed book is Gemeinschaftsrecht und tions of the Eurozone crisis, the political economy deutsches Recht: Die Europäisierung der deutschen of austerity in Southern Europe, and the implica- Rechtsordnung in historisch-empirischer Sicht tions of technical change for the future of work (Community Law and German Law: The Europea- and social protection. His article on “The Polit- nisation of the German Legal System in Histori- ical Economy of Austerity in Southern Europe”, co-empirical Perspective). (with Perez) was published in New Political [email protected] Economy in 2018. Philip Manow is Professor of Comparative Polit- [email protected] ical Economy at the University of Bremen in the Pamela Pansardi is currently Postdoctoral Department of Political Science. He held Profes- Researcher at the University of Pavia and Prin- sorships at the universities of Konstanz and cipal Investigator of the two-year research project and was director of a research group at “Gender and Power in Italian Politics”. Until the Max-Planck Institute or the Study of Societies, December 2017, she was Postdoctoral Researcher Cologne. He was visiting scholar at the Center for at the University of Milan, working for the project European Studies, Harvard, Sciences Po, Paris, REScEU “Reconciling Economic and Social and the Institute for Advanced Studies, Berlin. His Europe: Values, Ideas, and Politics”, led by Prof. research interests include comparative political Maurizio Ferrera. She is a regular contributor for economy, in particular comparative welfare state the EuVisions Observatory on Social Europe and research, the German political system, European editor (with Ilaria Madama) of its Social Policy integration and political theory. He has published, Pillar. Her works in EU studies concentrate on amongst others, in the British Journal of Political the exploration of the EU value-sphere through Science, the European Journal for Political Research, the tools of the (quantitative and qualitative) anal- Politics and Society, Legislative Studies Quarterly, ysis of language in political speeches, and have Comparative Political Studies, and Socio-Economic appeared in the Journal of European Integration Review. He is editor (with Kees van Kersbergen) and in the European Journal of Political Research. of Religion, Class-coalitions and Welfare States, [email protected] (Cambridge University Press, 2009), and author of the forthcoming book: Social Protection, Capitalist Alessandro Pellegata is currently a research fellow Production: The Bismarckian Welfare State and the at the University of Milan where he is involved German Political Economy, 1880-2010. in the REScEU project (“Reconciling Economic and Social Europe”). For REScEU he supervised [email protected] the conduction of a cross-national mass and elite Manos Matsaganis is Professor of Public Finance survey. Furthermore, he coordinates the Public at the Polytechnic University of Milan. He studied Opinion section of the EuVisions observatory at the School of Economics and Busi- (EuVisions.eu). Before joining REScEU, Ales- ness, the University of York, and the University sandro held a research fellowship at the Univer- of Bristol. He previously worked at the London sity of Siena. His main research interests are in the School of Economics, the Greek Prime Minister’s field of comparative politics, focusing especially Office, the University of Crete, and the Athens on electoral competition and government alter- University of Economics and Business. He has nation, political representation, public opinion, held visiting positions at the Center for European EU support and political corruption. His latest Studies at Harvard, at the Center for Equitable research has appeared, among others, in the Euro- Growth at UC Berkeley, and at the Center for the pean Political Science Review, International Journal

CONTRIBUTORS 23 of Public Opinion Research, International Political Kong. Prior to that, she was a Lecturer in Political Science Review, Italian Review of Political Science Science and International Studies at the University and Journal of European Public Policy. of Birmingham, UK, and a postdoctoral fellow in [email protected] Social Sciences at Collegio Carlo Alberto, Turin, Italy. Dr Scicluna received her Ph.D. in Inter- Lucia Quaglia is Professor of Political Science national Relations from La Trobe University, at the University of . She was awarded Melbourne, in 2013. Her teaching and research fellowships from the Hanse-Wissen- research interests include European integration, schafts Kolleg, the University of Bremen, the the law and politics of the EU, and the relationship Fonds National de la Recherche in Luxembourg, between international law and international poli- the Max Planck Institute in Cologne, the Scuola tics. Dr Scicluna’s monograph, European Union Normale Superiore and the European Univer- Constitutionalism in Crisis, was published by sity Institute. Her most recent books are: (2016) Routledge in 2015. Her most recent article, “Inte- The Political Economy of Banking Union, Oxford gration through the Disintegration of Law? The University Press (with D. Howarth); (2014) The ECB and EU Constitutionalism in the Crisis”, was European Union and Global Financial Regulation, published by the Journal of European Public Policy Oxford University Press. She has guest co-edited in 2017. 4 special issues of highly ranked academic jour- nals. Her work has been published in several [email protected] academic journals, such as Regulation and Gover- Alexander Spielau is a post-doctoral researcher at nance, Governance, Public Administration, Review the Max-Planck-Institute for the Study of Societies of International Political Economy, New Political in Cologne in the research group on the Political Economy, European Journal of Political Research, Economy of European Integration. He received Journal of Public Policy, Journal of European Public his Ph.D. in 2016 from the University of Cologne Policy, Journal of Common Market Studies, and and was a doctoral fellow at the IMPRS-SPCE. He West European Politics. was a visiting researcher at Columbia University [email protected] in New York and the MaxPo Centre at Sciences Po Paris in 2014. He is interested in the politics Florian Rödl is Professor for Private Law, Labour of macroeconomic adjustment and comparative Law and Social Law at Freie Universität Berlin. He capitalism. His most discussed article is “Better received his Ph.D. from the European University than the Euro? The European Monetary System, Institute (Florence) where he learned about the 1979-1998”, in: New Political Economy (with fundamental tension between European integra- Martin Höpner). tion and the democratic social state. He wrote his second dissertation (“Habilitation”) at Goethe- [email protected] Universität (Frankfurt aM), then serving as Filippo Taddei is Associate Professor of Inter- director of a junior researcher group at the Cluster national Economics at the Johns Hopkins School of Excellence “Formation of Normative Orders”. of Advanced International Studies (SAIS) where His recent study on “The European Pact on Social he teaches international finance and macro- Progress - the alternative to the liberalistic consti- economics. He is also Director of the Bologna tution of the EU’s single market” will be published Institute for Policy and Research (BIPR) and soon. the Master of Global Risk (MAGR) at SAIS. He [email protected] received his Ph. D. in Economics with distinc- tion from Columbia University and his degree in Nicole Scicluna is a Visiting Lecturer in Inter- Economics from the University of Bologna. He national Relations at the University of Hong has worked as Economic Advisor to the Italian

CONTRIBUTORS 24 Prime Minister and he has been one of the main core-periphery integration in Europe. Her recent designers of the Italian labour market reform, i.e., publications include “Making States for the Single the Jobs Act. His research deals with macroeco- Market: European Integration and the Reshaping nomics, international finance and the relationship of Economic States in the Southern and Eastern between the labor market and the pension system. Peripheries of Europe”, in West European Politics, Taddei was awarded the Lamfalussy Fellowship by “Governing Market Integration and Development the , and the Young Econ- - Lessons from Europe’s Eastern and Southern omist Award by the European Economic Associa- Peripheries”, in Studies in Comparative Interna- tion. His most discussed articles are “Intergenera- tional Development, and “The Rise of the Compe- tional Altruism and House Prices: Evidence from tition State? Transnationalization and State Trans- Bequest Tax Reforms in Italy”, with Giorgio Bellet- formations in Europe”, in Comparative European tini and Giulio Zanella, in the European Economic Politics. Review, and “International Capital Flows and [email protected] Credit Market Imperfections: A Tale of Two Fric- tions”, with Alberto Martin, in the Journal of Inter- Tiziano Zgaga is a Ph.D. candidate and teaching national Economics. assistant at LUISS Guido Carli University in Rome and academic coordinator at LUISS School [email protected] of Government. He holds a Bachelor’s degree in Frederik Traut is a Ph.D. candidate in political Political Science, a Master’s degree in Interna- economics at the Hertie School of Governance tional Relations and a Master of Arts (MA) in Law in Berlin. He has studied economics and inter- and Government of the European Union. In 2018, national affairs at the University of Bonn, the Zgaga was visiting researcher at the Hertie School University of Hong Kong and the Hertie School of Governance in Berlin. His dissertation focuses of Governance. His research interests include the on European Union (EU) fiscal and budgetary international political economy of banking regu- policy from a comparative federal perspective. lation, international finance, and the Economic Drawing a comparison with established feder- and Monetary Union. He also worked on these ations, the research analyses the relationship topics as a parliamentary advisor for members of between the EU and its Member States in fiscal the German Bundestag concerned with European and budgetary policy. economic affairs. [email protected] [email protected] Visnja Vukov is assistant professor at the Depart- ment for Political and Social Sciences at the Pompeu Fabra University and a senior researcher at the joint Johns Hopkins University and Pompeu Fabra University Public Policy Centre in Barce- lona. She holds a Ph.D. in political and social sciences of the European University Institute in Florence. Before coming to the UPF she worked as a post-doctoral research fellow at the MAXCAP project at the European University Institute. Her research interests include comparative and inter- national political economy, European integration, globalization and development, and she focuses in particular on the challenges and governance of

CONTRIBUTORS 25 A THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF GERMANY AND ITALY THE GERMAN POLITICAL crisis shook and continues to shake the founda- ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – tions of an economic structure to which Germany had adapted over the previous ten years. AND A COMPARISON TO THE A break-up of the currency zone, today less likely “SOUTHERN MODEL” than in 2009–2011 but still a possible scenario, Philip Manow67* would have fundamental and unpredictable reper- cussions for the German economy and the coun- Bremen – Konstanz try’s public finances. Currently, the crisis lingers on and is expected to remain with us in the coming 1. Germany in the Euro Area years, since European recovery would presup- – A New Equilibrium? pose that the euro area’s serious structural defects (EMU as an “incomplete” currency union; see De In this paper, I ask how German wage setting Grauwe 2012) be repaired. As long as this does not and, more generally, how Germany’s production occur, any “return to normalcy” remains unlikely. regime functions in the euro area. This also allows A high level of government debt and a low level me to compare the German export-led growth of competitiveness in southern Europe appar- model with the French or Italian models. The ently either require a complete change of the euro paper primarily covers the first decade of the new area’s institutional set-up - possibly a split into millennium, a time that not only saw the creation two different currency zones, one representing of the euro area and, with it, a fundamental trans- the northern export-led growth model under formation of the basic economic parameters a strong euro, the other the southern demand- within which the German model previously func- driven, consumption-based economic model with tioned. Starting in 2008 and triggered by the insol- continuous depreciations - or will be resolved in vency of Lehman Brothers, the world economy a drawn-out process of structural adjustment and also experienced a profound economic crisis— a prolonged recessive period in the periphery, the Great Recession. Although the comparisons possibly eased by massive transfers from the euro with the Great Depression of the late 1920s and area’s less burdened northern members (Iversen early 1930s that are frequently drawn (Eichen- and Soskice 2018). As gloomy as both scenarios green 2012; O’Rourke and Taylor 2013) appear a appear in economic terms, it remains wholly bit exaggerated, the depth and impact of the finan- uncertain whether either option would even find cial crisis seem to render it largely unrivalled by enough support to render it politically sustainable most other post-World War II crashes. The deep The paper addresses the question of how the economic slump in the wake of the Lehman bank- German economy has fared in these new and ruptcy subsequently spilled over into a dramatic profoundly challenging times. In this context, I challenge to the euro area, manifested in the will address the following more specific puzzles. severe sovereign debt crisis of some of its member countries and, consequently, in a persistent reces- • If the interplay between an independent sion (Scharpf 2011; Hall 2012; De Grauwe 2013; central bank with a non-accommodating Hancké 2013; Streeck and Schäfer 2013; Iversen, monetary policy, on the one hand, and a quasi- Soskice et al. 2016; Iversen and Soskice 2018). This corporatist system of wage coordination, on the other, was so central to the functioning 67* Paper prepared for presentation at the “Responses of European of Modell Deutschland after the breakdown Economic Cultures to Europe’s Crisis Politics” Conference at of Bretton Woods (Scharpf 1987; Hall 1994; Villa Vigoni, 25-27 June 2018. The paper draws on the manu- script Social Protection, Capitalist Production. The Bismarckian Hall and Franzese 1998), how have unions and Welfare State in the German Political Economy, 1880-2015, employers responded to the new environment forthcoming with OUP.

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 27 Philip Manow where the ECB’s monetary policy could no In my attempt to answer these questions, I use the longer be exclusively targeted at German wage label “supply-side corporatism” (Wolfgang Streeck) settlements, but was set with euro area-wide to help me describe the deeply ingrained mecha- inflation in mind (Hancké 2013)? nisms by which the German political economy • If the generous German welfare state is adjusts to a high interest rate environment. These designed in such a way that the “social part- mechanisms were employed when the German ners” could use or, for that matter, often abuse economy experienced its first adjustment crisis in it for their particularistic needs (Streeck 2009), response to the new monetary regime under the how did this close production-protection euro. I then address in some detail the profound nexus survive the fundamental reform of the welfare and labour market reforms that were a Bismarckian welfare state through what was central part of this adjustment process (together known as the Agenda 2010 under Chancellor with wage moderation), namely what was known Schröder? How has Germany managed to as the Agenda 2010 (see Section 2). Subsequently, I avoid the emerging low-wage sector under- analyse the changes in Germany’s wage bargaining mining the country’s high-skill/high-produc- system under the new monetary opportunity tivity/high-wage regime—as unions always structure, and how the welfare reforms have been had feared? In other words: Can the German conducive to the adjustment of wage coordination system function under conditions of dualisa- (see Section 3). Lastly, this gives me the oppor- tion (Palier and Thelen 2010; Emmenegger, tunity to compare the two political economies in Häusermann et al. 2012)? Apparently the the euro area (the continental and the southern 68 answer is yes, but how exactly? growth models) and to sketch how they function under the single currency (see Section 4). I relate • Finally, how can we explain Germany’s initial my description of the functioning logic of these economic troubles, which prevailed until two political economies to the argument devel- around 2005, its quite spectacular subsequent oped in previous papers, i.e., to an account of the comeback, plus its almost complete mirror interplay between welfare states, types of capi- image—namely the impressive boom in most talism, and party competition (cf. Kersbergen and southern member countries of the euro area Manow 2009; Manow 2009; Manow 2013; Manow up until the financial crisis (Italy seems to be 2015; Manow, Palier et al. 2017). This enables us to an exception here since the Italian economy locate the German political economy in a broader already stagnated since the early 2000s) and comparative framework. the bust ever since? What can the framework proposed here contribute to such an expla- 2. The Agenda 2010 – The End nation, particularly with its emphasis on the of the “Bismarckian Promise” interaction between social protection and capitalist production in the continental polit- Probably the most significant reform of the ical economies (see Section 4)? German welfare state in recent years was the groundbreaking Agenda 2010 reform, including the highly controversial labour market reforms (Hartz reforms) enacted under the red/green 68 I will only briefly touch on the political fallout of these developments. One of the political consequences/outcomes (SPD/Greens) coalition with Gerhard Schröder as of the profound welfare reforms was the rise and then firm Chancellor (Hassel and Schiller 2010; Arndt 2013: establishment of a new radical alternative to wing of 99; cf. 99-126). Given that the relatively peaceful the SPD. This affected the “strategic configuration of parties” (Kitschelt) in the German party system (Schumacher 2011) industrial relations in Germany have always been (Schumacher 2011; Arndt 2013). See also (Schwander and predicated on the welfare consensus between Manow 2016).

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 28 Philip Manow both Social and , for many common currency evolved exactly as anticipated Germany in the early 2000s represented the Euro- (Walters 1992; Carlin 2013). pean country where social reform was least likely The crisis could also be explained by the fact that (Kitschelt 2001)—despite the apparent malfunc- German capital flowed to the south immediately tioning of the German economy, as was mani- after the introduction of the common currency. fested in low growth and high unemployment. Today we are aware that this movement was driven Therefore, the comprehensive welfare reforms by the mistaken belief that capital within the euro enacted by the red/green coalition in 2002 and area—with its uniform interest rate, common 2003 came as a surprise to many observers. fiscal rules, and lack of exchange rate risks—could In the early 2000s, Germany struggled with low be safely shifted to where the “economic action” growth and high unemployment. It was a time was, i.e., where high growth rates and there- 69 when Germany was labelled the “sick man of fore high returns on investments prevailed. The Europe.” Real GDP growth had plummeted from 2 consumption and construction boom in southern percent in 1998 and 1999 to 0.5 and 0.4 percent in Europe was fuelled by what, from the perspective 2002 and 2003, respectively. In 2005, the German of the periphery, were exceptionally low interest economy was almost stagnant at 0.2 percent. In rates and this attracted German capital, thus rein- 2004/2005, unemployment came close to a stag- forcing the boom. The ECB, forced to pursue a gering 12 percent and, in absolute terms, reached “one size fits all” monetary policy in a currency the critical five-million threshold. area where both an overheated economy (Spain or The fact that Germany faced economic problems Ireland, for instance) and an economy in recession almost immediately after the introduction of the (such as Germany) soon existed , inev- new currency was no coincidence, but rather itably selected an interest rate that was too low to the consequence of the high real interest rates dampen the Spanish or Irish construction craze, that accompanied the Euro(see Krugman and but that was already too high for Germany’s bleak Obstfeld 2012: 767, Figure 20.8): “Before 1999, economy (and has subsequently been dubbed Germany had not only the lowest nominal interest a “one size fits none” rate). At a time when high rates, but also the lowest real interest rates. With growth rates, high employment, and rising real entry into the Monetary Union, however, these wages in the south seemed to be signs of exactly the comparative advantages were lost. Since nominal economic convergence process that optimists had interest rates converged whereas German infla- expected from the single currency - evidence of tion rates continued to be lower, real interest what is known in economics as the Balassa-Samu- rates in Germany actually became the highest elson effect (Illing, Jauch et al. 2012) - Germany in the euro area. As a consequence, economic had to undergo a politically and economically growth was lower in Germany than almost any painful process of structural reform. other EMU member country, unemployment At that time, however, Germany’s economic slump increased dramatically from 2000 to 2005, as did in the year 2000 was not perceived as having much social expenditures, whereas tax revenues fell by to do with the euro. Further, even if political actors 2.4 percentage points between 2000 and 2004” had been aware of the underlying causes (which (Scharpf 2011: 13). In the rest of the euro area, in all likeliness they were not), they still had to credit-fueled higher demand, higher growth, avoid at all costs de-legitimising the new currency, and a housing bubble, particularly in Spain and which had been introduced against the will of Ireland, drove inflation and thereby forced real the majority of Germans. Instead, the dominant interest rates down (Krugman and Obstfeld 2012). discourse held the prevailing labour market inflex- The divergence between higher- and lower-infla- ibility and high non-wage labour costs, a dysfunc- tion countries that had already been predicted as 69 Martin Wolf dryly comments: “Why anybody should early as 1992 in the famous Walters Critique of the have imagined that Greek and German government debts were equivalent is not easy to comprehend” (Wolf 2014: 47).

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 29 Philip Manow tional welfare state, and, in general, a significant services” (Vail 2010: 104) and also reflecting the political reform gridlock (Reformstau) responsible dependency trap inherent in generous benefit for the poor state in which Germany’s economy levels and long drawing periods so typical of found itself at the start of the new millennium. Germany’s social insurance system, a system Of course, not all of Germany’s poor economic tailored to insider interests and specifically to performance at the time can be blamed on the preserving their labour market and income status. new currency. It is quite apparent that Germa- Moreover, poorly camouflaged by the fact that ny’s GDP growth had been sluggish and its labour many jobseekers were channeled through expen- market performance poor even before the intro- sive work-creation schemes or training courses duction of the euro. This was primarily part of the of highly dubious usefulness was the fact that not long-term economic fallout of a set of circum- only was unemployment high, but employment stances that were to repeat themselves after 1999 was also low. The high number of early retirees for the entire country, namely, the entry of the completes this rather gloomy picture. former East German states into the new currency Various labour market stimuli failed to tackle these zone of unified Germany at an exchange rate that problems. Efforts to find solutions in tripartite 70 was far too high. It was also due to the fact that negotiations with the social partners - the tradi- the German production model in general and the tional corporatist approach that both the outgoing German welfare state in particular were tailored Kohl government and the incoming Schröder to the needs of a manufacturing sector that now, government had attempted - proved wholly inad- at best, produced stagnant employment, while the equate. Kohl’s belated and half-hearted reform German growth model seemed much less well attempts were a far cry from the “radical retrench- adjusted to the needs of the increasingly impor- ment” as which it has been labelled in the liter- tant service economy (Wren 2013). ature (Beramendi, Häusermann et al., 2015: 40), When unemployment finally surpassed the four- anyway. The social partners were more interested million mark in 2002, politicians and the public in protecting their position within Germany’s were alarmed. Yet unemployment continued to corporatist political economy than in responding increase: in 2005, 4.86 million people were without to the virulent labour market crisis. During the employment. This was the annual average, but in red/green coalition’s second term (after a narrowly the early months of that year the total number of won election in 2002), the failure to confront these unemployed had actually passed the symbolically problems within a tripartite framework was ulti- important five-million mark. What is more, long- mately the catalyst for a bold attempt to enact term unemployment was also a pressing problem. profound labour market and welfare reforms This pointed to the need to reform the job place- without the social partners’ consent. The reforms ment program of the unemployment insurance were designed to “wrest authority from neo- and to reconsider whether the passive character corporatist labour market institutions, which had of German labour market policies did not actu- failed to devise effective responses” to the severe ally provide the unemployed with rather perverse employment and unemployment problems of the incentives: “A full 32.8 percent of jobless workers times (Vail 2010: 102). This is what the Agenda between 1995 and 1999 had been on the rolls for 2010 and the Hartz reforms accomplished. They more than a year, reflecting the ineffectiveness of therefore decisively withdrew from the corporatist the BA’s [Federal Labour Office’s] job placement model that had dominated the German political economy for the last 50 years and in important 70 What subsequently developed was high unemployment, a massive increase in public spending (active and passive respects reneged on the “Bismarckian promise” labour market policies), a unification boom, and the Bun- that had prevailed in the previous five decades. desbank’s harsh monetary reaction, which led to a prolonged period of poor economic growth and low employment .

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 30 Philip Manow I refrain here from providing a detailed account itslosengeld II (also known as Hartz IV), which and full evaluation of the Agenda 2010 measures - corresponds roughly to the level of the former given that there are already a plethora of detailed social assistance, i.e., it does not take the level of assessments (Clasen 2005; Clegg and Clasen 2006; prior earnings into account, and by consequence Clegg and Clasen 2006; Eichhorst and Kaiser also not the length of the prior period of employ- 2006; Hassel and Schiller 2010; Vail 2010; Arndt ment and contribution payment. 2013; Carlin, Hassel et al. 2014; Hassel 2014; As a consequence, the reform fused the previ- Schwander and Manow 2016). A simple outline of ously separated systems of social assistance and the major reform measure must suffice. The first unemployment insurance. “This meant that status two Hartz laws, enacted in 2003, placed a stronger protection of the long-term unemployed was abol- emphasis on labour market activation through ished in favour of a joint flat-rate benefit for all the introduction of personnel service agencies jobseekers not entitled to unemployment insur- (Personal service Agenturen, PSA), and opened ance benefit, i.e., with prior employment shorter activation measures, previously limited to recipi- than the waiting period or after expiry” of Arbe- ents of earnings-related benefits, up to everyone itslosengeld I (Eichhorst and Kaiser 2006: 9). It (Carlin, Hassel et al., 2014: 63). At the same time, cannot be stressed too much that this represented benefit requirements were tightened: once a spell a very substantial attack on insider interests. At of unemployment lasts longer than 18 months, the the same time, due to the reform, benefit recipi- unemployed are now forced to accept any avail- ents have to accept any job offer to prove their will- able job, regardless of their qualifications and ingness to work, even jobs paid so poorly that the previous pay (Koch, Kupka et al. 2009). Avail- wage will remain below the social assistance level. ability and entitlement criteria were also tight- Wages are then topped up by transfer payments. ened, and the annual adjustment of benefits was abolished (Eichhorst and Kaiser 2006). Addition- Considering that the “old” welfare system had ally, the reforms comprised a number of smaller been geared primarily to the protection of status, policy measures promising to increase labour income, and the qualifications of skilled workers, supply and to make accepting employment worth- these measures clearly represented a major break while. Measures included the reduction of social with Germany’s “Bismarckian tradition” and contributions on low-paid jobs and marginal violated the interests of the workers in the indus- employment (what were known as “minijobs”). trial core - a traditional SPD support base. The Another activation measure was the introduction reform qualifies as a “dramatic shift from the of what were dubbed “Me Inc.” or “Ich-AGs”, i.e., status-preserving earnings-related principle to the a measure facilitating the creation of small (also means-tested basic-income principle for the long- single person) enterprises. The third Hartz law term unemployed” (Carlin, Hassel et al. 2014: reformed the public placement agency (Public 63). These reforms therefore represent a signifi- Employment Service) in order to improve its case cant break with cherished principles of Germa- management and the placement of jobseekers. ny’s welfare system. It is no surprise then that they met with vehement union protest and were highly The last and by far the most controversial and contested within the Social . In important part of the reform, the Hartz IV law, fact, they were enacted against a sizeable intraparty sharply reduced the drawing period for the opposition of “traditionalists” clinging passion- generous earnings-related unemployment benefit ately to Germany’s established Bismarckian ways. (Arbeitslosengeld I) from a maximum of 32 to From this it also becomes clear that one of the 12 months (18 months for older unemployed key aims of the Agenda 2010 was precisely not to persons). After this period, the unemployed have “sharpen the lines between social insurance (for to rely on the flat-rate, means-tested benefit, Arbe-

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 31 Philip Manow those who had paid the social contributions) and processes became merely discretionary, and new social assistance and in-work benefits for those procedural provisions made it harder to take excluded from the normal labour market and for action against noncompliant states” (James 2012: whom the state was asked to take responsibility” 18). As Paul De Grauwe dryly states: “For all prac- (Palier and Thelen 2010: 122). The objective was tical purposes, the Pact had become a dead letter” 72 the exact opposite, namely to blur these lines. To (De Grauwe 2014: 227). interpret the welfare reforms, as Thelen and Palier Politically, the German government saw its viola- do, as an attempt to protect the industrial core tion of the Stability and Growth Pact as the conse- model of the German political economy is there- quence of the pending welfare state reforms. As fore wholly misguided (see also Carlin, Hassel et Chancellor Schröder later explained, the red/ al. 2014: 66; Beramendi, Häusermann et al. 2015: 73 71 green coalition was confronted with a dilemma: 40). embarking upon a policy of structural reform by Despite the reforms—or because of them (see pursuing a highly unpopular welfare reform and below)—Germany violated the Maastricht three- simultaneously aggravating the recession with per-cent budget deficit criterion in the years 2002 a strict policy of fiscal consolidation would have to 2005, in the midst of the recession. “There was simply spelt political disaster and certain electoral not just a little irony in this fact, since in the early suicide. Forced to choose, the Schröder govern- 1990s it had been German negotiators who had ment opted for the long-term structural change: pushed to include an Excessive Deficit Proce- welfare reform. In retrospect, it is probably fair to dure in the ” (Eichengreen say that Schröder was proven right - economically, 2007: 372). In the ensuing conflict with the Euro- if not politically - since he was voted out of office pean Commission, Germany and success- in 2005 anyway. fully negotiated a less restrictive application of the Stability and Growth Pact. In retrospect, many 72 De Grauwe (2013) also caustically comments on the interpret this as the euro area’s “original sin” (cf. regulations of the old and the new Stability and Growth Pact: “Up to now, these sanctions have never been applied. The James 2012: 18), which paved the way for a period reader will be surprised at so much political naiveté from the of low fiscal discipline and which ultimately - in drafters of the Stability and Growth Pact when they believed the wake of the financial crisis in 2008/2009 - alleg- that such sanctions could ever be enforced” (De Grauwe 2014: 217). edly led to the profound sovereign debt crisis that 73 SPIEGEL: “The ECB accuses you of having softened threatened and still threatens to tear the euro area the criteria of the Stability and Growth Pact.” Schröder: “This apart. Although Greece’s entry into the euro area, critique has to be taken seriously. But one has to put it into based on grossly forged budget data, is certainly a perspective. We strengthened the growth aspect of the Pact with that reform. Specific burdens, such as the costs related to serious contender for the “original sin” award, and , now had to be taken into account. More although the crisis of the Eurozone in its essence importantly however, countries which undertook difficult never has been a sovereign debt crisis (Baldwin structural reforms had more leeway to stimulate growth. For us Germans, this was key, since we had initiated the Agenda and Giavazzi 2015), it is true that the outcome of 2010. In Germany, we were confronted with a stagnating the conflict between France and Germany, on the economy. At the same time we were very determined to push one side, and the Commission, on the other, made this reform through and to adjust the welfare state to the changed circumstances. Hence, we needed to emerge from future sanctions against other euro area members stagnation with the help of an economic stimulus package. who violate the Maastricht criteria hard to justify In this situation we were forced, also because of the welfare and quite unlikely to be imposed. In fact, in 2005 reforms, to emphasize the growth component of the Pact. In “the disciplinary mechanism was softened, many the end this proved to be successful. We did our homework with the Agenda 2010. This is one of the reasons why we came through the crisis better than others. Countries such as France 71 The fact that unions/works councils and employers/ or Italy are now forced to catch up under much more unfavor- firms in fact frequently protected the core workforce through able circumstances” (Spiegel, “Europa muss aufwachen,” 5 plan-level agreements is another issue. September 2011.

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 32 Philip Manow The combination of structural reforms, rational- The number of “regularly employed,” meaning ization in firms, and the wage moderation prac- those subject to mandatory social insurance ticed by unions ultimately led Germany out of contributions, even increased significantly from the recession, particularly in combination with its low point of slightly more than 26 million in the much higher growth and more specifically 2005 to 32.1 million in September 2017 (cf. Figure the much higher wage growth in Europe’s south. 1). Inequality, which had been steadily increasing German GDP grew at an impressive rate of 4.1 and since the 1990s, has been on the decline since 3.1 per cent in 2006 and 2007, respectively, before 2006 and poverty rates have decreased, too. For the financial crisis hit the German export-based instance, the GINI coefficient fell from 32.8 (2006) economy unusually hard. However, even the to 30.1 (2011) and has dropped further since, and Lehman crisis only temporarily interrupted the the poverty rate fell from 9.1 to 7.8 between 2007 75 revival of Modell Deutschland. As soon as global and 2013 (e.g., OECD 2015: 56). The claim that demand returned, German companies were able the reform increased “German inequality quite to overcome the massive external shock caused by dramatically” (Blyth 2015: 269) is wholly unsub- the financial crisis. The country came out of the stantiated. recession much faster than the UK or most other Total employment is also at a record high of around euro area members - although the subsequent 44.5 million people. With an employment rate of recession in Europe’s periphery did not leave 76 per cent, in Europe, Germany is now second German growth unaffected, of course (see Figure only to Sweden, and quite unlike its conserva- 3). tive homologues, France and Italy (Eichhorst and The labour market also weathered the Tobsch 2014: 6-7). It was this high employment remarkably well (Burda and Hunt 2011; Eichhorst rate which then also helped fuel domestic demand and Tobsch 2014: 3). The level of unemployment during the crisis when export demand collapsed. sank steadily and today (September 2017) is at Full-time, non-temporary employment is still the around 5.5 per cent (national figures; according dominant form in the German labour market, to the ILO definition the German unemploy- specifically for 40 percent of working-age individ- ment rate is 3.7 per cent) - less than half of the 12 uals and for 60 percent of those in gainful employ- per cent unemployment that was recorded at the ment (Eichhorst and Tobsch 2014: 10). The overall peak of the crisis in 2005. Today’s figure of around job growth, however, came at the cost of a signifi- 2.45 million unemployed and 800,000 open jobs cant increase in non-standard employment. Yet, if prompt German labour market experts to consider we want to bemoan this development, we should a full employment scenario to be possible in the bear in mind how high structural unemploy- 74 foreseeable future (see Figure 2). ment had been previously. We also should take Significantly, the higher labour market flexibility into account that “non-standard jobs contribute resulting from the Agenda 2010 reforms did not - to better labour market access and additional job as reform critics had claimed - come at the cost of creation, which generates additional income from undermining the “normal” segment of the labour work. Flexible types of contracts also contribute market. In the private sector there is a relatively to wage moderation in collective agreements and high probability that people will transfer from the to overall competitiveness” (vgl. Klinger, Rothe et non-standard segment of the labour market to its al. 2013; Eichhorst and Tobsch 2014: 4). Moreover, regular core. This regular core appears to have been for many, particularly mothers, part-time employ- strengthened rather than weakened by the reform. ment is the preferred form of employment, and does not lead to an accumulation of social risks 74 Of course, the massive influx of almost one million (Böhnke, Zeh et al. 2015). immigrants in the second half of 2015, most of them poorly qualified, changes this picture substantially. 75 See for instance, World Bank: http://data.worldbank.org/ indicator/SI.POV.GINI?locations=DE or (OECD 2015).

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 33 Philip Manow With these more flexible forms of employment There is no doubt that the welfare reforms created the Agenda 2010 managed to reduce the inac- real “losers” - in fact, they were designed to do tivity rate, which was their biggest achievement precisely that, but those were, contrary to the (Klinger, Rothe et al. 2013). Inactivity, wide- expectations of many, rather the labour market spread in the 1990s, “is no longer a problem of insiders. Some categories of households benefit the German labour market” (Hassel 2014: 68). substantially from higher transfers (Koch, Kupka While the overall flexibility of the labour market et al. 2009: 249-50) and overall spending on social has clearly increased, average job tenure has not assistance significantly increased after the reform: only remained stable but also even increased, “Hartz IV - widely considered the harshest of the from 10.3 to 11.5 years between 2000 and 2011 recent reforms - actually provided a boost for an (Eichhorst and Tobsch 2014: 13) - mainly due estimated one-third of those who were previ- to the fact that the Agenda 2010 and subsequent ously in the lowest tier of the old social assis- reforms rendered many routes to early retirement tance system,” particularly single mothers (Palier 76 much less attractive, but also because in 2007, and Thelen 2010: 138). Whereas these former another deeply unpopular reform measure raised ‘outsiders’ benefited, insiders also lost out consid- the retirement age to 67. It is important to note, erably. Against all conclusions of “dualization,” however, that high employment, low inactivity the reform “clearly and most drastically cut the etc. were as much due to a favourable economic benefits for well-insured labour market insiders” climate (weak euro, eastern enlargement of the (Beramendi, Häusermann et al. 2015: 41). EU, and low interest rates) as to the flexibility of Not surprisingly, the reforms were highly contro- the labour market promoted by the reforms. versial, and this is reflected in the conflicting At the same time, the rapidly increasing low-wage assessments of these reforms still found in the sector (see Rhein 2013) is the more worrying literature today. Whatever might be the final development for many, but even here opin- assessment of the reforms, given the substantial ions vary. Some emphasise that “the liberaliza- pathologies of Germany’s prior “welfare without tion of non-standard contracts has contributed work” model even critics of the Agenda 2010 can to the expansion of overall labour market inclu- hardly deny the urgent need for reform in the early sion and job growth in Germany and that at least 2000s. Labour market performance since then some forms of non-standard work provide step- also tends to discredit some of the initially very ping stones into permanent regular jobs. Atypical critical assessments of the Agenda: higher flexi- contracts do not necessarily undermine the domi- bility apparently did contribute to the employment nance of standard employment relationships and growth that reformers had wished for, and so far job quality in this primary segment but rather without undermining the core of regular employ- form a supplementary part of employment in ment. It therefore appears rather questionable to sectors that depend on more flexible and maybe 76 Combining unemployment insurance and Germany’s cheaper forms of labour” (Eichhorst and Tobsch social assistance scheme involved a huge cost shifting game 2014: 2). Not surprisingly, the reforms also created between the municipalities, which were responsible for social assistance, and the social insurance schemes (Hassel and the need for some re-regulation, and the introduc- Schiller 2010). The process conformed to the pattern described tion in 2014 of a binding wage floor (minimum in Chapter 6 above: the political incentive to substitute social wage) for many labour market sectors is one insurance contributions for taxes. Municipalities had an incentive to declare as many recipients of social assistance as of these re-regulating measures. Interventions “employable” as possible. In some instances, comatose patients like these moved the German political economy miraculously turned into active “jobseekers.” Whereas the further away from one of its formerly sacred prin- federal government had anticipated less than 3.5 million em- ciples - that of Tarifautonomie or autonomy of ployable recipients of ALG II/Hartz IV, in the end it was more than 5 million. The welfare state “retrenchment measure,” the the social partners in wage bargaining. Germany Agenda 2010, increased social assistance spending dramati- became less corporatist. cally to 25 billion euros —11 billion more than anticipated.

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 34 Philip Manow accuse the Agenda 2010 of having strengthened Source: OECD (https://data.oecd.org) “dualization” (Th elen 2014) without at the same However, the return of growth, the turnaround of time referring to the disheartening and unaccept- the German economy, and the substantial reduc- able exclusion of a very high number of long-term tion in the number of unemployed and inactive unemployed under the status quo ante. To put it persons came too late for the red/green govern- more specifi cally: a prior “dualization” between ment. In 2005, Schröder was forced to call new those in and those not in employment has been elections aft er having lost the large state of North substituted by today’s “dualization” between those Rhine-Westphalia, which had been tradition- in stable and those in marginal employment, and ally Social Democratic. With this state now in it seems strange to assess the one without alluding the hands of the oppositional Christian Demo- to the other (or to describe only the latter as “dual- crats, a two-thirds majority of the opposition ization”). Moreover, most labour market indica- in the Bundesrat, Germany’s second chamber, tors prove the higher employment dynamics today became a likely scenario. With such a majority, as compared to pre-reform times. the CDU/CSU-FDP opposition would have been In an evaluation of the reforms from a political able to block any government initiative (according point of view, both critics and proponents would to Article 77, Section 4 of the Basic Law for the probably concur that the labour market aft er Federal Republic of Germany, i.e., the German 77 the Agenda 2010 reforms is in a situation that is constitution). Schröder decided that attack was “fundamentally diff erent from the situation in the the best form of defence. In the early federal elec- late 1990s and early 2000s” (Eichhorst and Tobsch tions of 2005, the share of the vote of the red/green 2014). According to established performance coalition suff ered. However, the opposition, which criteria such as employment and unemployment, in the meantime had decided to rally around an youth unemployment, female labour market even more radical reform platform than what the participation, and average retirement age, it can be Agenda had brought, also lost vote shares (see stated that Germany today is no longer “adjusting Table 1). badly” (Manow and Seils 1999). Again, this overall Table 1 Bundestag elections, overview of results, assessment would not only have to make reference 1994-2013, in per cent to the domestic reforms, but also be put into the context of the new monetary environment, which 1994 1998 2002 2005 2009 2013 became much more favourable for the German SPD (Social Demo- 40.9 38.5 34.2 23.0 political economy aft er 2005 (see below). crats) 36.4 25.7 CDU/CSU (Chris- 35.1 38.5 35.2 33.8 Figure 1: Employment and Unemployment rate, tian Democrats) 41.5 41.5 2005-2017, in thousands FDP (Liberals) 6.9 6.2 7.4 9.8 14.6 4.8 Grüne (Green) 7.3 6.7 8.6 8.1 10.7 8.4 PDS/die Linke (ex- 5.1 4.0 8.7 11.9 Communists) 4.4 8.6 Turnout 79.0 82.2 79.1 77.7 70.8 71.5 Numbers indicate the share of valid votes. Source: www.bundeswahlleiter.de (Federal Returning Offi ce). While voters apparently punished the Social Democrats for their reform agenda, they showed little enthusiasm for the CDU’s attempt to posi- 77 Parliament can only override a two-thirds majority veto of the second chamber by finding/securing a two-thirds majority itself, which is a completely unrealistic prospect.

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 35 Philip Manow tion itself as even more “de-regulative” than the rates were interpreted as responses (of an inde- Schröder government. As a consequence, the pendent central bank) to inflationary tendencies, race was extremely close, and neither a centre- possibly provoked by exaggerated wage increases. right (CDU/CSU/FDP) nor a centre-left (SPD and It appeared that poor economic performance Greens) coalition gained a majority of seats. The pointed instead to the lack of competitiveness of upshot was that a Grand Coalition then ruled from German firms and products as the root cause of all 2005 to 2009. The Christian Democrats, however, the country’s economic troubles. had learned their lesson: in 2009, Chancellor Having been “socialized” with the implicit supply- moved the Christian Democrats’ side logic of Modell Deutschland in the post- program back to the centre. Given that in 2009 the Bretton Woods world where the Bundesbank’s genuine “left-wing”, orthodox anti-reform posi- independence and its hard currency policy ruled tion was occupied by Die Linke, a party which had supreme (Scharpf 1987; Hall and Franzese 1998; easily surpassed the German legal five-percent Franzese 1999), the relevant German actors, both threshold in the 2005 election thanks to the lack of in the political and economic spheres, believed popularity of the Agenda 2010 in the traditionalist that interest rates were not too high, but wages left milieu, the Social Democrats were crushed and welfare benefits were. Subsequently, monetary from two sides. There was little room left in the policy did not have to be adjusted, but German political centre for a that under wage costs did. Adjusting monetary policy was Schröder had once claimed - in imitation of Blair’s considered a taboo, at any rate, given the indepen- New Labour - to represent the New Centre (Die dence of the European Central Bank, which had neue Mitte) after Merkel ultimately decided to been modelled on the Bundesbank (James 2012). abandon her short flirt with a neoliberal agenda. Initially, the immediate post-euro recession thus In hindsight, the SPD’s electoral disaster was seemed to present German unions, employers, predictable, partly because a Social Democratic and politicians with a familiar challenge. The well- minister of labour had not only been responsible established interplay between wage bargaining for important labour market reforms between and monetary policy could not be continued 2002 and 2005, but also for another hugely unpop- under the new circumstances of the euro, given ular measure: the decision in 2007 to increase the that the ECB would not and could not target its retirement age to 67. However, the onset of the monetary policy exclusively on pilot agreements global financial crisis in 2009 also played into the between German employers and unions – as the hands of the CDU chancellor, since German voters Bundesbank had done in the past. However, in the are known to become more conservative in times high interest rate environment of the early 2000s, of economic crisis (Anderson and Ward 1996). German social partners felt that the circumstances they found themselves in were, if not comfort- 3. German Wage Bargaining able, then at least familiar (Hall and Franzese within the Euro Area 1998). What has been succinctly labelled Germa- ny’s “supply-side corporatism” (Wolfgang Streeck) In order to put the Agenda 2010 reforms into a kicked in: Germany experienced wage moderation broader economic context, we need to examine and productive company-level pacts concluded by them in relation to the changed monetary incen- the social partners, productivity-enhancing ratio- tive structure in the euro area. With respect to the nalization and, in part, relocation of firms, and nexus between monetary policy and industrial finally the welfare reforms enacted by a Social relations, it is important to note that relatively high Democratic government. It is worth highlighting interest rates and their recessive consequences had that this latter aspect of the adjustment process, not been perceived as the sole cause of Germany’s namely the profound welfare reform enacted by economic troubles in the early 2000s. High interest

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 36 Philip Manow 78 the red/green coalition, was a rather new element, economic performance. Just as everything that something from which the CDU under Helmut was wrong with Modell Deutschland in the early Kohl had largely shied away. Th us it signifi ed a 2000s could not be blamed on the new currency, major deviation from the course of earlier politics it is also impossible to explain today’s spectac- and also from the established approaches of social ular economic revival of the German economy by policy. exclusively citing the inherent strengths of Modell By creating space for the emergence of a large Deutschland. low-wage sector, the labour market and welfare Figure 2 German Exports and Imports as a reforms themselves subsequently exerted pres- percentage of GDP, 1980–2013 sure on the unions and thereby further contrib- uted to the wage restraint of the social partners. Of course, the boom in Europe’s periphery and the ensuing signifi cant increase in labour unit costs there helped restore the cost competitive- ness of German industry as well - while the cost pressures stemming from eastern enlargement also helped keep German wages under control. Th e new, much poorer members of the Euro- pean Union provided Germany with new product markets, but in particular with a supply of cheap production factors. Business relocation to the East or the threat of it helped German fi rms to keep their wage costs under control, as did the import of cheap labour under the EU Posting of Workers Directive. One component of this situation is undoubt- edly that German euro area partners can no Th e monetary parameters for the German model longer devaluate their currency in order to rebal- changed profoundly again when the banking ance their current accounts vis-à-vis Germany crisis eventually translated into a sovereign debt - rendering strategies of wage moderation by crisis for some of euro area member states. Th e German employers and unions now even more subsequent expansionary policy of the Euro- eff ective than they had been under the fl exible pean Central Bank, the low interest rate environ- or fi xed, but adjustable exchange rates of the past ment, the (from a German perspective) under- (Höpner and Lutter 2014). Painful and unpop- valued euro, the massive repatriation of capital ular “internal devaluation” is the only option left from the periphery to the centre: taken together, to Germany’s euro partners (De Grauwe 2013; all this boosted German investment and produc- De Grauwe 2014; Iversen and Soskice 2018: 12). tion substantially (Wolf 2014: 63). Germany’s While countries like France or Italy had hoped recent record-high trade surplus (see Figure 2) 78 To the extent that the German current account surplus is therefore to some extent the result of the euro has to be explained by interest rates that were too low and crisis, not its cause, which also means that it a euro that was undervalued, at least from a German per- cannot be explained by only referring to superior spective, both of which were the result of the ECB’s rather accommodating monetary policy, the European critique of Germany’s current account imbalances appear contradictory. The fact that a euro that is “too weak” for German industry is still “too strong” for the French or Italian exposed sectors has more to do with the low external value of the US dollar, the yen, and the British pound due to the massive quantitative eas- ing programs of their banks.

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 37 Philip Manow that the EMU would replace the Bundesbank’s de 2013 accounted for 22 per cent of German GDP facto monetary hegemony within the EMS with and 10 per cent of French GDP, and for 28 and a more lenient European monetary policy, at the 22 per cent of total employment in Germany and same time, the common currency exposed their France, respectively. economies to full, unfettered competition from Generally, since the introduction of the common German industry and foreclosed the devaluation currency, the labour markets in the centre and option in response to infl ationary wage settle- in the periphery developed in a counter-cyclical ments at home. fashion. German unemployment was high when Yet, it is important to emphasize that this very it was low in the rest of the euro area and started situation had been an anticipated, intended, to decline when it rose in the south—one of the and welcome consequence of monetary union. many asymmetries indicating that the euro area Italian and French government representatives is anything but an Optimal Currency Area (see hoped that the disciplinary eff ects of the common Figure 3). currency would help them keep wage infl ation Figure 3 Standardised unemployment rates in under control, given that national monetary and euro area member countries, 2000-2013 political authorities in the past had tended to give in too quickly to unions’ aggressive wage demands (see De Grauwe 2012). Th ese self-binding eff ects of the currency union were quite obvious from the beginning, as, for instance, Daniel Gros and Niels Th ygesen had already remarked in 1998 in what was to become one of the classic textbook on monetary union: “In sum, labour market fl exibility is always useful and if EMU forces labour market reforms that are needed anyway, the economy of EU can only gain” (Gros and Th ygesen 1998: 288). Bemoaning the euro’s de-regulatory eff ect on southern European industrial relations seems therefore to be rather a case of “dynamic incon- As we have seen, during the fi rst years of the euro sistency.” area the monetary environment for German unions Th e absence of a devaluation instrument within and employers’ associations was not completely the euro area certainly made German (Nordic) unfamiliar. Th e traditional German model could wage restraint more eff ective. Wage constraint, work reasonably under the ECB’s high interest rate “combined with heavy investment in training … regime (that is, high for sluggish Germany). What propelled northern Europe - Germany in partic- about the period aft er 2005 though, when the ular - to a hegemonic trade position within ECB’s interest rates became too low and accord- Europe” (Iversen and Soskice 2018: 12). Th is has ingly the euro too weak for the booming German contributed to an erosion of the industrial base economy? If the German export-led growth in the euro area periphery, the converse being the model presupposes wage moderation, but the ECB slight reversal of the long-term decline of employ- cannot substitute the Bundesbank’s disciplinary ment in manufacturing in Germany. German monetary policy, how do unions and employers industrial production increased by 8.7 per cent secure a moderate development of wages? Th e from 2010 to 2014, whereas in Italy and Spain, it answer to these questions can be divided into declined over the same period by 7.7 and 7.2 per several components. First, it is possible that the cent, respectively. Th e manufacturing sector in erosion of the German wage bargaining system

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 38 Philip Manow (Streeck 2009), i.e., its increasing devolution to productivity) service sector, the recent strong the company level, actually explains its continuing increase in the employment rate (Germany’s job capacity to deliver wage moderation. Second, miracle) and the corresponding low degree of the disciplining effect of the Agenda 2010 labour inactivity were to a large extent due to the striking market reforms is also worth mentioning. Further, expansion of the low-wage labour market segment, the moderating effect of eastern enlargement and primarily in services. This labour market dynamic of the currency union itself, and finally the disci- had previously been hindered by union wage coor- plinary consequences of crisis-induced immigra- dination, restrictive employment protection rules, tion should also be acknowledged. Let me briefly and the high “replacement rates” implicit in the elaborate on these points. generous regulations of the unemployment insur- Ironically, the more limited coverage of wage ance scheme, which were tailored to insider inter- negotiations, due to the erosion of member- ests (Rueda 2005; Rueda 2006). Once the Agenda ship both of the unions and the employers’ asso- 2010 reforms removed these protective features ciations, could turn out to be an explanation for removed, low union density and low productivity the continuing capacity of the German political in the service sector combined to bring about economy to moderate wages. Since the 1990s, unforeseen job growth in the third sector, keeping German collective wage agreements have been the costs of living down and thereby supporting largely substituted with company-level agree- wage moderation in manufacturing, too. ments or what are known as firm-level “produc- The result was a sectoral dualization of the German tivity pacts” (Rehder 2003). They replace employ- political economy - that is, the maintenance of ment guarantees by employers with workers’ the traditional German model in manufacturing consent to rationalization, partial relocations, and simultaneously the “deregulation” of the increased labour flexibility, and so on. If we are service sector - which many observers, including looking for an explanation for how the German the author, (cf. Manow and Seils 1999) for many economy continued to deliver wage moderation years considered quite unlikely, if not outright during times when the familiar strategic interac- impossible. The “frozen landscape” that Esping- tion between social partners and the central bank Andersen described when analysing the conserva- had ceased to function, it is important to empha- tive political economies of continental Europe in size the fact that the “control of labour costs in the the 1990s (Esping-Andersen 1999) has given way German industrial relations system shifted over to a political economy with employment rates very time from the dominance of coordinated wage similar to the high Scandinavian levels. Given that setting institutions to competitiveness-driven Germany’s Bismarckian welfare state is still based plant level adjustment” (Hancké 2002; Hassel on employment and payroll taxes, today’s quasi 2014: 26; Hassel 2017 (forthcoming)). The erosion full employment scenario also helps to control the of Germany’s wage coordination system would welfare state costs. then not be an indication of a fundamental change Further, the wage discipline of German workers in of Modell Deutschland(Streeck 2009), but a neces- the 2000s is certainly also due to monetary union sary precondition for the model to function as it itself, since regional economic integration, admit- had previously, albeit under profoundly different tedly evolved over many decades, substantially circumstances. intensified under the EMU and further increased This insight helps us to explain a second, prima with European enlargement in 2004. Both events facie puzzling aspect of Germany’s economic lend momentum to the establishment of a new recovery after 2004. Whereas the poor labour economic region that integrates new member market dynamic in the 1990s was due to partic- states from Central and Eastern Europe with the ularly weak job growth in the (low-skill, low- German economy, but also increases integration

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 39 Philip Manow with the Baltic and Benelux states. German trade anchored around two per cent or lower, German “with the new member states of the EU increased unions do not need strong monetary signals to from 2 percent to more than 7 percent of GDP figure out which wage hikes are likely to harm between 1994 and 2006. During that period, the international competitiveness of industries, intra-firm trade represented about 21.6 percent sectors, or companies. of imports from Eastern Europe” (Hassel 2014: Finally, the crisis itself appears to contribute to 63). Some observers even maintain that the new German wage restraint: while the labour inflow ways of “organising production by slicing up the from Europe’s periphery in the wake of the crisis value chain has been more important for Germa- is insufficient to bring relief to southern labour ny’s lower unit labour costs than German workers’ markets, it is apparently enough to ensure that wage restraint. According to estimates, German labour supply meets Germany’s increased labour off-shoring to Eastern Europe boosted not only demand. In 2013, Germany welcomed around the productivity of its subsidiaries in Eastern 400,000 new immigrants, a number only surpassed Europe by almost threefold compared to local by the US - and in 2015 more than a million companies, but it also increased the productivity migrants arrived, with similarly high numbers in 79 of the parent companies in Germany by more than 2016. 20%” (Marin 2010). In sum, even if the ECB were to pursue a much Wage development within this emerging, larger more accommodating monetary policy, this would economic region could be taken into account by be unlikely to result in German wage inflation the ECB’s monetary policy. To the extent that the to the extent that the boom in southern Europe ECB did take German wages into account, while did after 2000. It is more likely that the strength “Germany’s neighbours effectively targeted [these of German industry would be reinforced under a German wages] to hold down their own wages … lax monetary policy (due to what would then be a the northern European countries could pursue the weak external value of the euro). This points to the export-led growth strategies to which they had systematic differences in wage setting regimes in long been accustomed with considerable success” the coordinated “hard currency” north of the euro (Hall 2012: 358-359). This pattern was consider- area as compared to the largely uncoordinated ably strengthened in the first decade of the euro. “soft currency” south (Hancké 2013; Höpner and Now that (relatively) high growth and low unem- Lutter 2014; Iversen and Soskice 2018), which ployment have returned to Germany, we should have been at the heart of the crisis. I will now not expect that unit labour costs will increase as analyse these differences. steeply as they did during the boom in southern Europe. They will increase, but it seems safe to 4. One Currency, Two predict that they will remain largely in line with Political Economies productivity and international competitiveness. We can therefore assume that the German wage The fact that in pre-crisis times German unit setting regime is still able to deliver wage modera- labour costs remained stagnant or even decreased tion quite effectively, since functional equivalents (see Figure 4), whereas in most other countries to the monetary signals of the Bundesbank and 79 In this respect, a parallel between the early 1950s and the traditional system of pattern wage bargaining the 2010s can also be observed/identified: a steady inflow of qualified workers enabled Germany to combine full employ- seem to have been put in place: competitive firm- ment with low inflation. However, the massive inflow of level pacts, the relocation and regional economic refugees in 2015 (estimated at 1.3 million) is quite another integration of firms, the liberalization of the issue. This will translate into a huge quasi-Keynesian push for domestic demand - and integration into the labour market of service sector, the price pressure of international these mainly poorly skilled people will take an extremely long markets, etc. With the anticipated inflation firmly time.

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 40 Philip Manow of the euro area they increased, was something dency, German employers (and policy-makers) that had initially been interpreted as a welcome have to be much more sensitive about German economic convergence, given that wage levels in wages than, say, French or Italian employers and the south were way below the German level at fi rst policy-makers (Scharpf 2017). However, what is (Illing, Jauch et al. 2012). In retrospect, Germa- more central to my argument is the fact that the ny’s European neighbours have severely criticized discussion about defl ation in the south or refl a- the country’s economic and political adjustments tion in the north points to profound diff erences to the slump of the early 2000s as a strategy of in the two political economies, particularly with unfair labour cost dumping. Th e adjustments are respect to their diff erent abilities to deliver wage not considered a solution to the problem but are moderation. In fact, these diff erences explain why accused of being a cause of the widening competi- countries such as France and Italy pushed for tiveness gap between the centre and the periphery a single European currency in the fi rst place - it in the currency zone. was intended to represent the ultimate credible commitment to break with the infl ationary cycles Figure 4: Unit labour costs, 2000-2013 (index 80 with 2005 = 100; source: ECB) inherent to their political economies. Before the euro, the “typical situation in the high- infl ation countries usually involved powerful (or, at the very least, highly militant) labour unions that managed to extract high wages from employers, both in the public and in the private sector (high wages are defi ned here as wages that grow faster than labour productivity). Since employers passed on these wage increases through higher prices (or rising budgets), higher wages led into the next infl ationary cycle, where they would be raised again to refl ect higher infl ation, and so on, ad infi - From a “northern” perspective, in turn, Italian, nitum” (Hancké 2013: 16). High infl ation rates Spanish, or French labour had simply become then regularly triggered devaluations to regain too expensive, a trend concealed for some time price competitiveness. Yet these devaluations by massive capital infl ows (Hall 2014). Unable could only provide temporary relief. A weaker to moderate wages, fragmented and militant currency translates into increased costs of living unions in these countries successfully pushed for through higher prices for imported goods, and wage settlements signifi cantly above productivity unions, both strong and militant ones, are then growth plus infl ation, thereby steadily under- eager to compensate for the decrease in workers’ mining their industry’s competitiveness. Because real wages with higher (nominal) wages, which, in of their incapacity to correct for this through turn, initiates the next round of infl ationary wage- (nominal) currency depreciations within the euro price dynamics (Carlin and Soskice 1990, Chapter area, countries in the periphery are now forced to 12; De Grauwe 2013). Th e competitive advantage pursue a painful process of real depreciation. of each devaluation quickly dissipated in the next Whether German wages are “too low” or southern infl ationary wage-price spiral. wages “too high” is a debate in which it is not necessary to take sides (in fact, both assessments 80 It is therefore not true that the founders of the EMU are accurate and tautologically have to be accu- were insufficiently aware of the profound differences between rate if the comparison is restricted to the euro area the political economies of the EMU members (see Hall 2014). They were simply overoptimistic about how smoothly the only). With very diff erent degrees of export depen- anticipated adjustment process would take place.

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 41 Philip Manow It was the desire to break out of this inflationary common currency, would still not be sufficient to cycle and to credibly commit to a low inflation constrain domestic wage bargaining - at least not equilibrium, with the anticipated consequences instantly. This commitment would only become for domestic wage bargaining regimes, that moti- binding at a later point and then with much more vated countries such as Italy and France to pursue harmful consequences, namely, only after the the single currency strategy, since the EMS, southern economies had gone through a spectac- already described by Stanley Fisher as an “arrange- ular boom period. This then made the necessary ment by France and Italy to accept German lead- real devaluation, particularly the wage decreases, ership, imposing constraints on their domestic much more painful than before, both economi- monetary and fiscal policies” (quoted in James cally and politically. 2012: 208), had failed to fully deliver low infla- The initial surge in the south was indeed just the tion and exchange rate stability (cf. Eichengreen 81 complement of the later crisis: with little capacity 2007: 283). Instead, France and Italy were forced for wage moderation, with higher wages and to devaluate the Franc and the Lira several times, therefore higher inflation, the southern euro something which - apart from the fact that depre- area benefited from very low, partly negative real ciations provided only temporal economic relief 82 interest rates in the first five years of the mone- - was perceived as damaging national prestige. tary union. As wages then increased at a consis- The view that periodic devaluations were (and are) tently higher rate than wages in the north (Höpner an essential precondition for the functioning of and Lutter 2014), southern industry quickly lost 83 the soft currency political economies in Europe’s its cost competitiveness. This translated into south does not seem to be fully accurate, therefore growing current account deficits, which could (Scharpf 2011). It was precisely the intention to only be sustained by massive capital inflows. Once overcome these recurrent episodes that motivated these stopped in the wake of the Lehman bank- key Italian and French actors to opt for a common ruptcy and capital even started to flow in the currency. It is unsurprising then that these actors reverse direction, the crisis fully and dramatically have not proven to be particularly eager to regain materialised. the devaluation option, but are more interested in expanding their fiscal leeway (Iversen, Soskice et With respect to wage bargaining, the southern al., 2016). high-inflation equilibrium and the German low-inflation equilibrium seem to be opposites What the relevant political actors in the south did (Iversen, Soskice et al. 2016; Iversen and Soskice not anticipate, however, was that the much stricter 2018). In this context, Bob Hancké speaks of the constraint, the “irrevocable” commitment to a “two Europes”, “one with orderly wage-determi- 81 That the effects of the EMU for/on domestic wage bar- nation systems, where low wage and price infla- gaining regimes were not only anticipated, but also intended, is indicated, for instance, by the view of monetary economist 83 In fact, every year since the introduction of the euro, Niels Thygesen, member of the Delors Committee. Monetary unit labour costs have increased more dramatically in Italy and union, he stated, would be “a way of ‘reducing the scope for the France than in Germany (Höpner and Lutter 2014). The lack kind of lax and divergent monetary policies’ that characterized of wage moderation is partly due to unions’ strategies, partly Europe in the 1970s” (James 2012: 7). due to highly inflexible labour markets: “productivity growth 82 Of course, it is important to emphasize that devalua- was correspondingly weak …. The most important reason for tions were not always due to wage growth differentials, but the relatively inflexible labour markets of southern Europe sometimes also reflected domestic imperatives of Germany’s was legislation, which made it extremely difficult to lay-off monetary policy. One example of this was the increased inter- long-term workers” (Wolf 2014: 63). But it “really did not make est rates with which the Bundesbank wanted to cool down sense for countries whose industries were competing with an overheating economy in the wake of Germany’s post- those of China to allow their labour costs to rise faster than in unification boom. Also, the status of the deutschmark as a countries like Germany, whose industries were complemen- reserve currency sometimes forced the French or the Italians tary to those of China” (Wolf 2014: 293-294). The role of wage to devalue vis-à-vis the deutschmark during periods when the inflation in the public sector in Italy is well described in (Di US dollar was weak. Carlo 2018).

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 42 Philip Manow tion targets were internalised by the trade unions Iversen, Soskice et al. 2016; Iversen and Soskice 85 by means of inter-sectoral wage coordination, 2018). Differences between the continental and and another, where wages rose faster relative to the southern wage bargaining regimes can explain productivity, competitiveness collapsed, and trade both the political motives behind the strong push balances deteriorated sharply” (Hancké 2013: 13; for a common currency in the 1990s - as a means 84 Hassel 2014; Iversen and Soskice 2018). The of breaking the domestic inflationary cycles in the challenge, therefore, is not to explain why the soft currency countries (mainly Italy and France) euro area is not an optimal currency area, but and as the ultimate proof of reunified Germany’s why it is almost the exact opposite, why the single commitment to Europe - and what were then currency binds together two rather different types divergent dynamics of the two political economies of political economies—a hard currency, export- under the euro, which finally culminated in the led growth model, on the one hand, with a soft dramatic crisis of 2008/2009 and the subsequent currency, i.e., inflation-prone, consumption-based recession and sovereign debt crisis. Somehow growth model, on the other (Iversen, Soskice et al. ironically, or tragically, therefore, the export of 2016). One key motive for currency union was a the German low-inflation regime to the European geopolitical consideration: committing unified level, triggered the real divergence between the Germany irreversibly to the European project. In north and the south of the currency zone (Palier, addition, the currency union represented a quid Rovny et al. 2018), and it rather reinforced than pro quo of low inflation and low interest rates for weakened central traits of the German political the south and therefore a boost of credit-based economy, in particular its strong export depen- growth there, in exchange for abandoning the dence. option of devaluating in order to level out the wage restraint and productivity growth in the northern export industry (Iversen, Soskice et al. 2016). Apart from these two decisive factors, EMU came about not despite the profound differences between the northern and the southern political economy, but because of them: as a commitment of the south to the “German” low inflation equilibrium in order to break with the inflationary tendencies inherent in the southern model. This explanation of the euro crisis and its specific dynamic starts with a focus on national wage bargaining systems. It is also in line with several other recent explanations for the crisis (Hancké 2013; Hassel 2014; Höpner and Lutter 2014; 84 This bifurcation into two groups of countries had 85 This contradicts Martin Wolf’s diagnosis, however: the already occurred in the 1970s under the European Monetary euro crisis is not (or at least no longer) a “financial crisis with System: “The first group, made up of Germany, the Benelux fiscal consequences” (Wolf 2014: 302), but has since turned countries, and , had succeeded in limiting inflation into a competitiveness crisis with fiscal consequences. My to the mid to high single digits and in keeping their exchange position also diverges from Scharpf’s analysis, in which he rates stable …. In fact, this was a deutschmark-based arrange- emphasizes the fiscal problem of euro member states running ment, since Germany was the lowest-inflation country and a public debt in a “foreign” currency. With Draghi’s “whatever accounted for more than two-thirds of the collective GDP of it takes” guarantee the ECB has, in fact, become lender of last this group. The second set of countries - France, Italy, and the resort. Further, with historically low interest rates, debt service , and Ireland - had more difficulty restraining is cheaper than ever before. However, (the lack of) private inflation and were therefore unable to keep their currencies competitiveness remains a problem and, with sluggish growth, within the margins of the Snake” (Eichengreen 2007: 283). these states then also inevitably have a fiscal problem.

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 43 Philip Manow References: Carlin, W. and D. Soskice (1990). Macroeconomics and the Wage Bargain. A Modern Approach to Anderson, C. J. and D. S. Ward (1996). “Barometer Employment, Inflation and the Exchange Rate. Elections in Comparative Perspective.” Elec- Oxford, Oxford University Press. toral Studies15(4): 447-460. Clasen, J. (2005). Reforming European Welfare Arndt, C. (2013). The Electoral Consequences States: Germany and the United Kingdom of Welfare State Reforms: Social Compared. Oxford, Oxford University Press. Democracy’s Transformation and Its Political Clegg, D. and J. Clasen (2006). “Beyond activation: Costs. Amsterdam, Amsterdam University reforming unemployment protection systems Press. in post-industrial labour markets.” European Baldwin, R. and F. Giavazzi, eds. (2015). The Euro- Societies8(4): 555-581. zone Crisis. A Consensus View of the Causes Clegg, D. and J. Clasen (2006). New labour market and a Few Possible Solutions. London, CEPR risks and the revision of unemployment protec- Press. tion systems in Europe. The Politics of the Post- Beramendi, P., S. Häusermann, et al. (2015). Intro- Industrial Welfare State. K. Armingeon and G. duction: The Politics of Advanced Capitalism. Bonoli. London, Routledge: 192-210. The Politics of Advanced Capitalism. P. Bera- De Grauwe, P. (2013). “The Political Economy of mendi, S. Häusermann, H. Kitschelt and H. the Euro.” Annual Review of Political Science16: Kriesi. New York, Cambridge University Press: 153-170. 1-64. De Grauwe, P. (2014). Economics of Monetary Blyth, M. (2015). Austerity: The History of a Union. Oxford, Oxford University Press. Dangerous Idea. Oxford, Oxford University Press. di Carlo, D. (2018). The Political Economy of Public Sector Wage setting in Germany and Italy. Böhnke, P., J. Zeh, et al. (2015). “Atypische Beschäf- Responses of European Economic Cultures tigung im Erwerbsverlauf: Verlaufstypen als to Europe’s Crisis Politics: The Example of Ausdruck sozialer Spaltung?” Zeitschrift für German-Italian Discrepancies. C. Joerges and Soziologie 44(4): 234-252. J. Hien. Villa Vigoni, Como. Burda, M. C. and J. Hunt (2011). “What explains Eichengreen, B. (2007). The European Economy the German Labour Market Miracle in the Great since 1945: Coordinated Capitalism and Recession?” Brookings Papers on Economic beyond. Princeton, Princeton University Press. Activity Spring. Eichengreen, B. (2012). Hall of Mirrors: The Carlin, W. (2013). “Real Exchange Rate Adjust- Great Depression, the Great Recession, and the ment, Wage-Setting Institutions, and Fiscal Uses-and Misuses-of History. Oxford, Oxford Stabilization Policy: Lessons of the Eurozone’s University Press. First Decade.” CESifo Economic Studies59(3): 489- 519. Eichhorst, W. and L. C. Kaiser (2006). “The German Labour Market: Still Adjusting Badly?” Carlin, W., A. Hassel, et al. (2014). The Transfor- IZA Discussion Paper(2215). mation of the German Social Model. European Social Models From Crisis to Crisis: Employ- Eichhorst, W. and V. Tobsch (2014). “Flexible ment and Inequality in the Era of Monetary Arbeitswelten.” IZA Research Report59. Integration. J. E. Dolvik and A. Martin. Oxford, Eichhorst, W. and V. Tobsch (2014). “Not So Oxford University Press: 50-105. Standard Anymore? Employment Duality in

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 44 Philip Manow Germany.” IZA Discussion Paper(8155). Southern Europe.” Manuscript, Hertie School Emmenegger, P., S. Häusermann, et al., Eds. of Governance. (2012). The Age of Dualization. The Changing Hassel, A. (2014). “The Paradox of Liberalization Face of Inequality in Deindustrializing Soci- - Understanding Dualism and the Recovery of eties. Oxford, Oxford University Press. the German Political Economy.” British Journal Esping-Andersen, G. (1999). Social foundations of Industrial Relations52(1): 57-71. of post-industrial Economies. Oxford, Oxford Hassel, A. (2014). “Three sources for Germany’s University Press. export dependency: Industrial relations, social Franzese, R. J. J. (1999). “Partially Independent insurance and fiscal federalism.” Manuscript. Central Banks, Politically Reponsive Govern- Hassel, A. (2017 (forthcoming)). “No way to escape ments, and Inflation.” American Journal of imbalances in the Eurozone? Three sources for Political Science43(3): 681-706. Germany’s export dependency: Industrial rela- Gros, D. and N. Thygesen (1998). European mone- tions, social insurance and fiscal federalism.” tary integration: from the European mone- German Politics. tary system to economic and monetary union. Hassel, A. and C. Schiller (2010). Der Fall Hartz London, Prentice Hall. IV: wie es zur Agenda 2010 kam und wie es Hall, P. A. (1994). “Central Bank Independence weitergeht. Frankfurt am Main, Campus. and Coordinated Wage Bargaining: Their Inter- Höpner, M. and M. Lutter (2014). “One Currency action in Germany and Europe.” German Poli- and Many Modes of Wage Formation. Why the tics and Society31: 1-23. Eurozone Is Too Heterogeneous for the Euro.” Hall, P. A. (2012). “The Economics and Poli- MPIfG Discussion Paper14(14). tics of the Euro Crisis.” German Politics21(4): Illing, G., S. Jauch, et al. (2012). “Die Diskussion 355-371. um den Euro.” Leviathan40(2): 156-172. Hall, P. A. (2014). “Varieties of Capitalism and Iversen, T. and D. Soskice (2018). A structural- the Euro Crisis.” West European Politics37(6): institutional explanation of the Eurozone 1223-1243. Crisis. Welfare Democracies & Electoral Poli- Hall, P. A. and R. J. Franzese, Jr. (1998). “Mixed tics. Explaining Electoral Dynamics in Times Signals: Central Bank Independence, Coordi- of Changing Welfare Capitalism. P. Manow, nated Wage Bargaining, and European Mone- B. Palier and H. Schwander. Oxford, Oxford tary Union.” International Organization52(3): University Press: 257-280. 505-535. Iversen, T., D. Soskice, et al. (2016). “The Eurozone Hancké, B. (2002). The Political Economy of and Political Economic Institutions.” Annual Wage-setting in the Eurozone. Wage Policy in Review of Political Science19. the Eurozone. P. Pochet. Brussels, Peter Land: James, H. (2012). Making the European Monetary 131-148. Union. Cambridge, Belknap Press. Hancké, B. (2013). Unions, Central Banks, and Kersbergen, K. v. and P. Manow, Eds. (2009). Reli- EMU: Labour Market Institutions and Mone- gion, Class Coalitions and the Welfare State. tary Integration in Europe. Oxford, Oxford Cambridge Series on Social Theory, Politics University Press. and Religion. New York, Cambridge University Hassel, A. (2014). “Adjustments in the Euro- Press. zone: Varieties of Capitalism and the Crisis in Kitschelt, H. (2001). Partisan Competition and

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 45 Philip Manow Welfare State Retrenchment. When Do Poli- O’Rourke, K. and A. M. Taylor (2013). “Cross ticians Choose Unpopular Policies? The New of Euros.” Journal of Economic Perspectives Politics of the Welfare State. P. Pierson. Oxford, 27(3): 167-192. Oxford University Press: 265-302. OECD (2015). In it together - Why less inequality Klinger, S., T. Rothe, et al. (2013). “Makroökon- benefits all. Paris, OECD. omische Perspektive auf die Hartz-Reformen: Palier, B., A. Rovny, et al. (2018). The Dual Die Vorteile überwiegen.” IAB-Kurzb- Dualization of Europe: Economic Conver- ericht11/2013: 1-8. gence, Divergence, and their Political Conse- Koch, S., P. Kupka, et al. (2009). Aktivierung, quences. Welfare Democracy and Party Poli- Erwerbstätigkeit und Teilhabe. Vier Jahre tics. Explaining Electoral Dynamics in Times Grundsicherung für Arbeitssuchende. Biele- of Changing Welfare Capitalism. P. Manow, feld, Bertelsmann. B. Palier and H. Schwander. Oxford, Oxford Krugman, P. and M. Obstfeld (2012). Interna- University Press: 281-297. tionale Wirtschaft. Theorie und Politik der Palier, B. and K. A. Thelen (2010). “Institutional- Außenwirtschaft. München usw., Pearson. izing Dualism: Complementaries and Change Manow, P. (2009). “Electoral Rules, Class-Coali- in France and Germany.” Politics & Societies tions and Welfare State Regimes - or how to 38(1): 119 - 148. explain Esping-Andersen with Stein Rokkan.” Rehder, B. (2003). Betriebliche Bündnisse für Socio-Economic Review7(1): 101-121. Arbeit in Deutschland. Mitbestimmung und Manow, P. (2013). “Religious Cleavages, Divi- Flächentarif im Wandel. Frankfurt am Main, sions on the Left and the Political Economy Campus. of Southern Europe.” International Journal of Rhein, T. (2013). “Erwerbseinkommen. Deutsche Social Quality3(2): 78-105. Geringverdiener im europäischen Vergleich.” Manow, P. (2015). “Workers, Farmers, and Cathol- IAB Kurzbericht - Aktuelle Analysen aus dem ̈ icism: A History of Political Class Coalitions Institut fur Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung and the South-European Welfare State Regime.” 15. Journal of European Social Policy25(1): 32-49. Rueda, D. (2005). “Insider - Outsider Politics in Manow, P., B. Palier, et al., Eds. (2017). Worlds industrialized Democracies: The Challenge to of Welfare Capitalism and Electoral Politics. Social Democratic Parties.” American Political Oxford, Oxford University Press. Science Review 99(1): 61-74. Manow, P. and E. Seils (1999). Adjusting Badly: Rueda, D. (2006). “Social Democracy and Active The German Welfare State, Structural Change Labour-Market Policies: Insiders, Outsiders and the Open Economy. From Vulnerability and the Politics of Employment Protection.” to Competitiveness: Welfare and Work in British Journal of Political Science 36: 385-406. the Open Economy. F. W. Scharpf and V. A. Scharpf, F. W. (1987). Sozialdemokratische Kris- Schmidt. New York, Oxford University Press: enpolitik in Europa. Frankfurt, Campus. 264-304. Scharpf, F. W. (2011). “Monetary Union, Fiscal Marin, D. (2010). “Germany’s super competitive- Crisis, and the Preemption of Democracy.” ness: A helping hand from Eastern Europe.” MPIfG Discussion Paper 11/11. Max-Planck VOX - CEPR’s Policy Portal 20 June 2010: Institute for the Study of Societies, Cologne. http://www.voxeu.org/article/germany- Scharpf, F. W. (2017). “Vom asymmetrischen s-super-competitiveness.

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 46 Philip Manow Euro-Regime in die Transfer-Union – und was die deutsche Politik dagegen tun könnte “ Levi- athan 45(3): 286-308. Schumacher, G. (2011). ‘Modernize or Die’? Social Democrats, Welfare State Retrenchment and the Choice between Office and Policy. Amsterdam, University Amsterdam. Schwander, H. and P. Manow (2016). “‘Modernize and Die’? German Social Democracy and the electoral Consequences of the Agenda 2010.” Socio-Economic Review forthcoming. Streeck, W. (2009). Re-Forming Capitalism. Institutional Change in the German Political Economy. Oxford, Oxford University Press. Streeck, W. and A. Schäfer, Eds. (2013). Politics in the Age of Austerity. London, Wiley & Sons. Thelen, K. (2014). Varieties of Liberalization and the New Politics of Social Solidarity. New York, Cambridge University Press. Vail, M. I. (2010). Recasting Welfare Capitalism. Economic Adjustment in Contemporary France and Germany. Philadelphia, Temple University Press. Walters, A. (1992). Walters Critique. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance. P. K. Newman, M. Milgate and J. Eatwell. Basing- stoke, Hampshire, Palgrave Macmillan. Wolf, M. (2014). The Shifts and the Shocks. What we’ve learned - and have still to learn - from the financial crisis. New York, Penguin. Wren, A., Ed. (2013). The Political Economy of the Service Transition. Oxford, Oxford University Press.

THE GERMAN POLITICAL ECONOMY UNDER THE EURO – AND A COMPARISON TO THE “SOUTHERN MODEL” 47 Philip Manow 86 for the representation of public employers (TdL THE POLITICAL ECONOMY 87 OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE- for Germany, and ARAN for Italy), national courts of auditors (Corte Dei Conti) and academic/ SETTING IN GERMANY AND policy experts close to the field of interest. ITALY In preview, the main argument of this paper is Donato Di Carlo the following: while Germany pursued public sector wage restraint throughout the period Max Planck Institute for Studies of Societies 1994-2007, during the years 2002-2006, Italian public employers deliberately pursued a policy of Setting the Scene public sector wage inflation for strategic political purposes. After the crisis, wage restraint in Italy The chance to write this brief contribution stems was the result of unilaterally implemented wage from the invitation that I received to attend the cuts and freezes in the public sector. In Germany, Villa Vigoni conference. The general topic of the wages are, instead, prevented from rocketing conference revolves around discrepancies in the - notwithstanding favourable material condi- German and Italian responses to the multiple tions - by the peculiar structure of public sector crises affecting Europe. wage-setting, which brings together rich and poor Specifically, the subject matter of this paper Länder (and municipalities) into a structured deci- pertains to the domain of public sector employ- sional process which produces a low wage equi- ment relations and wage policies in the European librium. In both the TVöD and TV-L contracts, Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). The aim wage increases have to be set as a lowest common is to look at the political and institutional determi- denominator to take into consideration the ability nants of public sector wage policies in Germany of the poor Länder (in TV-L) and municipalities and Italy over the period 1991-2015. In so doing, (TVöD) to pay. Italy, in contrast, experienced a I ask the following interrelated questions: What pro-cyclical pattern of public sector wage inflation were the political and institutional determinants and restraint. During the good times of the Euro, of Germany and Italy’s divergent public sector public sector wages increased beyond macroeco- wage trajectories before the crisis? And, while Italy nomic fundamentals, driven by the political moti- underwent severe post-crisis austerity measures vations of the “Southern bloc” (composed of the which led to public sector wage deflation, why parties such as Alleanza Nazionale and Unione have public sector wages not risen consistently in Di Centro) inside the Berlusconi-led centre-right Germany notwithstanding the budget surplus and coalition. The pattern of wage inflation had started low unemployment? to be reversed before the crisis occurred, when Tommaso Padoa-Schioppa was finance minister, The empirical basis of the argument developed under the centre-left coalition led by Romano here is provided by research pursued in the context Prodi in 2006-2007. Eventually, however, when of my doctoral project at the Max Planck Insti- the crisis unfolded, wage restraint was unilater- tute for the Study of Societies, in Cologne. Besides ally imposed by the finance minister Giulio Trem- the analysis of macroeconomic data and primary onti in 2009 and was then continued by the subse- institutional sources, the essay draws on exten- sive fieldwork carried out in both countries. I have 86 TdL (Tarifgemeinschaft deutscher Länder) is the associa- conducted interviews (24 in Germany and 17 in tion of finance ministers of the German Laender in charge of Italy) with key policy-makers in the top echelons of negotiating public sector wage contracts. the Finance ministries, trade unions, associations 87 ARAN (Agenzia per la Rappresentanza Negoziale delle Pubbliche Amministrazioni) is the Italian independent agency in charge of representing the government during negotiations with trade unions.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 48 Donato Di Carlo quent governments. Overall, Italy had seven years CPE research interested in studying public sector of wage freezes which substantially contributed to wage-setting should, instead, look at the institu- deflate its economy pro-cyclically. tional constellation shaping processes of public In sum, discrepancies in public sector wage-setting sector wage-setting proper and stop understanding in the two countries can be attributed to different the working of the public sector solely as a func- institutional structures for the determination of tion of export-sector interests. This constellation, I public sector pay and interest representation. A posit, is composed of three key elements; first, the system of soft fiscal constraints in Italy allows for structure of the public administration determines the political willingness of sovereign employers to the distribution of administrative competencies pay inflationary wages in good times. In Germany, among the layers of the public administration – instead, a system of hard fiscal constraints for sub- and therefore the distribution of personnel costs; national governments precludes the pursuit of a second, the structure of the taxation system deter- policy of wage inflation. In the former country, the mines the ability to pay of sovereign employers structure of public sector wage-setting leads to the located at the different levels of the public admin- politicisation of wage determination processes. In istration; and, third, the characteristics of public the latter, wage policy choices are constrained ex sector employment relations determine legal rights ante by the fiscal constitution of the state. and the structure and modes of interest represen- tation. The implications of this argument for comparative political economy (CPE) are manifold. Contrary The remainder of this paper is organised as to what is usually believed (Hancké 2013; Höpner follows; Section 1 engages with the problem of and Lutter 2014; Johnston 2016; Johnston and public sector wage divergence in the EMU; Section Hancke 2009; Johnston, Hancke, and Pant 2014), 2 provides a summary of the German case study, wage restraint in the German public sector is while Section 3 deals with the Italian one. Due to space constraints, I will skip a thorough review of not due to effective/defective inter-sectoral wage 88 co-ordination imposed by the export sector upon the literature and provide only stylised accounts sheltered sector wage-setters (Di Carlo 2018). of the case studies. Nor was or is it pursued to protect export price competitiveness in the interests of an “hege- 1. The Problem of Divergent monic social coalition” between employers and Public Sector Wage-setting skilled labour in the export industries (Baccaro in the EMU and Benassi 2016; Baccaro and Pontusson 2016; Hassel 2014). Public sector wage-setting is, first Joining the EMU entails losses of national sover- and foremost, a public finance problem. It involves eignty vis-à-vis the policy tools available for the state actors located at different levels of the public macroeconomic stabilisation of the economy (De administration, representing heterogenous insti- Grauwe 2016). Of the four standard policy tools tutional interests (very diverse from those of the available for the control of the economy (Scharpf German export industry). Furthermore, public 1991), monetary policy is delegated to a suprana- sector wage policies do not come uncontested. tional independent central bank; fiscal policy is Studying the politics of fiscal policy teaches us that de jure constrained by national and supranational significant conflicts can emerge inside the sover- Fiscal Compacts, while exchange rates are relin- eign employers bloc: for example, between finance quished. In this scenario, wage policies remain the ministers with diverse vested interests across most important pillar of macroeconomic policy- different state levels (as in Germany) or between making for domestic social partners in the EMU. politicians (who make promises) and the finance 88 For a more detailed discussion on public sector wage ministers of their governing coalition (who have setting in the German context, see Di Carlo (2018) and Keller to pay for them). (2011).

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 49 Donato Di Carlo While private sector wage policies are often Starting from the Golden Rule: beyond the remit of governmental authorities WP= 1,9% + Δ avg. LP (e.g., Tarifautonomie in Germany), public sector wage policies are of particular interest, given Where: that their implementation necessarily coincides WP = wage policy implemented with the fiscal stance of the sovereign employers ECB inflation target = 1,9% in charge of earmarking fiscal resources for wage contracts. Thus, looking at public sector wage Δ Avg. LP = % change (yoy) in total labour trajectories is a fundamental way of looking at the productivity in the economy fiscal trajectories of governments. Public sector Sovereign employers can then adopt three alter- wage-setting matters in the EMU, both with regard native types of wage policies: to the co-ordination of the fiscal policies of euro Member States, but also, and especially so, for the i. Policy of wage inflation > Golden Rule impact that wage inflation can have on macroeco- ii. Policy of wage restraint < Golden Rule nomic imbalances via divergent unit labour costs 89 iii. Policy of the Golden Rule = Golden Rule (ULC) and price inflation (Baccaro and Tober 2017; Hancké 2013; Johnston, Hancke, and Pant Ideally, in order to avoid a rise of macroeconomic 2014). imbalances, trajectories of nominal wages would have had to develop in line with national produc- From the perspective of the EMU’s macroeco- tivity rates and the supranational price target. nomic regime - an economic system rooted in Reality has proven different from theory. Panel price stability - relatively stable ULC inflation is a in Figure 1 shows the divergent trajectories of required in order to avoid structural divergence of nominal wages in the public sectors of the EMU Members’ price inflation in the medium to long participants during the good times of the Euro. run. The trade imbalances to which this diver- Three clusters can be observed. At the two oppo- gence leads can, in fact, no longer be absorbed site extremes, we find Germany (alone) pursuing through adjustable exchange rates (Carlin and a policy of remarkable public sector wage restraint Soskice 2014, Ch. 12). 91 and the so-called GIIPS countries experiencing In this context, the European Commission had substantial public sector wage inflation. The core adopted what is understood as the Golden Rule of 90 countries of the EMU, interestingly, have had Wage Bargaining as the formal policy guideline wage developments almost perfectly in line with for national social partners: wage-setting is to be the Golden Rule. based upon the European Central Bank’s (ECB) Not surprisingly, public sector wage developments inflation target plus average productivity in the have mirrored quite faithfully the trajectory of real economy. Given the absence of pan-European exchange rates (REER) (Figure 2) since the launch wage co-ordination, this was meant to engineer a of the single currency. The connection between virtuous interaction between national wage poli- public sector wage inflation/restraint, REER cies and the supranational monetary policy and, at appreciations/depreciations and current account the same time, avoid inflation differentials and the imbalances is evident. Research has, in fact, shown rise of macroeconomic imbalances in the mone- that current account imbalances in the EMU had tary union. In an abstract world, three types of their root cause primarily in sheltered sector wage wage policies are thus available to national public inflation (Baccaro and Tober 2017; Hancké 2013; sector wage-setters. Johnston, Hancke, and Pant 2014), of which the public sector constitutes the bulk. 89 See Höpner and Lutter (2014) for a review of the em- On average, public sector employment in the pirical literature. 90 For a more detailed description, see Collignon (2009). 91 Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Spain.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 50 Donato Di Carlo EMU accounts for more than 15 per cent of total had undergone wage infl ation in the good times employment. Th e sovereign employers are the of the single currency all experienced post-crisis single biggest, political and economic, employers restraint, as part of the harsh austerity measures in every advanced economy. Since public wages which followed. Arguably, public sector wage- are paid out of taxpayers’ money, wage policy in setting is the fi rst and most accessible policy the public sector cannot but be a subset of fi scal domain from which governments glean resources policy. With regards to the latter, studies by the in hard times. Germany, in contrast, did not European Central Bank (Holm-Hadulla et al. perform the eagerly awaited symmetric adjust- 2010, 4) also fi nd that “government wage expen- ment (Bibow 2012) through an expansionary diture is subject to a pro-cyclical bias in most public sector wage policy. It continued along euro area countries and at the euro area aggregate the trajectory of moderate public sector wage level”. A pro-cyclical policy of wage infl ation in increases inaugurated in the aft ermath of re-unifi - the public sector can thus lead to losses of REER cation (Di Carlo 2018; Keller 2016; 2014). competitiveness, underpin excessive imports, Th us, overall, the wage trajectories in the Italian and contribute to an overall expansionary - pro- and German public sectors develop asymmetri- cyclical - fi scal stance in the economy. Vice versa, cally in both good times (panel a) and hard times in hard times, public sector wages are hardly hit by (panel b). In the fi rst decade of the EMU, Italy the fi scal authorities. experienced public sector wage infl ation, while Figure 1: Indexes* of hourly wages in the public Germany pursued wage restraint. In hard times, sectors of EMU countries (1999-2015). Germany continued its pattern of moderate public sector wage increases (despite slightly expanding public sector employment in some sectors such as and care), while Italy underwent remarkable wage restraint. Figure 2: Real Eff ective Exchange Rates (REER) of EMU members (2000-2013), based upon unit labour costs (ULCs), weighted against 14 EU trading partners. Quarterly data (.1=1st quarter)

Source: EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts, September 2017 release. *Indexes are discounted by labour productivity in the total economy. In (a), 1999=100. In (b), 2009=100. EMU Core = , , , France, Th e Neth- erlands. EMU Periphery = Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Spain. Th is is particularly evident when observing devel- opments in public sector wages in the aft ermath of the crisis. Panel b in Figure 1 shows the poli- Source: Bruegel Datasets, REER for 178 countries, a new data- base (Latest update: June 6,2017). cies of public sector wage restraint pursued in the GIIPS countries aft er 2009. Th e countries which EMU Core = Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Nether- lands. EMU Periphery = Spain, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 51 Donato Di Carlo Notwithstanding the relevance of public sector 2. The Political Economy of wage policies for the smooth functioning of the Public Sector Wage Restraint single currency, very little research is available on in Germany: die öffentlichen the topic. The public sector has been neglected Kassen sind immer leer both by industrial relations scholars and the comparative political economists – not to mention scholars of European affairs. 2.1 The 1990s: blühende Landschaften hit the EMU fiscal In industrial relations, a set of works exists that constraints studies the structures of public sector employ- ment relations and patterns of institutional change With regard to public sector wage-setting in (Bach and Bordogna 2016; 2013; L Bordogna, Germany, it needs to be distinguished between Dell’Aringa, and Della Rocca 1999; Keller 2016; public employees and civil servants (Beamten). 2011; Keller and Seifert 2015). These studies Collective bargaining regulates wage-setting for are highly informative, but remain mostly at a the former. Unilateral legislation by the Govern- descriptive level. In CPE, the public sector has ment sets employment and pay conditions for the always been treated as a satellite of the export 92 latter. Given the structure of the German public sector’s interests. The perspective adopted in administration, three levels of employment exist: these studies was always that of inter-sectoral wage the Federation (Bund), the states (Länder), and the co-ordination between the exposed sectors and municipalities (Gemeinden). Public employers at the sheltered ones. Surprisingly enough, no atten- each level are responsible for their employees and tion was ever paid to the structure of the public can choose whether to employ personnel as civil administration, the role of the state as a sovereign servants or as public employees. At the federal employer (Hyman 2008; Traxler 1999), the char- level, the sovereign employers are represented in acteristics of public sector employment relations negotiations by the ministry of the interior, flanked or the fiscal constitution of the state. The study of by the finance minister. At theLänder level, the public sector wage bargaining remains a neglected regional finance ministers are grouped together in and misunderstood aspect in the discipline. The the so-called Tarifgemeinschaft deutscher Länder status quo in the literature is not satisfying and a (TdL). At the municipal level, municipalities are clear-cut understanding of the political and insti- grouped into a state level association Kommunaler tutional determinants of public sector wage setting Arbeitgeberverband (KAV). The 16 associations in missing in both industrial relations and CPE. from each Land are then represented together by the Vereinigung der kommunalen Arbeitge- berverbände (VKA). Overall, until 2002, the three employers corresponding to the three public administration levels negotiated jointly with the trade unions under the leadership of the federal minister of the interior (a practice termed Tarifge- meinschaft). Given that the German Constitution (Grundg- esetz) attributes most of the competencies to the sub-national governments, the Länder and the 92 Di Carlo (2018) provides a thorough literature review of this literature in the context of European CPE. It also provides municipalities are the entities which bear the costs an empirical falsification of the thesis according to which wage for administrative personnel disproportionately. restraint in the German public sector is the result of export- While for the Länder expenditure for personnel sector-led pattern bargaining.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 52 Donato Di Carlo amount to around 40-45 per cent of their total esterno. In the 1990s, public sector wage restraint expenditure, the municipalities spend 25 per cent occurred out of concerns for fiscal deficits by the of the budget on personnel, while the federal level federal finance minister . The consoli- spends only around 9-10 per cent (Destatis data). dation measures implemented in 1996 are effec- Given this cost structure, personnel costs (a stock) tively summarised by the IMF fiscal consolidation (and hence wage increases (a flow)) constitute a dataset: major concern for the finance ministers of the “Fiscal consolidation in 1997 was Länder and municipalities. Most importantly, the primarily motivated by deficit reduction states and municipalities act as tax collectors for and meeting the Maastricht deficit criteria the federation, with whom they share tax revenues … To shore up the public finances, the according to vertical and horizontal fiscal equal- authorities adopted in late 1996 substantial isation grants which are enacted via pre-deter- discretionary fiscal measures as part of mined formulae. Given the taxation structure, the the budget for 1997, which were heavily Länder and municipalities simply cannot readily weighted on spending cuts … With these manipulate their marginal tax revenues. The only measures, the authorities expected that the way that the Länder have to increase their tax general government deficit would decline revenues is through changes in legislation via the to 2% of GDP in 1997, safely under the Bundesrat, which would require the consensus of Maastricht reference value. Spending cuts all the Länder. The result of this joint-decision in the 1997 budget amounted to 1% of trap (Scharpf 2005) is that the fiscal structure in GDP and were based on wage restraint and which lower levels of government are embedded retrenchments, spending limits imposed at puts enormous pressure on the expenditure side the federal and state level, reducing sick – of which the personnel costs are among the pay coverage and restricting spa visits, and most significant items – leaving not much choice tightening eligibility for unemployment other than to keep the personnel expenditure in benefits.” check - disproportionately so for the Länder. This tense situation worsened after the absorption of 2.2 The Early 2000s: The Länder the poor new Länder into the fiscal equalisation Offensive system in 1995. In the early 2000s, the drivers for restraint were In fact, wage restraint in the German public sector different. Wage restraint was the result of a process started both before (and in relation to) the EMU, of institutional change which overhauled the old and as a consequence of the fiscal costs of reuni- Tarifgemeinschaft. The process was driven and fication. The blühende Landschaften promised by wanted by the finance ministers of the Länder. At to his fellow Germans, inevitably the core of Länder finance ministers’ preoccupa- came to clash with the fiscal constraints set in tions was the concern about keeping the personnel the Maastricht Treaty and the following Stability cost of their state administrations under control. Growth Pact (forcefully insisted upon by the They also started a controversy with the unions, German finance minister Theo Weigel). Public in 2003, on extending working hours (Dribbusch sector wage restraint first emerged in 1994 via a 2006). For them, keeping costs down is of dispro- wage freeze for civil servants unilaterally imposed portionate importance given their cost struc- by the government, together with a moderate tures and, especially, given the impossibility of wage settlement collectively negotiated for public freely manipulating their marginal tax revenues. employees. It was then pushed through decisively To achieve this end, they opted to free themselves via a Spaarpaket before the fiscal year of 1997 - from the (expensive) leadership of the federal in order to comply with the Maastricht vincolo

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 53 Donato Di Carlo level in public sector wage negotiations. Also, they there is increasing difficulty in recruiting public wanted to separate themselves from the (trouble- employees (especially teachers and nurses). Public some) municipal level in which public employees opinion also appears to be in favour of expanding potentially have the highest disruptive power public employment. Yet, one can barely notice an to affect negotiating dynamics thanks to their upward trajectory of wage increases. Why? strength in basic community services (e.g., in local To be sure, increases in public employment in transport and waste disposal). the categories mentioned are indeed visible. Yet, I Negotiations to reform the system started after the argue that public wages are structurally prevented signature of the 2002 collective/national contract from increasing in Germany because of the unique and were concluded in 2005 with the creation public sector wage-setting regime. of the Tarifvertrag für den Öffentlichen Dienst With regards to the TV-L contract, TdL negotiators (TVöD) contract which regulates public employees are forced to take into consideration the ability of at federal and municipal level. Wage restraint the finance ministers from the poor Länder to pay. emerged as a combination of extended working The poor states greatly value the benefits of collec- hours, a rationalisation of special bonuses and a tive bargaining coordinated through the TdL, moderate lump-sum compensation of €300 per especially in order to avoid direct wage competi- year in the years 2005, 2006 and 2007. The unions tion with the richer Länder and to avoid setting exchanged restraint for participation in reforming up costly bargaining units to handle negotiations the old bargaining structure. and internecine conflict. Moreover, they still have TdL did not want to be part of TVöD, and, after to make sure that the rich Länder, with a higher very tense negotiations and strike actions, ability to pay, do not push up wage settlements throughout 2006, they reached an agreement with driving them into bankruptcy. In the internal poli- the unions on the creation of the new Tarifvertrag tics of TdL, it does not take much to convince the für den Öffentlichen Dienst der Länder (TV-L). finance ministers of the rich states to hide behind The agreement envisaged lump sums of various the poor ones: they have, so to speak, an interest amounts depending on the pay grades, to be in being outvoted. Personnel costs are, on average, paid out to employees in July 2006, January 2007 higher in the books of the old Länder, when and September 2007, a rationalisation of special compared to the new ones, which underwent a bonuses and the extension of working hours. massive re-structuring after re-unification. Setting As a parallel development, the reform of the wages calibrated as a lowest common denomi- fiscal federalism system in 2006 has restored to nator decreases their fiscal opportunity costs - i.e., the Länder the competence to legislate on the frees fiscal resources can be spent on other items employment and wage conditions of their own (or hoarded as budget surpluses, which the finance civil servants. This has introduced an element ministers of accountable states seem to value of competitive federalism and created an hori- considerably). At the same time, richer Länder zontal diversification of wage conditions across can blame the restraint on the poor finances of the states, with Berlin and located at the the others. TdL itself has an organisational interest opposite extremes of the continuum (DGB 2016). in keeping the 15 state finance ministers together (Hesse is not in the TdL). The rich states would 2.3 Public Sector Wage-setting in most probably have to pay higher wages than they the Age of Prosperity currently pay (without upward competition) and would see their transaction costs in negotiations Germany is living through times of budget increase. The poor Länder would find themselves surpluses and almost full employment. Also, in a fully competitive federal system, in which they would be net losers. The system is granted some

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 54 Donato Di Carlo flexibility for diversification and competition via bargaining rights in conjunction with civil servant the possibility for the states of hiring civil servants status gave birth to a regime of “double guarantee”, and thus can unilaterally decree wage settlements. or, as scholars have put it, “pluralism without With regard to the TVöD contract, a similar logic markets” (Lorenzo Bordogna 1994; Giugni 1992). applies, although without the cleavage rich vs During the 1980s, this public sector wage-setting poor states. This is because poor municipalities regime led to uncontrolled wage inflation and are widespread also in . Substantial politically-tolerated, leapfrogging dynamics in wage increases are prevented from the necessity a context of union fragmentation and recurring to avoid bankruptcy of poor municipalities and/ disputes (Cella 1991). or a likely increase of transfers from the Federal The public sector wage-setting regime of the level. Negotiators in the VKA, together with the first republic consisted of a highly fragmented federal finance and interior ministers, are aware system in which smaller trade unions (sindacati of the necessity to avoid costly settlements which autonomi), independent of the peak level confed- risk endangering the finances of lower levels. erations, the CGIL, CISL and UIL, had established Thus, in the German system, key explanatory a dense network of clientelistic relations with factors for public sector wage restraint are the political referents in parliament (Ricciardi 2013, structure of the public sector wage-setting regime, 120-27). This network led to what was termed the direct accountability of Länder finance minis- “wage jungle” (giungla retributiva) (Gorrieri 1973) ters and their isolation from political influence. to indicate the practice of setting public sector wages regardless of any economic or administra- 3. The Political Economy of tive logic. Wage-setting in the public sector simply responded to the political logic of (re-) producing Public Sector Wage Inflation consent. Political actors in parliament were thus 93 and Restraint in Italy: We able to pass specific laws (leggine settoriali) will Find the Money, if we hiding them from the scrutiny of public opinion, Like delivering favourable provisions (income and non-income related) to their affiliated sub-groups 3.1 The 1990s: Depoliticisation of workers in the public sector (Talamo 2009b). of Public Sector Collective Major reforms of the system of public sector pay Bargaining? determination were passed in 1992-1993 with the ambition to make the process “apolitical” Until the end of the 1960s, pay and employment and to contain public expenditure. The public relations in Italy were unilaterally set by the sover- law status of public employees was abolished and eign employer through laws or administrative the employment relationship was “privatised” acts. In this system, public employees enjoyed the (privatizzazione del pubblico impiego). Collective 94 employment status of civil servants, which guar- bargaining became the legal method to regulate anteed employment security and seniority careers terms and conditions of employment. The reform (Rusciano 1978). Over time, collective bargaining of the summer of 1993 introduced a two-tier rights were granted and, during the 1970s, the wage-bargaining system in which the main pillar practice spread throughout the branches of the 93 This practice was unveiled also by a Parliamentary public sector, until the 1983 Legge Quadro intro- Commission (Commissione Coppo) in 1977 and later de- duced collective bargaining as a primary mode nounced in the famous “Report on the fundamental problems of pay determination – although contracts still of the State” by Professor Massimo Severo Giannini in 1979. needed to be transformed into administrative acts 94 Approximately 80% of public employees were subjected to the reform. Core functions of the state were not privatized, to come into effect. The introduction of collective- such as judges, police, the army, etc.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 55 Donato Di Carlo consisted of nationally agreed and uniform wage wage negotiations for political purposes. However, increases negotiated between the newly-created the creation of ARAN could not circumvent the independent agency (Agenzia per la Rappresen- political nature of public sector wage-setting in tanza Negoziale delle pubbliche amminstrazioni - which the fiscal costs for the determination of ARAN) and the trade unions. The second pillar wage increases had to be earmarked in budget regarded wage increases at the decentralised level laws. The way in which Italy reformed its system to be negotiated by individual administrations and did not shelter the finance ministers from party the workplace personnel representation bodies in politics. ARAN would negotiate with the trade a context of “organised decentralisation” (Lorenzo unions on how to distribute resources, while the Bordogna 2012; L Bordogna, Dell’Aringa, and quantum of the fiscal resources to be earmarked Della Rocca 1999). before the government’s mandate remained fully The wage contracts were to last for a two-year in the hands of the government. duration (biennio contrattuale) and the wage During the 1990s, the trade unions acted respon- increases were to be decided according to three sibly in the determination of the public sector criteria. First, wage increases at national level were pay. In a context of weak political parties, the to be calculated according to the rate of “expected unions played a major role in tripartite consulta- inflation” (Tasso di Inflazione Programmata, tion for the reform of collective bargaining and, TIP) for the subsequent two-year contract. This above all, the production of public sector wage rate would have to be negotiated in a concerted restraint. The unions exchanged wage restraint manner between the government, employers and with political influence on the determination of the unions during two sessions (one in the spring legislation related to the re-structuring of public and one in the autumn) throughout the preceding sector employment relations (Talamo 2009a, 4-5). year. Second, in the event of a discrepancy between Unions also shared in the objective of complying the expected and the actual inflation, the subse- with the external constraints imposed on public quent two-year contract would have to incorpo- finances by the accession phase to the EMU in 95 rate resources ex post on order to compensate 1999 (Hancké and Rhodes 2005). for lost purchasing power. This provision would be calculated upon the basis of the difference 3.2 The Early 2000s: The Return between the expected rate of inflation and the of (Political) Incomes Policies actual rate. To these criteria for centrally deter- mined wage increases, local administrations could The scenario for public sector wage-setting add resources to the central contracts according to changed substantially with the advent of the productivity increases. These additional resources centre-right coalition (2001-2006) led by Silvio would have to be paid in part by resources granted Berlusconi. Although, formally speaking, the from the central level and in part by the finances institutions for public sector collective bargaining of the local administrations. were not changed during the years of inflation (mostly 2002-2006), the function of pay determi- The creation of the independent agency, ARAN, nation was re-oriented towards a logic of political as the monopolistic representative of all public consent. This was made possible by the incon- administrations in national level negotiations sistencies of the structure created in 1993, which had the purpose of insulating wage bargaining made room for the return of the politicisation of from the incursions of party politics. The tech- public sector wage determination. nical body, in a principal-agent relationship with the government, was meant to prevent the distor- tions of the previous model. After theMani pulite 95 Confirmed in interviews with heads of public sector branches of CGIL, CISL, but also confirmed in interviews with scandal(s) in the 1990s, the political establishment decision makers in the top echelon of ARAN. Interviews car- came to be held inadequate to continue handling ried out in winter 2017/2018.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 56 Donato Di Carlo According to the legal structure, the government Fini, its leader, had been appointed deputy prime would decide the fiscal resources to be earmarked minister, Berlusconi saw, as the driving force of in the budget law which preceded the beginning of the coalition, a special alliance with Umberto the two-year contract. These resources, inserted in Bossi, Northern League’s leader, and Giulio Trem- the budget law, were decided ex ante by the sover- onti, the appointed finance minister acting as the eign employer and would be publicly known to guarantor between the two leaders. This special all actors. Since resources are already earmarked relationship came to be known as the “Northern before the beginning of negotiations between axis” (Diamanti and Lello 2005, 22-23). Proof ARAN and the unions - and unions know the exact of the close ties between Berlusconi and Bossi amount already granted - this becomes the “point was the recurring practice of dining together at of non-return” in the bargaining cycle. Instead of Berlusconi’s villa in Arcore every Monday evening serving as a ceiling for wage setting, the determi- to discuss the interests of the Northern middle nation of the quantum by the government makes classes, small- and medium-sized enterprises, and room for political contestation. The unions, in fact, freelance professionals. contest the amount of available resources, oppose As representatives of the South - and the centre the beginning of negotiations with ARAN, and - the coalition included the post-fascist Alleanza exploit the already-agreed upon number in order Nazionale (AN) and the post-Christian-Demo- to increase the resources required by lobbying the cratic Unione di Centro (UDC). These parties government. were rooted in the Southern areas of the country The capability of the unions to obtain greater which were characterised by high levels of unem- resources depends on the willingness of the ployment and in which public sector employ- government to reach a compromise with them. The ment (and wage inflation therein) has historically centre-right government was not united behind played a key role as a socio-economic stabiliser a policy of public sector wage inflation. In fact, in the local economies (Cassese 1977; Santoro the House of Freedoms (La Casa delle Libertà), 2014). The remaining forces of the coalition, AN as the coalition was named, was not united at all. and UDC, thus came to constitute the “Southern It consisted of four very heterogeneous parties bloc” - inspired by the values of the Social Right geographically and sociologically rooted in (destra sociale), representing the lower classes of different parts of the country (Diamanti 2003). the South and employees in the public admin- After the end of the first republic, the centre-right istration. As the leader of UDC put it to me, the had been formed in 1994 (and reformed in 2001) Southern bloc “represented all those people which by Berlusconi’s capacity to bring together, into a were not taken care of by the Arcore tablemates” unique political space, parties with strongholds in (interview with the then leader of the UCD. Rome, different parts of the country. 9 February 2018). AN and UDC strongly, and In the North, Berlusconi had secured a pact with vocally, supported public works and infrastruc- the Lega Nord (Northern League) centred on the ture building in the South, as well as resources middle classes’ quest for a neo-liberal agenda for public employment, with a special eye on the comprising tax cuts, fiscal federalism, a clamp- Lazio region where most of the central adminis- down on immigration, and reduced state inter- trations are based and where AN has historically vention. After the disastrous experience of the been strongly rooted. mid-1990s, the House of Freedoms campaigned The bargaining cycles which led to public sector together again and won the elections in 2001, wage inflation in Italy are the two-year contracts opening a new era for the centre-right. Although of 2002-2004 and 2004-2006. On both occa- Alleanza Nazionale (AN) was the second polit- sions, the direct mobilisation of political capital ical force in the coalition (12%), and Gianfranco by Gianfranco Fini, the deputy prime minister

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 57 Donato Di Carlo and leader of AN and the Southern bloc, was of 3.3 Public Sector Wage-setting fundamental importance for increasing fiscal in the Age of Sovereign Debt resources previously granted through budget laws. Crises: The Show must not Go on With regard to public sector wage policy, Fini has been repeatedly capable of imposing the inter- The pattern of public sector wage inflation in ests of the Southern bloc on the whole coalition, Italy started to be reversed in the 2006-2008 wage especially against the will of the finance minister bargaining cycle. This occurred under the pres- Tremonti. AN and UDC, in coalition with the sure exercised by the finance minister Tommaso trade union confederation CISL (the most repre- Padoa-Schioppa in the centre-left coalition in sentative union in the public sector), have always government. The finance minister strongly wished been open with respect to their interest in repre- to enforce a wage freeze during the negotiations senting the vast constituency of public employees for the renewal of the 2006-2008 public sector for whom they forcefully obtained the increase in contracts. This was meant to compensate for the the resources available for public sector contracts. wage excesses of the previous two bargaining Politically, allowing for public sector wage infla- cycles (2002-2004 and 2004-2006) which had tion served two inter-twined purposes. For Berlus- occurred under the centre-right coalition in coni’s Forza Italia, conceding inflationary wage government. Wage freezes were only avoided at increases in the public sector had the purpose of the very last minute thanks to the political media- dividing the unions (the CISL from the irksome tion of the Prime Minister during CGIL) during their open contestation regarding private negotiations with the heads of the public the government’s reformist agenda. Berlusconi sector branches of the trade unions confedera- acted behind the scenes to support the political tions (Interviews conducted with the then leaders mediation of the deputy prime minister with the of the public sector branch of CGIL (in Bologna, trade unions. For the Southern bloc of the coali- 20 November 2017) and of CISL (in Rome, 5 tion, Fini’s political mediation came to serve their February 2018)). However, much less money was electoral interests perfectly. In courting their core earmarked for public contracts and the result was constituency, the public employees, AN’s leader a harsh conflict between the finance minister and Fini repeatedly proved himself capable of over- the prime minister. coming the opposition of the other coalition Measures for wage restraint were introduced unilat- partner, the Northern League, which was opposed erally in 2008 (2009 budget law) written by Giulio to generous public sector increases. Notwith- Tremonti, before Italy came under pressure from standing this opposition, Fini managed to exploit the financial markets in summer 2011. Restraint public sector wage increases in favour of political was then strengthened by various governments consent by successfully mobilising political capital (political and technocratic) in 2010 and 2011 and to increase resources for public wages in subse- eventually extended in 2013 until, in spring 2015, quent budget laws. There has been, in this sense, a a verdict of the Constitutional Court has declared clear political willingness on the part of the Italian the multi-year wage freeze pursued unilaterally by sovereign employers to grant inflationary wages various governments since 2010 to be unconsti- for reasons other than the mere adjustment of the tutional. The judgment forced the government to personnel expenditure to macroeconomic devel- restart collective bargaining with the trade unions opments. for the years ahead without, however, imposing compensation for lost purchasing power, which would have severely endangered the weak state of public finances. Legislation passed in 2008 had imposed a wage ceiling on the wage increases,

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 58 Donato Di Carlo declaring unlawful every wage agreement that tragedies. For Italy to survive in a hard currency went beyond the established ceiling. A decree law regime with Germany at its core, a re-structuring of May 2010 unilaterally cancelled wage rounds of its public sector wage-setting regime should be for 2010-2012. This freeze was then extended via a priority so as to avoid de-stabilising wage/fiscal administrative decision for the years 2013 and expansion and subsequent austerity measures. 2014 (Lorenzo Bordogna and Pedersini 2013). Cyclical developments in wage-setting are also likely to have a strong impact on the morale of Conclusions public employees and the quality and efficiency of the public administration. Public sector wage-setting is an extremely inter- I wish to conclude with an important clarification. esting field in which to observe the discrepancies There is no pretension here to praise Germany and in policy-making between Germany and Italy. belittle Italy; nor should the reader see this paper The relevance of public sector wage-setting in the as support for the austerity measures pursued as political economy of European integration stems nemesis in the public sectors of the GIIPS. Rather, from two factors. Public sector wage policy coin- it is the opposite reasoning that motivates my cides necessarily with fiscal policy. Given the enor- inquiry: from the perspective of the EMU macro- mous size of the public sector in advanced econo- economic governance, both trajectories of marked mies, divergent public sector wage trajectories can restraint and inflation are equally deplorable. underpin discrepancies in the fiscal co-ordination of the EMU participants. Secondly, public sector Indeed, the core countries of the EMU have been wage-setting can produce negative spillovers for able to produce stable public sector wage trajecto- REER competitiveness, and underpin trade imbal- ries both before and after the crisis (Figure 1). This ances. has contributed to stabilise their REERs (Figure 2). Hence, a more balanced approach to public sector In Germany, the observable pattern of marked wage policies exists, and not just in abstract terms. wage restraint started in the mid-1990s out of Future research could take off from this observa- fiscal concerns by the federal finance minister. It tion and ask what the institutional determinants was then driven by fiscal concerns of the Länder of balanced wage growth in public sectors are. finance ministers, in the 2000s. As we observe the Looking at these countries’ public sector wage- German public sector wage-setting regime today, setting regimes should teach us something about after the reforms of the early 2000s, it emerges how to design a set of institutional changes aimed that Länder finance ministers are institutionally at avoiding the problem of structural divergence sheltered from political incursions and are locally when the good times return. accountable. Given the structure of its fiscal feder- alism and of the employers’ interest representa- tion, Germany is institutionally entrapped into a low-wage-increase equilibrium, which impedes a more inflationary stance in public sector wage- setting. In Italy, the observable pattern of public sector wage inflation of the early 2000s can, first and foremost, be attributed to the political willing- ness of sovereign employers to tolerate inflation for strategic political advantages. Patterns of wage inflation in good times, followed by austerity and cuts in hard ones, resemble hubris and nemesis

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 59 Donato Di Carlo References “Economic Crisis and the Politics of Public Service Employment Relations in Italy and Baccaro, Lucio, and Chiara Benassi. 2016. France.” European Journal of Industrial Rela- “Throwing out the Ballast: Growth Models and tions 19 (4): 325-40. the liberalization of German Industrial Rela- Carlin, Wendy, and David Soskice. 2014. Macro- tions.” Socio-Economic Review: mww036. economics: Institutions, instability, and the Baccaro, Lucio, and Harry Jonas Pontusson. 2016. Financial System. New York: Oxford University “Rethinking Comparative Political Economy: Press. The Growth Model Perspective.” Politics & Cassese, Sabino. 1977. Questione amministrativa Society. e questione meridionale: dimensioni e reclu- Baccaro, Lucio, and Tobias Tober. 2017. “The Role tamento della burocrazia dall’unità ad oggi. of Cost and Price Competitiveness in the Euro- Giuffrè. zone.” Unpublished Manuscript, University of Cella, Gian Primo. 1991. “Nuovi attori nelle Geneva. relazioni industriali.” Milano, ed. Franco Angeli. Bach, Stephen, and Lorenzo Bordogna. 2013. Collignon, Stefan. 2009. “Wage Developments Reframing Public Service Employment Rela- in Euroland or: the Failure of the Macroeco- tions: The Impact of Economic Crisis and the nomic Dialogue.” Sant’Anna School of advanced New EU Economic Governance. Sage London: Studies, Pisa/Centro Europa Ricerche, Roma. Publications Sage UK: London. De Grauwe, Paul. 2016. Economics of Monetary ———. 2016. Public Service Management and Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Employment Relations in Europe: Emerging from the Crisis. Abigdon: Routledge. DGB. 2016. “Besoldungsreport 2016. Die Entwick- lung der Einkommen der Beamtinnen und Bibow, Jörg. 2012. The Euro Debt Crisis and Germa- Beamten von Bund, Ländern und Kommunen.”, ny’s Euro Trilemma. Levy Economics Institute published online May 2016. https://www. of Bard College: Levy Economics Institute, google.de/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&sour- Bordogna, L, C Dell’Aringa, and G Della Rocca. ce=web&cd=1&ved=0ahUKEwiUrPiS- 1999. “The Reform of Public Service Employ- seDTAhXFKVAKHaQZDCAQFgg- ment in Italy: A Case of Coordinated Decen- pMAA&url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.dgb. tralization”, in: Bach. S., Bordogna, L., Della de%2F%2B%2Bco%2B%2Bcb6f18d4- Rocca, G., and Winchester, D.(eds), Public 15d5-11e6-a659-52540023ef1a%2FDGB- Service Employment Relations in Europe: Trans- Besoldungsreport-2016. formation, Modernization or Inertia. pdf&usg=AFQjCNF80mHJF_iqAcB2Z_ Bordogna, Lorenzo. 1994. “Pluralismo senza IA2etIvEU7hw&cad=rja. mercato.” Franco Angeli, Milano. Di Carlo, Donato. 2018. Does Pattern Bargaining ———. 2012. “Employment Relations and Union Explain Wage Restraint in the German Public Action in the Italian Public Services-Is There a Sector. 18/3. Cologne: Max Planck Institute for Case of Distortion of Democracy.” Comp. Lab. the Study of Societies, L. & Pol’y J. 34: 507. Diamanti, Ilvo. 2003. Bianco, rosso, verde... e Bordogna, Lorenzo, and Roberto Pedersini. 2013. azzurro. Mappe e colori dell’Italia politica. Il mulino. Diamanti, Ilvo, and Elisa Lello. 2005. “The Casa delle Liberta: a house of cards?” Modern Italy

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 60 Donato Di Carlo 10 (1): 9-35. 91115071210.1080/13501760902872742. Dribbusch, Heiner. 2006. “Strike against increase in Johnston, Alison, Bob Hancke, and Suman working time ends in compromise.” published Pant. 2014. “Comparative Institutional online 26 June 2006. https://www.eurofound. Advantage in the European Sovereign europa.eu/ga/observatories/eurwork/articles/ Debt Crisis.” Comparative Political Studies strike-against-increase-in-working-time-ends- 47 (13), published online Nov: 1771-800. in-compromise. doi:10.1177/0010414013516917. Giugni, Gino. 1992. “La Privatizzazione del Keller, Berndt. 2011. “After the End of Stability: rapporto di lavoro nel settore pubblico.” Lavoro Recent Trends in the Public Sector of Germany.” informazione 11: 5-8. The International Journal of Human Resource Gorrieri, Ermanno. 1973. La giungla retributiva. Il Management 22 (11): 2331-48. mulino. ———. 2014. “The Continuation of Early Austerity Hancké, Bob. 2013. Unions, Central Banks, and Measures: The Special Case of Germany.” EMU: Labour Market Institutions and Mone- Transfer: European Review of Labour and tary Integration in Europe. OUP Oxford. Research 20 (3): 387-402. Hancké, Bob, and Martin Rhodes. 2005. “EMU ———. 2016. “8 Germany: Retrenchment Before and Labor Market Institutions in Europe The the Great Recession and its Lasting Conse- Rise and Fall of National Social Pacts.” Work quences.” Public Service Management and and Occupations 32 (2): 196-228. Employment Relations in Europe: Emerging from the Crisis 26: 191. Hassel, Anke. 2014. “The Paradox of Liberal- ization—Understanding Dualism and the Keller, Berndt, and Hartmut Seifert. 2015. “Atyp- Recovery of the German Political Economy.” ical Forms of Employment in the Public Sector– British Journal of Industrial Relations 52 (1): Are there any?”. 57-81. Ricciardi, Mario. 2013. “La parabola: ascesa e Holm-Hadulla, Fédéric, Kishore Kamath, Ana declino della contrattazione collettiva in Italia.” Lamo, Javier J Pérez, and Ludger Schuknecht. Rusciano, M. 1978. Il pubblico impiego in Italia. Il 2010. “Public wages in the euro area: towards Mulino, Bologna. securing stability and competitiveness.” ECB Santoro, Patrizia. 2014. Deboli ma forti. Il pubblico Occasional Paper (112). impiego in Italia tra fedeltà politica e ammortiz- Höpner, Martin, and Mark Lutter. 2014. “One zatore sociale: Il pubblico impiego in Italia tra Currency and Many Modes of Wage Forma- fedeltà politica e ammortizzatore sociale. Fran- tion. Why the Eurozone is too Heterogeneous for the Euro.” Hyman, Richard. 2008. The State in Industrial Relations. Sage Publications. Johnston, Alison. 2016. From Convergence to Crisis: Labor Markets and the Instability of the Euro. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press. Johnston, Alison, and Bob Hancke. 2009. “Wage Inflation and Labour Unions in EMU.” Journal of European Public Policy 16 (4): 601-22. doi:Pii

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 61 Donato Di Carlo coAngeli. Scharpf, Fritz W. 1991. Crisis and Choice in Euro- pean Social Democracy. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press. ———. 2005. “No Exit from the Joint Decision Trap?: Can German Federalism Reform itself?”. Talamo, Valerio. 2009a. “Gli interventi sul costo del lavoro nelle dinamiche della contrattazione collettiva nazionale ed integrativa.” Lav. Pubb. Amm: 3-4. ———. 2009b. “Pubblico e privato nella legge delega per la riforma del lavoro pubblico.” Gior- nale di diritto amministrativo 5: 3-14. Traxler, Franz. 1999. “The State in Industrial Rela- tions: A Cross-national Analysis of Develop- ments and Socioeconomic Effects.” European Journal of Political Research 36 (1): 55-85.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PUBLIC SECTOR WAGE-SETTING IN GERMANY AND ITALY 62 Donato Di Carlo GEO-POLITICS OF As a consequence, the German economy boomed EXPORTING TOO MUCH: after the crisis, while the citizens of Greece, Italy and Spain suffered from austerity policies (Blyth CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES 2012). This debate fed a morality play that OF GERMANY AND JAPAN portrayed the Greeks, Italians and Spaniards as the morally inferior lazy brethren of Northern Margarita Estévez-Abe Europeans. It appeared as if European solidarity Maxwell School, Syracuse University was giving way to an ugly family feud over who Collegio Carlo Alberto owes what to whom. The aim of this paper is to extend the discussion “Ten times Trump asked [Ms Merkel] if he could beyond Europe and the EMU. The consequences negotiate a trade deal with Germany. Every of the EMU go well beyond the Euro-zone borders. time she replied, ‘You can’t do a trade deal with Not only did the Euro improve the terms of intra- Germany, only the EU.”96 EMU trade for the Euro-zone North; it also I. Introduction: Going improved their competitiveness outside Europe. The first meeting between Chancellor Angela Beyond the North-South Merkel and the President Donald Trump focused Problems inside the Euro attention on the importance of Germany’s rela- Zone tively advantageous trade terms. Trump bitterly complained about Germany—the largest economy The financial crisis—the Eurozone crisis in partic- in Europe. Trump took aim at the German trade ular—initiated an important debate over the surplus, and demanded a bi-lateral agreement to distributive implications of the EMU. Aside from rectify the “unfair” trade imbalance between the questioning the wisdom of the austerity policies two countries. While European elites shrugged imposed by the Troika—the European Commis- off Trump’s comments as the ramblings of an sion (EC), the European Central Bank (ECB), and uncouth novice who did not understand how the the International Monetary Fund (IMF)—many EU worked, the reality was actually the other way people began to focus on what they perceived around. It was European—and German—elites to be the structural problems of the EMU. The who had been too slow to realize that they could EMU, it was argued, structurally advantaged the no longer free-ride on the Americans. Trump’s Northern European economies at the expense of statements about trade imbalances and NATO the weaker Southern European economies. The funding actually reflect an inconvenient truth for single currency rewarded the Northern Euro- Europeans: the era is over. Europe pean member states with a weak currency (much and the US can no longer count on the presence of weaker counterfactually than in the absence of the a common enemy to unite them. EMU), while it punished the Southern European member states by robbing them of the policy tool Germany is an exporting powerhouse. It is the they long relied upon to boost their competitive- third largest exporter in the world after China ness—i.e. currency devaluation (Hall 2012, Streeck and the US. Germany exports almost as much as 2015). The Euro thereby improved the terms of the US does. The volume of German exports is trade for the Northern European member states. close to twice as large as that of Japan, the fourth largest exporter. Germany, however, stands out 96 This is the report of the meeting between the Chancellor for its trade surplus. For an economy of its size, Angela Merkel and the President Donald Trump in March it imports relatively little. In fact, as Baccaro 2017. https://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/americas/ us-politics/angela-merkel-donald-trump-explain-eu-trade- and Pontusson (2016) note, Germany relies on 11-times-germany-chancellor-us-president-a7699591.html foreign—rather than domestic—demand to stim-

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 63 Margarita Estévez-Abe ulate its economy. When a large wealthy economy Aoki’s work on the Japan firm provide pioneering relies on foreign demand to propel its economy, examples of this scholarship.98 Indeed, Germany other countries must pay the price in trade defi- and Japan became the real life models that helped cits. Even within the EU, criticisms of this beggar the conceptualization of Coordinated Market thy neighbor policy emerged (Varoufakis 2017). Economies (CMEs) in the Varieties of Capitalism Outside the EU, the same criticisms have led to literature.99 They both shared similar character- serious geo-political tensions between the US and istics: neither was a neo-corporatist system, but Europe. both had developed organizational capacities to This short paper argues that the dramatic rise in coordinate economic activities. Firms cooperated German exports would not have happened without with one another, and employers did the same the Euro, and that the EU has served as a cover to with their employees in their joint effort to inno- shield Germany from any bi-lateral trade disputes vate and navigate the ups and downs of business that might have emerged. Consequently, the cycles. In both countries, banks and closely-knit German growth model has exacerbated geo-polit- corporate ownership patterns stood out. ical problems between two sides of the Atlantic. Their economic success stories of the 1970s This paper uses Japan as a counter-factual case to and 1980s notwithstanding, the 1990s brought highlight the importance of the special advantages daunting challenges to both countries. The that Germany enjoys thanks both to the EMU and German economy suffered after the re-unifica- the EU. tion and unemployment rates soared. This was the period when Germany was nicknamed “the II. Similar Pasts and sick man of Europe.” Japan fared no better. After Similar Challenges, but the burst of the so-called Bubble Economy in the Charting New Paths early 1990s, Japan plunged into a long period of economic stagnation. Furthermore, the two Germany and Japan provide us with a pair of countries also began to experience demographic similar cases—two economies that are alike in problems. Their models of welfare capitalism many ways except one had the protection of the assumed households with male-breadwinners. EU and EMU while the other did not. This paper Their employment practices and welfare states takes advantage of the initial similarities and had developed with traditional gendered divisions divergences following the creation of the EMU. of labor in mind, whereby men were expected to This particular combination of similarities and become breadwinners and women were expected divergences makes Germany and Japan an ideal to become unpaid carers for their families (Daly pair of comparative cases to explore the effects of 2011; Lister 1994; Leitner 2003; Sainsbury 1994). the EMU. First, let me talk about their initial simi- Comparatively strong employment regulation in larities before moving on to the discussion of their Germany and Japan protected male breadwinners’ more recent divergent paths. jobs, and their welfare states mostly addressed the needs of male breadwinners. The other side of the During the postwar period, Germany and Japan coin was sex-discriminating employment prac- emerged as competitive economies that possessed distinctive characteristics. Their models of capi- 98 Aoki (1983), Cole (1971, 1989), Dore (1973), Patrick (1976), talism inspired a whole generation of compara- Streeck (1984,1992) represent some of the most influential tive studies of economic/ production regimes in contributions that initiated firm-level comparative analyses of the 1980s and 1990s.97 Wolfgang Streeck’s work advanced industrial countries. on the German production regime and Masahiko 99 For instance, when Estévez-Abe et al (2001) distinguish CMEs that rely on firm-specific skills and industry-specific skills, this 97 The Varieties of Capitalism literature in many ways synthe- distinction heavily relies on the Japanese (firm-specific) and sized and built upon their contributions. See footnote 3. German (industry-specific) cases.

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 64 Margarita Estévez-Abe tices and underdeveloped services for working contrast, turned to foreign demand and overtook mothers—i.e. scarcity of work-family reconcili- Japan as an exporting superpower. Furthermore, ation policies (Estévez-Abe 2005, 2006). As a as demand for skilled labor increased, Germany result, maternal employment rates in these coun- increasingly recruited women and foreigners. In tries remained lower than the OECD average. Japan, such changes are only occurring now— Given the fact that among the OECD countries with a delay of ten years (Estévez-Abe and Naldini fertility rates are higher where female labor force 2016). participation rates are high, it is not surprising that fertility rates plunged in Germany and Japan. III. Why Did Their Economic It is no coincidence that they are the most “aged” Fates Diverge? OECD countries. The economic fortunes of the two countries began Why did the trajectories of Germany and Japan to diverge in the 2000s and the pace of divergence come to diverge so much? Proponents of the Vari- accelerated after the financial crisis in 2008. While eties of Capitalism might attribute the German Germany recovered from its economic stagnation economic success to its CME. By the same token, they might argue that Japan’s relative decline is in the 1990s, Japan did not. In Germany, as the 100 economy recovered and unemployment rate went due to Japan not really being a CME any longer. down in the latter half of the 2000s, labor shortages This explanation is too shallow. Baccaro and became the new problem. Demographic aging Pontusson (2016) are right to claim that a dichoto- means the shrinking of younger cohorts, and it mous taxonomy that omits so many countries does directly affects the number of young male workers not provide the best model tool to understand the who are available in the labor market. There are challenges facing super- aging mature economies. two potential solutions: (i) to increase the activity Baccaro and Pontusson (2016) pay greater atten- rate of the native population; and or (ii) to increase tion to how mature countries manage “demand- side” factors in their effort to promote economic immigration. Germany did both in the latter half 101 of the 2000s. The Hartz Reforms and the pension growth. They argue that Germany explicitly reform removed work disincentives and pushed chose to seek out foreign demand while neglecting up male employment rates. Germany also began to expand its own domestic demand. They point to promote female employment and immigration out how the German employers and unions made of skilled foreigners (Blome 2016: Constant and a pact to reduce wages when they joined the EMU Bienvenue 2011; Hien 2013; Morgan 2013; Wiliarty in order to preserve their competitiveness in an 2010). Japan, in contrast, just stagnated. In spite effort to capture foreign markets. of its shrinking workforce, Japan did not feel the I agree with the importance of examining the labor market crunch as early as Germany because demand management particularly in the context of its prolonged recession. This long recession 100 Iversen and Soskice dropped Japan from their list of motivated many women to enter the labor market, CME as they shifted their analysis to the causal link between which in turn further depressed wages. What the CMEs and proportional representation systems (see Cusack, Japanese initially referred to as “the lost decade” Iversen and Soskice 2007). Others have continue to look at Japan as a form of highly organized capitalism (Estévez-Abe of the 1990s, eventually became the “lost decades.” 2008; Streeck and Yamamura eds. 2005). Japan could not export its way out of the economic 101 Baccaro and Pontusson (2016) criticize the VOC as be- recession as Germany had done, as its currency ing too “supply-side” in their justification of their demand-side kept on strengthening against the dollar. Japan approach. However, Michael Piore (2016) is correct to point out, in his commentary on Baccaro and Pontusson (2016), thus tried to boost domestic demand. This effort that the “macro” versus “micro” distinction might be more yielded a national public deficit of 237% of the appropriate to describe how Baccaro and Pontusson situate GDP compared to 79% in Germany. Germany, in themselves vis-à-vis the VOC rather than the contrast between “demand-side” and “supply-side.”

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 65 Margarita Estévez-Abe of demographic aging. That said, Baccaro and favorable terms of trade. In 2006, the combined Pontusson (2016) fail to pay attention to the economy of the EU28 was the largest in the world specific advantages that Germany enjoyed under accounting for 30% of global GDP (Eurostat the umbrella of the EMU and the EU. As Baccaro 2018). Ten years later, it fell to 25% and became and Pontusoon (2016) claim, Germany initially the second largest after the US, but these numbers moderated its wage growth in its attempt to seize underscore the importance of the advantage that greater market shares in the new single market Germany gains from easy access to this market. initially. But it would not have been able to capture Furthermore, the third and fourth conditions so much of foreign demand had it not been for the removed potential bottlenecks for Germany’s EMU/EU framework. export-oriented strategy for growth. The EU The EMU—in combination with other advan- shielded Germany from any trade sanctions. tages the EU provides—helped create extremely Indeed, if any sanctions were to be threatened, favorable conditions for German exporters. First, they would have to target the whole of the EU. No Germany benefited handsomely from the new less importantly, Germany enjoyed access to a vast single currency, which, because it reflects the labor pool within the Schengen area. If Germany macro-economic performance of all Euro-zone had not enjoyed the aforementioned four condi- countries, including some quite dysfunctional tions, it would have struggled to manage its aging ones, will always appreciate less than the Deutsch- society and would have suffered similar economic Mark would have done. Second, the EU harmo- problems to those facing Japan. nized all key product regulations across the EU member states removing any trade barriers. Third, IV. Exposure to Currency the EU shielded Germany from any possibility of Risk, Euro and the Distorted having to engage in unfavorable bi-lateral negotia- Geo-Politics of Trade: tions, whether with any specific EU member-state Germany Gains and Japan or powerful non-EU trading partner such as the Loses US. Four, the Schengen Agreement expanded the potential labor pool for Germany. Let us now contrast Japan to Germany. Japan The first two conditions de facto turned the Euro- faced a completely different, significantly more zone into a big domestic market for German volatile exchange rate environment. The first exporters as they no longer faced any currency currency shock came in 1985, when the Finance risk in trading within the Euro-zone. Because Ministers from the G5 countries met in the Plaza the monetary union also took away less competi- Hotel in New York City and agreed to inter- tive countries’ capacity to devalue, more competi- vene in the currency market to raise the value tive countries were better-positioned to reap the of the Japanese yen. The so-called Plaza Accord benefit of the bigger single market. Germany was was an action orchestrated by the US to correct such a country—and a huge one by European Japan’s allegedly unfair currency advantage, which standards. Germany enjoyed a scale of merit due allowed it to enjoy a large trade surplus with the to the size of its own domestic market, and now US. Figure 1 shows the dramatic currency fluc- could enjoy an even bigger scale of merit thanks to tuations against the dollar that Japan has expe- the expanded de facto domestic market. Further- rienced over the past forty years. Immediately more, Germany also had easy access to the markets after the Plaza Accord, the value of the US dollar in those EU member states outside the Euro-zone nearly halved against the yen within a matter of such as the UK. Given that the national currencies months. This was the first of three drastic waves of non-Euro-zone member states tended to appre- of currency appreciation that Japan was to expe- ciate more, Germany again stood to gain from rience: the second one in 1994/5, and then again

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 66 Margarita Estévez-Abe in the late 2000s. Japan’s off -shoring of produc- Both Germany and Japan faced diff erent but simi- tive facilities abroad had started in earnest in the larly dramatic economic shocks in the 1990s and mid-1990s increasing the relative share of foreign in the 2000s. However, the structural advantage production of Japanese manufacturers. Given the provided by the Euro made it much easier for fact that the US is its major export market, drastic Germany to deal with its problems aft er 2000. As currency appreciation meant losing price compet- mentioned earlier, Germany faced the shock of the itiveness in the US as well as suff ering the earning German re-unifi cation, which sent its economy losses as the earnings were calculated in the Japa- into a prolonged economic downturn. Germa- nese yen. Th e harsh currency environment made ny’s high levels of unemployment rates continued it indispensable for Japan to boost its domestic throughout the 1990s. Th e uptake in the exports market. While private companies struggled to occurred before the labor market and welfare adjust their business models to the new currency reforms in the early and mid-2000s—the Hartz environment, the public sector tried to compen- Reforms and the Pension Reform—and grew sate for the shortfall in demand due to recession larger aft erwards. Germany’s current account and demographic aging. In the aft ermath of the surplus grew more or less steadily aft er joining fi nancial crisis, another wave of currency appre- the EMU (Figure 2). In addition to the increase ciation negatively aff ected Japanese exports in an in Germany’s within the Euro-zone trade volume, already weak global market. In contrast, Germany Germany also gained a lot from non-Eurozone enjoyed its biggest ever trade surplus—roughly member states such as the UK. Again, Figure 3 9% of its GDP in the post-crisis years. shows how British trade defi cit with Germany Figure 1. Shift s in the Value of the US Dollar in grew aft er Germany joined the EMU. When the Japanese Yen (1975-2018) Euro-crisis and the austerity policies in a number of largest member states suppressed the demand

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 67 Margarita Estévez-Abe for German products, Germany turned to other export markets including China and the US. Figure 4 shows how German (as well as the overall Euro- pean) trade surplus with the US rapidly increased as a combination of weak domestic demand in EU member states and reliance on foreign demand as the US economy recovered from the crisis. Figure 2. Germany’s Current Account Surplus

Source: Romano 2018, p.8. Figure 3. British Trade Defi cit in Goods and Services with Germany (in British pounds)

Source: https://www.ons.gov.uk/economy/nationalaccounts/ balanceofpayments/timeseries/lgmi/pb

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 68 Margarita Estévez-Abe Figure 4. US Trade Defi cit in Goods with perform relative to Germany in the 2000s.102 A Germany and Other Selected Trade Partners (in further blow to Japan was the third dramatic wave US dollars) of currency appreciation, which came right aft er the 2008 Financial Crisis. Japanese export perfor- mance worsened and wage levels in manufacturing began to drop as shown in Figure 5.

Source: Th e US Census Bureau, Foreign Trade Data.https:// Figure 5. Hourly Wages in Manufacturing www.census.gov/foreign-trade/balance/index.html (2010=100) Japan, in turn, faced two major fi nancial shocks in the 1990s—the fi rst was the burst of its own spec- ulative bubble in the early 1990s and the second was the Asian Financial Crisis in 1997, which hit hard Japanese major banks since they were big lenders in many of the coun- tries aff ected by the crisis. Unlike Germany, whose recovery was aided by the Euro, Japan was penal- Source: OECD Statistics ized by extremely unfavorable exchange rates. In the years immediately following the burst As Figure 6 indicates, the drop in labor share of the so-called bubble economy, Japan experi- was much bigger in Japan than in Germany. As enced another drastic currency appreciation in in Germany, labor market deregulation led to a 1994/1995. Th e Japanese growth rate of multifactor dualization of the labor market. However, unlike productivity was higher than that of Germany 102 OECD (2018), Multifactor productivity (indicator). doi: throughout the 1990s, but Japan began to under- 10.1787/a40c5025-en (Accessed on 22 June 2018)

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 69 Margarita Estévez-Abe Germany, Japan had no access to an expanded V. Geo-Political Euro-denominated quasi-domestic market. In a Implications of Too Much shrinking market with strong currency, corpo- Surplus rations maintained their profi ts by paying their workers less. In the absence of the advantages of Germany’s trade surplus aff ected the geopolit- Euro, the strong yen led Japanese manufacturers ical relationship between the EU and the United to off -shore most of their production, and the States. Geopolitically, both Germany and Japan number of workers employed in manufacturing are similar. Partly for historical reasons, they both decreased more in Japan than in Germany and underspend on their own defense budgets and Italy. Th e new demand composition in Japan’s rely on others—the US or the NATO—to provide aging society added low wage service sector jobs security. Germany benefi tted greatly from the to the economy instead. Schwellnus et al. 2017 EU, which not only foreclosed any possibility of calculate that most of the decline in labor’s share bi-lateral trade negotiations between a member of the economy in Japan can be attributed to the state and a non-EU country, but made it diffi cult reduction of labor share in service jobs, while in to link trade and security issues. Th is meant that Germany the decline originated in its manufac- Germany could continue to amass trade surplus turing sector. If the Euro did not exist, Germany against the US, but the US could not raise issues with its strong national currency would have off - about Germany’s meager defense budget. Th e situ- shored its production to a much greater degree. ation in Japan was very diff erent. Revenue from investments in Eurozone countries Th roughout the 1980s and the 1990s, Japan’s would have suff ered from currency volatility— large trade surpluses with the led to earnings going down every time the Deutsche multiple rounds of bi-lateral negotiations between Mark appreciates. the two countries (Schoppa 1997). Th e Plaza Figure 6. Changes in Gross and Net Labor Shares Accord must be seen as the US’s reaction against in OECD Countries, 1995-2014 Japan’s trade surplus. In the US-Japan bi-lateral negotiations, security and trade issues were linked, and the negotia- tions prompted Japan to agree to various concessions. Japan “self-imposed” an unof- fi cial export quota to the US; built factories in the US; paid for the cost of the US military bases in Japan; coor- dinated its monetary policy with the US; and Source: Schwellnus et al. 2017. procured overpriced military weapons from the US. Furthermore, the US demanded that Japan adopt expansionary monetary and fi scal policies to boost its own domestic demand (and to buy more US goods); and Japan obliged by means of a low interest rate policy and greater public invest- ments. Th e monetary expansion right aft er the

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 70 Margarita Estévez-Abe Plaza Accord led to the rise of a speculative bubble Conclusion in Japan, which fed the Bubble Economy of the 1980s. Unconstrained by anything like the Maas- When domestic demand starts to contract due tricht Treaty and helped by its abundant domestic to demographic aging, it is very diffi cult for the savings, the Japanese government continued its government to fi ns a quick solution. It can either fi scal expansion. export more or boost domestic demand. Th is short paper has argued that Germany enjoyed Figure 7. Growth Accounting special advantages. In the absence of the EU and the monetary union, Germany would have suff ered the long stagnation of Japan. Baccaro and Pontusson (2016) argue that it was the polit- ical coalition in Germany that led Germany to rely heavily on foreign demand in lieu of any attempt to boost domestic demand. Th ey contrast Germany to the UK and Sweden as examples of countries that have adopted more lax consumer loans and mortgage lending to boost domestic Source: Sánchez and Yurdagul (2017) demand for diff erent reasons. Although it is not Th e US Government has been complaining about mentioned in their piece, it is important to note Germany’s excessive reliance on foreign demand that these were both countries outside the mone- (i.e. exports). However, as Merkel explained to tary union and hence could not enjoy the bene- Trump, no bi-lateral negotiations are possible, fi ts Germany enjoyed. Th e Netherlands, which because foreign trade is an EU competence. is a smaller country, which thrived within the Th e inability of the largest European economy monetary union, exports a lot and does not resort to work out bi-lateral solutions has now led the to fi nancial policies to boost domestic demand. Trump Administration to raise the specter of Given its small population size, they are the third tariff s against the whole of the EU. One could largest exporter of agricultural goods in the world. argue that the whole of the EU is now paying the Unlike the Netherlands, Denmark, another price for German trade surpluses. Furthermore, member state that stayed out of the currency the inability of the US to link security and trade union, also relies on domestic demand stimula- issues in dealing with the EU trade partners seems tion by extremely accommodating mortgage poli- to be eroding the very foundation of the NATO. cies. Japan, too, shift ed to expansive monetary Again, the history of the Japan-US trade confl icts policy in the 1980s in its attempt to stimulate and the negotiations can tell us what counter- domestic demand. Once the speculative bubble factually would have happened to Germany in burst in Japan, the prolonged banking crisis in the absence of the EU and the Euro. Like Japan, the 1990s that continued into the early 2000s, Germany probably would have had to build more prevented Japanese banks from doing the same. factories in the US as a way of cultivating polit- In the absence of the past banking crisis, Japan ical capital in the US (Japanese big manufactures most likely would have pursued a similar policy to cleverly invested in “swing states” for Presidential stimulate domestic demand. elections) and to buy more “made in US” military weaponry.

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 71 Margarita Estévez-Abe References 11072018-AP-EN.pdf/4446ce4e-d45c-4b31- 9108-23ebb026ea20 Aoki, Masahiko. 1983. The Economic Analysis of Estévez-Abe, Margarita. 2008. Welfare Capitalism the Japanese Firm. Elsevier Science Ltd. in Postwar Japan. Cambridge University P ress. Baccaro, Lucio and Jonas Pontusson. 2016. Estévez-Abe, Margarita. 2006. “Gendering the “Rethinking Comparative Political Economy: Varieties of Capitalism: A Study of Occupa- The Growth Model Perspective.” Politics and tional Segregation by Sex in Advanced Society. 44(2): 175-207. Industrial Societies,” World Politics (October, Blome, Agnes. 2016. The Politics of Work-family 2006): 142-175. Policy Reforms in Germany and Italy. NY: Rout- Estévez-Abe, Margarita. 2005. “Gender Bias in ledge. Skills and Social Policies: The Varieties of Blyth, Mark. 2012. Austerity: A History of a Capitalism Perspective on Sex Segregation,” Dangerous Idea. New York: Oxford University Social Politics vol.12, no. 2 (Summer Press. 2005): 180-215. Cole, Robert. 1971. Japanese Blue-Collar: The Estévez-Abe, Margarita. “Reinterpretation of Changing Tradition. Berkeley, CA: University the Welfare State. “ with Torben Iversen and of California Press. David Soskice in Peter Hall and David Cole, Robert. 1989. Strategies for Learning: Small Soskice eds. Varieties of Capitalism: The Insti- Group Activities in American, Japanese, a n d tutional Foundations of Comparative Swedish Industry. Berkeley, CA: University of Advantage. London: Oxford University Press. California Press. Hall, Peter A. (2012) The Economics and Politics Constant, Amelie F., and Tien, Bienvenue N. of the Eurozone Crisis.” German Politics 21(4): 2011. “Germany’s Immigration Policy and 355-371. Labor Shortages” IZA Research Report Hien, Josef (2013) “Unsecular Politics in a Secular No.41. October 2011. Environment: The Case of Germany’s Chris- Cusack, Thomas R. Torben Iversen and David tian Democratic Union Family Policy.” German Soskice. 2007. “Economic Interests and the Politics. 22(4): 441-460 Origins of Electoral Systems.” The American Leitner, Sigrid. 2003. “Varieties of Familialism: The Political Science Review. 101(3):373-391. Caring Function of the Family in Comparative Daly, Mary. 2011. “What Adult Worker Model? A Perspective.” European Societies 5(4): 353-375 Critical Look at Recent Social Policy Reform Lister, R. 1994. “She has other duties’ Women, Citi- in Europe from a Gender and Family Perspec- zenship and Social Security. In S Baldwin and t i v e .” Social Politics 18(1): 1-23. J. Falkingham eds. Social Security and Social Dore, Ronald. 1973. British Factory, Japanese Change: New Challenges to the Beveridge’s Factory. Berkeley, CA: University of Cali- Model. fornia Press. Morgan, Kimberly J. 2013. “Path Shifting of the Eurostat. 2018. “A new Eurostat publica- Welfare State: Electoral Competition and the tion A statistical portrait of the European Expansion of Work-Family Policies in Western Union compared with G20 countries The Europe.” World Politics 65(1): 73-115 EU in the world – 2018 edition” Eurostat News- Patrick, Hugh. ed. 1976. Industrialization and Its release 116/2018. https://ec.europa.eu/ Consequences for Japan. Berkeley, CA: Univer- eurostat/documents/2995521/9077665/1- sity of California Press, 1976.

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 72 Margarita Estévez-Abe Piore, Michael. 2016. “Varieties of Capitalism Theory: Its Considerable Limits.” Politics and Society. 44(2): 237-241. Sainsbury, Diana. Ed. 1994. Gendering the Welfare States. London. Sage Publications. Schoppa, Leonard. 1997. Bargaining with Japan. NYC: Columbia University Press. Streeck, Wolfgang. 2015. “Why the Euro divides Europe.” New Left Review 95 (September/October2015): 5–26. Streeck, Wolfgang, and Kozo Yamamura eds. 2005. The Origins of Non-Liberal Capitalism: Germany and Japan in Comparison. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Streeck, Wolfgang. 1992. Social Institutions and Economic Performance: Studies of Industrial Relations and Advanced Capitalist Economies. Sage Publications. Streeck, Wolfgang. 1984. Industrial Relations in Germany: A Case Study of the Car Industry. Heinemann Educational Books. Varouvakis, Yannis. 2017. Adults in the Room: My Struggle with Europe’s Deep Establishment. London: Bodley Head. Wiliarty, Sarah E. 2010. The CDU and the Politics of Gender in Germany: Bringing Women to the Party. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

GEO-POLITICS OF EXPORTING TOO MUCH: CONTRASTING TRAJECTORIES OF GERMANY AND JAPAN 73 Margarita Estévez-Abe IDEATIONAL DIFFERENCES European integration reviewed. For the past three BETWEEN ITALIAN AND years, Europe has been mesmerised by the Euro crisis, namely the struggle to resolve the debt GERMAN GOVERNMENTS problems facing Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal DURING THE CRISIS and Spain (the GIIPS. In its early stage, econo- mists were already warning that the Eurozone did Federico Bruno not constitute an “optimal currency area” and that University of Milan it would have been subject to asymmetric supply and demand shocks. However, other kinds of 1. Introduction evaluations prevailed. The Euro arose as a Franco- German political project: Germany accepted to In this contribution, based upon secondary liter- give up its monetary sovereignty in exchange for ature, I will review the ideational approaches to a French agreement on its re-unification, whereas the Euro crisis of the Italian and of the German France aimed to tame the power of the Bundes- governments. In Section 2, I will show how bank by establishing a European central bank (Hall ideational factors contributed to the making of 2012, 356). The other Member States had interests the Eurozone. In Sections 3 and 4, I account for in joining the monetary union, too. The Northern the role of ideas during the Euro crisis respectively countries could benefit from the fixed internal in Italy and Germany. In Section 5, I conclude by exchange rate – which prevented their Southern comparing the role, the content and the function competitors from competitive devaluation – and of these ideas in the two countries. from a low external exchange rate. The Southern countries, in turn, would have enjoyed lowered 2. Ideational factors in the interest rates to finance their public spending, making of the Euro and the possibility of imposing some wage disci- pline; however, in exchange for this, they had to The roots of the Euro crisis are to be sought in the give up the instrument of competitive devalua- asymmetrical design that has characterised the tions, which represented one of the pillars of their Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) since its growth model (Ibid., pp. 358-60). inception (Hall 2012, 2014)where do the roots of Political and immediate economic interests, the crisis lie, how can the response to the crisis however, under-determine the reasons why the be explained, and what are its implications for single currency was made possible. In order to European integration? It explores how prevailing grasp them fully, we should also account for economic doctrines con-ditioned the institutional ideational factors. At the European level, the rise shape of the single currency and locates the roots of of the monetarist paradigm in the 1980s, caused the crisis in an institutional asymmetry grounded by the unsuitability of Keynesian policies to deal in national varieties of capit-alism, which saw with stagflation, played a key role (McNamara political economies organised to operate export- 1999). Monetarist views shaped the institutions of led growth models joined to others accustomed the EMU: a rule-based monetary-policy targeted to demand-led growth. The response to the crisis on inflation in the hands of an independent is reviewed and explained in terms of limitations central bank, and a fiscal policy in the hands of in European insti-tutions, divergent economic the Member States. Furthermore, monetarist ideas doctrines and the boundaries of European solidar- entailed that supply-side and structural reforms ity. Proposed solutions to the crisis based on defla- would constitute the one-size-fits-all formula to tion or reflation are assessed from a varieties of secure competitiveness in the whole Eurozone capitalism perspective and the implications for (Hall 2012, 356-57).

IDEATIONAL DIFFERENCES BETWEEN ITALIAN AND GERMAN GOVERNMENTS DURING THE CRISIS 74 Federico Bruno Ideas played a crucial role in the making of the economists (including the distinguished ordolib- Euro even at national level. In Italy, the position eral economist Herbert Giersch) and published of the Italian government during the integration on the Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, concisely process was shaped by the interplay of economic represented the former faction: it claimed that ideas and foreign policy beliefs. Economic and the political economies of the European states foreign policy ideas were, on occasion, conso- were still too different for the establishment of nant in fostering the integration process, as in the a common currency. In turn, the Ordnungspoli- case of the negotiation of the Maastricht Treaty tisches Plädoyer by Olaf Sievert (1993), Giersch’s in 1990-1992; other times, the policy imperative student, represented the pro-EMU faction of of remaining at the heart of European integration the ordoliberal camp. In his article, published in prevailed over more sceptical economic consid- September 1992 in the same newspaper, Sievert erations, as in the last phase of the EMU in 1999 claimed that the monetary discipline of the EMU (Quaglia 2004). would have secured the ordoliberal principles of In Germany, the position of the government on stability of monetary policy, and of responsibility. the EMU was characterised by a tension between This division within the ordoliberal camp was to ordoliberalism, represented by Hans Tietmeyer re-emerge during the Euro crisis. and by the Bundesbank, and Europeanism, For the first years, the EMU seemed to work embodied by Chancellor Helmut Kohl and by smoothly: the Northern countries were institu- his vision of a “community of stability” (Dyson tionally well-equipped for the architecture of the 1998, 39). To be sure, Kohl’s vision was not antag- monetary union, and started developing huge onistic to ordoliberalism; on the contrary, being surpluses. In the meanwhile, the Southern econo- “based on strict fiscal discipline and economic mies, despite having lost the possibility of compet- convergence” (Ibid., p. 40), it overlapped it. The itive devaluation, benefited from low interest rates ordoliberal features of Kohl’s vision stemmed and from the flows of money deriving from their both from his convictions and from the need to Northern partners’ surpluses (Hall 2012, 360). But, secure the support of the Bundesbank and of the as always happens, the honeymoon was destined finance ministry. However, Kohl’s position was to end: the Euro crisis made the structural flaws also motivated by his intimate Europeanism and of the Eurozone evident, and called for its reform. by his commitment for a Western and European Germany (Ibid., p. 39). During the negotiations, 3. Italy: From Berlusconi’s Kohl’s Europeanism offered historical and political Opportunism to Monti’s legitimation to the EMU (Ibid., p. 61), whereas the Pragmatic Europeanism ordoliberal ideas represented powerful ideational resources. First, they offered the theoretical basis When the crisis broke out in autumn 2008, Italy from which the German proposals were derived; was not immediately hit: this allowed Prime second, they limited the win-set of acceptable Minister Silvio Berlusconi to downplay the impact outcomes for the German government, therefore of the crisis, and focus on domestic issues (Jones strengthening its position in the negotiations. 2017, 2). At this stage, he claimed that the crisis It is worth noting that, outside of the core exec- was a problem of other European states, not Italy’s. utive, the ordoliberal camp was split into two, The situation worsened in Summer 2011, as diffi- respectively against and in favour of the EMU. culties in the negotiation of the second Greek bail- The manifesto entitled Die währungspolitischen out programme and a second round of the stress Beschlüsse von Maastricht: Eine Gefahrfür Europa test of the European Banking Association raised (“The Monetary Policy Decision of Maastricht: concerns about the stability of the Eurozone: inves- A Threat for Europe”), signed in June 1992 by 62 tors started losing confidence in the Italian bond market, and the early counter-measures adopted

IDEATIONAL DIFFERENCES BETWEEN ITALIAN AND GERMAN GOVERNMENTS DURING THE CRISIS 75 Federico Bruno by Berlusconi during the summer did not calm the mechanisms determined the stance of the govern- markets. Since the difficulties in re-financing the ment: institutional constraints, a pro-European Italian debt threatened the stability of the whole attitude, and a large domestic win-set. The institu- Eurozone, the ECB started to buy Italian bonds tional constraints worked in two ways. On the one and urged the government, in exchange, to adopt hand, the incomplete architecture of the EMU did measures (such as a reform of the pension system) not provide any automatic insurance for countries to secure debt sustainability on the long term. hit by the crisis, thus amplifying the influence of Berlusconi’s leadership proved to be inadequate market pressures: the government felt obliged to to deal with the crisis. His parliamentary majority adhere to the FC, if it wanted to obtain a Euro- was divided, as the Lega Nord refused to accept pean insurance against the crisis. On the other, the any measure involving pensions, and he came into FC was in line with the framework set by previous conflict with his powerful Minister of Finance, fiscal rules (for instance, the Stability and Growth Giulio Tremonti. The internal divisions both Pact), and opposing the FC would have not put/ within the executive and its parliamentary majority called into question the overall framework. The led to ineffective and tardy measures. Berlusconi pro-European attitude of the government led it lost credibility in Europe (as testified by Angela not only to defend the national interest, but also Merkel’s and ’s chuckles after a to safeguard the European integration process: question about Berlusconi during a press confer- the signature of the FC was a demonstration of ence) and in the markets (rating agency Standard the Italian commitment to the European project. & Poor’s lowered the rank of Italian bonds from Finally, the parties in the Parliament broadly A+ to A). Eventually, he decided to resign, and supported the FC, in line with their Europeanist President Giorgio Napolitano appointed Mario attitude – even if in a reactive, rather than proac- Monti as the new Prime Minister in November tive, way. This prevented the government from 2011 (see Schmidt and Gualmini 2013). evaluating the opportunity of not signing the Treaty (pp. 218-21). The case of the Fiscal Compact (FC), accurately described by Moschella (2017), shows the role of 4. Germany: between ideational factors in Monti’s government. From a pragmatic Europeanism and mere economic perspective, the decision of the ordoliberalism government to adhere to the FC was puzzling, as it clearly penalised Italy, and offered no guarantees of Unlike Italy, the crisis hit Germany from the begin- success (pp. 208-10). Furthermore, despite being ning. As mentioned above, the EMU architecture popularly remembered as a zealot of austerity, enabled Northern economies to pile up important Monti and his ministers constantly asserted that surpluses. In investing this money, the German fiscal discipline did not represent the best way to banking sector let down its conservative, risk- address Italy’s long-term problems, and that they averse reputation and became embroiled in the would have prioritised growth-oriented measures, financial bubble (Dyson 2010, p. 400): important instead. Instead, the government abided to the commercial banks (the most famous case was the austerity rules because it feared adverse market IKB) and the state-owned Landesbanken needed to reactions: the perception of Italy’s vulnerability be bailed-out by the government. However, when “nurtured a ‘there is no alternative’ mind-set that the financial crisis turned into the sovereign-debt dominated the policy-makers’ thinking and led crisis that menaced the Eurozone, Germany was them not to even conceive of the possibility of out of danger, and, unlike the Southern econo- looking for alternative courses of action” (p. 217). mies, did not face an immediate threat. Its imme- Along with the fear of punishment, three other diate interests were, on the one hand, to secure

IDEATIONAL DIFFERENCES BETWEEN ITALIAN AND GERMAN GOVERNMENTS DURING THE CRISIS 76 Federico Bruno the Eurozone (not least because of the exposure of diate interests derived from its status of Northern, its banks in the Southern countries), and, on the export-led political economy, they shaped the other, to shift away the costs of rescuing the Euro- German strategy for the reform of the Eurozone. zone. The fact that the immediate consequences The interplay between stability, responsibility and of the crisis were much heavier for the Southern competitiveness resulted in an approach charac- countries than for their Northern counterparts terised by intergovernmentalism and market disci- increased Germany’s power during the negotia- pline. Intergovernmentalism was seen as the best tions (see Schimmelfennig 2015). guarantee to prevent any mutualisation of the debt; There has been a huge debate on the impact of market discipline, in turn, was seen as the driving ideas on Germany’s behaviour during the Euro force for the reforms, necessary to overcome the crisis. Some claim that the German government lack of competitiveness that afflicted the Southern strictly adhered to the principles of the ordolib- economies, and this constituted, according to the eral ideology, whereas, according to others, it was ordoliberal (and German) account, the real cause driven by self-interest and pragmatism (Hien of the Euro crisis (see Matthijs and McNamara and Joerges 2017, collected several contribu- 2015). tions on this topic). Ordoliberalism and pragma- On the other, ordoliberal ideas represented a tism should not be considered as being mutually constraint to the German executive (see Jamet, excluding: within the German government, we Mussler, and De Corte 2011, 64). Even the prag- could find both more pragmatist (such as Chan- matist leaders had to pay lip-service and to justify cellor Merkel) and more ordoliberal (such as their policies through ordoliberal principles: this the director of Bundesbank, Jens Weidmann, or is what Chancellor Merkel did in 2011 in Freiburg, Finance Minister, Wolfgang Schäuble) leaders. the birthplace of ordoliberalism, when she The German position seems therefore to have been defended her European strategy, and what Klaus shaped by a tension between ordoliberalism and Regling, the chief of the ESM, did in 2017 in the pragmatism. The ordoliberalism of the German same city, when he claimed the consistency of the executive, however, was not a strict version of the ESM with the principles of Ordnungspolitik. More- theory, but a more superficial, crude adaptation of over, beyond the German executive, the remarks it (see Hien and Joerges 2018; and Wyplosz 2017). of many influential ordoliberal economists (such The German political discourse during the crisis as Hans-Werner Sinn), highly critical towards the was dominated by ordoliberal concepts: stability, European strategy of Merkel’s governments, posed responsibility, and competitiveness. The more a further constraint on the government. Eventu- ordoliberal leaders stressed the Haftungsprinzip ally, some of these economists took part in the (principle of responsibility): the rescue of the foundation of the Euro-sceptic party Alternative Eurozone should not have entailed a mutuali- für Deutschland. Once again, the ordoliberal camp sation of the sovereign debt, and the Member was split into two(see, also, Jacoby 2014). States should have remained responsible for their own public finances. In turn, the more pragmatic 5. Conclusions leaders justified, upon the basis of the stability During the Euro crisis, in both Italy and Germany, principle, those policies that diverged from the we could witness the resurfacing of the ideational ordoliberal orthodoxy, such as the bail-out pack- dynamics that had characterised the previous ages for indebted countries, or the establishment stage of the monetary integration. In Italy, the of the European Stability Mechanism (ESM). committed Europeanism of the Monti govern- Ordoliberal ideas played, therefore, a double ment led Italy to accept the German-inspired role. On the one hand, together with the imme- reforms of the Eurozone, although they penalised

IDEATIONAL DIFFERENCES BETWEEN ITALIAN AND GERMAN GOVERNMENTS DURING THE CRISIS 77 Federico Bruno it as a demand-led political economy. In Germany, between bargaining power and size of the win-set, the tension between a pragmatist Europeanism see Putnam 1988, p. 440). In Germany, quite and ordoliberalism – that already characterised the opposite happened: not only did ordoliberal Kohl’s chancellorship – shaped the European ideas provide a set of principles to articulate the strategy of the government. In the aftermath of reform of the Eurozone, but they also dramatically the crisis, however, these ideas showed their weak- restricted the win-set, thus improving the govern- nesses. On the one hand, the last ment’s bargaining power. (2018) are the perfect representation of the end of the so-called “permissive consensus”: by now, it has become very hard – if not impossible – for a government to justify its choice only relying on Europeanism. On the other, the fact that the Euro- zone is still considered to be in danger despite the reforms undertaken during the crisis shows all the limits of the German approach. Italian and German ideas during the crisis were substantively different. Italian Europeanism translated into a preference for a supranational approach, while the stress on the need to foster growth (that characterised even the Monti govern- ment, despite its commitment to fiscal discipline) reflected a preference on market-correcting poli- cies. In turn, the German commitment to ordo- liberal principles translated into an intergovern- mental, market-discipline-oriented approach, suited to secure responsibility and competitive- ness. It is worth noting that the German approach is consistent with the monetarist founding of the EMU and with a certain national egoism, whereas the Italian one requires a high solidarity among European countries, which, to date, does not exist. In this sense, borrowing the Varieties-of-Capi- talism jargon, we could speak of a “comparative advantage” of German ideas over the Italian ones. Finally, the ideational attitudes of the govern- ments had different effects in Italy and in Germany. In Italy, Berlusconi’s opportunistic lead- ership prevented the government from setting up an effective and timely strategy against the crisis. The Europeanist attitude of the Italian parliament during Monti’s government, in turn, widened the win-set of acceptable reforms: while this secured the participation of the Italian government in the reform process, it also diminished its nego- tiating power in the bargaining (on the relation

IDEATIONAL DIFFERENCES BETWEEN ITALIAN AND GERMAN GOVERNMENTS DURING THE CRISIS 78 Federico Bruno Bibliography Putnam, Robert D. 1988. “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Dyson, Kenneth. 1998. “Chancellor Kohl as Stra- Games.” International Organization 42(03): tegic Leader: The Case of Economic and Mone- 427. tary Union.” German Politics 7(1): 37-63. Quaglia, Lucia. 2004. “Italy’s Policy towards Euro- ———. 2010. “In the Shifting Shadows of Crisis: pean Monetary Integration: Bringing Ideas Pivot Points, Crisis Attribution, and Macro- Back In?” Journal of European Public Policy Economic Policies under Grand Coalition.” 11(6): 1096-1111. German Politics 19(3-4): 393-415. Schimmelfennig, Frank. 2015. “Liberal Inter- Hall, Peter A. 2012. “The Economics and Poli- governmentalism and the Euro Area Crisis.” tics of the Euro Crisis.” German Politics 21(4): Journal of European Public Policy 22(2): 177-95. 355-71. Schmidt, Vivien, and Elisabetta Gualmini. 2013. ———. 2014. “Varieties of Capitalism and the Euro “The Political Sources of Italy’s Economic Prob- Crisis.” West European Politics 37(6): 1223-43. lems: Between Opportunistic Political Leader- Hien, Josef, and Christian Joerges, eds. 2017. ship and Pragmatic, Technocratic Leadership.” Ordoliberalism, Law and the Rule of Economics. Comparative European Politics 11(3): 360-82. Oxford-Portland OR: Hart Publishing. Sievert, Olaf. 1993. “Geld, Das Man Nicht Selbst ———. 2018. “Dead Man Walking? Current Euro- Herstellen Kann - Ein Ordnungspolitisches pean Interest in the Ordoliberal Tradition.” Plädoyer Für Die Europäische Währungs- European Law Journal. union.” In Währungsunion Oder Währungs- chaos, eds. Peter Bofinger, Stefan Collignon, Jacoby, Wade. 2014. “The Politics of the Euro- and Ernst-Moritz Lipp. Gabler. zone Crisis: Two Puzzles behind the German Consensus.” German Politics and Society 32(2): Wyplosz, Charles. 2017. “The Euro and Ordolib- 70-85. eralism.” In Ordoliberalism: A German Oddity?, eds. Thorsten Beck and Hans-Helmut Kotz. Jamet, Jean-François, Werner Mussler, and Stefaan CEPR Press. De Corte. 2011. “Eu Economic Governance: The French and German Views.” European View 10(2): 259-60. Jones, Erik. 2017. “Relations with Europe.” Italian Politics 32(1). Matthijs, Matthias, and Kathleen McNamara. 2015. “The Euro Crisis’ Theory Effect: Northern Saints, Southern Sinners, and the Demise of the Eurobond.” Journal of European Integration 37(2): 229-45. McNamara, Kathleen. 1999. The Currency of Ideas. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press. Moschella, Manuela. 2017. “Italy and the Fiscal Compact: Why Does a Country Commit to Permanent Austerity?”, Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica 47(2): 205-25.

IDEATIONAL DIFFERENCES BETWEEN ITALIAN AND GERMAN GOVERNMENTS DURING THE CRISIS 79 Federico Bruno A CULTURAL POLITICAL Cultural political economy integrates institu- ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE tional, material and ideational viewpoints, and adopts a decisive neo-Weberian historical evolu- EUROPEAN CRISIS tionary perspective to show how they have co-evolved and re-enforced one another since the Josef Hien 1950s, creating the discrepancies and irritations University of Milan that we witness today between the Northern and Southern Member States. The contribution exem- Introduction plifies the cultural political economy approach to the crisis with the German-Italian discrepancies In 2011, a Greek minister wrote in a newspaper that have been growing slowly since the 1950s, but about the Troika that “we are dealing here with have accelerated during the past 30 years. While in idiots and Protestants, hence there is no solu- the 1950s and 1960s both economies started from tion” (cited in Makrides, 2015, p. 373). Looking at similar premises, they are worlds apart today. the split between the crisis and non-crisis coun- tries, it seems, at first glance, that the crisis coun- While cultural political economy has been tries are all Catholic or Orthodox, while the non- promoted for a decade and a half, this approach, crisis countries overwhelmingly share a Protes- to date, has not come centre-stage in the Euro- tant background. The cultural and ethical rooting pean discussion on the crisis. The paper argues of German ordoliberalism and the reliance of that this is due to the fact that, while, in essence, German politicians on the concept helps German these approaches are on the right track towards politicians to approach the crisis as a morality tale a more encompassing post-disciplinary under- of Northern saints and Southern sinners (Hien standing, they have not left their foundational 2017). Do we witness a new Thirty Years’ War basis in rational-efficiency-centred institution- in Europe? Not quite; the ideational and cultural alism or in material Marxism. The paper proposes split between Catholic/Orthodox and Protes- a new starting-point for cultural political economy tant countries also overlaps with the material anchored in a Weberian framework that is onto- interest-based fault lines between creditor- and logical and epistemological better suited to inte- debtor-countries or the institutional differences grate institutional, material and ideational expla- between those countries that generate economic nations and set them in an evolutionary context demand primarily through exports or those that over time. do so through internal demand. So far, the Euro- After an introduction to the concept of cultural pean crisis has been analysed through the lenses political economy (Section 1), the paper lays out of the Variety of Capitalism concept, the growth the socio-economic points of divergence between model framework, or ideational accounts. These the Catholic and the Protestant thought as they three accounts have generally been applied in developed from the 1930s onwards in Germany isolation from one another. There has been little and Italy (Section 2). It also explores how much room for cross-fertilisation, arguably, due to the of this socio-economic thought found its way into different points of epistemological departure that the institutional reform of both countries in the emphasise either institutional rational efficiency, 1950s and 1960s, and traces the evolution of the the material driving forces, or the constructivist two doctrines and the institutions which they motives for the political economies during the informed to the present day (Section 3). crisis. This paper adopts the concept of cultural political economy, modifies it, and applies it to the North-South conflict.

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 80 Josef Hien 1. The Dominant Approaches The political economies of the countries that have within Political Economy to adopted the euro are simply too heterogeneous to the Crisis be subsumed under a single currency. Authors such as Wolfgang Streeck, Lucio Baccaro, The “Varieties of Capitalism” approach has domi- Johannes Lindvall and Stefan Svallfors had already nated comparative political economy for almost criticised the “Varieties of Capitalism” scholarship 20 years (Hall and Soskice 2001). Putting the firm, before the crisis for not accounting for the far- business networks, and their interaction with the reaching processes of neo-liberalisation that all of (welfare) state at the centre of the analysis, “Vari- these national economies have undergone since eties of Capitalism” scholars argue that market the 1990s. The decline in union density and corpo- economies cluster into co-ordinated and liberal ratist arrangements, as well as wage dispersion and market economies. Co-ordinated market econo- the dualisation of the labour markets, eroded the mies rely on diversified quality production. They equilibrium that the co-ordinated market econo- orient their production towards market niches mies had found before the 1980s (Streeck 2009; where quality and customisation are important. Baccaro and Howell 2011; Lindvall and Rothstein A state-run vocational-training system ensures 2006; Lindvall 2006; Svallfors 2016; Svallfors and the supply of skilled labour, and high employment Tyllström 2018). The different ways in which these protection creates incentives to invest in specific liberalisations were executed contributed to signif- skills. The system is co-ordinated through strong icant shifts in the configuration of GDP growth employer and employee organisations. In the orig- in both Germany and Italy. This is the gist of the inal account of the Varieties of Capitalism and in growth model perspective. It emphasises that, in most of the follow-up literature, Italy and Germany the 1990s, Germany turned from a growth model are classified as co-ordinated market economies. that was equilibrated between domestic demand During the 2000s, the Varieties of Capitalism and exports, to an export-led economy. The share approach reigned supreme. The introductory of exports in German GDP growth doubled in the chapter of Hall and Soskice’s Varieties of Capitalism 1990s and 2000s (Baccaro and Pontusson 2016, book has been cited according to google scholar 189). To support the export competitiveness of 11,522 times. Chapters such as Estevez-Abe et al. the price-sensitive German manufacturing goods, (2001) on social protection and the formation of domestic demand (household consumption) was skills have led to paradigmatic changes in entire suppressed through wage depression. Unions in sub-fields of political-economy (e.g., welfare state the manufacturing sector agreed to wage restraints studies). However, the theory has been seriously and the rest of the labour market was de-regulated challenged through the shockwaves that the finan- (Baccaro and Benassi 2017; Hassel 2017). cial crisis sent through the European co-ordi- For the proponents of the Growth model perspec- nated market economies (Hall 2014; Johnston tive and the scholars of the preceding liberalisa- and Regan 2015). The crisis drastically showcased tion, the German model runs at the expense of a strong “variety within the variety” of European the Southern political economies of the Eurozone, co-ordinated market economies between North, which are geared towards demand-led growth. South, and Central and Eastern Europe (Höppner The proposed and enforced solutions of Germany and Lutter 2017; Armingeon, Guthmann and to the Euro-crisis also have to be seen in this light. Weisstanner 2015; Perez and Matsaganis 2018). The interests of the German export coalition are Accounts started to re-classify countries, and Italy the underlying motives of the austerity policies is now presented as a “mixed-model”. The euro is that the German government made the pre-condi- the bête noire for researchers who emphasise the tion for loans and rescue packages. These austerity “within variety” of European political economies. measures risk being counter-productive because

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 81 Josef Hien they stifle domestic demand, which has tradition- Arguably, a fourth explanatory strand for the ally been the key driver of growth in Southern euro crisis also exists, one which, to date, has European economies. In the literature on the lived in the shadow of the three other approaches. European crisis, this features as a cleavage dividing Here, historical evolutionary pathways are at the Northern and Southern Europe between importer centre of attention, allowing for a more integra- versus exporter states. The cleavage sometimes tive epistemic perspective than the other three also appears as a cleavage between debtor versus approaches: economic historians have devel- creditor states (Dyson 2014). oped a notion that has so far not been picked up A third explanatory framework for the Euro- much in the mainstream of political economy: the crisis is based upon ideas. The ideational turn in idea of different economic cultures (Abelshauser comparative political economy has demonstrated 2003; Abelshauser, Gilgen and Leutzsch 2013). the power of economic ideas in politics (Berman It brings a historical-evolutionary perspective 1998, 2006; Blyth 2003; Carstensen and Schmidt that tracks the embeddedness of socio-economic 2016). During the euro crisis, idiosyncratic actors in national cultures, traditions, and preva- national economic ideologies such as German lent economic ideas within a nation-state (Dyson ordoliberalism and French dirigisme experienced 2017). Here, the crucial role of “meaning making” an unexpected explosion of public and schol- to reduce complexity in the economy is brought arly interest because they link expert ideas with a out. The concept of cultural political economy common national tradition of how the economy or economic cultures highlights the importance should be run (Economist 2015; and instrumental use of shared imaginaries for 2014; Blyth 2013; Scharpf 2016; Hien and Joerges contemporary economic actors (Jessop 2010; 2017; 2018; Needergard and Snaith 2015; Amable Jessop and Sum 2017; Best and Paterson 2015; 2017). In particular, the clash between French Esch and De Jong 2017). While the economic economic ideas and their German counterparts cultures notion of the historians around has been blamed for the prolonged stalemate Abelshauser is based upon the rational efficiency between the countries on what is the right crisis accounts of , the notion of cultural policy (Brunnermeier, James and Landau 2016). political economy advanced by Ngai-Ling Sum and Bob Jessop is rooted in Marx and Gramsci. The “Varieties of Capitalism”, the growth model Jessop and Sum’s cultural political economy prom- perspective, and the ideational accounts exist ises a “dialectic of discursivity and materiality” largely independently from one another. The (Jessop 2004, 164) but the initial vow to “produce reason for this can be found in the different epis- a Marxist-inflected ‘cultural political economy’” temological points of departure. The “Varieties (Jessop and Sum 2001: 92) makes this difficult. of Capitalism” model is anchored in a rational- Like the cultural economy concept of the Biele- efficiency-oriented institutionalism. The growth feld historians, Sum and Jessop want to present model perspective relies ultimately on an interest an integrative account, but both approaches still coalition between segments of capital and labour emphasise material and institutional conditions in the export sector. And the ideational approaches over ideational factors. Ideas are regarded as tools rely on the power of ideologies to serve as blue- to solve collective-action problems in the tradition prints for socio-economic actions and institu- of North, or as fig leaves to manipulate and veil the tion-building. A severe downside to all three is true material conditions to establish hegemony in that they do not incorporate an explicit histor- a Gramscian sense (Jessop and Sum 2001: 94-95) ical evolutionary perspective. Moreover, they are making one wonder where the culture in these two largely apolitical, since they leave electoral consid- cultural political economy approaches actually erations and the anchoring of different economic resides. It is certainly understandable that scholars strategies in the population by the wayside. that have worked within the Marxist paradigm for

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 82 Josef Hien most of their careers will not give it up even when offer a much more solid fundament to arrive at trying to stretch its boundaries towards a “post- an “organic synthesis” of the “soft” and “hard” disciplinary” (Jessop and Sum 2001: 89) perspec- (Sum and Jessop 2013: 23; Staricco 2015: 9) parts tive. But it is fair to ask them why the “anti- of cultural political economy without subscribing cultural” (Smith 2001: 6) theorist par excellence, fully to total constructivism or total materialism. Karl Marx, is chosen as the starting-point for the For the rest of social science, culture as an explan- formulation of this post-disciplinary approach. atory variable is (often not without foundation) Might not Max Weber, for whom culture had been accused of being a residual category that gets the starting-point of any socio-economic analysis, evoked when all other explanations fail (Staricco be more fruitful as a point of departure? 2017). However, the strength of a cultural polit- Culture, in Weber’s work, is the “most funda- ical economy that is based upon Weber, is that it mental category” (Swedberg and Agevall 2005:56) can integrate the trichotomy between material, and “culture is a finite segment on which human ideational and institutional accounts that currently beings confer meaning and significance” (Weber divides the study of political economy and the euro 1904: 81). “Weber emphasizes to study capitalism crisis. As in Weber’s famous switchmen metaphor, not only as an economic phenomenon but also as it is not interests, ideas or institutions that deter- a cultural phenomenon” (Swedberg and Agevall mine action, but all three together. When they all 2005: 57). Moreover, for Weber, social science was point into the same direction, they form a self- about “Verstehen”, about finding out about the reinforcing compound, an amalgam, that is very “subjective meanings”. Social science should not hard to overcome or to break up. This is exactly emulate the positivism of the physical sciences but the case in the Eurozone crisis, and the following should instead be a “Geisteswissenschaft”, literally, will show how ideas, interests and institutions a “science of the spirit”. Therefore, social analysis re-inforced themselves in an evolutionary process and, especially, the study of political economy, over time, and came to determine today’s position should be a “science which is concerned with the of crisis and non-crisis countries. subjective meaning of action”, in which “explana- tion requires a grasp of the complex of meaning” 2. Catholic and Protestants (Weber 1968: 9). Hence, Weber’s sociology is Reactions in Socio-economic about the analysis of meaning-making and shared Concepts to the Crisis of imaginaries which speak very much to the core 1930. concept of shared imaginaries and meaning- making that not only Sum and Jessop but also the Language and religion are two major carriers of Bielefeld School put centre-stage in their accounts. culture. This paper focuses on religion, and traces Insightful in this respect is a quick look at the how the different socio-economic doctrines of subtitle of Weber’s opus “Economy and Society”, religious institutions left their imprint on post- which reads: “An Outline of Interpretative Soci- WWII ideologies and institutions. Our story ology”. There is also an emerging trend towards starts with the world economic crisis of the 1930s, neo-weberian approaches to the EU in general which re-formed the dominant strands of socio- (Ferrera 2017, 2018). But these are only perceived economic thought in Europe. The ordoliberal as manipulating themes in the existing cultural project as it evolved in Germany from the late political economy approaches due to their rooting 1920s onwards is the reaction of Protestant social in Marxist materialism. Hence, it is not surprising thought to the upheavals of Weimar that cumu- that the ideational components of Jessop and Sum’s lated in the World Economic Crisis of 1929. analysis have been heavily criticised for an ad hoc evoking of cultural themes when their explanatory Walter Eucken, the founding father of the Ordo- toolkit is exhausted (Staricco 2015). Weber would liberal School, had already commented, in the

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 83 Josef Hien 1930s, that the loosening ties to the churches had their own benefit. Just as in Protestantism, ordo- facilitated the people turning to secular-isms in considers people to be “neither angels the Weimar period and that “religion had increas- nor devils” (Dietze 1947, 26), but rather “justi- ingly lost the power to provide individuals’ lives, fied and sinners at the same time; that is why it and thus also their economic activity, a context of is decisive to place them within an order that meaning” (Eucken 1932). Numerous “explicitly disciplines the peccator” (Reuter 2010: 3). In normative-anthropological deliberations” of the his work, Eucken seeks a compromise between ordoliberals were derived from Protestantism, and “a Calvinist theocracy with its near identity of “the strong affinity of a liberal ethos [was] largely church and state and the Lutheran two-kingdoms influenced by Protestantism” (Jähnichen 2010: 11, doctrine with its separation of the spiritual and 13). secular spheres” (Petersen 2008, 23). His concepts The “deep Protestant grammar” (Manow 2001) of mirror Bonhoeffer’s “authoritative-paternalistic ordoliberalism was no accident. All the key figures [...] thinking” that “trusts an order and authority of the first ordoliberal generation were Protes- based on law and responsibility more than indi- tants. Eucken wrote in a 1942 letter to Alexander vidual freedom” (Falcke 2011, 382). Ordoliberal- Rüstow: “I could neither live nor work if I did ism’s notion of society is not paternalistic, even not believe that God exists.” (Lenel 1991, 12) The though the state’s capability to provide order is so ordoliberal project that developed in the late 1930s important to it. The state is supposed to hold back and early 1940s in the Freiburg circles was there- and limit itself to setting the underlying condi- fore a genuinely Protestant attempt to design an tions for the social order. Ordoliberals reject social economic order. The project was meant as an anti- transfer payments as false incentives. Uncondi- dote to the social-Catholic, the Keynesian-welfare- tional transfers for reasons of solidarity would, in state, and the neoclassical Austrian-Anglo-Saxon the end, result in the “total catastrophe for state approaches. The key figure was the Protestant theo- and society” and make citizens “slaves of the state” logian Dietrich Bonhoeffer/Bonhöffer. Between (Röpke 1949, 257). Instead, the state should limit 1938 and 1944, he brought Protestant theologians itself to ensuring equal opportunity and creating (Otto Dibelius, Constantin von Dietze), Protes- the conditions for helping people to help them- tant economists (Walter Eucken, Leonard Miksch, selves. This is what sets ordoliberal ideology apart Adolf Lampe), Protestant jurists (Franz Böhm, from the Keynesian and Beveridgean welfare-state Hans Großmann-Doerth), and Protestant histo- concept that aims at equality in society, on the one rians (Gerhard Ritter) together in the Bonhoeffer hand, and social-Catholic welfare concepts that Kreis and the Arbeitsgemeinschaft Erwin von emphasise a male-breadwinner-centred corpo- Beckerath, the two most important ordoliberal ratist-transfer-heavy welfare state, on the other. circles in Freiburg (Goldschmidt 1997). Eucken saw social policy as something that would, TheFreiburger Denkschrift, which originated from in the long run, kill all individual self-responsi- these circles and was to be the blueprint for post- bility. He emphasised that it would “foster collec- war re-construction, laid out the first coherent tivization, create coercion and dependency that Protestant economic and social ethics. Its under- would diminish self-responsibility and endanger lying values clearly differentiate ordoliberalism the unfolding of the powers which strive in the from nineteenth century laissez faire liberalism, individual human being for fulfillment” (Eucken and the post-Keynesian Anglo-Saxon neoliber- 1949, 113). Müller-Armack, who later became alism, which has become the dominant ideational State Secretary in the Ministry of the Economy, paradigm since the late 1970s. Although self- opined, as early as 1947, that, in any case, “the interest induces people to give their best, it can social policy results […] have been quite poor” also bring them to manipulate competition to (Müller-Armack 1947, 130). Kaufmann notes

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 84 Josef Hien that, for , later to become Minister spirit” (Quadragesimo Anno, 88) spread by “the of the Economy and the single most prominent errors of individualist economic teaching” stem- Christian Democratic exponent of ordoliberalism, ming from a “poisoned spring” (Quadragesimo “economic policy was the best social policy”. (cited Anno, 88). Instead, the papal letter puts forward in Kaufmann 2003, 131). that economic life must again be “subject to and Due to their Protestant religiosity, the ordolib- governed by a true and effective directing prin- erals searched for a political home in the Chris- ciple” (Quadragesimo Anno, 88). tian Democratic Party (not in the Liberal Party). Quadragesimo Anno marks a new step in Cath- Franz Böhm was Minister in Hessen and became olic social thinking. Catholic social thinking is member of the Federal Parliament, Ludwig Erhard now no longer limited to social welfare insti- was Minister and became later Chancellor and tutions (as it still was in Rerum Novarum) that Alfred Müller-Armack State Secretary. However, engage in repair work after capitalism has brought these Protestant ordoliberals faced a mighty oppo- social dislocation and hardship by destroying the nent within the Christian Democratic party: the old social order. Instead, its plea for corporatism social Catholic faction. At the same time as the makes a step towards actively shaping capitalism. ordoliberals, and also as a reaction to the crisis of This is new and novel thinking, different from the late 1920s, the social Catholics had developed the Vogelsangian pleas to go back to a medieval socio-economic ideas that ran, in most points, estate-based social order, even though it embodies exactly the opposite from the Protestant ordolib- these ideals to a certain extent. The difference is erals. Their ideology was based largely upon the that it fuses them with a decisive Christian Demo- social Encyclical Quadragesimo Anno, which, like cratic plea to democratise the capitalist system the Ordo Manifesto (1936), had been issued as a by arguing for the centrality of associations. The response to the world economic crisis which began Encyclical promotes a specific type of neo-corpo- in 1929.The prime target of criticism in Quadra- ratism in which the state only intervenes as a gesimo Anno is the current “economic dictator- last resort (Invernizzi-Accetti 2019). Christian ship” (Quadragesimo Anno, 109) brought about by Socialism emphasises the importance of collec- a rampant system of free competition which had tive organisation for the common good (Quadrag- led to the “virtual degradation of the majesty of esimo Anno, 85). Employers and employees should the state” (Quadragesimo Anno, 109). According be organised in mutual associations depending to Quadragesimo Anno, “the free market has on the sector of activity. These mutual associa- destroyed itself” (Quadragesimo Anno, 109). tions should grant a stable and smooth running The Encyclical stresses that its socioeconomic of the economy, which would avoid strikes, on concept is neither neo-liberal nor socialist, but the one hand, and wage deprivation, on the other. marks a distinct, Catholic third way. In contrast The Encyclical notes that “both workers and to socialism, private property remains central, employers with united strength and counsel can but, unlike neo-liberal conceptions, any private overcome the difficulties and obstacles and let a property has to be subject to the increase of the wise provision on the part of the public authority common good. Quadragesimo Anno is of the view aid them”. (Quadragesimo Anno, 73). Wages that “the right order of economic life cannot be should be negotiated fairly in bi-partite negotia- left to a free competition of forces” (Quadragesimo tions, and only in cases of stalemate or dissatisfac- Anno, 87). The judgment is harsh: “free competi- tion should the state intervene. Workers should be tion […] clearly cannot direct economic life” as protected by ample worker-protection legislation “it cannot curb and rule itself” (Quadragesimo that would regulate maximum work hours as well Anno, 88). Unrestricted free market competi- as women in work and child labour. Co-determi- tion would be directed by the “evil individualistic nation should reduce industrial conflict and give

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 85 Josef Hien the employed a say in the administration of the kept secret because of widespread scepticism in firm. In general, “the riches that economic-social both camps towards collaboration. The Catho- developments constantly increase ought to be so lics were later reported to have rejected both the distributed among individual persons and classes term and the concept of a , that the common advantage of all, which Leo XIII since it contained too much ordoliberal Protestant had praised, will be safeguarded”. (Quadragesimo thinking. Both churches were still very far from Anno, 75). The prime aim of the economy is to their (cautious) ecumenical moves of the 1970s, increase the aggregate wealth, instead of individual despite having joined forces in a single party (the riches. This shared wealth should be generated not CDU) for the first time in German history. only through the payment of a “just wage” and the The ordoliberals joined the Christian Democratic regulation of working hours and conditions, but party for electoral considerations. With German also through a system of re-distribution. There- partition, the denominational balance had shifted fore, “we must strive that at least in the future the to roughly 50 per cent Catholics and 50 per cent abundant fruits of production will accrue equi- Protestants in West-Germany. Since Protes- tably to those who are rich and will be distrib- tants not only voted Christian Democrat but also uted in ample sufficiency among the workers”. Liberal and Social Democrat (but almost all Cath- (Quadragesimo Anno, 61). With its emphasis on olics voted Christian Democrat), they needed the corporatist organisation of socio-economic rela- Catholics to form an electoral coalition to get at tions and the transfer-heavy male-breadwinner least some of their points through. However, given model, the Encyclical reads like an anti-manifesto the differences in socio-economic ideology, Social to Protestant ordoliberal claims. Catholics worked in, the early years of the republic, Thus, ordoliberalism distinguished itself clearly as an effective counterweight to ordoliberal ideas. from Catholic social ethics, and this is largely On the other hand, ordoliberalism also balanced due to the different (Hien 2012) conceptions of social Catholicism towards a moderate position the human being that Catholics and Protestants away from its hardcore corporatist standpoints of loaded into Social Catholicism and ordoliber- the 1930s. Such a moderation effect did not exist in alism. Catholicism assumes that individuals are Italy. Here, the mono-confessionalism pampered not equipped with the same intellectual, moral, through the softer version of fascist totalitari- and physical capabilities. For this reason, ensuring anism led to a less clear-cut break with the past fair and equal starting-conditions and opportuni- and a general easier embracing of corporatist and ties (level playing-field), as ordoliberals do, would Social Catholic (even Christian Socialist) ideas (a not suffice for Catholic social ethics; instead, good example here is Amintore Fanfani). society must also guarantee a certain amount of In contrast to the West-German Christian Demo- re-distribution (Quadragesimo Anno, 75). cratic CDU, the Italian Democrazia Cristiana The mutual distrust between both camps was (DC) was all Catholic. The DC’s founding father tangible up into the 1960s. In 1963, the leading Alcide De Gasperi is portrayed by historiography figures of German Catholic social teaching (von as a pragmatic realist politician (Cau 2009, 431), Nell-Breuning, Gundlach) and ordoliberalism a governor interested in organising with little or (Röpke and Rüstow) met secretly in a hotel in no stake in ideology or doctrine. De Gasperi was Augsburg to discuss whether the social Catho- partly keen on presenting himself in this way. lics could be won over for the term “social market He said, in preparation of the Christian Demo- economy” that the ordoliberal Alfred Müller- cratic Congress in 1949, “He [Giuseppe Dosetti] Armack had coined. One of the participants had been getting ready for this congress for many later commented that this was an extremely deli- months … in thoughtful analysis … Unfortu- cate meeting (Emunds 2010: 1-2). It had to be nately, I have not had so much time, as I have had

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 86 Josef Hien to deal with practical tasks and constructive expe- oration with the Communist Party in the 1970s, riences” (cited in Cau 2009, 432). Newer historio- and was subsequently kidnapped and murdered graphic research shakes this picture, pointing to by the Brigate Rosse. Amintore Fanfani became the early formative experience of De Gasperi and prime minister in the 1960s and overhauled the his training as a Catholic sociologist and Catholic economy in a corporative fashion. Like every militant in (Pombeni and Nobili Schiera strong ideological group, the Dossetians had a 2009). In his early writings, De Gasperi empha- central journal, the Cronache Sociali. Its contribu- sised the centrality of the Catholic corporatism tions were inspired and impressed by the labour of the Quadragesimo Anno and its connection to victory in Britain, and by Keynes’ and Beveridges’ the personalist concepts of Emmanuel Mounier political economic ideas of re-organisation. The and Heinrich Pesch. The independence of organ- first programmatic party manifesto of the DC isations was “a natural consequence of personal developed during a series of clandestine meet- freedom” since they were “natural organs of civil ings that rotated around the homes of several of society” (Cau 2009, 441). While De Gasperi and its founding members during 1942 and the first Konrad Adenauer were similar regarding the months of 1943 also bore a strong imprint of compromisability of ideological positions for their the Catholic left. Copies were secretly diffused political ambitions, the Italian Catholic left was throughout Italy during the German occupation. arguably much more than its German The manifesto is signed with one of De Gaspa- counterpart. ri’s pseudonyms, but was the result of extensive To the left of De Gasperi stood the “profes- collaboration of the wings or factions (correnti) of sorini” (young professors) or “dossetians”, who the whole party [the DC] (Masala 2004, 106). The were recruited from a circle of young university programme incorporated a detailed plan for the researchers around Dossetti – a professor and future institutional framework of the new Italian social philosopher at the Catholic University of state, and also featured prescriptions for industrial Milan. Two other central figures in his faction relations and a detailed social policy agenda. were Giorgio La Pira, who later became mayor The programme tried to walk the typical Chris- of Florence, and Giuseppe Lazzati, who became tian Democratic line between calls for the rector of the Catholic University of Milan (Masala nationalisation of key industries and the impor- 2004, 101). Dossetti’s social thinking drew heavily tance of private entrepreneurship. However, on personalism inspired by the French Emmanuel the programme had a strong Christian Socialist Mounier’s or Jacques Maritain’s philosophy of leaning inspired through the Encyclical Quadragn- Christian Democracy (Müller 86). Like Pesch’s esimo Anno. Moreover, the existence of the largest and Oswald von Nell-Breuning’s personalism in communist party outside of the Soviet Union in Germany, the emphasis was more on the view Italy created a stronger drift of party competition that “the human personality unfolds through towards left-wing socio-economic issues (Ferrera organic belonging to the successive communities” 1984, 1986). Fighting fire with fire, the Christian (La Pira cited in Acanfors 2007, 312). In contrast Democrats had to propose strong social ideas to De Gasperi’s insistence on interclassism and to curb the influence of the Communist party mediation, which bears relics of the conservative (PCI). The most remarkable prescription of the Austrian Catholic Vogelsangian thought, it aimed programme is for the establishment of two parlia- at getting rid of classes all together. mentary chambers, of which one would be elected Dossetti’s followers had a long-lasting influence while the other would serve as a forum for corpo- on Italian Christian Democracy and Italian post- ratist-interest representation (Manow 2015). This war institutions. His student Aldo Moro engi- “assembly of the organized interests” (DC 1943, neered the compromesso storico, the first collab- 1) should be “founded foremost on the elected

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 87 Josef Hien representatives of the organized professions”. a leftist reformer for whom, in the words of the (DC 1943, 1) This represented an almost word for leader of the Catholic union wing of the party in word incorporation of the provisions of the social 1952, “the battle of the DC has to be fought, […], encyclical Quadragesimo Anno into the Christian on the territory of social justice, on the recogni- Democratic program. The concept was one of a tion of the new rights of the new status of work” “liberal Christian idea of a free organic collabo- (Gronchi cited in Vecchio 1978, 182). Gronchi and ration of all means of production” (DC 1943, 2). his union wing pressed for comprehensive social In line with the provisions of Quadragesimo Anno, policy programme and the integration of the lower the State should be confined to a role of “vigi- classes as “resistance to Bolshevism, in doctrine lance” (DC 1943, 2) that guarantees the func- as well as in the social political regime, does not tioning of the neo-corporatist model. Regarding compensate for blocking the working classes in the issue of social security, the program spelled their aspirations for more justice” (Gronchi cited out that “social insurance should be extended, in Vecchio, 181). These thoughts were not mere simplified, its organization decentralized and its lip service. Under the leadership of Fanfani, the management put into the hands of the people that party’s left wing, with its connections to farm it concerned“(DC 1943, 2) reflecting the subsid- leagues and Catholic unions, gained consider- iarity clauses of Quadragesimo Anno. In Germany, able strength within the party. Fanfani wanted to such corporatist positions can only be found in compensate for the organisational agony of the DC the Ahlen programme or manifesto of the CDU, under De Gasperi. As a contemporary fellow party an internal concession to the left-Catholic party member observed, they were convinced that “if wing on the part of Adneauer in the 1940s, which the absolute majority had not been reached in the was quickly quashed and replaced by the Protes- country, it was partly the fault of the DC, due to its tant liberal conservative Düsseldorfer Leitsätze organizational insufficiencies, the scarce compre- in 1949. Another difference between Italian and hensive penetration of the various social classes, German social Catholicism was that the DC could […], its complicated and tired apparatus” (Boiardi count on the backing of a strong Catholic union cited in Galli 1978, 161). Fanfani foresaw for the movement (“Gronchians” headed by Giovanni DC a much more active role in the penetration of Gronchi, the influential union leader), while, in society than under De Gasperi. Fanfani’s view was Germany, the Catholic unions were subsumed that the party should not only be a transmission under the roof of the Deutscher Gewerkschafts- belt and interlocutor between state and society, bund and pulled into the orbit of the Social Demo- but that it should also actively influence and model crats (Schroeder 1992). both institutions. Fanfani was convinced that the party had to liberate itself from the Vatican and 3. The Impact of Catholic from Confindustria (the Italian employers asso- and Protestant Doctrines on ciation). His vision was of a modern mass party Politics and Institutional firmly anchored on the territory and all-encom- Set-up of both Economies passing in its aspirations to the electorate. Fanfani started with the countryside by ordering Under De Gasperi the Catholic left remained Paolo Bononi to build up a dense network of rural contained and the socio-economic policy was savings banks and peasant leagues, the so-called dominated by the liberal linea Einaudi, but, once Coldiretti. They not only gave out loans to farmers De Gasperi resigned, the Christian Socialist Amin- but also became a strong interest group or faction tore Fanfani became the leading figure of the party. within the DC (Ginsborg 1990, 171). In order to Corporatism started to be re-instated wholesale. anchor in the urban areas, Fanfani promoted the Fanfani, a student and follower of Dossetti, was expansion of a huge network of Christian Demo-

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 88 Josef Hien cratic circoli (social organisations), which usually The party also had to simultaneously distance itself consisted of a venue with an alcohol licence in the from the liberal employer’s association, Confin- centre of the town or neighbourhood in which dustria, in order to increase its financial autonomy Catholic workers could gather. At the end of the (Galli 1978, 72). The prime means for this were 1950s, these ACLI (Associazioni Cristiane dei the creation of the Ministry of State Holdings Lavoratori Italiani) circoli boasted over one million (Ministro delle partecipazioni statali), which was members. Many of them still exist to this day, even approved by parliament after prolonged and fierce though the DC is long gone. In order to acquire debate on 22 December 1956. One year later, on more members, Fanfani initiated large-scale 11 January 1957, the law on fossils (legge idro- membership subscription campaigns that were carburi) followed, which gave the state company held in festival-like atmospheres in which prizes ENI (Ente Nazionale Idrocarburi) a monopoly were handed out for inscription. These yearly on research and exploitation in this sector. The canvassing campaigns increased the membership strategy to curb the power of business over the of the DC from 1,341,000 in 1955 to 1,377,286 in party, and society in general, was completed by 1956, and boosted it to 1,400,179 in 1958. This the withdrawal of all IRI (Instituto per la Ricon- went hand in hand with a shift of the socioeco- struzione Italiana – a large state holding) compa- nomic background of the DC members in favour nies from Confindustria only a year later on 1 of working-class members. Between 1955 and January 1958. Galli notes that, from this point on, 1959, the proportion of members coming from “the party that used to be the prince of the indus- the working and lower middle classes increased trial complex controlled progressively the means from 52.2 per cent to 56.7 per cent (Galli 1978, of production, which are the source of true power” 178). The figures added up in the following way: (Galli 1978, 180). ENI, a huge oil and gas company the presence of workers increased from 19 per founded in 1953, is exemplary of this process. The cent to 21 per cent, while landless farm labourers Christian Democrat Enrico Mattei “a man of few accounted for 6.8 per cent, as opposed to 6 per cent. principles and great entrepreneurial skill” (Gins- This saw the share of working-class members rise borg) became its restless president. Starting with from one quarter to 28 per cent (Galli 1978, 178). the state petrol company AGIP, Mattei built up an Though these figures do not display a substantial industrial empire in the state sector that, within increase on their own, they do when one takes the a few years, encompassed business sectors as family dimension of Italian society into account. diverse as petrochemicals, motorway construc- Galli notes that “the DC of Fanfani started to gain tion, synthetic rubber production, contract engi- control over the electorate independent from the neering, construction and nuclear research (Gins- institutions of the bourgeoisie” (Galli 1978, 178). borg 1990, 164-165). Despite the rampant clien- Fanfani was a fervent exponent of the Catholic telism and often corrupt practices within ENI, it left, but, at the same time, he had sympathised contributed – together with IRI, the second large with fascism and had held some minor offices state holding – as a key driver of Italy’s post-war during fascism. His interpretation of Catholic economic miracle. The flipside of this success Socialism sometimes blurred the lines to fascist was that it tightened the state’s, and therefore corporatist organisation of society. By contrast, the party’s, grip on society and created a class of German Catholicism was pulled in a liberal direc- politico-economic Christian Democratic barons tion by the ordoliberals and Protestants after of whom it became increasingly hard to judge World War Two, and therefore away from stronger whether their motivations were fuelled by left corporative thinking. The new corporatist strategy Catholic ideology or pure rent-seeking for them- entailed that the DC tightened its grip over the selves and their party fraction (corrente). existing state entities and even created new ones. Fanfani had intended to build a party with elec-

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 89 Josef Hien toral ties that were independent of the Vatican, contributed immensely to Adenauer’s landslide the allies and Confindustria. He wanted to do this victory in the next election. 1957 was not only the with a strong left corporatist program. But, owing year of Adenauer’s big pension reform but was, at to Italy’s regional disparities, this played out in the same time, also the “Conceptual final stroke of different ways in different parts of the country. the social market economy” (Schulz cited in Conze While the North saw the construction of a strong 2009, 169). As a compensation, an “interconfes- Christian Democratic subculture based upon sional compromise” (Manow 2001), the core ordo- a Christian Democratic worldview, the South liberal projects of an independent federal central witnessed the establishing of a gigantic clientelist bank (Bundesbank) and the Cartel Law, which led party machine. The party was Catholic-Christian to the formation of an independent Cartel Agency, Democratic in the North and clientelist-corrupt in were finally enacted. 1957 was also the endpoint of the South. In the same way, some of the large state another often unnoticed struggle between ordo- holdings became synonymous with the rampant liberal Protestants and Social Catholics: the intro- favouritism and clientelism of the DC. The special duction of a corporatist interest mediation insti- blend of corporatism that Fanfani had elabo- tution (Bundeswirtschaftsrat). It was to guarantee rated in his 1948 book Economia (Fanfani 1948) a democratisation of the economy by establishing was too vulnerable to corruption and clientelism. a second forum for interest representation from The transformation of the DC under Fanfani into capital and labour next to parliament as foreseen a corporatist party was, especially in the South, in Quadragesimo Anno. This idea was pushed by coupled with a drifting towards a clientelist party. the unions and social Catholics, but was heavily In the Italian case, the initial social Catholic moti- opposed by the ordoliberals. Ludwig Erhard (ordo- vations for a specific and distinctive model of liberal, Protestant, Minister of the Economy and corporatist capitalism were, after the 1960s, grad- later Chancellor) could not fully erase the plans, ually replaced by vote- and rent-seeking interests. but he managed to postpone and transform them. However, ideology and interests re-enforced one Seven years later and seven legislative proposals another in the Italian model for spoils distribu- later, the result was the establishing of an expert tion and contributed both to its stability and to the committee that is still of central importance in difficulties to reform it right up to the present day German economic affairs today. It is dubbed the and the Eurocrisis. Council of the Five Sages of the Economy (fünf Wirtschaftsweise) and has - ever since its estab- In Germany, too, the Christian Democratic left lishment - been a hotbed of ordoliberal economic also left its mark on the early set-up of institutions, expertise that counsels the federal government but, due to the balancing effect between ordoliberal on matters of political economy. Hence, the Protestants and social Catholics, the outcome was re-instalment of German socio-economic insti- much less corporatist than in Italy. Social Catho- tutions in the 1950s and 1960s was heavily influ- lics in Germany also had the upper hand but only enced by social Catholic ideas but it did not lead as long as their subculture and political connec- to a wholesale influence of Catholic corporatism tions remained strong. The re-instalment of the ideology due to the counterweight of the ordolib- German Bismarckian welfare state was a key social eral faction within the CDU. On the other hand, Catholic project. The pension reform of 1957 was central elements of the German socio-economic an enormous popular success. The ordoliberals system never had any ordoliberal imprint. The fought it where they could but were defeated. A anti-ordoliberal huge welfare state and the large public opinion survey from the Allensbach Insti- amount of co-ordination within Germany’s organ- tute found that Germans ranked it as the “Most ised capitalism which was further re-inforced popular event in the eight year long history of the during the Keynesian episodes under the Social Federal Republic”. (Conze 2009, 169). The reform

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 90 Josef Hien Democratic regimes of the 1970s and only came the eve of re-unification (Pollack and Pickel 2003). to an end with the stagflation crisis in the late West Germany, until re-unification, experienced 1970s (Scharpf 1991). However, after the stagfla- only a slight drop in church affiliation (though tion crisis, Germany slowly began to embark on a church attendance dropped remarkably). In 1987, reform trajectory inspired by ordoliberal Protes- 42.9 per cent were Catholic, while Protestants tant ideology. This process, which picked up speed became a minority for the first time with a drop but met much resistance from a still strong social to 41.6 per cent. The number of unaffiliated had Catholic wing within the CDU, was accelerated risen from 3.6 per cent in 1950 to 11.4 per cent in with German re-unification. 1987 (FOWID 2011). Through the strong decrease Re-unification brought huge economic problems. in church affiliation in the East, re-unification During the 1990s, Germany underwent the trans- boosted the “non-members of a statuary religious formation from being regarded as the strong man corporation”, as the census of 2011 put it, to 33 per to being regarded as the sick one. This was the cent in the same year. member- chance for an ordoliberal comeback. The neolib- ship sank to 31 per cent of the population and eral reform agenda, with its emphasis on deep Protestant church membership to 30.8 per cent. welfare cuts, privatisation, equal starting condi- Social Catholicism had already lost much of its tions, the individualisation of social risks and political clout in the Christian Democratic Party equality of opportunity, came against the back- in the 1980s when the Christian Democratic drop of skyrocketing unemployment, debt, and Employees’ Association (Sozialausschüsse) lost sluggish economic growth. This made it ever the both members and influence. Angela Merkel, more politically attractive. Reunification also the East German daughter of a Protestant Priest, opened an enormous practical laboratory for neo- became the symbol of the (neo-) Protestantisation liberal politics. Approximately 14,600 formerly of the German Christian Democrats, a party that state-owned companies with 4 million employees had, for most of its post-WWII history, been more together with 2.4 billion hectares of land and a Catholic than Protestant in its programme, its huge public housing stock were to be privatised membership and its electorate. Norbert Blüm, the according to the “principles of the social market last prominent “heart-Jesus-Marxist” (Herz-Jesu- economy” (§2 Treuhandgesetz). However, these Marxist), ended his last term as welfare minister “principles of the social market economy” were in 1998 and was hissed at the party congress at now interpreted as being more liberal than ever Leipzig in 2003 for his critique of the new neolib- before. In addition, re-unification altered the elec- eral party programme (Zeit 2003). The Protestant toral map of Germany. With the addition of the Finance Minister Wolfgang Schäuble became the Eastern states, 16 million citizens from a Protes- equivalent of a re-strengthened ordoliberalist. tant cultural background joined the German elec- This enabled a series of welfare reforms in the torate and decreased the importance of the Cath- 1990s, and later the famous Agenda 2010, which olic vote for the Christian Democratic Party (Hien was hammered out by the Red/Green coalition 2013). under Chancellor Schröder, but was espoused and After German partition, West Germany (FDR) passed with the votes of the Christian Democratic became 45.8 per cent Catholic and 50.6 per cent Party. Chancellor Merkel stated the following when Protestant. In (GDR), the 1950 assuming office in 2005: “I want to thank Chan- census showed 85 per cent Protestants and 10 cellor Schröder personally for bravely opening a percent Catholics. Through a strong policy of door with the Agenda 2010” (Merkel, 2005). This de-Christianisation, the GDR brought these was the “homework” that Germany demanded figures down to 25 per cent Protestants, 5 per cent from the crisis countries in exchange for fiscal soli- Catholics and 70 per cent unaffiliated in 1989 on darity. Due to the mono-confessional situation of

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 91 Josef Hien Italy, a similar reform process and trajectory never happened, and this is the key to understanding the sharp divergence in the positions of the two econ- omies. Even after the implosion of the DC in the early 1990s under the impact of heavy corruption scandals, the Catholic Church has not ceased to be an influential variable in Italian politics. Some even argue that, without the DC as interlocutor, it has become even stronger. It is very hard to reform the Italian political economy from the outside, as most Northern Protestant countries in the Euro- zone demand, because it is anchored so strongly in the cultural background of the country. A cultural background that is composed of ideas, interests and institutions that have, over the past 60 years, formed a very dense amalgam. Social Catholic ideas are loaded with interests since the clien- telist ties of vote aggregation in Southern Italy not only survived the dissolution of the DC but were inherited and incorporated by Silvio Berlusconi’s “descent” into politics (discesa in campo).

4. Conclusion

The Euro crisis has now been dragging on for almost a decade. The fixing and emergency measures have not led to an easing of European relations, but have infuriated the European public, putting Northern populations against Southern ones. A look at the tabloids suffices. The powerful German tabloid Bild headlines read: “This is how the Greek Cheated us”, “Why do we Pay for Greek Luxury Pensions” and “Go Sell your Islands, you Bank- rupt Greeks” (Bild 2010c; Bild 2010a; Bild 2010b). The approach of cultural political economy to the European crisis taken here suggests that there are no “quick fixes” to be expected through structural reforms. Instead, it has shown how political econ- omies like the German and Italian ones evolved over almost a century, and that institutions, ideas and interests interacted in setting their pathways providing a highly durable complex of relations that are hard to break up, especially from the outside.

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 92 Josef Hien References ments have now also been acknowledged by the celebrities of the Varities of Capitalism Abelshauser, W. (2003): Kulturkampf: Der deutsche approach. Weg in die Neue Wirtschaft und die ameri- Baccaro, L., and C. Howell (2017): Trajecto- kanische Herausforderung, Berlin: Kadmos. ries of Neoliberal Transformation. Cambridge: Abelshauser, W., D. Gilgen and A. Leutzsch (eds) Cambridge University Press. (2013): Kulturen der Weltwirtschaft, Göttingen: Berman, S. (1998): The Social Democratic Moment: Vandenhoek und Ruprecht. Ideas and Politics in the Making of Interwar Acanfora, Paolo (2007): “Myths and the Polit- Europe. Cambridge MA: Harvard University ical Use of Religion in Christian Democratic Press. Culture”, Journal of Modern Italian Studies, 12 Berman, S. (2006): The Primacy of Politics: Social (3): 307-338. Democracy and the Making of Europe’s Twen- Bruno A. (2017): “Dirigisme and Modernism vs tieth Century, New York, Cambridge Univer- Ordoliberalism”, in: Josef Hien and Christian sity Press. Joerges (eds.), Ordoliberalism, Law and the Rule Best, J., and M. Paterson (2015): “Towards a of Economics, Oxford: Hart Publishing. Cultural Political Economy – Not a Cultural Armingeon, K., and L. Baccaro (2014): “The Crisis IPE”, Millenium: Journal of International and Germany: The Trading State Unleashed”, Studies, 43(2): 738-740. in: B. Eberlein and V. Schneider (eds), Complex Bild (2010a): “Geheimakte Griechenland: Wie Democracy. Varieties, Crisis, and Transforma- Athen Sich Den Euro Erschwindelte”, BILD.de./0 tions, Wiesbaden: Springer VS, 165-184. Available at: http://www.bild.de/politik/2010/ Armingeon, K., K. Guthmann and D. Weisstanner griechenland-krise/geheimakte-wie-die- (2015): “How the Euro Divides the Union: The griechen-in-den-euro-kamen-14462666.bild. Effect of Economic Adjustment on Support for html. Democracy in Europe”, Socio-Economic Review, Bild (2010b): ‘Griechenland-Pleite: Warum 14 (1): 1 26. Zahlen Wir Ihre Luxus-Renten Mit Milliarden- Baccaro, L., and C. Howell (2011): “A Common Hilfe?’, BILD.de,/0 27/04/2010. Available Neoliberal Trajectory: The Transformation of at: http://www.bild.de/politik/wirtschaft/ Industrial Relations in Advanced ”, wir-zahlen-luxus-rente-mit-milliarden- Politics & Society, 39 (4): 521-563. hilfe-12338430.bild.html. Baccaro, L., and J. Pontusson (2016): Rethinking Bild (2010c): “Griechenland: Verkauft Doch Eure Comparative Political Economy: The Growth Inseln, Ihr Pleite-Griechen! – Wirtschaft – Model Perspective”, Politics & Society, 44 (2): Bild.de”,BILD.de, 27/10/2010./0 Available at: 175-207. http://www.bild.de/politik/wirtschaft/griech- Baccaro, L., and C. Howell (2017): “Unhinged: enland-krise/regierungathen-sparen-verkauft- Industrial Relations Liberalization and Capi- inseln-pleite-akropolis-11692338.bild.html. talist Instability”, MPIfG Discussion Paper Blyth, M. (2003): “Structures do not Come with an 17/19 Instruction Sheet: Interests, Ideas, and Progress Baccaro, L., and C. Benassi (2017): “Throwing out in Political Science”, PS: Political Science and the Ballast: Growth Models and the Liberal- Politics, 1 (4): 695-706. ization of German Industrial ”elations”, Socio- Blyth, M. (2013): Austerity: The History of A Economic Review, 15 (1): 85-115. The advance- Dangerous Idea, Oxford: Oxford University

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 93 Josef Hien Press. Estevez-Abe, M., T. Iversen and D. Soskice (2001); Blyth, M., and M. Matthijs (2018): “Black Swans, “Social Protection and the Formation of Skills: A Lame Ducks, and the mystery of IPE’s Missing Reinterpretation of theWelfare State”, in: P. Hall Macroeconomy”, Review of Political Economy, and D. Soskice (eds), Varieties of Capitalism: 24 (2): 203-231. The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Cambridge, Cambridge University Brunnermeier, M., H. James and J.-P. Landau Press, pp. 145-183. (2016): The Euro and the Battle of Ideas. Princ- eton NJ: Princeton University Press. Falcke, H. (2011): “Welche Ansätze Für Eine Wirtschaftsethik finden wir bei Dietrich Carstensen, M., and V. Schmidt (2016): “Power Bonhoeffer?”, Evangelische Theologie, 71: through, over and in Ideas: Conceptualizing 376-95. Ideational Power in Discursive Institution- alism”, Journal of European Public Policy, 23 (3): Fanfani, A. (1948): Economia, Brescia: Morcel- 318-337. liana. Cau, Maurizio (2009): “Alcide De Gasperi: A Polit- Ferrera, M. (1984): Il welfare state in Italia. Sviluppo ical Thinker or a Thinking Politician?”, Modern e crisi in prospettiva comparata, Bologna: Il Italy, 14 (4): 431-444, at 441. Mulino. Conze, E. (2009): Die Suche nach Sicherheit, Ferrera, M. (1986): “Italy”, in: P. Flora (ed), Growth , Siedler Verlag. to Limits: The Western European Welfare States Since World War II, Volume 2, Germany, United DC (1943): Le Idee Ricostruttive della Democrazia Kingdom, Ireland, Italy, Berlin, Walter de Cristiana, Rome. Gruyter. Dyson, K. (2014): States, Debt and Power, Oxford: Ferrera, M. (2017), “The Stein Rokkan Lecture 2016 Oxford University Press. Mission Impossible? Reconciling Economic Dyson, K. (2017): “Ordoliberalism as Tradition and Social Europe after the Eurocrisis and and as Ideology”, in: J. Hien and C. Joerges (eds), Brexit”, European Journal of Political Research, Ordoliberalism, Law and the Rule of Economics, 56: 3-22. doi:10.1111/1475-6765.12185 Oxford: Hart Publishing. Ferrera, M. (2018): “Mass Democracy, the Welfare Economist (2015): “German Ordoliberalism has State and European Integration: A Neo-Webe- Had a Big Influence on Policy-making during rian Analysis,” European Journal of Social the Euro Crisis”, Economist, 9 May 2015. Theory, First Published July 3, 2018 https://doi. org/10.1177/1368431018779176 Eucken, W. (1949): Die Sozialpolitische Frage, Heidelberg, Weber. Financial Times (2014): “The Wacky Economics of Germany’s Parallel Universe”, by Wolfgang Eucken, W. (1932 [1997]): “Staatliche Struk- Munchau, 16 November 2014. turwandlungen und die Krisis des Kapital- ismus”, ORDO: Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von FOWID: “Religionszugehörigkeit Bevölkerung Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 48: 5-25. 1970-2011”, available at: https://fowid.de/ meldung/entwicklung-religionszugehoerig- Esch, Femke van, and Eelke de Jong (2017): keiten-nach-bundeslaendern-1950-2011. “National Culture Trumps EU Socialization: The European Central Bankers’ Views of the Galli, G. (1978): Storia Della Democrazia Cris- Euro Crisis”, Journal of European Public Policy, tiana, Bari: Laterza. DOI: 10.1080/13501763.2017.1391862 Ginsborg, P. (1990): A History of Contemporary

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 94 Josef Hien Italy, London: Penguin Books. und Gesellschaft, 1: 49-58, at 11, 13. Goldschmidt, N. (1997): “Die Entstehung Jessop, B. (2004): “Critical Semiotic Analysis and der Freiburger Kreise”, Historisch-Poli- Cultural Political Economy”, Critical Discourse tische Mitteilungen: Archiv für Christlich- Studies, 1 (2): 159-174. Demokratische Politik, 1-17. Jessop, B., and N.-L. Sum (2017): “Putting the Hassel, A. (2017): No way to escape imbalances Amsterdam School in its Righful Place: A Reply in the Eurozone? Three Sources for Germa- to Juan Ignacio Staricco’s Critique of Cultural ny’s Export Dependency: Industrial Rela- Political Economy”, New Political Economy, 22 tions, Social Insurance and Fiscal Federalism”, (3): 342-354. German Politics, 26 (3): 260-379. Lindvall, J. (2006). “The Politics of Purpose: Hall, P. (2014): “Varieties of Capitalism and the Swedish Economic Policy after the Golden Euro Crisis”, West European Politics, 37 (6): A g e”, Comparative Politics, 38 (3): 253-272. 1223-1243. Johnston, A., and A. Regan (2016): “European Hien, J. (2012): “Competing Ideas the Religious Monetary Integration and the Incompatibility Foundations of the German and Italian Welfare of National Varieties of Capitalism”, Journal of States”, Florence: Cadmus, European Univer- Common Market Studies, 54 (2): 1-19, 318-336. sity Institute. Johnston, A., and A. Regan (2018): “Introduction: Hien, J. (2013): “The Ordoliberalism that Never Is the European Union Capable of Intergating was”, Contemporary Political Theory, 12 (4): Diverse Models oif Capitalism?”, New Political 349-358. Economy, 23 (2): 145-159. Hien, J. (2017): “The Religious Roots of the Kaufmann, F.-X. (2003): Sozialpolitisches Denken. European Crisis”, Journal of Common Market Frankfurt aM: Suhrkamp. Studies. Early View http://onlinelibrary.wiley. Lenel, H.O. (1991): “Walter Eucken’s Briefe an com/doi/10.1111/jcms.12635/abstract. Alexander Rüstow”, ORDO: Jahrbuch für die Hien, J., and C. Joerges (eds)(2017), Ordoliber- Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 42: alism, Law and the Rule of Economics, Oxford 11-14, at 12. and Portland OR: Hart Publishing. Masala, C. (2004): “Born for Government: The Hien, J., and C. Joerges (2018): “Dead Man Democrazia Cristiana in Italy”, in: M. Gehler Walking? Current European Interest in Germa- and W. Kaiser (eds), Christian Democracy in ny’s Ordoliberal Tradition”, European Law Europe since 1945, Volume 2, London: Rout- Journal. Early view https://doi.org/10.1111/ ledge. eulj.12277. Manow, P. (2001): “Ordoliberalismus als ökono- Höppner, M., and M. Lutter (2017): “The Diver- mische Ordnungstheologie”, Leviathan, 29: sity of Wage Regimes: Why the Eurozone is too 179-98. Heterogeneous for the Euro”, European Political Manow, Philip, (2015): “Workers, Farmers and Science Review, 10 (1): 71-96. Catholicism: A History of Political Class Coali- Invernizzi-Accetti, C. (2019): What is Christian tions and the South-European Welfare State Democracy? The Forgotten Ideology, Cambridge; Regime”, Journal of European Social Policy, 25 Cambridge University Press. (1): 32-49, doi:10.1177/0958928714556969 Jähnichen, T. (2010): “Die Protestantischen Müller-Armack, A. (1947): Wirtschaftslenkung Wurzeln der Sozialen Marktwirtschaft”, Ethik und Marktwirtschaft, Hamburg: pub house.

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 95 Josef Hien Nedergaard, P., and H. Snaith (2015): “‘As I A Critical Engagement with Cultural Polit- Drifted on a River I could not Control’: The ical Economy”, New Political Economy, 22 (3): Unintended Ordoliberal Consequences of the 328-341. Eurozone Crisis”, Journal of Common Market Sreeck, W. (2005): “Requirements for a useful Studies, 53: 1094-1109. Concept of Complementarity”, in: C. Crouch, Perez, S.A., and M. Matsaganis (2018): “The Polit- W. Streeck, R. Boyer, B. Amable, P.A. Hall ical Economy of Austerity in Southern Europe,” and G. Jackson, “Dialogue on ‘Institutional New Political Economy, (23 (2): 192-207, DOI: Complementarities and Political Economy’”, 10.1080/13563467.2017.1370445. Socio Economic Review, 3 (2): 359-382. Petersen, T. (2008): “Die Sozialethik Emil Brun- Streeck W. (2009): Re-Forming Capitalism: Institu- ners und ihre Neoliberale Rezeption”, HWWI tional Change in the German Political Economy, Research Paper No. 5-6, 1-27. Oxford, Oxford University Press. Pollack, Detlef, and Pickel Gert, (2003): “De-insti- Streeck, W. (2013): “The Politics of Public Debt: tutionalization of Religion and Religious Neoliberalism, Capitalist Development and the Individualization in Eastern and Western Restructuring of the State”, German Economic Germany”, KZfSS Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziol- Review, 15 (1): 143-165. ogie und Sozialpsychologie, 55 ( 3): 447-74. Streeck, W. (2016): “Commentary on Lucio Pombeni, Paolo, and Giuliana Nobili Schiera Baccaro and Jonas Pontusson, ‘Rethinking (2009): “Alcide De Gasperi: 1881-1954-A Polit- Comparative Political Economy: The Growth ical Life in a Troubled Century”, Modern Italy, Model Perspective’”, Politics & Society, 44 (2): 14 (4): 379-397. 175-207. Pontusson, J., and D. Weisstanner (2018): “Macro- Sum, N.-L., and B. Jessop (2013): “Towards a economic Conditions, Inequality Shocks and Cultural Political Economy: Putting Culture in the Politics of Redistribution, 1990—2013”, its Place in Political Economy”, Cheltenham: Journal of European Public Policy, 25 (1): 31-58, Edward Elgar. Reuter, H.-P. (2010): “Vier Anmerkungen zu Philip Svallfors, S. (2016): “Politics as Organised Combat Manow‚ “Die Soziale Marktwirtschaft als inter- – New Players and New Rules of the Game konfessioneller Kompromiss? Ein Re-State- in Sweden”, New Political Economy, 21 (6): ment”, Ethik und Gesellschaft, 1: 1-22. 505-519. Röpke, W. (1949): Civitas humana : Grundfragen Svallfors, S., and A. Tyllström (2018), “Resilient der Gesellschafts- und Wirtschaftsreform, 3rd Privatization: The Puzzling Case of For-profit ed., Erlenbach-Zürich: pub house. Welfare Providers in Sweden”, Socio Economic Schroeder, W. (1992): Katholizismus und Einheits- Review, Early View. https://doi.org/10.1093/ gewerkschaft. Der Streit um den DGB und der ser/mwy005. Niedergang des Sozialkatholizismus in der Swedberg, R., and O. Agevall (2005): The Max Bundesrepublik bis 1960, Reihe: Politik- und Weber Dictionary, Stanford CA: Stanford Gesellschaftsgeschichte. Band 30. Bonn: Dietz University Press. Verlag. Thelen, K. (2015): Producer Coalitions and Smith, Philip (2001): Cultural Theory: An Intro- National Growth Strategies (paper presented at duction, Malden MA: Blackwell. the 22nd International Conference of Europe- Stariccio, J.I. (2017): “Putting Culture in its Place? anists, Paris, 8-10 July 2015).

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 96 Josef Hien Quadragesimo Anno, Pius XI, (1931): available at: http://w2.vatican.va/content/pius-xi/en/encyc- licals/documents/hf_p-xi_enc_19310515_ quadragesimo-anno.html, 75, last accessed 22 August 2017. Vecchio, G. (1979): La democrazia Christiana in Europa (1891-1963), Milan, Mursia. Weber, M. (1904) “Die ‘Objektivität’ sozialwissen- schaftlicher und Sozialpolitischer Erkenntnis”, Archiv für Sozialwissenschaften und Sozialpo- litik, 19 (1): 22-87. Weber, M. (1968): Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, New York: Bedminster Press. Zeit (2003): “Blüms Erben: Kulturkampf in der CDU”, available at: http://www.zeit.de/2003/43/ CDA

A CULTURAL POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO THE EUROPEAN CRISIS 97 Josef Hien B SECTORS OF THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF ITALY AND GERMANY WORLDS APART: Just when Germany’s mortgage debt started to THE DIVERGENCE OF decline seriously in the year 2000, the Italian one began to rise steeply and similar trends can SOUTHERN-EUROPEAN be observed in house prices. At the same time, HOUSING-CONSTRUCTION German export surpluses began to grow to ECONOMIES AND NORTHERN- unprecedented levels, while mortgage- and wage- EUROPEAN EXPORT repressed domestic demand left the housing and construction sector starving. Not surprisingly, ECONOMIES we find a negative cross-sectional association between the importance of exports and construc- Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau tion in OECD countries from the 1980s onwards. Max Planck Institute for Studies of Societies As we argue in the discussion, construction- and Introduction export-driven economies require systematically different macroeconomic conditions. Construc- In both public debates about the economic hetero- tion, for instance, thrives with low interest rates, geneity of Southern and Northern European econ- higher inflation, and relies almost exclusively omies - and especially the Italian and German ones on wage-driven domestic demand. Conversely, - as well as in Comparative Political Economy, the exports require stable inflation and, if possible, construction sector and housing construction in undervalued real exchange rates. For Germany, particular are rarely debated topics. This contrasts exports became cheaper due to its wage repres- with their overall economic importance and the sion. One the one hand, the inclusion of structur- important cross-country differences in housing ally heterogeneous economies in one monetary construction. Our contribution argues in favour union could therefore be seen as problematical, as of taking this “forgotten sector” seriously in Polit- macroeconomic policies cannot address contra- ical Economy, in which manufacturing or finance, dictory demands. On the other hand, it could also as of late, have been the predominant focus. be an insurance-mechanism, as construction cycle However, lessons learned in these sectors have downturns are no longer as correlated between hardly been transferred to construction, with its countries as they were previously. different sectoral logics. 1. Construction: A Neglected We therefore show how Germany and Italy - and Core Component of Advanced Southern Europe more generally - have moved along different housing and construction trajec- Capitalist Economies tories over the last decades. Italy became a high- In the shadow of economic sectors as predom- homeownership country with initially low mort- inant as manufacturing, finance, and various gage debt, while Germany remained a country of services-sector branches, contemporary Political tenants with initially high mortgage-debt levels and Economy has neglected core components of capi- a declining trend since then. Germany maintained talist economies. Among those sectors left behind, a large private rental market, whereas stronger the construction sector stands out not only with historical rent legislation eroded the Italian rental regard to its contribution to GDP, but also with market (Voigtländer 2009). Most notably, the regard to its contribution to employment (espe- end of the post-war construction cycle led to an cially for low- and medium-skilled workers). It, a-synchronisation of construction cycles in both moreover, contributes largely to the formation of countries. Germany was uniquely booming after the physical capital stock of modern economies, re-unification just as Italy’s construction boom even if its added-value contribution varies signifi- was about to take off, leaving Italy with surplus cantly across OECD economies. housing and Germany with housing shortages today.

WORLDS APART: THE DIVERGENCE OF SOUTHERN-EUROPE HOUSING-CONSTRUCTION ECONOMIES 99 AND NORTHERN-EUROPEAN EXPORT ECONOMIES Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau When we speak of construction, we distinguish it dwelling) product demands for mostly individual from the debates on housing and especially housing solutions in the form of made-to-order produc- finance which have gained overwhelming atten- tion. This reduces repeatability, mass-standardisa- tion since the dawn of the global financial crisis in tion, and thus continuous productivity increases 2007/08 (Schwartz and Seabrooke 2008b). These within the sector. Moreover, the multitude of debates usually discuss aspects of wider financiali- sites on which firms have to operate as well as the sation, such as the effects of financial (de-) regula- number of trades that are involved both within a tion, product developments in the financial sector firm as well as across construction projects create for the purpose of insurance, hedging, and specu- complex, industry-specific co-ordination prob- lation, as well as general macroeconomic steering lems. Furthermore, due to the close bond between actions to create GDP growth in a globalising producer and buyer, the mostly regional nature economy through capital attraction (Schwartz of the construction market, and the necessity to 2009, Fuller 2018). However, very few studies are form consortia and small companies which act actually interested in the real economy output as suppliers to these trades limit competition of activities in the housing sector, which should and customer diversification severely. Last, high accompany the rise of housing finance (Malpezzi capital requirements and the longevity of produc- and Maclennan 2001). tion processes create a high sensitivity to changes We want to stress the fundamental role of in the monetary, financial, and regulatory envi- construction for any governmental gross fixed ronment. capital formation. Since governments in advanced Consequently, the different sectoral logic also capitalist economies usually do not own factory promotes different macroeconomic repercussions. productions, they spend their investment neces- For reasons of space, we will focus only on two sarily not on machine goods,103 but largely on the macroeconomic policy aspects of construction production of infrastructure and (social) housing. activity. First, the construction sector serves as a They are thus the principal clients of the construc- kind of natural buffer to macroeconomic shocks. tion sector. The sector refers to all parts of an Due to its dominant role as an investment goods economy that are concerned with the construc- industry in conjunction with a higher general level tion, maintenance, and utilisation of buildings of volatility in investment compared to general and other structures (i.e., dwellings and infra- demand, the construction sector faces additional structure), and the adjustment and change of vulnerability to changes in the general economic building stock through construction activity. The climate. Thus, the severity that booms and slumps stock of dwellings matters not only with regard have on construction activity goes hand-in-hand to its absolute number, but also with regard to with a higher likelihood of adverse effects on the the level and development, that is, the cumulated industry during these business-cycle events. (building) assets as well as the residential capital In contrast to manufacturing, a loss of demand in stock (Rußig, Deutsch, and Spillner 1996, 12f., 104 the construction sector usually represents a severe Fleming 1988, Gornig and Michelsen 2017). short-term threat to the regional business models Yet, compared to other sectors, the construction of firms. On the one hand, although production sector shows certain industry-specific qualities. lasts, on average, over a longer period of time, One of these is that the nature of the (building/ the dependence on long-term finance represents a threat to payment and fulfilment of contractual 103 With the noticeable exception of car pools and military obligations both on the side of customers as well equipment. as on that of the construction firms itself. Hence, 104 The construction sector resembles not so much a singu- lar industry (in the narrow understanding), but rather a com- construction firms cannot simply “wait and see” plex sub-system of the economy due to its deep interlinkages during crises, but are under constant threat of with other sectors such as manufacturing for the production of insolvency despite full order books. On the other pre-manufactured steel or concrete parts.

WORLDS APART: THE DIVERGENCE OF SOUTHERN-EUROPE HOUSING-CONSTRUCTION ECONOMIES AND NORTHERN-EUROPEAN EXPORT ECONOMIES 100 Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau hand, a reduction in employment – which is some- tate a national strategy of export-orientation, it has thing necessary during times of reduced order to curtail both the inflationary effects of construc- numbers – is difficult to accomplish as a construc- tion activities as well as the overall size and contri- tion firm needs to retain various trades and skills bution of the sector itself. On the other hand, due in order to maintain its operational capacities. to its role for the active domestic macroeconomic This retention of excess labour capacities in this management, one can attribute the promotion of “populated” sector prevents the immediate severe construction activity to the domestic consump- increase of overall unemployment in an economy. tion-led growth model (Baccaro and Pontusson Only in the case of a lasting recession and further 2016). Since national housing and ownership reduced order numbers will small construction patterns vary significantly across OECD countries and specialised supply-trade firms face bank- for historical reasons (Kohl 2017), a government ruptcy and thus ramp up unemployment overall. is unable to change the general role of construc- Hence, the delay of unemployment due to the tion activity in the short term. For instance, a necessity to retain intra-firm skills makes the government that encourages property ownership sector a buffer for macroeconomic shocks and a relies on the availability and the provision of new bearer of significant adjustment costs of business- housing stock to make this model work. cycle downturns in general. Given the difference in the underlying monetary Second, the construction sector is a core playing- conditions as well as the importance that govern- field for governments wanting to engage in macro- ments attribute to construction, there is an overall, economic management, because a government’s distinguishable effect on the macroeconomic capacity to steer economic activity through invest- performance of an economy and, thus, poten- ment depends on its access to the sector. For one, tially on the development of macroeconomic it is the easiest way to increase overall economic imbalances. For the discussion about European activity. An activist government can use the sector macroeconomic imbalances, this means that the (in so far as labour capacity is available econ- construction sector is at the core of the origins of omy-wide) to enlarge positive employment and the North-South divide. growth. However, a government willing to enforce construction activity has to provide conducive 2. Diverging Housing and macroeconomic and monetary conditions (e.g., Construction Trajectories in lower capital costs and increased capital avail- Southern Europe and Germany ability in the domestic economy to be spent on housing and infrastructure). Yet, in so doing, it The differences in housing and construction faces negative consequences for the overall export between Southern and Northern Europe are not competitiveness which profits from quite different of recent origin. Traditionally, Southern Euro- conditions such as a comparably lower inflation pean housing and construction regimes have rate and unit labour cost developments (that result been characterised as distinct from Northern in an effective real exchange-rate under-valuation European countries, and, even internationally, with regard to trading partners). Hence, construc- have been exceptional along a variety of dimen- tion companies benefit from the opposite mone- sions (Castles and Ferrera 1996). First of all, all tary conditions than export-oriented manufac- Southern European countries have developed into turing firms. high-homeownership countries, comparable only to the completely privatised housing regimes of This, in turn, has consequences for the national Eastern Europe and largely surpassing even the growth strategies and the development of national traditional Anglo-Saxon high-homeownership housing regimes. If a government wishes to facili- countries (Stephens, Lux, and Sunega 2015). In

WORLDS APART: THE DIVERGENCE OF SOUTHERN-EUROPE HOUSING-CONSTRUCTION ECONOMIES AND NORTHERN-EUROPEAN EXPORT ECONOMIES 101 Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau the German-Italian comparison, the homeowner- had already taken place and Italy had become a ship gap amounts to 30 plus percentage points, as country of homeowners. shown in Figure 1. A second dimension is the kind of homeown- Figure 1: Homeownership rates in Germany and ership which has mostly grown in the form Southern Europe of condominium or apartment ownership in Southern European coun- tries. Legal arrangements of privately owning parts of a building on the same plot of land were absent in German Civil Code between 1901 and 1951. Aft er being legally intro- duced, owner-occupied fl ats remained a very exceptional form of tenure until the late 1970s (Kohl 2017, Chapter 4). Even nowadays, fl ats that are available for purchase under condominium ownership law are still a minority in German cities, albeit a growing one. Much to the contrary, coun- Source: (Kohl 2017) tries following the French Civil Code have either Th e fl ipside of these diff erences in tenure is, of always known a sort of condominium ownership course, that the rental stock is much larger in or introduced an updated form of it much earlier Germany than in Southern Europe. One reason in the twentieth century. In Italy in the 1930s, still behind these diverging developments is that the under Mussolini’s policies in favour of an owner- regulation of private rental relations was histori- ship society (Bortolotti 1978), most of the new cally much more intense in Southern Europe than constructions were apartment buildings with fl ats in the North (Weber 2017, Kholodilin 2018). in condominium ownership (Di Feliciantonio and All countries started rent regulation and tenant Aalbers 2018). Th is mostly urban phenomenon protection during the two World Wars. Yet, makes Southern European countries’ housing Southern European countries were both slower stock appear as an exception among OECD coun- in de-regulating aft er the wars and more likely to tries (Hoekstra 2005) and creates crucial diff er- re-introduce hard rent freezes when rent infl ation ences in how the urban fabric works. German risked endangering the social peace. One poten- major cities, for instance, are populated by majori- tial cause for these social policies via consumption ties of (private) tenants, whereas Italian cities have price stops was the lack of functioning and eff ec- long since moved to homeowner majorities. Given tive wage co-ordination in the South (Höpner and tenure and house-price related voting patterns Lutter 2018). A direct consequence of strong rent (Ansell 2014), this can be a crucial political diff er- regulation, however, was the increasing conver- ence as well. sion of private rental units into owner-occupied A third dimension of a South-Northern diver- ones and a fl ight of landlords from this market gence is in the sector of new constructions. While segment. When Italy started its de-regulation of all countries saw a similar post-war re-construc- rent prices again in the 1980s, large conversions tion boom which peaked in the 1970s, the subse-

WORLDS APART: THE DIVERGENCE OF SOUTHERN-EUROPE HOUSING-CONSTRUCTION ECONOMIES AND NORTHERN-EUROPEAN EXPORT ECONOMIES 102 Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau quent trajectories were diff erent from each other. A fi nal divergence was in house price and mort- Germany had an exceptional construction boom gage developments, as presented in Figure 3. aft er re-unifi cation, which set it apart from all While Southern European countries witnessed other countries. Scandinavian countries at that continuously rising real house prices over the last time had just experienced a house price bust and fi ve decades, Germany’s house prices stagnated major recession, and Southern European coun- until the crisis of 2007, only to take off in 2010 tries were just about to start one of their most when house prices started to decline again in all extensive construction booms in the mid-1990s. Southern countries. Th e German house prices, in As a result, the building cycles, usually correlated relation to 1990, have even overtaken the Italian with the general business cycle, became asyn- development again in recent years. House prices chronous among countries that began the Euro- are, of course, closely related to mortgage indebt- pean Monetary Union, as Figure 2 shows. Italy’s edness. Traditionally, Southern European econo- housing boom was still the most conservative mies were characterised by family-owned forms one among Southern European countries; hardly of housing fi nance. Rather than relying on bank going beyond the 5 units built per 1,000 inhabit- credit, ex-ante savings and within-family credit ants. A potential source of distortion here could be were supposed to fi ll the gap left by a still under- that a certain number of informal housing units developed social system (Schwartz and Seabrooke were not counted in the construction statistics, 2008a, Blackwell and Kohl 2018). Although due to informal housing being part of the belated elements of this system might still persist, the urbanisation process in Southern Europe (Allen recent mortgage-debt growth in Southern Euro- 2004). But in all Southern European countries, the pean countries reveals a changing picture, as construction sector made up large shares of the Figure 3 shows. Germany has had a higher mort- GDP and was booming at a time when Germany’s gage debt per GDP until the late 1990s. But with was in a deep recession. the end of the re-unifi cation boom, all Southern Figure 2: Construction cycles105 European economies overtook Germany in terms of institutionalised mortgage debt. Th is was driven by house price increases, but also by banks relying more on external (foreign) capital and new securitisation tech- niques.106

Source: National construction statistics; (Bolt et al. 2018) 105 Numbers use housing completions. If not available, housing starts or permits were deflated by the first lag times 0.95 of permits issued. The displayed deflated Greek permit- 106 Spain being a prime case for the latter development (van based numbers still reflect speculative exaggeration before the Gunten and Navot 2016). crisis 2007 and need to be interpreted accordingly.

WORLDS APART: THE DIVERGENCE OF SOUTHERN-EUROPE HOUSING-CONSTRUCTION ECONOMIES AND NORTHERN-EUROPEAN EXPORT ECONOMIES 103 Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau Figure 3: House prices and mortgage debt per prices (and outstanding mortgage debt) remain GDP surprisingly sticky. In Germany, by contrast, the construction sector has been running at full capacity and still not producing suffi cient (aff ordable) urban housing to fi ll the run-up shortages or to drive down urban prices (Voigtländer et al. 2017).

Note: House prices (above fi gure) and mortgage debt per GDP fi gures (below fi gure). 3. Discussion: What are the Source: (Jordà, Schularick, and Taylor 2017, Knoll, Schul- implications of different arick, and Steger 2015, Amaral 2018). housing/construction regimes Th e only point of convergence in the countries’ for the broader political housing systems has been the decline of social economy in Europe? rental housing (Harloe 1995). It amounted tradi- tionally to up to a third of Germany’s housing If it was not the construction sector that most stock, but never more than 10 per cent in the case employees and domestic credit was allocated to in of Southern European countries. In recent years, Germany, where did the factor input go? Germany, this public housing segment has been generally in much more than other Northern European count- retrenchment mode, reported to be about 4 per ries, developed into an export-driven economy cent in Germany in 2012 (Bundestag 2012).107 (Baccaro and Pontusson 2016). While tenden- cies of export-orientation or currency under-va- One consequence of these diverging construction luation can be traced back to the post-war period trends is that housing markets in the North and (or even earlier) in the German case (Höpner South are currently facing very diff erent prob- 2018, Scharpf 2018), it was not until the last three lems. In Southern Europe, the overcapacity of the decades that Germany produced persistently high construction industry has led to a construction- and even growing exports surpluses. Th is occurred driven prolonged recession, to an oversupply of at the same time that its construction sector and housing and high vacancy rates, as well as prob- mortgage debt declined, while Southern Europe lems of mortgage delinquency and foreclosures produced a mortgage-driven construction boom. (Cano Fuentes et al. 2013, Gentili and Hoekstra Not surprisingly, OECD countries display a nega- 2018). Given the oversupply of housing, however, tive cross-sectional association between the 107 Even if non-profit housing organisations and co-opera- importance of their export and their construction tives still make up more than 10 per cent of Germany’s private sectors in the economy, with Germany and Sout- rental sector.

WORLDS APART: THE DIVERGENCE OF SOUTHERN-EUROPE HOUSING-CONSTRUCTION ECONOMIES AND NORTHERN-EUROPEAN EXPORT ECONOMIES 104 Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau hern Europe choosing alternative strategies along tion or export-dominated regimes are in place, this negative association. they tend to produce their own stabilisers. The fact that countries usually do not have both In international perspective, the two different - a thriving export and a booming construction trajectories of economies can even help stabilise sector - has to do with the different macroeco- each other, as when export economies simultane- nomic environments that the two sectors require ously export their surplus capital to lend it to the in order to prosper. The construction sector works domestically consuming construction economies best in times of higher inflation and lower interest (Fuller 2018). Having countries with asynchro- rates. Construction and particularly the purchase nous construction cycles in a monetary union, of houses requires cheaply available capital, and however, can also be a blessing in disguise, because higher inflation makes the burden of mortgage it could act as a risk-sharing mechanism.108 When indebtedness less onerous. It also motivates people construction is down in one economy, it could be to switch from financial to the intangible asset of compensated for by an upturn in another one.109 housing. The mostly manufacturing export sector The risks of a construction-cycle and hence busi- in the economy, by contrast, requires low inflation ness-cycle downturn could thus become uncor- through higher interest rates in order to have reli- related and work as a sort of insurance, with one able exchange rates, i.e., expectable prices both of economy absorbing the capacities and demand of goods imported and of goods sold abroad. Finally, the other. Yet, the extent of the insurance-mech- on the demand side, the construction sector anism might be limited, as the regional character almost exclusively relies on domestic demand, of construction reduces the easy transferability of whereas the export sector, by definition, is much workers, firms, and building traditions from one less in need of domestic demand. Much to the country into another. contrary, it emphasises wage restraint to guarantee This rosier insurance mechanism could also be the competitiveness of goods exported abroad. thwarted by the inability to adjust the macroeco- Therefore, one can understand the worry of the nomic steering of inflation and interest rates to Bundesbank in 2017 when discussing the poten- nationally different construction markets. This tial negative macroeconomic consequences of an meant in particular that the common European ongoing house-price boom in Germany (Bundes- interest rate in the early 2000s was too restrictive bank 2017). for the German construction sector, where house- Whatever initiated the divergence along different hold debt was decreasing and construction output construction/export trajectories in the 1980s down (Scharpf 2018). Conversely, Southern Euro- and 1990s, the different functional requirements pean economies faced house-price, construction, of dominant sectors in conjunction with social as well as mortgage booms, and thus the risk of an blocs defending their interests acted as rein- overheated economy followed by an even deeper forcing mechanism to keep countries on the track recession. Therefore, the current struggles within (Baccaro and Pontusson 2018). A comparative the Eurozone can also be interpreted through the look at party manifestos (Kohl and Spielau 2018), lens of structurally different economies: some of for instance, reveals that OECD countries with a them relying on debt-financed domestic demand large construction share in the economy, are asso- with large construction sectors, and others relying ciated with all manifestos that are more likely to on wage- and credit-restraint domestic demand in defend infrastructure and housing investments, favour of a growing export sector. independently of party cleavages. In countries with large export sectors, by contrast, party mani- 108 See Schelkle for a related argument (Schelkle 2017). 109 One can compare this to times when urban construc- festos are rather associated with the defence of free tion cycles had not been synchronised in national economies trade across party families. Thus, once construc- and provided for regional balancing.

WORLDS APART: THE DIVERGENCE OF SOUTHERN-EUROPE HOUSING-CONSTRUCTION ECONOMIES AND NORTHERN-EUROPEAN EXPORT ECONOMIES 105 Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau References Kees Dol and Joris Hoekstra. 2013. “From Housing Bubble to Repossessions: Spain Allen, Judith. 2004. Housing and Welfare in Compared to Other West European Countries.” Southern Europe. Oxford: Blackwell. Housing Studies 28 (8): 1197-1217. Amaral, Francisco. 2018. House Prices in Spain, Castles, F.G., and M. Ferrera. 1996. “Home Owner- 1870-2015. University of Bonn: Master’s thesis. ship and the Welfare State: Is Southern Europe Ansell, Ben W. 2014. “The Political Economy of Different?” European Society and Politics 1 (2): Ownership: Housing Markets and the Welfare 163-185. State.” American Political Science Review 108 Di Feliciantonio, Cesare, and Manuel B. Aalbers. (2): 383-402. 2018. “The Prehistories of Neoliberal Housing Baccaro, Lucio, and Jonas Pontusson. 2016. Policies in Italy and Spain and Their Reification “Rethinking comparative political economy: in Times of Crisis.” Housing Policy Debate 28 the growth model perspective.” Politics & (1): 135-151. Society 44 (2): 175-207. Fleming, Michael. 1988. “Construction.” In The Baccaro, Lucio, and Jonas Pontusson. 2018. Structure of the British Industry, edited by Peter “Wirtschaftswachstum nach dem Fordismus: Johnson, 213-234. London: Unwin Hyman. Neue Ansätze in der vergleichenden poli- Fuller, Gregory W. 2018. “Exporting Assets: EMU tischen Ökonomie.” WSI-Mitteilungen 71 (2): and the Financial Drivers of European Macro- 83-95. economic Imbalances.” New Political Economy Blackwell, Timothy, and Sebastian Kohl. 2018. “The 23 (2): 174-191. origins of national housing finance systems: a Gentili, Martina, and Joris Hoekstra. 2018. comparative investigation into historical varia- “Houses without People and People without tions in mortgage finance regimes.”Review of Houses: A Cultural and Institutional Explora- International Political Economy 25 (1): 49-74. tion of an Italian Paradox.” Housing Studies:1- Bolt, Jutta, Robert Inklaar, Herman de Jong, 23. doi: 10.1080/02673037.2018.1447093. and Jan Luiten van Zanden. 2018. “Rebasing Gornig, Martin, and Claus Michelsen. 2017. ‘Maddison’: New Income Comparisons and the “Construction sector: Full order books, good Shape of Long-run Economic Development.” growth prospects.” DIW Economic Bulletin 7 GGDC Research Memorandum 174. (6/7):75-85. Bortolotti, Lando. 1978. Storia della politica Harloe, Michael. 1995. The People’s Home? Social edilizia in Italia : proprietà, imprese edili e lavori Rented Housing in Europe and America. Oxford: pubblici dal primo dopoguerra ad oggi (1919- Blackwell. 1970). Rome: Editori Riuniti. Hoekstra, J. 2005. “Is There a Connection between Bundesbank. 2017. Immobilienmärkte und Welfare State Regime and Dwelling Type? mikroprudenzielle Aufsicht. Vortrag von An Exploratory Statistical Analysis.” Housing Andreas Dombrat beim 39. Symposium des Studies 20 (3): 475-495. Instituts für Bank- und Finanzgeschichte. Höpner, Martin. 2018. “Strategic Undervaluation: https://www.bundesbank.de/Redaktion/DE/ The History of Germany’s Export Orientation “ Reden/2017/2017_05_04_dombret.html. MPIfG Discussion Paper. Bundestag, Deutscher. 2012. “Schriftliche Fragen.” Höpner, Martin, and Mark Lutter. 2018. “The Drucksache 17/10425, 03.08.2012. Diversity of Wage Regimes: Why the Eurozone Cano Fuentes, Gala, Aitziber Etxezarreta Etxarri,

WORLDS APART: THE DIVERGENCE OF SOUTHERN-EUROPE HOUSING-CONSTRUCTION ECONOMIES AND NORTHERN-EUROPEAN EXPORT ECONOMIES 106 Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau is too Heterogeneous for the Euro.” European of Residential Capitalism in the International Political Science Review 10 (1): 71-96. Political Economy: Old Welfare States and the Jordà, Òscar, Moritz Schularick and Alan M New Politics of Housing.” Comparative Euro- Taylor. 2017. “Macrofinancial History and the pean Politics 6: 237-261. New Business Cycle Facts.” In NBER Macroeco- Schwartz, Herman. 2009. Subprime Nation. Amer- nomics Annual 2016, vol. 31, edited by Martin ican Power, Global Capital, and the Housing Eichenbaum and Jonathan A. Parker. Chicago: Bubble. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press. Chicago University Press. Schwartz, Herman M., and Leonard Seabrooke. Kholodilin, Konstantin A. 2018. “Measuring 2008b. “Varieties of Residential Capitalism Stick-Style Housing Policies: a Multi-Country in the International Political Economy: Old Longitudinal Database of Governmental Regu- Welfare States and the New Politics of Housing.” lations.” DIW Discussion Papers 1727. Comparative European Politics 6 (3): 237-261. Knoll, Katharina, Moritz Schularick and Thomas Stephens, Mark, Martin Lux and Petr Sunega. Steger. 2015. “No Price Like Home: Global 2015. “Post-Socialist Housing Systems in House Prices, 1870-2012.” Centre for Economic Europe: Housing Welfare Regimes by Default?” Policy Research Discussion Paper 10166. Housing Studies 30 (8): 1210-1234. doi: Kohl, Sebastian. 2017. Homeownership, Renting 10.1080/02673037.2015.1013090. and Society: Historical and Comparative Van Gunten, Tod, and Edo Navot. 2018. “Varieties Perspectives. London: Routledge. of Indebtedness: Financialization and Mort- Kohl, Sebastian, and Alexander Spielau. 2018. gage Market Institutions in Europe.” Social “The Political Economy of Diverging Export Science Research 70: 90-106. and Construction Trajectories since the Demise Voigtländer, Michael. 2009. “Why Is the German of the Keynesian Construction State.” Unpub- Homeownership Rate so Low?” Housing Studies lished manuscript. 24 (3): 355–372. Malpezzi, Stephen, and Duncan Maclennan. 2001. Voigtländer, Michael, Philipp Deschermeier, “The Long-run Price Elasticity of Supply of Ralph Henger and Björn Seipelt. 2017. Zuwan- New Residential Construction in the United derung, Wohnungsnachfrage und Baubedarfe States and the United Kingdom.” Journal of in Deutschland. Edited by Stephan Mitschang, Housing Economics 10 (3): 278-306. Erhaltung und Sicherung von Wohnraum. Rußig, Volker, Susanne Deutsch and Andreas Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft mbH Spillner. 1996. Branchenbild Bauwirtschaft: & Co. KG. Entwicklung und Lage des Baugewerbes sowie Weber, Jan Philip. 2017. The Regulation of Private Einflußgrößen und Perspektiven der Bautätigkeit Tenancies - A Multi-Country Analysis Univer- in Deutschland,Berlin: Duncker & Humblot. sität Regensburg: Dissertation. Scharpf, Fritz. 2018. “International Monetary Regimes and the German Model.” MPIfG Discussion Paper 1. Schelkle, Waltraud. 2017. The Political Economy of Monetary Solidarity: Understanding the Euro Experiment: Oxford: Oxford University Press. Schwartz, H., and L. Seabrooke. 2008a. “Varieties

WORLDS APART: THE DIVERGENCE OF SOUTHERN-EUROPE HOUSING-CONSTRUCTION ECONOMIES AND NORTHERN-EUROPEAN EXPORT ECONOMIES 107 Sebastian Kohl & Alexander Spielau BANKING CRISIS investors) instead of letting them go bankrupt, INTERVENTIONS IN even though bad investment decisions and unrea- sonably high exposures to risks had led to such GERMANY AND ITALY: THE scenarios. States simply had no alternative but to UNPLEASANT CASE OF save banks. THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK Governments vowed never to let their econo- RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK mies be held hostage by struggling banks again. This resulted in increased regulation at interna- Frederik Traut tional (such as Basel III) as well as at European level, more stringent supervision especially for Hertie School of Governance the most important banks (e.g., the European Single Supervisory Mechanism - SSM), and other Introduction common rules for banks across Europe, especially with regard to their resolution in the case of fail- The banking crisis of the late 2000s not only had ures. This common approach towards regulation a long-lasting impact on the European Union, its became necessary as the recent crisis had revealed economy, and many of its citizens, it also changed major contagion risks across countries (Fecht, the political discourse to a certain extent. Refer- Grüner, & Hartmann, 2012). In Europe, this con- ences to the billions mobilised overnight to rescue tagion across national banking sectors was accom- struggling banks have become defining parts of panied by interdependencies in a monetary union many political debates surrounding financing through public debts that rose as a result of the welfare spending, rescuing bankrupt firms, and banking and economic crises. The new rules im- reducing taxes. Why could states raise money for plemented in Europe in recent years are supposed bank rescues but not for pensioners or workers? to avoid banking crises through regulation and su- There is some truth in this argument: confronted pervision as well as through market discipline by with great turmoil on financial markets, liquid- making the bankruptcy of a bank a credible threat ity and solvency problems of major parts of the for investors. This paper focuses on the newly banking sector, in addition to an alarmed public, introduced European resolution framework for many European countries intervened in markets failing banks that contributes to the latter. and saved a number of struggling banks with In theory, investors are supposed to bear the full taxpayers’ money. Governments injected capital risk of their investment and supervise it accord- into failing banks, they bought non-performing ingly; any prospect of government intervention loans (NPLs), facilitated take-overs, or guaranteed in times of crisis distorts such incentives. It is a banks’ assets. This was necessary due to the high straightforward assumption of economic theory importance of banks for the rest of the economy. that investors would choose their preferred risk They were often “too-big-to-fail” (Krugman, class by maximising their utility in a trade-off 2010), meaning that a single bank was so im- between security and returns. Some investors portant for the functioning of an economy that a might very well be risk-seeking in return for high country could not afford to let it go bankrupt. In premia and allow a firm to behave hazardously, other cases, governments feared public panic and while many others might prefer to contain risks the breakdown of their banking sector simply due and control the respective firm more stringently. to a loss of confidence if they let one bank fail – a In a perfect world, all actors are aware of these risks self-fulfilling prophecy. As soon as banks can no and should either be ready to face the consequenc- longer fulfil their role as financiers of businesses, es or hedge against losses. The prospect of state an economic crisis is almost inevitable. Hence, intervention in times of crisis changes this pattern most major economies bailed out their banks (and

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 108 Frederik Traut and, consequentially, may lead to riskier behav- rules and used taxpayers’ money to save banks iour of firms because their investors do not see the through recapitalisation or at least to facilitate need to control them as stringently; in fact, they their liquidation. This was highly criticised by may even push them into risky business since they German politicians, because it probably reduced know that there is a certain amount of government the credibility of the new resolution regime. I will insurance that limits their risk. Due to the system- argue that Italy had little choice but to evade the ic importance of banks for all major economies, new rules to some extent since they were imple- their investors can usually count on bail-outs by mented prematurely for countries that were at an the respective government. Eventually, this leads earlier stage of the crisis than Germany or other to both potential economic crises through the in- northern European countries. efficiently risky behaviour of banks and high costs The following section will be dedicated to sketch- for taxpayers for direct bank rescues. ing the new EU approach towards re-structuring To address this problem, the new European resolu- struggling banks. Afterwards, I will describe the tion regime was put in place once most states had banking crises in Germany and Italy, the respec- saved their banks. Future investors should face tive government responses, and the effects that the an undistorted risk of loss, leading to lower costs new rules had on the crisis responses. I will con- for taxpayers and better market control of banks. clude with a comparison of the two cases and an However, parts of the EU had not overcome the argument on how the premature introduction of a crisis at this point and the new regime bound their strict and stringent resolution regime has damaged hands to address threats to investors and whole the very purpose for which it was intended. economies that were still formed under the old regime. Italy is a prime example of this. I contrast The EU’s Pledge to Let Italy’s long-lasting banking crisis and the effects of Investors Pay First introducing new rules during the ongoing crisis with Germany, whose banking crisis ended early The EU Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive after heavy state intervention. (BRRD – European Union, 2014a) and the EU In the following, I will argue that, while both were Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM –European affected by the same crisis, the cases of Germany Union, 2014b) are supposed to rule out state aid and Italy reveal major differences in their banking for struggling banks and to ensure orderly resolu- sectors prior to, during, and in reaction to the tion if they fail. While the BRRD is an EU-wide crisis. Germany intervened much faster and with measure to harmonise regulation and resolution, much more power than Italy when the crisis hit in the SRM is a feature of the banking union that the period from 2007 to 2009. Italy’s banks were especially includes the countries of the Eurozone not greatly affected by the international turmoil, and their banks, which are supervised by the ECB. partially due to better supervision and more sta- The introduction of such regulation is a political bility-oriented regulators. The Italian crisis un- signal for all those who criticised costly govern- folded more slowly following the economic down- ment interventions during the Global Financial turn and never reached a peak like the German Crisis of 2007 to 2009 (GFC) and who fear future one, but lasted much longer. Timing was key here cross-border bail-outs in the case of bank failures because the new European resolution regime was due to contagion risks across closely interlinked introduced after the German crisis had been re- economies. But it is also a measure to get incen- solved, but before the Italian banks ran into deep tives for investors straight and reduce excessive trouble. This bound Italy’s hands in addressing its risk-taking. Shareholders and bondholders are banking problems in the same way in which the supposed to be the first ones to bear the losses of a Germans had. Italy partially circumvented the struggling bank through so called bail-in mecha-

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 109 Frederik Traut nisms that result in financing the bank’s resolution and more efficient so that triggering it is a real or recapitalisation through investor liability before threat. any other stakeholder have to step in. The resolution fund is an instrument of last resort Key to achieving a change in future investor in- that is supposed to cover the costs of bank resolu- centives is the credibility of such a scheme. Inves- tion if the liability cascade is not enough to cover tors will adjust their behaviour only to a limited them. Only if investors already covered losses of at extent if they can expect bail-ins to remain an ex- least 8 per cent of the bank’s balance-sheet total, ception and bail-outs – the standard intervention does a bank qualify for aid from the resolution during the GFC – to prevail as a standard reaction fund, which serves as a backstop against state in- to bank failures. In particular, the SRM was sup- tervention that would have to pay for resolution posed to be a solution that credibly regulates the costs not covered by investor liability (European resolution of a failing bank – including investor Union, 2014b). It is financed through contribu- liability – complementing the new Single Super- tions from banks themselves so that, in theory, visory Mechanism that was supposed to prevent taxpayers do not have to bear any of the costs. Europe-wide systemic banking crises in the first Even though credibility and coherence are key place. A potential result of such a credible resolu- for changing the incentives for investors, the tion regime is a virtuous circle in which market new resolution framework entails exceptions and forces require banks to act more prudently, which loopholes. Not only do the usual exceptions for results in fewer banking crises and renders the German savings banks and similar small financial new resolution regimes almost unnecessary. firms tend to make the new framework incoher- In the event of a crisis that threatens a bank’s exist- ent, but also the definitions on when a bank must ence, the new resolution mechanism is organised be resolved or when it can be saved using state aid around two pillars: a liability cascade for bank in- in order to avoid significant negative consequenc- vestors (the bail-in mentioned before), diverging es for the rest of the economy remain unclear. An from usual insolvency regulation, and a resolution important loophole in this regard is precautionary fund for the case that recapitalisation through the recapitalisation (see Article 16 SRM Regulation/ bail-in is not enough to cover the costs of a po- Article 32 BRRD), which has already been used tential failure. These pillars come into effect when in Italy to circumvent resolution rules. In the case a normal insolvency of a financial firm would of precautionary recapitalisation, a government endanger financial stability. The liability cascade can provide state aid to a struggling bank if it is means that, after own funds are used up for re- solvent and systemically important for a country’s capitalisation measures, junior and even senior economy (see Hellwig, 2017) for a detailed analy- bondholders must write off their investments sis of precautionary recapitalisation). These rules or convert them into shares to recapitalise the were meant for extraordinary cases, but they were firm, following a pre-determined pattern. While already used on the first serious occasion when seeming like a straightforward consequence of Italian banks ran into trouble. “bad” investments, losses for senior investors have Given that the new mechanisms had already been rarely occurred in the past, which probably played circumvented when they were tested for the first a role when investment decisions were made. time, it seems questionable whether they can gain This corresponds to the too-big-to-fail argument enough credibility to change the incentives for mentioned before. Letting a bank fail based upon investors as described above. If BRRD and SRM normal procedures, even if it is not too-big-to-fail, are regarded as sham standards, they will not have would probably take much time and destroy trust much impact. It seems questionable whether gov- in the financial system if the state did not step in ernments would be able to resist demands to use and smoothen the failure. Pre-determined rule- exceptions from the new rules when banks in their based recapitalisation can make this process faster countries fail.

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 110 Frederik Traut I will come back to this problem after outlining helped the bank both directly and indirectly with the banking crisis developments in Germany and more than 7bn € (Handelsblatt, 2008). Italy, which have led to state aid in recent years State banks also faced tremendous losses from un- and how they differ. reasonably high exposure to failing US markets; other state banks, states, and the federal gov- The German Response to the ernment stepped in and bailed them out. For Crisis: Quick, Costly, example, WestLB, the state bank of North Rhine- Successful Westphalia, was recapitalised through guarantees covering risks of about 5bn € based on the book The German federal government and several values of assets whose fair values were obviously state governments as well as government agencies much lower; this was regarded as illegal direct heavily intervened in the banking markets in the state aid by the EU Commission, which neverthe- period of turmoil between 2007 and 2009. Both less subsequently proceeded to allow it (German private banks and state banks (especially Landes- Ministry of Finance, 2013). Later, a bad bank took banken, state-level banks that were mostly owned over most toxic loans and the remaining parts by the respective federal state and the semi-public of WestLB were liquidated. For many other state Sparkassen) ran into major trouble during the fi- banks, it is evident that they behaved hazardously nancial crisis in the US – partially because of their when investing in American asset-backed securi- investments in risky assets, and partially because ties, often encouraged and poorly supervised by of a loss in confidence in the banking market fol- politicians who represented the respective states lowing the failure of major international banks. on the banks’ boards Hallerberg and Markgraf The crisis responses included the outright nation- (2018) provide an examination of political in- alisation of banks, relief from bad loans through fluence on German state banks before the crisis special asset management corporations (bad which resulted in bad supervision and risky be- banks), state-guarantees, and the facilitation of haviour; Traut (2017) examines the way in which take-overs or liquidation. Some examples might three state banks (Sachsen LB, HSH Nordbank, be helpful to illustrate the mismanagement of and BayernLB) came to be in crisis and finds major German banks prior to the crisis and how much shortcomings in risk management and reactions the German government intervened: to warnings as well as outright moral hazard. This IKB, a bank specialised in lending to medium-size hints at highly distorted incentives prior to the enterprises, was the first German bank that faced crisis and insufficient supervision from German great difficulties in the GFC and had to be saved by government entities that resulted in great inter- public entities in the 2007–2008 period. It suffered ventions and high costs for taxpayers. dangerous losses from large investments in the in- The list could be extended much further: names 1 famous US asset-backed securities market that like Hypo Real Estate or Commerzbank are still brought the bank to the brink of failure, which it strongly associated with the crisis, and obligations was feared would initiate a chain reaction of fail- from bank rescues have not yet disappeared yet. ures that would bring the German economy to its This becomes clearer when looking at indicators knees. The state-owned bank KfW (which already for the aggregated involvement of government en- held a share of the bank prior to the crisis) and tities in supporting the financial sector through the federal government intervened and bailed out several agencies and state-owned firms. Figures IKB with direct capital injections and guarantees 1.1-1.3 show how much Germany invested into for outstanding debts. Eventually, the government saving its banks by becoming a shareholder of 1 US mortgages to dubious borrowers were bundled and sold banks or their asset management companies (bad all over the world under the assumption that losses from some banks), taking over debt from struggling banks mortgages would be outweighed by profits from others – they were not.

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 111 Frederik Traut (often correlated with becoming a shareholder, pervision might work better and risk and return which explains the similar curves in Figures 1.1 are actually connected (European Commission, and 1.2), or giving out guarantees for bank debts, 2014). Given the German experience and the state which are contingent liabilities (Figure 1.3). of its economy, a new resolution regime seems like German involvement in rescue operations started an adequate measure to foster financial stability. quickly in 2007 and stopped growing in 2009 Figure 1: Assets (e.g., equity in banks), liabili- when the international financial markets were sta- ties, and contingent liabilities (e.g., guarantees) bilised. Since then, new state intervention has not resulting from supporting financial institutions been required. in Germany and Italy (Eurostat, 2018). The sheer size of the rescue packages needed during the GFC reveals the immense problems in the German banking sector. These problems certainly required a reaction by regulators and changes in the regulatory framework. Especially in the cases of the failures of banks with poten- tial systemic importance such as Commerzbank or Hypo Real Estate, state aid was unavoidable, which included compensation for the shareholders and the non-participation of the bondholders in the rescue operations. This was mostly due to lack of rules that facilitated investor liability. Those who made giant profits from risky bank investments in the past were bailed out and only suffered minor losses (Reiermann & Reuter, 2009). Simply to avoid future hazardous behaviour on the part of banks, it was important to set up a framework in which every bank can fail and which makes actual holders of stocks and bonds responsible for con- trolling the bank’s activities and bearing the con- sequences if they fail to do so. A credible bank resolution framework was proba- bly among the most important consequences of the crisis. As soon as banks can be treated almost like normal firms that can go bankrupt if they make bad investments, more disciplined behaviour and more supervision by investors will follow. Fur- thermore, the quick crisis resolution in Germany and the following economic boom as well as the general structure of German investors (usually, normal citizens do not invest substantial amounts of their life savings into bank bonds or shares) re- sulted in a truly fresh start for investment in banks, as investors could adjust their expectations and investment behaviour to the new environment. A new framework could be introduced in which su-

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 112 Frederik Traut Italy: a Hidden Banking balance sheet – a measure to reduce capital re- Crisis quirements – was much harder in Italy than, for example, in Germany. Italian regulators were also The Italian crisis experience was quite different well-informed about potential risks to bank assets, from the German one. As already indicated by because they collected much more data than inter- the numbers on government involvement in the national standards would have required (OECD, financial sector in Figure 1, Italy did not inter- 2009). Regulators basically prevented Italian vene heavily in the markets early on. While the banks from holding assets that later turned out to displayed numbers show almost no support for be toxic. Second, Hallerberg and Markgraf (2018) banks, it is important to recognise that the govern- show that especially (semi-) state banks in Italy ment did indeed give out a guarantee for insured were relatively well-managed and were efficiently deposits to avoid a bank run in case the depositors supervised before the GFC. This stands in stark lost trust. Furthermore, guarantees for some types contrast to the management and supervision of, of bank liabilities were announced and banks were for example, German state banks. partially shielded from losses from non-financial The problems for Italian banks came later, when sector lending. The Italian government had also many other countries had already consolidated prepared instruments to recapitalise struggling their financial sectors or were in the process of banks (OECD, 2009). However, these measures doing so. As we can also see in Figure 1, Italy were much less specific than the German ones, eventually intervened to support its banks when since German banks actually failed in the period the economic crisis – the second phase of the 2007 to 2009 due to high exposure to toxic assets, GFC in Europe – became an unbearable burden while Italian banks were much less exposed to for some banks. This economic crisis was partial- turmoil on international markets. As the OECD ly caused by funding and liquidity problems for stated, ”[t]he Italian financial system managed banks, which resulted in tightened credit condi- to cope with the ‘first round’ of the crisis better tions for firms which relied on financing from than most of its European peers […]” (OECD, banks (OECD, 2009); however, as a trade-depend- 2009, p. 37) and mostly suffered due to spill-over ent economy, Italy was also highly affected by the effects that reduced confidence in banks and in- world-wide economic downturn. Furthermore, creased funding costs. The measures taken by the larger Italian banks suffered from exposure to Italian government mostly aimed at reducing such Eastern European markets, which suffered great burdens for Italian banks. economic turmoil as international credit condi- The Italian banking sector was apparently kept in tions tightened (Di Quirico, 2010). Support for rather good shape by regulators prior to the GFC. domestic banks became necessary in the course Two examples illustrate this: first, the general reg- of this economic crisis whenever more bank loans ulatory attitude towards the risk-taking of banks to local businesses became non-performing and was relatively strict in Italy (Laeven & Levine, the credit-crunch – the unavailability of credit for 2009). Especially regarding the factors that were businesses – worsened. among the determinants of the GFC, Italian regu- It is important to stress again that the Italian crisis lators were exceptionally prudent. Regulators for was fundamentally different to that of other coun- different types of financial firms collaborated and tries: while banks and bursting bubbles brought closed loopholes that banks could have used to 2 the world economy to the brink of chaos, Italian avoid regulation. Shifting loans outside a bank’s bank troubles were rather the result of these 2 Such efficient collaboration between regulators was an excep- worldwide problems. The Italian economic down- tion in major economies. See Barth, Caprio & Levine (2012) turn and its banking crisis went hand in hand, for a detailed discussion on how regulators in industrial countries had the powers and resources to efficiently supervise while the GFC preceded the worldwide economic banks prior to the GFC, but did not use them and failed to co- problems. Italian banks had to reduce credit as a operate efficiently.

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 113 Frederik Traut result of financial market turmoil and a lack of case of Monte dei Paschi di Siena (MPS), 4 which liquidity in the period 2007 to 2009. The highly enjoyed precautionary recapitalisation. MPS had leveraged Italian corporate sector could not cope failed to collect enough money from private in- with the resulting credit-crunch and the general vestors to meet the requirements of the EU-wide economic downturn. 3 As a result, it now accounts bank stress test, which is supposed to ensure ad- for 80 per cent of Italian banks’ non-performing equate capitalisation of major banks. The bank, loans (NPLs), reflecting a long-lasting recession as just like the two smaller banks, requested precau- well as a reluctance on the part of banks to write tionary recapitalisation to solve this problem. In off NPLs (Jassaud & Kang, 2015). mid-2017, it was found that MPS as the country’s The economic crisis in Italy eventually lasted fourth-largest bank was important enough and at much longer than the recessions in other Euro the same time generally solvent so that recapitali- countries, with the resulting NPL problems pro- sation was feasible under the loopholes in the new ducing a slow-motion banking crisis. Shortly after resolution rules. After shareholders and junior the SRM regulation took effect in January 2016, bondholders contributed 4.3bn € to its rescue, the Italian banks ran into trouble when their funding Italian state contributed more than 5bn € to the and liquidity positions eroded in the course of bank’s capital in exchange for shares (European the ongoing NPL crisis. The smaller banks Banca Commission, 2017b). Again, senior bondholders Popolare di Vincenza and Banca tried to did not participate in the bail-in prior to the gov- prevent liquidation through loopholes in the ernment bail-out. It is not very far-fetched to say banking resolution directive, but their limited size that this state intervention again recalls German prevented this. They were eventually sold in 2017 reactions to its own banking crisis; this time, it under Italian insolvency law, including substantial looks quite similar to the rescues of IKB or Com- state guarantees on the liquidation mass (Europe- merzbank. an Commission, 2017a). The common resolution Estimates show that the two Italian regions mostly regime was not used in this case; an important affected by the bank turmoil, the Veneto and feature of the liquidation of the two Italian banks , saw a substantial decline in business was that senior bonds were protected from losses lending of 6 per cent and 3 per cent respectively in as well as small savers’ junior bonds – partially 2016, while similar regions do not show such pat- financed by the Italian state (Humblot, 2017). terns (Zingales, 2017). Rome could only choose Hence, the promise that taxpayers would not pay between great turmoil on financial markets as a for bank failures was not kept. The liquidation of result of non-interventionist resolution of strug- a failing bank using state guarantees and other in- gling banks (leading to a credit-crunch which struments of state aid to facilitate liquidation very already induced the economic crisis that had much recalls the German reaction to the failure of caused these troubles) or finding loopholes to in- SachsenLB – a German state bank that failed in the tervene in the banking crisis to resolve the problem early days of the GFC in 2007 due to unreasonably smoothly. Discretionary intervention would have high exposure to risky US assets. been a viable choice in 2007, but now the Italian Much more important, however, is probably the government faced a different regulatory environ- ment.

3 Germany strongly supported its industry in replacing international demand by domestic public spending. While 4 MPS had also faced major difficulties before and had already these efforts were successful, they were also classic Keynesian been a burden for financial stability for years. For example, it measures and had little to do with Germany’s celebrated model managed to circumvent regulators in some cases and lost hun- of Ordnungspolitik– a concept that relies on rules and rejects dreds of millions in the GFC due to risky transactions. It also discretionary intervention in markets. Perhaps, one could say had to be supported by the state in 2012 when it failed to raise that Italy behaved in a more “German” way than Germany enough capital to meet stricter European capital requirements during the crisis. (Thompson, 2013).

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 114 Frederik Traut The ownership structure of bonds and the poten- The future of the Italian banking system remains tial losers of non-intervention eventually made uncertain. Italy’s quantity of NPLs is still the this a non-choice. Italian households are tradi- highest in Europe in absolute numbers (The Econ- tionally among the most important buyers of omist, 2017). The government in Rome seems to bank bonds for investment purposes, exposing lack the power and resources to solve the NPL the most vulnerable economic players to great problem in due time; the new all-populist govern- economic pain in the event of resolution. This is ment will probably make it even more difficult partially due to an under-developed pension fund to convince investors to relieve banks of NPLs at sector (which would then pool savers’ money) reasonable prices. For the foreseeable future, Eu- and tax incentives that favour bonds over deposits ropean regulation and political constraints (in- (Grasso, Linciano, Pierantoni & Siciliano, 2010). cluding the reluctance of northern countries to Banks obviously had an interest in selling bonds enter risk-sharing schemes) make it unlikely that that secured their own funding and Italians were the NPL crisis can be resolved without harming willing to buy them. Italian households’ bond Italy’s economy or investors – among them, many ownership was 200 million € in 2017 – four times normal citizens saving for their retirement. higher than that of German households (Barbera, 2017). Letting senior bondholders participate in Bail-in, Bail-out, and recapitalisations would have meant expropriat- How Double-Standards Hurt ing citizens who had invested into allegedly safe Everyone assets. Their long-running investments were sup- posed to pay for their pensions or other big plans Both data and anecdotal evidence on government and could not simply be sold to investors at a low intervention during recent banking crises as well price to get out of the business after the rules were as on banking supervision show major differences changed externally. Hence, Rome basically had no between Germany and Italy. Italy did relatively choice but to circumvent the new rules. well in terms of banking supervision and regula- Despite its own interventions in similar cases, tion prior to the crisis. Nevertheless, a long-last- the German government heavily opposed any ing economic downturn brought its banks into state aid by the Italian government under the new serious trouble. This economic downturn was a resolution framework. German politicians and result of the global financial crisis of the period government officials condemned all government 2007 to 2009 and resulted in huge amounts of efforts to cushion the Italian banking crisis and to non-performing loans on bank books. In contrast, protect senior bondholders. It was argued that the Germany’s banks were much more exposed to the new resolution framework was circumvented on initial financial crisis and partially caused it. This the first occasion and that the European authori- required early and severe government interven- ties should not have allowed state guarantees to tion by government entities. Figures 1.1-1.3 show facilitate the liquidation of the two smaller banks, that the magnitude of these interventions ex- nor the precautionary recapitalisation for MPS. ceeded Italian state aid for its banks by far. When A conservative German MEP was quoted in the Italy’s banks needed state aid, the German crisis Financial Times a few days prior to the eventual had already been resolved and its government had MPS decision with the statement: “the promise started working on preventing such events in the that the taxpayer will not stand in to rescue failing future. banks any more is broken for good” (Brundsen, A consequence of Germany’s early intervention 2017). The same article spoke of “outrage among was that its banks’ balance sheets were relatively German politicians” that rules introduced after clean when the financial crisis turned into a Eu- the GFC had been undermined. ropean economic crisis. This stands in contrast to the Italian experience where bank balance

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 115 Frederik Traut sheets turned sour over the years, resulting in a vestment patterns can emerge; Germany was ap- slow-motion banking crisis. This Italian banking parently at such a stage after heavily intervening in crisis overlaps with the introduction of EU rules the markets. Italy did not intervene in its markets to address the reasons for the last financial crisis, so much, and suffered a slowly evolving crisis including a new resolution regime that was sup- based upon an economic crisis. Consequently, posed to prevent government interventions with Italy was not ready for the new rules when they taxpayer money to save banks. In Germany, these were introduced, and investors could not react ap- rules were introduced in a more or less stable en- propriately. vironment and it seems reasonable to assume that One could very well accuse the Italian govern- market participants could change their behaviour ments of recent years of doing too little against the accordingly. This would be in line with the goals economic crisis that then resulted in the Italian of introducing the new resolution regime: reduc- banking crisis; they certainly also failed to work ing incentives for moral hazard by banks and their on the NPL problem (Zingales, 2017). Especially investors, and making them liable for their mis- during the major downturn of the world-econo- takes. my in the period 2008-10, Berlusconi’s right-wing Thus, the outrage of German politicians about government reacted much more timidly com- state aid for Italian banks in 2017 is understand- pared to Britain’s centre-left government or Ger- able from their point of view: it hurts the credibil- many’s centrist grand coalition. Italy rather stuck ity of the newly introduced resolution regime that to the general European rules of non-intervention, was supposed to prevent interventions like the one while its peers conducted classic Keynesianism. conducted by Germany in the GFC. As argued Neoliberal Britain, as well as Germany with its before, credibility is key to change the future be- tradition of Ordnungspolitik, faced great trouble haviour of banks and investors as well as to make during the GFC and did not stick to their princi- resolution feasible at all. It is perfectly reasonable ples. In contrast, traditionally interventionist Italy for a German government that just cleaned up acted in a restrained way and adhered more to its banking sector to want to change the rules as the principles of prudence and order, at least with long as no new problems have emerged that might regard to banking supervision, and did not have to require new intervention. intervene. The Italian government clearly did not It is problematical, however, to impose such rules conduct “rogue policies” or moral hazard that led on Italy for the same reason. As argued before, the to failing banks prior to the crisis, nor did finan- Italian banking crisis evolved from an economic cial firms in general. Instead, it was the economic crisis and hit much later. In contrast to Germany environment that caused problems on the Italian in the period 2007 to 2009, Rome’s hands to banking market. resolve its own crisis on the banking market from It is not without irony that Italy adhered to north- 2016 onwards were bound by the new regulatory ern European principles for too long. This does regime introduced in 2014-16. The Italian gov- not mean that it was intelligent to do so, nor does ernment could not react to a crisis of its banks as it mean that the Italian economy was in exception- Berlin had done. Yet, the Italian economic crisis ally good shape prior to the crisis, of course. had been caused by the worldwide economic The introduction of the European resolution downturn and resultant market turmoil from the regime had two purposes: the economic one was GFC; one can very well say that these crises belong to change the future incentives of banks and their together and cannot be regarded separately. investors in order to reduce the risk of banking The timing aspect is key to understand the flaws of crises; the political one was to show voters that no the new system and the need to circumvent them. more tax money would be used for bank rescues. One cannot change incentives retrospectively. The Premature implementation prior to all the af- new rules can only work when they are introduced fected banking markets being cleaned up prob- in a relatively stable environment in which new in-

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 116 Frederik Traut ably mainly served the political purpose, but this happened at the cost of the economic one. Since current regulation cannot change past incentives, solutions had to be found to deal with the impact of the new rules on old investors. This corrupt- ed the credibility of the system, thereby certainly harming the economic purpose of these rules for the foreseeable future as well as probably harming the political signal in general.

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 117 Frederik Traut Bibliography DES EUROPÄISCHEN PARLAMENTS UND DES RATES vom 15. Mai 2014 zur Festlegung Barbera, A. (2017, July 19). “We warned Italy eines Rahmens für die Sanierung und Abwick- in 2014 about risks for banks.” La Stampa. lung von Kreditinstituten und Wertpapier- Turin. Retrieved from http://www.lastampa. firmen (2014). Brussels: European Parliament it/2017/07/19/esteri/lastampa-in-english/ & Council of the European Union. Retrieved enria-eba-we-warned-italy-in-about-risks-for- from https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/ banks-ZqtCBNa7Yp1dPEtxY5CHWI/pagina. DE/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:32014L0059&fro html. m=DE. Barth, J. R., Caprio, G., & Levine, R. (2012). Guard- European Union. VERORDNUNG (EU) Nr. ians of Finance : Making Regulators Work for 806/2014 DES EUROPÄISCHEN PARLA- us. Boston MA: The MIT Press. MENTS UND DES RATES vom 15. Juli 2014 Brundsen, J. (2017, June 26). “Berlin leads back- zur Festlegung einheitlicher Vorschriften und lash against Italian bank rescue.” The Financial eines einheitlichen Verfahrens für die Abwick- Times. London. Retrieved from https://www. lung von Kreditinstituten und bestimmten ft.com/content/71ece778-5a53-11e7-9bc8- Wertpapierfirmen im Rahmen eines e (2014). 8055f264aa8b. Brussels: European Parliament & Council of the European Union. Retrieved from https:// Di Quirico, R. (2010). Italy and the Global eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/DE/TXT/ Economic Crisis. Bulletin of Italian Politics, PDF/?uri=CELEX:32014R0806&from=DE. 2(2), 3-19. Retrieved from https://www.gla. ac.uk/media/media_191024_en.pdf. Eurostat. (2018). Ergänzende Tabellen zu öffentli- chen Interventionen zur Unterstützung von European Commission. (2014). Umfassende Finanzinstitutionen - Eurostat. Retrieved 29 Reaktion der EU auf die Finanzkrise: Wich- May 2018, from http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/ tige Schritte in Richtung solider Rahmen- de/web/government-finance-statistics/exces- bestimmungen für den Finanzsektor in Europa sive-deficit/supplemtary-tables-financial- und einer Bankenunion für den Euroraum. crisis. Retrieved 10 June 2018, from http://europa.eu/ rapid/press-release_MEMO-14-244_de.htm. Fecht, F., Grüner, H. P., & Hartmann, P. (2012). “Financial integration, specialization, and European Commission. (2017a). Staatliche systemic risk.” Journal of International Beihilfen: Kommission genehmigt Beihilfe Economics, 88 (1), 150-161. Available at: für den Marktaustritt der Banca Popolare di https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2012.01.012. Vicenza und der Veneto Banca gemäß dem italienischen Insolvenzrecht, einschließlich German Ministry of Finance. (2013). Bundesfi- des Verkaufs einiger Teile von Intesa Sanpaolo. nanzministerium - Fünf Jahre Finanzmarkt- Retrieved 6 June 2018, from http://europa.eu/ stabilisierungsfonds unter dem Dach der rapid/press-release_IP-17-1791_de.htm. Bundesanstalt für Finanzmarktstabilisierung. Retrieved 29 May 2018, from https://www. European Commission. (2017b). Staatliche bundesfinanzministerium.de/Content/DE/ Beihilfen: Kommission genehmigt vorsor- Monatsberichte/2013/12/Inhalte/Kapitel- gliche Rekapitalisierung der italienischen Bank 3-Analysen/3-6-fuenf-jahre-finanzmarktstabi- Monte dei Paschi di Siena (MPS). Retrieved 6 lisierungsfonds.html. June 2018, from http://europa.eu/rapid/press- release_IP-17-1905_de.htm. Grasso, R., Linciano, N., Pierantoni, L., & Siciliano, G. (2010). Bonds Issued by Italian Banks: Risk European Union. RICHTLINIE 2014/59/EU

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 118 Frederik Traut and Return Characteristics (Working Papers OECD. (2009). OECD Economic Surveys: Italy No. 67). Rome. Retrieved from http://www. 2009 (OECD Economic Surveys: Italy). Paris: consob.it/documents/46180/46181/qdf67en. OECD Publishing. https://doi.org/10.1787/ pdf/e22656a7-738a-4205-8912-3cb0e6254057. eco_surveys-ita-2009-en. Hallerberg, M., & Markgraf, J. (2018). “The Reiermann, C., & Reuter, W. (2009, February Corporate Governance of Public Banks Before 2). “The State’s Silent Takeover: Germany’s and After the Global Financial Crisis.” Global Big Banking Bailout.” Der Spiegel. Hamburg. Policy, 9, 43-53. https://doi.org/10.1111/1758- Retrieved from http://www.spiegel.de/inter- 5899.12562. national/business/the-state-s-silent-takeover- Handelsblatt. (2008). Fehlspekulationen: Koali- germany-s-big-banking-bailout-a-605044. tionsspitzen billigen Rettungspaket für IKB. html. Retrieved 29 May 2018, from www.handels- The Economist. (2017). “Going South.” The Econ- blatt.com/politik/deutschland/fehlspekula- omist, 68. tionen-koalitionsspitzen-billigen-rettung- Thompson, M. (2013, January 29). “Scandal spaket-fuer-ikb/2927418.html?ticket=ST- at world’s oldest bank.” CNN Money. 2721244-TXkdeP70FwJwZKoexppn-ap1. London. Retrieved from http://money. Hellwig, M. (2017). Precautionary Recapitalisa- cnn.com/2013/01/29/news/economy/italy- tions: Time for a Review. Brussels. Retrieved banking-scandal/index.html. from http://www.europarl.europa.eu/ Traut, F. (2017). The Failures of German Landes- RegData/etudes/IDAN/2017/602089/IPOL_ banken in the Financial Crisis: Micro-Reasons IDA(2017)602089_EN.pdf. and Internal Dynamics. Hertie School of Humblot, T. (2017). Italy: liquidation of Veneto Governance. Retrieved from https://sites. Banca and Banca Popolare di Vicenza. Paris. google.com/site/frederiktraut/research. Retrieved from http://economic-research. Zingales, L. (2017). “Italy’s non-existent bank bnpparibas.com/Views/DisplayPublication. rescue strategy.” Retrieved 10 June 2018, aspx?type=document&IdPdf=30109. from http://www.italy24.ilsole24ore.com/art/ Jassaud, N., & Kang, K. (2015). A Strategy for business-and-economy/2017-02-24/italy-s- Developing a Market for Nonperforming non-existent-bank-rescue-strategy--165915. Loans in Italy A Strategy for Developing a php?uuid=AE3n0xc. Market for Nonperforming Loans in Italy Authorized for distribution (IMF Working Paper No. WP/15/24). Washington. Retrieved from https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/ wp/2015/wp1524.pdf. Krugman, P. (2010, April 1). “Financial Reform 101.” . New York. Retrieved from https://www.nytimes.com/2010/04/02/ opinion/02krugman.html. Laeven, L., & Levine, R. (2009). “Bank Gover- nance, Regulation and Risk Taking.” Journal of Financial Economics, 93 (2), 259-275. https:// doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2008.09.003.

BANKING CRISIS INTERVENTIONS IN GERMANY AND ITALY: THE UNPLEASANT CASE OF THE NEW EUROPEAN BANK RESOLUTION FRAMEWORK 119 Frederik Traut COMPARING THE GERMAN AND sets of interests in the two countries, but it can ITALIAN APPROACHES TO also be ascribed to different economic cultures (or ideas) concerning macroeconomic governance BANKING UNION in the euro area and the completion of Economic and Monetary Union. It is, however, important to Lucia Quaglia point out that both Germany and Italy were inter- University of Bologna nally divided (i.e., had different domestic prefer- ences) on some of the issues at stake. 1. Introduction 2. The Negotiations on the The establishment of a Banking Union repre- Construction of the Banking sented a major development in European economic governance and European integration Union history more generally. The Banking Union was The main purpose of the Banking Union was to the main response of the European Union (EU) break the dangerous link (the so-called “doom - to be precise, the euro area - to the sovereign loop”) between the high and rising sovereign crisis in the euro area periphery and the ensuing debt in the euro area peripheral Member States fragmentation of the financial markets in the euro and domestic banks, which had come to hold an area (Donnelly 2014; De Rynck 2015; Epstein and increasing amount of this debt (Veron 2012). At Rhodes 2016; Glöcker et al. 2016; Howarth and the same time, the Banking Union was an attempt Quaglia 2016a,b; Nielsen and Smeets 2017; Scha- to address the increasing fragmentation of finan- effer 2016; Schimmelfennig 2016; Skuodis 2017). cial markets in the EU, which was a consequence The Banking Union, as initially proposed by the of the crisis. Banks reduced their cross-border so-called “Four Presidents’ Report” (Van Rompuy activities, and the cost of money (e.g., the interest 2012), was supposed to break the “vicious circle” rate paid on bank loans) also varied considerably between ailing banks and fiscally-weak sovereigns, across the Member States of the euro area. In turn, elevating the “responsibility for supervision to this disrupted the conduct of the single mone- the European level”, and providing for “common tary policy of the European Central Bank (ECB) mechanisms to resolve banks and guarantee (Howarth and Quaglia 2016). customer deposits”. Moreover, the European Stabi- lity Mechanism (ESM) was to “act as the fiscal In June 2012, the President of the European backstop to the resolution and deposit guarantee Council, the President of the Eurogroup, the Pres- authority”. Hence, the Banking Union was to be ident of the Commission, and the President of the based upon four pillars: single banking supervi- ECB, prepared an interim report entitled “Towards sion, single banking resolution, common deposit a Genuine Economic and Monetary Union” (Van guarantee scheme, and common fiscal backstop. Rompuy 2012), the above-cited “Four Presidents’ Report” or Van Rompuy Report. The report, which This paper compares the approaches of Germany was discussed at the European Council and Euro- and Italy to the Banking Union by focusing on group meetings in late June, proposed what later their preferences concerning each of the four main became known as the Banking Union. However, components of the Banking Union. It is argued the most pressing issues discussed at the Council that German and Italian policy-makers had meetings concerned the possibility of using the different views concerning the construction of the ESM directly to re-capitalise ailing Spanish banks, Banking Union, its purposes and its institutional rather than doing so indirectly, that is to say, via design. These dissimilar visions for the Banking a loan to the Spanish government, which would Union had partly to do with different underlying have weakened the already fragile fiscal position

COMPARING THE GERMAN AND ITALIAN APPROACHES TO BANKING UNION 120 Lucia Quaglia of Spain. Spanish and Italian policy-makers were cant” banks would continue to be under the direct the main supporters of direct re-capitalisation by supervision of the national competent authorities, the ESM (Financial Times, 29 June 2012). Reluc- albeit according to increasingly harmonised rules tantly, German policy-makers agreed to it, but and practices. Moreover, the ECB was permitted posed, as a condition, the supranationalisation of to step in, by taking direct supervisory respon- banking supervision by transferring it to the ECB sibilities, if and when necessary (Howarth and (The Economist, 29 June 2012). Consequently, Quaglia 2016b). the Member States asked the Commission to put The regulation on the SRM was proposed by forward legislative proposals for the establishment the Commission in July 2013. Most of the nego- of the Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) (Euro tiations concerned the scope of the SRM, the summit 2012). Subsequently, German policy- decision-making process in the Single Resolu- makers reneged on their commitment to allow tion Board (SRB), and the establishment of the the ESM directly to recapitalise banks (Financial Single Resolution Fund (SRF). The Commission, Times, 18 October 2012). supported by French, Spanish and Italian policy- Two legislative proposals concerning the establish- makers, proposed that the SRM should cover all ment of the SSM were prepared by the Commis- euro area banks and that the Commission should sion in close collaboration with the ECB (Nielsen be given the final power to decide whether to and Smeets 2017; Glocker et al. 2016) and were place a bank in resolution and determine the officially put forward in September 2012. During application of resolution tools (Financial Times, the negotiations on the SSM, the most controver- 10 July 2013). These policy-makers were also in sial issues concerned the distribution of super- favour of a timely setting up of a large SFR. For visory power between the ECB and the compe- example, Treasury Minister Fabrizio Saccomanni tent national authorities. The Commission’s (2013) sent a letter to the other EU finance minis- proposal, which was also supported by France, ters stressing that, in order “to break the nexus” Italy and Spain, envisaged the direct supervision and “reduce the risk of contagion”, the system of all euro area banks in the SSM by the ECB. had to rely on “common financial resources”. By The ECB (2012) issued an opinion, supporting contrast, German policy-makers argued that the the proposal and calling for a Single Resolu- SRB should be given the power to decide on reso- tion Mechanism (SRM) to complement the SSM. lution, and insisted on the setting up of a small However, German policy-makers opposed the SRF through an intergovernmental agreement transfer of supervisory competences for the coun- (Financial Times, 8 November 2013). The ECB, try’s regional public savings banks and co-opera- the Commission and the European Parliament tives to the ECB (Financial Times, 12 December (EP), mainly challenged the German position. The 2012). The institutional design of the SSM eventu- ECB (2013) issued a 32-page opinion that the SRB ally agreed by the Member States in the European should be, from the very start, a single “strong and Council (2012) involved a compromise that took independent” body. In order to move the negoti- the German preferences into account. Thus, the ations forward, the Eurogroup and Ecofin (2013) ECB was to be “responsible for the overall effec- issued a statement that made it clear that the SRM tive functioning of the SSM” and the “oversight of should be “fiscally neutral over the medium term the euro area banks”. This supervision, however, so that taxpayers will be protected”. was to be “differentiated” and the ECB would In March 2014, an agreement was reached in the carry it out in “close co-operation with national Council of Ministers on the establishment of the supervisory authorities”. Direct ECB supervision SRM. As advocated by German policy-makers, was to cover only the so-called “significant banks”, the Commission’s proposal was modified: the SRB while thousands of smaller, so-called “less signifi- would be responsible for the planning and reso-

COMPARING THE GERMAN AND ITALIAN APPROACHES TO BANKING UNION 121 Lucia Quaglia lution of cross-border banks and those directly opposition, the proposal for the EDIRA was supervised by the ECB, while national resolu- removed from the final Commission document tion authorities would be responsible for all other “A Roadmap Towards Banking Union” (2012). banks, except if or when a bank required access German policy-makers and German banks feared to the SRF. However, it would be possible for the that they would probably become net contributors SRB to decide to exercise its powers directly with to an EDIS - bailing out depositors in other euro regard to other banks. Under German insistence, area Member States (Donnelly 2014; Howarth the SRF, financed by bank levies raised at national and Quaglia 2016a; Schimmelfennig 2016; Schild level, was to be set up through an intergovern- 2017). German banking associations and indi- mental agreement (Schild 2017). It would initially vidual banks also feared that an EDIS would consist of national compartments that would be impinge upon their sectoral institutional protec- gradually merged over a period of eight years. tion schemes (Handelsblatt, 7 November 2012). German policy-makers - joined by the Austrian, By contrast, policy-makers in France and in the Dutch and Finns - insisted that the funds of the euro area periphery regarded the EDIS as the final ESM - as a backstop of the SRF - could not be used pillar of the Banking Union, necessary to sever to cover legacy problems, which was to be revealed the “doom loop” between banks and sovereigns by a comprehensive assessment of euro area banks (, 11 September 2015). by the ECB (Howarth and Quaglia 2016a), as elab- The issue came back on the policy agenda in June orated below. The SRM regulation was adopted in 2015, when the “Five Presidents’ Report” on the conjunction with the Bank Recovery and Resolu- future of the euro called for an EDIS (Juncker tion Directive (BRRD), which harmonised reso- 2015). In the autumn of 2015, the Commis- lution instruments and powers in the EU. The sion proposed the EDIS as “the third pillar of BRRD and the SRM regulation introduced a new the Banking Union” (Commission 2015). The instrument in bank resolution, the bail-in, which Commission proposal would, as a first step, substantially reduced the need for public funding involve the establishment of a mandatory “rein- to bail out banks (Nielsen and Smeets 2017). The surance”’ scheme that would “contribute under German-led coalition insisted on an earlier entry certain conditions when national deposit guar- into force of the bail-in than the originally envis- antee schemes are called upon”, and thus, in effect, aged date in 2018. Other policy-makers, especially act as a backstop to national deposit guarantee from Italy (Visco 2016), resisted this, but to no schemes. The proposal was supported by French, avail. The start date for the entry into force of the Italian and Spanish policy-makers. By contrast, bail in was eventually moved forward to 2016 (The the German finance minister, Wolfgang Schäuble Economist, 14 December 2013). strongly criticised the proposal: his concern was The other missing pillar of the Banking Union, that “German taxpayers” would have to “foot the beside the common backstop, was what later bill” (Financial Times, 10 September 2015). In came to be known as the European Deposit Insur- order to make progress on the EDIS and overcome ance Scheme (EDIS) (see Gros and Schoenmaker German opposition, the Commission proposed 2014). In June 2012, the interim Van Rompuy that savings and co-operative banks be exempted (2012) report mentioned the need to set it up. from having to contribute to the EDIS (Reuters, 2 Subsequently, the Commission prepared a draft November 2015). proposing a new agency, the European Deposit In June 2017, the Governor of the Bank of Italy, Insurance and Resolution Authority (EDIRA), Ignazio Visco, and Treasury Minister Pier Carlo which would oversee a new European Deposit Padoan renewed their calls for a common deposit Guarantee and Resolution Fund (Financial Times, guarantee scheme (Bloomberg, 23 June 2017). 13 September 2012). However, due to German Nonetheless, given the impasse reached in the

COMPARING THE GERMAN AND ITALIAN APPROACHES TO BANKING UNION 122 Lucia Quaglia negotiations on the EDIS, due to strong opposi- 3. Economic Interests and tion from Germany, the Commission discarded Ideas Concerning Banking its earlier proposals for fully-fledged EDIS in the Union in Germany and Italy autumn of 2017 (Howarth and Quaglia 2018). Trying to establish some common ground between The construction of the Banking Union was the positions of the two coalitions, the President of characterised by the need to reconcile different the ECB Mario Draghi argued before the EP that national sets of interests and ideas concerning the “EDIS remains a fundamental pillar of Banking macroeconomic governance. At the risk of over- Union”, although “risk reduction and risk sharing simplifying, the main line of division was between should go in parallel”, thus “there cannot be an the Northern (German-led) coalition and the EDIS if the level of unpaid bank loans [mostly in Southern coalition, with France in-between, but the euro area periphery] is not reduced” (Reuters, overall closer to the Southern coalition. 20 November 2017). Germany policy-makers, like the policy-makers Overall, the Banking Union was established in from Austria, Finland and The Netherlands, timely fashion between 2012 and 2014. However, shared similar interests: they had sound fiscal it was incomplete and hence asymmetric in three positions; they had mostly healthy banks; and they main respects. First, a rather “complex” compro- were likely to be net contributors to any mecha- mise was reached concerning the resolution nism for financial support in the Banking Union. process in the SRB, and Member State govern- However, the German approach was also shaped ments retained an important say on the use of the by the ordo-liberal economic paradigm. The resolution funds in the SRM. Second, a common German authorities were particularly concerned deposit guarantee scheme was not set up. Third, about “moral hazard” - that is to say, not to provide no common fiscal backstop was established. incentives for any “risky” behaviour of sovereigns Most of the intergovernmental negotiations basi- and banks – or for “legacies problems” derived cally boiled down to distributional conflicts on from past “supervisory forbearance” (Schild 2017; two dimensions: the centralisation of decision- Schaeffer 2016). making, and the allocation of costs via risk-sharing The argument of moral hazard featured promi- (Schild 2017). The discussions pitted the countries nently in the German debate (2014). Even though expected to make net contributions to common the term, as such, was not regularly used by most rescue funds - either from taxpayers or from German policy-makers, Finance Minister Wolf- banks - against those that expected to be the prin- gang Schäuble used it both to justify the transfer of cipal recipients. Thus, compromises were sought supervisory power over banks receiving aid from during the negotiations. The institutional design the ESM (New York Times, 18 November 2011) eventually agreed for the Banking Union was and to oppose the creation of the Common (DGS) closer to the preferences of the German led-coali- (Financial Times, 8 December 2015). More gener- tion as far as risk-sharing was concerned, whereas ally, the fear of moral hazard was implicit in talk of Germany had to make concessions concerning the fiscal transfers. Moral hazard was of great concern transfer of decision-making to the EU/euro-area for policy-makers in some countries, notably level (Skuodis 2017). The result was an incomplete Germany, that were less likely to need finan- and asymmetric Banking Union, which was rather cial support in the Banking Union because their different from the one initially envisaged: out of banking systems were in sufficiently rude health the four pillars initially proposed, only one and a and/or because these governments had a suffi- half were set in place (supervision and resolution, ciently strong fiscal position that would enable respectively). them to withstand real and potential bank losses.

COMPARING THE GERMAN AND ITALIAN APPROACHES TO BANKING UNION 123 Lucia Quaglia There were several moral hazards that preoccupied the euro area, which was at risk of losing Member the German government: for bank shareholders, States and even falling apart following the sover- bondholders, and depositors; for the banks them- eign debt crisis. Indeed, the prospect of a euro selves; and for governments. Thus, policy-makers area collapse was worrisome for all its members, in Germany sought to establish clear limits to their Germany included. Hence, German policy- financial assistance to ailing banks and govern- makers were willing to proceed - albeit with some ments in countries hit by the sovereign debt crisis. reluctance - with the Banking Union. They were also keen to minimise the elements of Yet, countries were not “unitary actors” in the nego- the Banking Union that could result in fiscal trans- tiations on the Banking Union because they often fers from fiscally and financially stable Member had different (even competing) domestic political States to ailing Member States. Thus, Germany economy preferences that had to be reconciled was keen to supra-nationalise banking supervi- (Moravcsik 1993: 30-1). In other words, different sion for systemic banks – an important quali- domestic economic interest groups were likely to fication for Germany, given the three-pillared be affected in different ways by the Banking Union; configuration of its national banking system - they therefore lobbied domestically as well as at but opposed mechanisms for financial support to the EU level in order to pursue their preferences. ailing banks and their sovereigns (Howarth and This was particularly the case in Germany, where Quaglia 2016b). German concerns about moral the national position was pulled in different direc- hazard help to account for the limited scope of the tions by the representative associations of each of SRM agreed upon, the delay to an agreement on a the three pillars of the German banking system. Common DGS, and the limited amount of ESM The big commercial banks wanted the Banking funds made available and the strict condition- Union and wanted it to apply both to all banks ality attached to their use. A core element of the in Germany and the euro area, while the domes- German political discourse on the Banking Union tically-focused co-operative and savings banks was that (German) taxpayers should be protected did not want Banking Union to apply to them. against all future public bail-outs of banks (Schild Domestic divisions weakened German reluctance 2015). to Banking Union, contributing to Germany’s Germany was the largest economy in the euro area, negotiating position as a “constrained veto player”. and had a sizeable current account surplus and a Italian policy-makers, like policy-makers from sound fiscal position. Consequently, Germany Spain and other countries in the euro area had a strong bargaining position resulting from periphery, shared similar interests concerning the asymmetric interdependence (Schild 2017). It was Banking Union: they had weak fiscal positions; the pivotal country, the “win set” of which deter- they had several ailing banks; and they were at risk mined what was acceptable (or not) in the negotia- of contagion from the crisis (Howarth and Quaglia tions on the Banking Union. This explains why the 2016a). Moreover, domestic banks in these coun- compromise solutions were generally within the tries held considerable amounts of national win-set of Germany on several (but not all) issues, government bonds, creating a “doom loop” bank- and why the institutional design of the Banking sovereigns (Veron 2012). Policy-makers in Italy Union had a German “imprint”. German policy- were keen to secure financial support mechanisms makers enjoyed a “constrained veto power” in the for ailing banks and sovereigns. In return, they construction of Banking Union (Bulmer 2016; were willing to accept the supra-nationalisation Bulmer and Patterson 2013) because German and of banking supervision. Moral hazard was less of French banks were heavily exposed (i.e., they had a concern for policy-makers in countries such as invested substantially) in the EU/euro periphery. Italy, that would be more likely to need access to Moreover, Germany had a stake in the survival of external financial support in the Banking Union

COMPARING THE GERMAN AND ITALIAN APPROACHES TO BANKING UNION 124 Lucia Quaglia because their banking system was in poorer health was incomplete and asymmetric, whereby full and/or their domestic fiscal position was weaker. monetary union was not coupled with full For Italian policy-makers, the over-riding impor- economic union (Dyson, 2000; Hodson 2009; tance of EU-level support mechanisms was to Verdun, 1996). Fiscal Union was notably missing bolster international financial confidence in the and had deliberately been left out, principally Italian banking system. They also advocated the (but not exclusively), because of the opposition mutualisation of risks. Thus, the SRF and the of German policy-makers, and despite the half- common fiscal backstop of the ESM were a priority hearted calls of French and Italian policy-makers for the Italian government. In the final stage of for a gouvernemente economique in the euro area the negotiations in December 2013, the Italian (Dyson and Featherstone 1999). Moreover, there finance minister, Saccomanni (2013), called for a was some debate as to whether the ECB should “common backstop” to “provide contribution to be responsible (or not) for banking supervision in the cost of resolution without conditionality”. the euro area. Partly (but not exclusively) due to opposition of German policy-makers, the super- In the negotiations on the Banking Union, the vision of banks was left at national level (Dyson Member States had an asymmetric distribution and Featherstone, 1999). Thus, the Banking Union of bargaining power determined by the size of the can be seen as a crisis-driven attempt to address national economy and the banking system, the several important issues that were sidestepped or relative stability of the national banking system papered over during the EMU negotiations which and the state of the public finances. Italy and other led to the Maastricht Treaty. euro area periphery countries were mostly deman- deurs: they were directly hit by the crisis and After the (partial) establishment of the Banking needed German political and financial support Union, the debate on the completion/reform of for the Banking Union to go ahead. Hence, they EMU re-gained momentum. In October 2015, the had relatively limited bargaining power. Coun- President of the European Commission, in close tries that were not directly hit by the sovereign co-operation with the President of the Council, debt crisis and were relatively less exposed to it - the President of the Eurogroup, the President first and foremost, Germany, which was also - by a of the European Central Bank, and the Presi- significant margin - the largest economy in the EU dent of the European Parliament, produced what with the second largest banking sector after the became known as the “Five Presidents’ Report” on UK - were better positioned to resist the requests “Completing Europe’s Economic and Monetary of the “demandeurs” and impose their design for Union”. This report built on “Towards a Genuine the Banking Union. The asymmetric distribution Economic and Monetary Union” (the so-called of bargaining power during the Banking Union “Four Presidents’ Report”) of June/December negotiations, which were skewed in favour of 2012, the Commission’s “Blueprint for a Deep Germany, accounts for the prioritisation of some and Genuine EMU” of November 2012, and the components of the Banking Union rather than Analytical Note “Preparing for Next Steps on others. Better Economic Governance in the Euro Area” of February 2015. The Five Presidents’ report stated 4. Banking Union and the the objectives of a “genuine Economic Union”, a “Financial Union”, a “Fiscal Union”, and a “Political Completion of EMU Union”, arguing that these four Unions depended The Banking Union was presented as contributing on each other and should therefore be developed to the completion of EMU. Indeed, the institu- in parallel and with the participation of all euro tional design of EMU agreed by the Maastricht area Member States. Treaty and eventually set up from 1999 onwards

COMPARING THE GERMAN AND ITALIAN APPROACHES TO BANKING UNION 125 Lucia Quaglia In December 2017, the European Commission presented a package of initiatives that included, amongst others: a proposal to bring the Euro- pean Stability Mechanism (ESM) into the EU legal framework, transforming it into a Euro- pean Monetary Fund; and a Communication on establishing a European Minister of Economy and Finance minister. Negotiations on these reform proposals have barely started and are expected to last for some time. However, we can expect that the different interests and ideas that character- ised the German and Italian approaches to the Banking Union and to EMU more generally will play out in the negotiations of these pieces of legis- lation as well. The additional complication is that the recently elected Italian government is likely to adopt a more Eurosceptic stance compared to that of previous Italian governments. Acknowledgements: Parts of this paper were informed by my joint research with David Howarth (University of Luxembourg). I wish to thank the participants to the conference at Villa Vigoni for their perceptive comments.

COMPARING THE GERMAN AND ITALIAN APPROACHES TO BANKING UNION 126 Lucia Quaglia References EDIS. 24 November, Brussels. European Council. 2012a. Council Agrees Position Bulmer, S. 2014. “Germany and the Eurozone on Single Supervisory Mechanism. December, Crisis: Between Hegemony and Domestic Poli- Brussels. tics”. West European Politics 37 (6): 1244-1263. Glöckler, G., J. Lindner & M. Salines. 2016. Commission. 2012. Communication: A Roadmap “Explaining the Sudden Creation of a Banking towards a Banking Union. 28 November, Brus- Supervisor for the Euro Area”. Journal of Euro- sels. pean Public Policy 24 (8): 1135-1153. De Rynck, S. 2015. “Banking on a Union: The Poli- Gros, D., and D. Schoenmaker. 2014. “Euro- tics of Changing Eurozone Banking Supervi- pean Deposit Insurance and Resolution in the sion”. Journal of European Public Policy 23 (1): Banking Union”. Journal of Common Market 119-135. Studies 52(3): 529-546. Donnelly S. 2014. “Power Politics and the Under- Hodson, D. (2011), Governing the Euro Area in supply of Financial Stability in Europe”. Review Good Times and Bad. Oxford: Oxford Univer- of International Political Economy 21 (4): sity Press. 980-1005. Howarth, D., Quaglia, L., (2018), ‘The Difficult Draghi, M. 2014. Speech at the conference for the Construction of a European Deposit Insurance 20th anniversary of the establishment of the Scheme: A step too far in Banking Union?’, European Monetary Institute. 12 February 2014, Journal of Economic Policy Reform, http://www. Brussels. tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/17487870.2 Dyson, K. (2014), States, Debt, and Power, Oxford: 017.1402682. Oxford University Press. Howarth, D., and L. Quaglia. 2016a. The Political Dyson K. (2000). The Politics of the Eurozone. Economy of Banking Union. Oxford: Oxford Oxford: Oxford University Press. University Press. Dyson, K. and K. Featherstone (1999). The Road Howarth, D., and L. Quaglia. 2016b. “Interna- to Maastricht. Oxford: Oxford University Press. tionalized Banking and National Preferences Epstein, R. and M. Rhodes. 2016. “The Polit- on European Central Bank Supervision”. West ical Dynamics behind Europe’s New Banking European Politics 39 (3): 438-461. Union”. West European Politics 39 (30): 415-37. Juncker, J.-C. 2015. Completing Europe’s Economic Eurogroup and Ecofin Council. 2013. Statement and Monetary Union. Brussels [Five Presidents’ on the SRM Backstop. 18 December. Report] Euro Summit. 2012. Statement of the Euro Area Nielsen, B., and S. Smeets. 2017. “The Role of the Heads of State or Government. 29 June. EU Institutions in Establishing the Banking Union. Collaborative Leadership in the EMU European Central Bank. 2013. Opinion on a Reform Process”. Journal of European Public Proposal for a Single Resolution Mechanism. 6 Policy, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13501763.20 November, Frankfurt. 17.1285342. European Central Bank. 2012. Opinion on a Saccomanni, F. 2013. Letter to the Other Finance Proposal for a Single Supervisory Mechanism. 1 Ministers. 13 December, Rome. February, Frankfurt. Schaffer, D. 2016. “A Banking Union of Ideas? European Commission. 2015. Proposal for an The Impact of Ordoliberalism and the Vicious

COMPARING THE GERMAN AND ITALIAN APPROACHES TO BANKING UNION 127 Lucia Quaglia Circle on the EU Banking Union”. Journal of Common Market Studies 54 (4): 961-980. Schild, J. 2017. “Germany and France at Cross Purposes: the Case of Banking Union”. Journal of Economic Policy Reform, doi.org/10.1080/17 487870.2017.1396900. Schimmelfennig, F. 2016. “A Differentiated Leap forward: Spillover, Path-dependency, and Graded Membership in European Banking Regulation”. West European Politics 39 (30): 483-502. Skuodis, M. 2017. “Playing the Creation of the European Banking Union: What Union for Which Member States”. Journal of European Integration, doi.org/10.1080/07036337.2017.14 04056. Van Rompuy, H. 2012. Towards a Genuine Economic and Monetary Union, [Four Presi- dents’ Report]. Brussels. Verdun, A. 1996. “An ‘Asymmetrical’ Economic and Monetary Union in the EU: Perceptions of Monetary Authorities and Social Partners?”. Journal of European Integration 20 (1): 59-81. Veron, N. 2012. Europe’s Single Supervisory Mecha- nism and the Long Journey Towards Banking Union. Bruegel, October, Brussels. Visco, I. 2016. Speech: The State of the Union. 5 May, Florence.

COMPARING THE GERMAN AND ITALIAN APPROACHES TO BANKING UNION 128 Lucia Quaglia MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, and Italy for a long time, these recent changes in ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER German mothers’ employment are surprising. What happened to the care ideals in both coun- EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY tries and what impact do they still have on public POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN policies and on maternal employment? DISCREPANCIES? Based on this research I argue that childcare norms and attitudes towards gender equality not Agnes Blome only shape maternal employment, but are also related to changes of public work-family policies. Introduction Thus, where attitudes and the cultural context changes, mothers’ employment-friendly policies Germany and Italy were long known for their fa- become more likely and this will be reflected in milialist and male-breadwinner-oriented models increasing maternal employment rates. I use at- of welfare capitalism. Social security and labour titudinal data from the European Values Study markets developed based on traditional gendered (EVS) to examine country-level differences in cul- divisions of labor, where men are expected to tural norms regarding the gender division of work become breadwinners and women are expected and beliefs that children and family life suffer to become unpaid carers. Work-family reconcili- when a mother works for pay. To analyze policies, ation policies such as care services were absent, I examine maternity and parental leaves as well as or, if they existed, reinforced traditional gender publicly funded childcare for 0-3 years old chil- roles by supporting long leaves and part-time dren. work for mothers. As a consequence, women’s and mothers’ employment rates have been low in both countries. Yet, in recent years the labour market Maternal employment, work- participation of mothers increasingly shows di- family policies and cultural verging trends. While maternal employment rates norms in Germany jumped to 70 percent in 2014, only 56 percent of Italian mothers participated in the Due to their unequal access to positions and eco- labour market in the same year. nomic resources, men and women are affected dif- ferently by the economic context. Several studies This piece draws on institutional and cultural on gender inequalities in the labour market show factors to describe and explain recent trends in that women in general spend less hours in paid maternal employment in Germany and Italy. work and are less likely to have highly remunerated While a large body of research focuses on the positions than men (Mandel and Semyonov 2005, impact of public policies and labour market char- Pettit and Hook 2009, Dieckhoff et al. 2015). This acteristics, more recent research takes into account is especially the case when women have children. cultural factors such as ideas and norms about Childless women and men, but also fathers, have mothers’ employment and childcare. In countries higher employment rates and work longer hours where “ideals of care” emphasize the importance than mothers (Boeckmann et al. 2015). Yet, cross- of maternal care for small children, maternal em- country differences in maternal employment rates ployment rates may be lower because mothers’ point to the importance of country-specific con- labour market participation may be perceived as textual factors that shape women’s decisions about in conflict with the ideal of “good motherhood” employment as well as employers’ understanding (Kremer 2007, Boeckmann et al. 2015). Since the and treatment of mothers in the workforce. For in- traditional male-breadwinner model shaped both stance, the Varieties of Capitalism literature claims public policies and people’s attitudes in Germany that the way the market economy works influ-

MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN 129 DISCREPANCIES? Agnes Blome ences the degree of sex segregation in a country. Wrohlich 2018, Budig et al. 2012, Korpi et al. 2013, A country’s production system emphasizes either Nieuwenhuis 2014). Others claim that certain specific or general skills. Since general skills are aspects of work-family policies such as lengthy more easily portable on the labour market than parental leaves and part-time employment have specific skills, countries with an emphasis on adverse labour market consequences for women specific skills (Coordinated Market Economies, (e.g. Mandel and Semyonov 2005, 2006; Pettit and CME) provide more generous employment secu- Hook 2009). This literature has provided evidence rity provisions and social protection to safeguard of large cross-national variation in the design of people who lose a job during e.g. a recession (Hall work-family policies – not only between Anglo- and Soskice). Moreover, because employers have Saxon, Scandinavian and Conservative welfare invested in worker training they are interested in states, but also within these groups. For example, committing employees to their workplaces. By an- the Conservative welfare states Germany, France ticipating women’s discontinuous work and lower and Italy strongly differ in their family policy ap- working hours due to care responsibilities, em- proaches. While the French model of comprehen- ployers often practice statistical discrimination. sive childcare support comes close to the Nordic As a consequence, women are often excluded from welfare states, Italy is characterized by very low many sectors of employment in these economies public support of working mothers. Germany (Estevez-Abé 2006, Mandel and Shalev 2009). only recently reformed some of the work-family Social protection schemes designed to protect the reconciliation policies, but is at the same time male model of full-time continuous employment characterized by regulations such as the income reinforce the effect (“institutional complemen- splitting that continue to support the male bread- tarities”). In addition, generous family policies winner model. may exacerbate employer’s reluctance to invest in International comparisons have also highlighted women’s specific skills’ training and to hire them. the role of normative beliefs in shaping maternal Long maternity and parental leaves, in particular, employment. In fact, some argue that the deci- worsen women’s chances, because firms would sions of mothers do not simply respond to the have to find a replacement for someone with spe- policy context, implying that other factors than cific skills (Estevez-Abé 2005, 2006). economic gains play a role for a mother’s decision The comparative feminist welfare state schol- to take up employment and to what extent (Pfau- arship has long pointed to the extent of a male- Effinger 2004, Kremer 2007). Rather, the cultural breadwinner orientation of social policies, where a support of mothers’ employment is also decisive. strong male breadwinner welfare state undermines In a mothers’ employment supportive cultural women’s and mothers’ employment (Lewis 1992, setting, maternal employment is more likely to in- Sainsbury 1996). While some focused on the role crease than in a context with a lack of support for of classic social policies such as unemployment working mothers (Budig et al. 2012). protection and pension schemes for fostering the Normative beliefs towards childcare and maternal male full-time continuous breadwinner model, a employment not only shape mothers’ employment prominent body of research claims that maternal decision-making processes, but are also mirrored employment is shaped by work-family reconcili- in policy design. For example, generous work- ation policies designed to alleviate gender-based family policies that enable mothers to take a long labor market inequalities. All in all, this literature leave from the labour market reflect conservative is inconsistent in their conclusions (Brady et al. understandings of the gender division of work 2018). Some argue that generous work-family pol- (Budig et al. 2012). At the same time, work-fam- icies encourage female and maternal employment ily policies may change people’s attitudes towards and reduce motherhood penalties (Müller and maternal employment in the long run (Ziefle and

MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN 130 DISCREPANCIES? Agnes Blome Gangl 2015). To understand change it is therefore Graph 1: Employment of mothers aged 25-54 essential to analyze developments of normative years in European welfare states, 2005 and 2014 beliefs and public policies over time. In recent decades, many rich democracies have reformed work-family reconcilia- tion policies, yet maternal employment continues to differ across countries. Differences in the (changes to the) cul- tural context may explain the discrep- ancies. When policy-makers consider work-family policy reforms they take into account the electorate’s norma- tive beliefs. When their beliefs change, policy change becomes more likely (Blome 2017). Together with changed cultural expectations regarding mater- nal employment, these reformed poli- cies may then shape mothers’ decisions Note: Mothers with at least one child under 14 years old. about employment as well as employers’ treatment Source: OECD Family Database of mothers in the workforce.

Mothers’ employment rates: One of the main differences between working Large differences in Europe, mothers in Germany and Italy is related to the sharp increase in Germany, number of hours worked. Part-time work in Germany is widespread, and mothers, in par- continuing low levels in ticular of very small children, usually work few Italy hours (Statistisches Bundesamt 2017). In contrast, Maternal employment is on the rise throughout (quality) part-time work is often not available to Europe. At the same time, the employment level Italian mothers. Therefore, the barriers to take up differs considerably between European welfare employment while children are small are high. It states (Graph 1). In 2014, more mothers are in em- should be noted, though, that the recent increase ployment than in 2005 in all countries except for of maternal employment rates in Germany is Greece, and the Slovak Republic. Still, the related to a rise in (near) full-time employment.1 average growth is moderate (about 4 percentage Compared to 23 percent in the mid-2000s, more points). Germany stands out for a considerable in- than 30 percent of German mothers worked full- crease of maternal employment from 63 percent time in 2013 (OECD Family Database). At the to 70,3 percent, while in Italy only 56 percent of same time, the share of German mothers who mothers are in employment in 2014 compared to worked part-time remained at about 40 percent 54 percent in 2005. during the years. In Italy, the relationship between motherhood status and working hours is inverse: more mothers work full-time (35 percent) than part-time (21 percent) and this has not changed over time.

1 The OECD defines full-time/part-time work as more/less than 30 hours per week.

MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN 131 DISCREPANCIES? Agnes Blome During the economic crisis, women in both For example, the joint taxation splitting system Germany and Italy had been protected by the and the free co-insurance of non-employed persistence of sectoral and occupational segrega- spouses incentivizes mothers to opt out of the tion by gender in their countries. Most employ- labor market or to reduce labor market participa- ment losses happened in the manufacturing and tion. While Germany made substantial changes in construction sectors as well as in selected finan- the work-family policies between 2000 and 2008, cial branches which are dominated by men (Eu- policy developments in Italy have been discon- ropean Commission 2012). At the same time, em- tinuous and fragmentary (Blome 2017). The fol- ployment growth in the services sector – which is lowing paragraphs describe (1) the developments where many women work – is often accompanied in maternity and parental leave schemes and (2) by a rise in temporary work and related to more childcare provision for children under three years precarious employment conditions (reference). of age. In Italy, most of the increase in women’s employ- In Germany, mothers are entitled to paid maternity ment took place in lower ranked job positions, leave 6 weeks before and 8 weeks after birth. After and lower educated women experienced less job maternity leave, parents may be on parental leave. losses than highly educated women (Gálvez-Mu- After its first adoption in 1986 parental leave reg- ñoz et al. 2014). Furthermore, older workers (49 ulation changed several times in Germany. Since years and older) appear to have been able to keep 1992 parents have a right to return to their previ- jobs at the expense of younger women (and men). ous employer until the child is 3 years old. The last As women tend to have children once their labour substantial reform took place in 2006, when the market prospects are more secure, they are older maximum duration of paid parental leave for all when they become mothers. Since older workers parents was increased to 14 months including two are more likely to keep their jobs, this might partly “use-it-or-lose-it” fathers’ months and the previ- explain the stability in maternal employment rates ously flat-rate sum changed to an income-related in Italy and the rise in Germany. measure of 67% of previous net income with a cap As shown, part-time work is one of the maternal of €1,800. A further reform in 2011 abolished the employment facilitating factors in Germany. It is entitlement of social assistance beneficiaries to related to other institutional differences between the flat-rate basic parental leave allowance of €300 Germany and Italy. The following section con- and reduced the replacement rate to maximum centrates on the – arguably – two most important 65% for parents who earn more than €1,200. In public work-family reconciliation policies: mater- 2015, parental leave was flexibilized by giving nity and parental leave regulations and the public parents the possibility to share more months (up provision of childcare. to 32 paid leave months). It can be classified as a generous parental leave scheme that offers some Public work-family incentives for fathers to participate in care work and thus enable couples a more gender equal divi- reconciliation policies: sion of work. Expansion in Germany, stagnation in Italy In Italy, mothers are entitled to a comparatively long maternity leave of five months at 80% of pre- At the beginning of the 1990s, Germany and Italy vious earnings. Paid parental leave was created in stood paradigmatically for welfare states in which 1994 and offered up to six months per parent at the lack of day care and other policies supporting 30% of earnings for a child under six. The 2000 mothers’ employment led to a strong gender divi- parental leave reform gave fathers the right to sion of labor. The support of the male-breadwin- claim the benefit independently of the mother. ner model was more comprehensive in Germany: Parents are entitled to a total of 10 paid parental

MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN 132 DISCREPANCIES? Agnes Blome leave months, but each of them may only claim 6 es in coverage rates (Naldini and Jurado 2013, months at most. If one parent (usually the mother) Naldini and Saraceno 2008). During the crisis uses 6 months and the other (often the father) uses years the small expansion came to a halt in 2008 at least 4 months, the leave period may be extend- (13 percent). ed by one month. In addition, fathers are entitled In sum, the German family policy model became to two days paternity leave. The low replacement much more supportive of the dual-earner model, rate and the short overall duration of parental while in Italy, maternal employment is not sup- leave makes the Italian parental leave scheme par- ported by public policies and childcare remains simonious with little incentives for a more gender the responsibility of mothers. The most impor- equal division of work. tant reforms happened after the Millennium in Children older than three are well covered by Germany. public provision of childcare in both Germany and Italy. However, parents of children aged Attitudes towards gender between 0 and 3 years faced care supply shortages. equality, maternal There is a gap between the end of paid parental leave and the start of ample childcare. In the be- employment and childcare ginning of the 1990s, only 3 percent of children of More recent research on the determining factors of that age group had a publicly subsidized childcare maternal employment argues to take into account place in Western Germany (40 percent in Eastern the cultural context of maternal employment. At- Germany) (Statistisches Bundesamt 2004). Fur- titudes toward gender equality and toward proper thermore, opening hours in Germany were only childcare shape both individuals’ decisions to short. Often, children did not stay until lunch- return to or to look for employment and employ- time. Only 6 percent of 0-3 years old children ers’ willingness to employ mothers. At the same had access to publicly provided childcare in Italy time, the population’s beliefs are reflected in in 1994 (Centro nazionale di documentazione e work-family policy design and their reforms. The analisi per l’infanzia e l’adolescenza 2002). Thus, following paragraphs will assess the normative in both countries mothers were the primary care- beliefs of Italians and Germans towards gender taker for the very young children. equality, childcare and maternal employment. In 2004 and 2008 two reforms pushed the pro- Budig et al. (2012) argue that motherhood-based vision of childcare places for children younger employment differences are less likely in countries than three years in Germany. The 2004 reform where gender ideologies support both men’s and required municipalities to provide enough places women’s contribution to the household income, for children below three to meet demand, or as a while dominant ideals of care that emphasize minimum to make places available for children mothers’ care for children may be associated with with parents in employment/training. The 2008 higher employment differences. reform introduced the right to a childcare place The following analyses are based on three waves for children over one year of age. Since 2013, every of the European Values Study. A battery of ques- child between the age of one and six has had the tions is asked to assess people’s attitudes towards legal right to a place in a daycare centre or with a gender equality, the gender division of work and qualified childminder. The ratio of the number of childcare. By way of factor analysis two indica- places available per 100 children of that age group tors were identified that represent (1) attitudes rose from 14 percent in 2006 to 33 percent in towards gender equality and (2) attitudes towards 2017 (Statistisches Bundesamt 2017). In Italy, by childcare and maternal employment. The graphs contrast, medium-range reforms and much fewer show the deviations from the mean over all years. financial resources led to only marginal increas-

MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN 133 DISCREPANCIES? Agnes Blome The higher the value the more progressive are atti- Graph 3: Attitudes towards childcare tudes towards gender equality and towards child- care and maternal employment. Italians have had more progressive attitudes towards gender equality than Germans (Graph 2). Yet, the change in Germany between 1990 and 2008 is remarkable. In 2008, the likelihood to support gender equality is higher in Germany than in Italy.

Graph 2: Attitudes towards gender equality

Note: Values are based on a factor analysis. The factor loads on the following questions: (1) A working mother can establish just as warm and secure a relationship with her children as a mother who does not work, (2) A pre-school child is likely to suffer if his or her mother works, (3) A job is alright but what most women really want is a home and children. Source: European Values Study 1990, 1999, 2008.

The picture also holds when we look at specific groups in society (Graph 5). In both countries, women have more progressive attitudes towards childcare and maternal employment than men. Yet, Italian women are much less supportive of Note: Values are based on a factor analysis. The factor loads on the maternal employment than German women. In following questions: (1) Both the husband and wife should contribute to household income, (2) Having a job is the best way for a woman addition, people with low incomes have more tra- to be an independent person, (3) Being a housewife is just as fulfilling ditional attitudes in both countries – again with a as working for pay, (4) A working mother can establish just as warm big difference between Germany and Italy. People and secure a relationship with her children as a mother who does with a high income have more progressive views not work. in Germany, while they are not different to the Source: European Values Study 1990, 1999, 2008. mean in Italy.

A significant change in Germany is also noted for attitudes toward childcare. In 2008, more Germans were positive toward maternal employment than in 1999 and even more compared to 1990. Italians, by contrast, continued to be opposed to maternal employment despite a small change between 1999 and 2008 (Graph 3).

MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN 134 DISCREPANCIES? Agnes Blome Graph 5: Attitudes towards childcare by social cies likely build the context for the low maternal groups employment rates in Italy and the increase in mothers’ labour force participation in Germany. Despite the overall developments, the data also show some degree of polarization in attitudes in both countries. Certain groups of the electorate (e.g. women, people with high incomes) drive the change of attitudes towards more progressive at- titudes in Germany while others (e.g. men, people with low incomes) tend to support the traditional male-breadwinner model. The situation is similar in Italy, even though attitudes polarize the popula- tion to a lesser extent.

Conclusion Note: Values are based on a factor analysis. The factor loads on the Maternal employment increasingly differs following questions: (1) A working mother can establish just as warm and secure a relationship with her children as a mother who does between Germany and Italy. This article aimed at not work, (2) A pre-school child is likely to suffer if his or her mother showing how institutional and cultural develop- works, (3) A job is alright but what most women really want is a ments build a context for maternal employment. home and children. More precisely, it shows how policy effects are Source: European Values Study 1990, 1999, 2008. influenced and conditioned by cultural contexts. By examining the evolution of attitudes towards gender roles, maternal employment and child- The comparison of Germany and Italy shows in- care I show how the cultural context changed in creasing cultural differences. While Germans have Germany and enabled a series of work-family had traditional attitudes towards gender equality policy reforms. Both factors then contributed to and maternal employment for a long time, this the increase of maternal employment. At the same changed around the Millennium. Even though time, attitudes did not change to a similar extent Italians had slightly more progressive attitudes in Italy. As a result, only small-scale changes hap- toward gender equality than Germans in the be- pened to work-family policies. This likely contrib- ginning of the 1990s, this reversed in the 2000s. uted to the persistent low maternal employment Especially regarding opinions on childcare and rates. maternal employment, Italians seem to contin- Several questions are left for further research. ue to favor a more male-breadwinner-oriented In this paper I have looked at the relationship family model (see Lomazzi 2017). The fact that between maternal employment, cultural factors attitudes in Germany changed before the turn of and public policies on the macro level. Analyses the millennium while policy reforms happened on the individual level may explore further the after implies that policy-makers reacted to the role attitudes and policies play for an individual’s changed cultural context and re-designed policies. or couple’s decision (when) to return to employ- In Italy, by contrast, attitudes hardly changed, and ment after a baby was born. A pertinent ques- policy-makers might not have deemed it neces- tion is why attitudes changed so dramatically in sary to reform policies (see Blome 2017 for a more Germany, but less so in Italy. Religion, seculariza- detailed account of the policy reforms). Both the tion and unification arguably play a role, but given cultural context and the respective (adapted) poli- the diverging attitudes of societal groups obvious-

MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN 135 DISCREPANCIES? Agnes Blome ly these factors are not the whole story. Last, future research should attend to the question of unequal policy responsiveness, i.e. whether and under which political conditions policy-makers respond to certain groups of the electorate – e.g. women and the highly educated in the case of work-family policies – more than to others.

MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN 136 DISCREPANCIES? Agnes Blome References tional Segregation by Sex in Advanced Indus- trial Societies.” World Politics 59(1): 142–75. Blome, Agnes. 2017. The Politics of Work-family Gálvez-Muñoz, Lina, Paula Rodríguez-Modroño, Policies in Germany and Italy. Abingdon/New and Tindara Addabbo. 2014. The impact of York: Routledge. austerity on women’s work in Italy and Spain. Blome, Agnes. 2018. „Von Kinder, Küche, Kirche Available at: www.aiel.it zu Kinder, Karriere, KiTa? Geschlechterrollen, Hall, Peter A, and David W. Soskice 2001. Varieties Familienpolitik und Religion im Wandel der of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations Zeit“, Sozialer Fortschritt 67, special issue of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford „Ökonomisierung und Konfession. Was University Press. bleibt?“, edited by Josef Hien and Wolfgang Schroeder, pp. 453-475. ISTAT. 2013. Rapporto Annuale: La Situazione del Paese, Rome, Istat. Available at: www.istat.it. Boeckmann, Irene, Joya Misra, and Michelle J. Budig. 2015. “Cultural and Institutional Factors Korpi, Walter, Tommy Ferrarini and Stefan Shaping Mothers’ Employment and Working Englund. 2013. “Women’s Opportunities Hours in Postindustrial Countries.” Social Under Different Family Policy Constellations: Forces 93: 1301-1333. Gender, Class, and Inequality Tradeoffs in Western Countries Re-Examined.” Social Poli- Budig, Michelle J., Joya Misra, and Irene Boeck- tics 20: 1-40. mann. 2012. “The Motherhood Penalty in Cross-National Perspective: The Importance of Kremer, Monique. 2007. How Welfare States Care. Work-Family Policies and Cultural Attitudes.” Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press. Social Politics 19: 163-193. Lomazzi, Vera. 2017. “Gender role attitudes in Centro nazionale di documentazione e analisi per Italy: 1988–2008. A path-dependency story l’infanzia e l’adolescenza. 2002. I servizi educa- of traditionalism.” European Societies 19(4): tivi per la prima infanzia. In Quaderni no. 21. 370-395. Firenze: Istituto degli Innocenti. Mandel, Hadas and Moshe Semyonov. 2005. Dieckhoff, Martina, Vanessa Gash and Nadia “Family Policies, Wage Structures, and Gender Steiber. 2015. “Measuring the Effect of Insti- Gaps: Sources of Earnings Inequality in 20 tutional Change on Gender Inequality in the Countries.” American Sociological Review 70: Labour Market.” Research in Social Stratifica- 949-967. tion and Mobility 39: 59-75. Mandel, Hadas and Moshe Semyonov. 2006. “A European Commission. 2012. The Impact of the Welfare State Paradox: State Interventions and Economic Crisis on the Situation of Women and Women’s Employment Opportunities in 22 Men and on Gender Equality Policies. Luxem- Countries.” American Journal of Sociology 111: bourg: Publications Office of the European 1910-1949. Union. Müller, Kai-Uwe and Katharina Wrohlich. 2018. Estevez-Abe, Margarita. 2005. “Gender Bias in Does Subsidized Care for Toddlers Increase Skills and Social Policies: The Varieties of Capi- Maternal Labor Supply?: Evidence from a talism Perspective on Sex Segregation.” Social Large-Scale Expansion of Early Childcare. Politics 12(2): 180–215. DIW Discussion Paper No. 1747. https://www. diw.de/sixcms/detail.php?id=diw_01.c.596085. Estevez-Abe, Margarita. 2006. “Gendering the de Varieties of Capitalism – a Study of Occupa-

MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN 137 DISCREPANCIES? Agnes Blome Naldini, Manuela and Chiara Saraceno. 2008. “Not totally frozen, but far from structural reforms.” Social Policy & Administration 42(7): 733-748. Naldini, Manuela and Teresa Jurado. 2013. “Family and welfare state reorientation in Spain and inertia in Italy from a European perspective” Population Review 52(1): 43–61. Nieuwenhuis, Rense. 2014. Family policy outcomes: Combining institutional and demographic explanations of women’s employment and earn- ings inequality in OECD countries, 1975-2005 (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 2438617). Social Science Research Network, Rochester, NY. Statistisches Bundesamt. 2004. Kindertagesbe- treuung in Deutschland. Einrichtungen, Plätze, Personal und Kosten 1990 bis 2002. Wiesbaden Statistisches Bundesamt. 2017. Statistiken der Kinder- und Jugendhilfe. Kinder und tätige Personen in Tageseinrichtungen am 01.03. eines Jahres. Wiesbaden. Ziefle, Andrea and Markus Gangl. 2015. “Do Women Respond to Changes in Family Policy? A Quasi-Experimental Study of the Dura- tion of Mothers’ Employment Interruptions in Germany.” European Sociological Review 30: 562-581.

MATERNAL EMPLOYMENT, ATTITUDES TOWARD GENDER EQUALITY AND WORK-FAMILY POLICIES. GERMAN-ITALIAN 138 DISCREPANCIES? Agnes Blome C GERMAN AND ITALIAN PERCEPTIONS, DIFFERENCES AND MISGIVINGS ITALY AND GERMANY DURING countries facing severe economic and financial THE CRISIS: difficulties. As Grabbe (2012) pointed out, the sovereign debt crisis is more than the breakdown SUPPORT FOR THE EU AND of both a currency and a political project, as it is 110 RECIPROCAL VIEWS also causing a loss of trust between EU Member States. Alessandro Pellegata By taking Germany and Italy as illustrative exam- Università degli Studi di Milano, Department of ples of this “Core-Periphery” divide, this article Social and Political Sciences aims to investigate the evolution of public support Mutual trust among citizens of different EU for the EU in these two countries, both before Member States is a cornerstone for the estab- and after the Euro crisis, and its relation with the lishment of a sense of European identity and mutual perceptions of both countries as expressed the strengthening of the EU integration process by public opinion and the political élites. We postu- (Hooghe and Verhaegen 2017). However, the late that, given the leading role played by Germany current multifaceted crisis that the EU is expe- within the EU institution and the different narra- riencing and some side effects of the integration tives fuelled in the core and peripheral Member process have not only exacerbated public opposi- States, Italian citizens and representatives tend to tion to the EU, but are also eroding the stock of blame Germany both for the Euro crisis and for mutual trust among the citizens of the different the bad Italian economic situation. Therefore, we Member States that was accumulated after the end expect to find a significant association between the of the Second World War. In particular, the recent orientations of Italians towards the EU and their Eurozone crisis has increased the tension between view of Germany. Empirical analyses have been core countries of Northern Europe, with strong conducted using cross-sectional survey data at macro-economic performances, and countries of both the mass and élite levels taken from multiple the Southern periphery, struggling with excessive sources. The findings obtained confirm our expec- deficits and increasing public debt. Two competing tations. narratives about who is to blame for the crisis are at play. The core countries’ narrative is about feck- Political Commonalities but less Greeks and Italians and the inability of their Long-lasting Stereotypes national institutions to adopt structural reforms to keep their public debt under control and thereby Germany and Italy share numerous historical render the Euro sustainable. The narrative running commonalities, such as a late nation-building in peripheral Member States blame the Northern process which occurred only in the second half countries, Germany in primis, for their austerity of the nineteenth century, and the experience of measures and their lack of solidarity towards authoritarian regimes during the two world wars. 110 This article has been presented at the workshop “Re- Germany and Italy are both founding members sponses of European Economic Cultures to Europe’s Crisis of the EU and, since the end of WWII have been Politics: The Example of German-Italian Discrepancies” held characterised by a pronounced Europeanism by in Villa Vigoni, Menaggio (IT) on 25 – 27 June 2018. The present contribution is mostly taken by Olmastroni, Francesco both their political élites and citizens. Moreover, and Alessandro Pellegata (2018) “Members Apart: A Mass- both countries have undergone major political Elite Comparison of Mutual Perceptions and Support for the changes after the end of the Cold War: the re-unifi- European Union in Germany and Italy”, Contemporary Italian cation of West and East Germany following the Politics 10 (1): 56-75. This study received the financial support of the project “Reconciling Economic and Social Europe: The tearing down of the Berlin Wall in 1989, and the Role of Values, Ideas and Politics (REScEU)”, funded by an collapse of the traditional party system in Italy, Advanced Grant of the European Research Council (Grant no. following the Mani Pulite corruption scandal(s) 340534, P.I: Maurizio Ferrera).

ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: SUPPORT FOR THE EU AND RECIPROCAL VIEWS 140 Alessandro Pellegata in the 1990s. Italian-German relations are intense In Germany, the debate over the Euro crisis has and co-operative at the cultural, economic and been framed as a conflict between “Northern societal level, as well as in daily political life. In saints” and “Southern sinners” (Matthijs and 2015, Italy ranked third among EU countries for McNamara 2015). Hard work, prudent savings, the total value of German imports, and Germany moderate consumption, wage restraint, and is the biggest source of Italian imports and the first fiscal stability – primarily in Germany, but also destination for Italian exports (Diedrichs 2010; in Austria, Finland and The Netherlands – were Dinger 2013). seen as northern virtues and were juxtaposed to However, Germany and Italy have been also char- the southern vices of low competitiveness, meagre acterised by longstanding stereotypes and preju- savings, disproportionate consumption, inflated dices. Germans express a high self-esteem and wages, and fiscal profligacy which characterised consideration of their leading role in Europe, the offensive acronym of “PIIGS” (the countries of and, while they admire Italy for its lifestyle, they Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece and Spain). There- consider its institutions to be inefficient and fore, Germany supports a markedly “discipli- corrupt. On the other hand, Italians appreciate narian” approach, deeply rooted in the ordoliberal German efficiency and the hardworking ethic of its doctrine (Bulmer 2014; Meiers 2015), according people but, at the same time, criticise their exces- to which the burdens of fiscal adjustment should sive rigour and their harsh and uncompassionate fall exclusively on national governments and nature. (Pew Research Center 2012, 2013; Frie- taxpayers. drich Ebert Stiftung 2016). Gian Enrico Rusconi In contrast, a large part of the Italian media and of (2008), one of the most important scholars of the political élite, even among mainstream polit- Italian-German relations, argues that, since the ical parties, blame the excessive rigour and lack end of the Cold War, several political events have of solidarity of the EU institutions and northern represented sources of tension in Italian-German governments, Germany in primis, and advance the bilateral relations and have contributed to exacer- notion of debt pooling in the form of Eurobonds bating the divergent views that the two countries or fiscal equalisation schemes. They oppose the have of each other. conditionality regime and austerity measures, and call for more flexibility in the application of rules, Core versus Periphery: the mobilisation of EU resources for investment Germany-Italy Relations in and growth, and, most importantly, the “mutu- Times of Crisis alisation” of risks (Ferrera 2017). The REScEU (Reconciling Economic and Social Europe: Values, With the outbreak of the Euro crisis, the EU and Ideas and Politics) Mass Survey provides evidence the integration process, which, for many years, in support of the difference between the Germans’ had represented the common denominator of and the Italians’ approval of financial bailouts, and German-Italian bilateral relationships, have their views about who is to blame for the recent become the most challenging source of tension Eurozone crisis (Ferrera and Pellegata 2017). between these two countries. A new sharp dividing Previous research has shown a positive relation line over the issue of fiscal stability and, ultimately, between support for the EU and macroeconomic cross-national solidarity has polarised German performance (Anderson 1998; Anderson and and Italian publics, their media and their political Kaltenhaler 1996). Considering that the economic élites. Thus, two opposing narratives about who crisis, fiscal austerity measures and the condi- is to blame for the crisis and the initiatives that tionality regime have produced clear and tangible should be taken to manage its detrimental conse- losses in the Euro periphery, we expect to find a quences are in play. sharper decrease in public support for the EU in

ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: SUPPORT FOR THE EU AND RECIPROCAL VIEWS 141 Alessandro Pellegata Italy than in Germany caused by the onset of the Figure 1. Public Mood towards the EU in Eurozone crisis. However, we push our expecta- Germany and Italy tions a step forward by postu- lating an association between support for the EU and the Ital- ians’ view of Germany. Th e narra- tives of both the media and the Italian political élite scapegoat EU institutions and their policy initiatives for the stagnant Italian economy and its excessive public debt. Given the strong relations that have occurred historically between Germany and Italy, and the leadership that the former plays within the EU institu- tions (Paterson 2011; Kundnani Notes: Mood in the two countries has been estimated through 2015), Italian citizens and its political élite tend the dyad ratio algorithm (WCalc soft ware, Stimson 1999). to identify the EU behaviour with that of the role Source: Eurobarometer 1973-2016. of Germany. Th us, we expect to fi nd evidence in support of a decline in the level of trust of Ital- Th e green line in the graph plotted in Figure 1 ians vis-à-vis Germans relating to their decreasing represents our estimate of the public mood of support for the EU. Italians towards the EU, while the red line indi- cates that of the Germans towards the EU. Th is Assessing the Relation indicator should be interpreted as the annual between Support for the EU share of citizens who express “pro-EU” stances. and Mutual Feeling Th e average level of public mood towards the EU is quite high in both Germany (65.7%) and Italy A vast amount of the literature has argued that, (70.0%), confi rming the marked Europeanism from the early 1990s, the EU and the integration that has characterised the two countries from the process started to be politicised in domestic poli- beginning of the EU project. However, the two tics, and became increasingly disputed aft er the countries show diff erent patterns of variation over onset of the fi nancial crisis (Hooghe and Marks time. Th e public mood of the Germans towards 2009; Hutter, Grande and Kriesi 2016). In order the EU remained high and fairly constant during to estimate the preferences of the Germans and the 1970s and the 1980s. It decreased during the the Italians for the EU, we have built a measure 1990s, aft er the re-unifi cation process and the of public mood based upon several EU-related decision to abandon the Deutschmark, but subse- issues. Th is measure stems from the concept of quently increased again to remain high even policy mood developed by Stimson (1999), which in recent years. As expected, the Italian mood, is an aggregate and longitudinal estimation of the in contrast, relentlessly decreased from 1993, opinions of citizens on one or more controver- following the adoption of the Maastricht Treaty, sial policy issues. More precisely, we have aggre- and fell below the threshold of 50 per cent aft er gated the frequency distributions of responses the onset of the sovereign debt crisis. While, in to survey questions related to general attitudes 2016, two Germans out of three expressed posi- towards the EU gathered from Eurobarometer tive orientations towards the EU, only 37 per cent series conducted between 1973 and 2016. of Italians supported the integration process.

ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: SUPPORT FOR THE EU AND RECIPROCAL VIEWS 142 Alessandro Pellegata Unfortunately, we could not rely on a yearly esti- Figure 2. Germany-Italy mutual feelings. Mass mate of the reciprocal views of the Germans and (upper panel) and elite (lower panel) level the Italians to allow us to make a longitudinal description of their evolution. However, a number of recent surveys provide us with data that depict alarming signals regarding the mutual feel- ings of the Germans and Ital- ians. Th e Friedrich Ebert Foun- dation (2016) shows impor- tant diff erences in the opinions of the Germans and the Italians regarding the role of Germany within EU institutions. While 68 per cent of the Italian respond- ents agreed with the statement that Germany should contribute more to the EU budget since it receives more advantages than other Member States, 66 per cent of Germans took the opposite position. Furthermore, while an impressive 81 per cent of Italian respondents believe that Germany is abusing its power within the EU Th en, to test our conjecture that the orientations at the expense of other EU Member States, only of Italians towards the EU and their views about 19 per cent of their German counterparts agree on Germany are related, we have investigated empiri- this position (see Figure 2). Few available data at cally which individual-level factors are associated the élite level confi rm this discrepancy. A recent with the view of Germany expressed by Italian citi- élite survey conducted by REScEU between 2017 zens and their political representatives. Unfortu- and 2018 among the national representatives of nately, as already observed, data on the reciprocal seven EU Member States, including Germany and views of Germans and Italians do not system- Italy, asked the respondents to evaluate Germa- atically cover a long period. As a result, we have ny’s political and diplomatic behaviour during the selected two partially diff erent questions in order Euro crisis on a scale ranging from 0 (a self-inter- to operationalise Italian views of Germany in the ested hegemon) to 10 (a solidaristic leader). As the last ten years taken from the Transatlantic Trends lower panel of Figure 2 indicates, the average value Survey and the LAPS-PRIN PEI survey.111 Th e fi rst of German MPs is 5.7, while the average score survey question asked respondents to evaluate among Italian MPs is 3.5. their feelings towards Germany, its institutions, and people using either a 100-point or 10-point 111 For Transatlantic Trends Survey, see http://www.gmfus. org/initiatives/transatlantic-trends-%E2%80%93-public-opini- on, and for LAPS PRIN_PEI data, see the Special issue “Italian Foreign Policy: To Take Arms against a Sea of Troubles?” of the Italian Political Science Review.

ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: SUPPORT FOR THE EU AND RECIPROCAL VIEWS 143 Alessandro Pellegata “thermometer” scale, with 100 (or 10) meaning a As expected, the lower the level of support for the very warm, favourable feeling, 0 meaning a very EU expressed by Italian citizens and their polit- cold, unfavourable feeling, and 50 (or 5) meaning ical élite, the lower their feeling towards Germany. not particularly warm nor cold. For the sake of This result is consistent, including a control for consistency, we re-scaled the original values in the impact of ideology, which is never signifi- order to obtain a 10-point scale. This survey item cantly related to Italians’ views of Germany. Not was available in 2006, 2008 and 2016. In 2012, surprisingly, the negative association between we selected an item which presented a different the perceived threat of the economic recession wording. This item asked respondents whether for Italy/Europe and feeling towards Germany is they had a favourable or unfavourable opinion significant only after the onset of the economic of Germany. We have recoded the original Likert crisis. In contrast, the perceived cultural threat scale, which included four response catego- posed by immigration is never significantly asso- ries into a dummy variable: “tend not to favour” ciated to the dependent variable. Finally, the nega- (0) and “tend to favour” (1). The main explana- tive evaluation of the influence exerted by Germany tory variables included in the regression models within the EU expressed by Italian public opinion refer to individual perceptions of the economic and its élite is strongly associated with the negative and migration crises, the role of Germany and its feeling of Italians towards the former. leadership during and after the crisis, and their opinion of the EU and their country’s membership of the Eurozone.112 The results are controlled for the inclusion the ideological orientations, gender, age, and education of the respondents.113 Table 1 summarises the main findings obtained in regres- sion analyses.114 Table 1. Main Regression Results

Italian public opinion View of Germany 2006 2008 2012 2016 Negative attitudes towards the EU - - - - Economic downturn is a threat to Europe/Italy n.s. n.s. n.s. - Immigration is a threat to Europe/Italy n.s. n.s. Negative evaluation of Germany’s influence in Europe - -

Italian national MPs View of Germany 2006 2008 2012 2016 Negative attitudes towards the EU - - - - Economic downturn is a threat to Europe/Italy n.s. n.s. Immigration is a threat to Europe/Italy n.s. n.s. Negative evaluation of Germany’s influence in Europe - 112 Detailed information on the exact wording of different Note: -: negative and significant regression coefficient; n.s.: not questions and their sources is provided in Olmastroni and Pel- significant regression coefficient. legata (2018) and its Online Appendix. Source: Transatlantic Trends Survey (2006; 2008; 2012); 113 Because of the very low number of observations and in order to maximise the number of cases for each predictor, we LAPS, PRIN-PEI (2016). have decided to omit controls from the regression models for political élites. 114 For a detailed presentation and discussion of all the regression results see Olmastroni and Pellegata (2018) and its Online Appendix.

ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: SUPPORT FOR THE EU AND RECIPROCAL VIEWS 144 Alessandro Pellegata Conclusions

The empirical results that emerge from this study undoubtedly represent a serious challenge to the integration process. The multiple crises that Europe is recently experiencing and the policy initiatives implemented by the EU to address them have detrimental effects not only on support for the EU and its institutions, but also on the labori- ously accumulated capital of respect and mutual trust among both the national governments and the citizens of the different Member States. In particular, Italian citizens and their political élite are likely to assimilate the EU and its behaviour with Germany’s “hegemonic” role within the EU institutions. However, recent public opinion surveys also show that the EU is re-gaining confidence in the eyes of the citizens, and, more interestingly, that there is a broad support, even in core countries such as Germany, for policy initiatives aimed at strength- ening pan-EU solidarity (Ferrera and Pellegata 2017; PEW Research Center 2017). Many Euro- pean citizens still believe in the EU, provided that the EU changes its course, carrying on solidarity- enhancing measures to re-assure voters worried about the negative consequences of the integra- tion process and the recent crises. Our results suggest that European leaders should follow this strategy with due diligence to avoid new losses of intra-European cohesion and the consequential damage to the stability, security and development of the EU community.

ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: SUPPORT FOR THE EU AND RECIPROCAL VIEWS 145 Alessandro Pellegata References gration Are Not To Ebb Away.” EUROPP – European Politics and Policy. Available at: Anderson, C.J. 1998. “When in Doubt, Use http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/europpblog/2012/03/15/ Proxies: Attitudes toward Domestic Politics and eu-trust-institutions, last accessed 22 July 2017. Support for European Integration.” Compara- Hooghe, L., and G. Marks. 2009. “A Postfunc- tive Political Studies 31 (5): 569-601. tionalist Theory of European Integration: Anderson, C. J., and K.Kaltenhaler. 1996. “The From Permissive Consensus to Constraining Dynamics of Public Opinion toward European Dissensus.” British Journal of Political Science Integration, 1973-1993.” European Journal of 39 (1): 1-23. International Relations 2 (2): 175-199. Hooghe, M., and S. Verhaegen. 2017. “The Effect Bulmer, S. 2014. “Germany and the Eurozone of Political Trust and Trust in European Citi- Crisis: Between Hegemony and Domestic Poli- zens on European identity.” European Political tics.” West European Politics 37 (6): 1244-1263. Science Review 9 (2): 161-181. Diedrichs, U. 2010. “Germany’s View of Italy in Hutter, S., E. Grande, and H. Kriesi. 2016. Polit- the New Century: New Challenges and Old icizing Europe. Integration and Mass Politics. Stereotypes.” Modern Italy 15 (3): 293-305. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Dinger, D. 2013. From Friends to Collaborators. Kundnani, H. 2015. “The return of the German A Constructivist Analysis of Changes in Italo- question: why conflict between creditor and German Relations with the End of the Cold War. debtor states is now the defining feature of Baden-Baden: Nomos. European politics.” EUROPP – European Politics Ferrera, M. 2017. “The Stein Rokkan Lecture 2016. and Policy, Accessed 25 September 2017. Avail- Mission Impossible? Reconciling Economic able at: http://bit.ly/1uNCLMl, last accessed 25 and Social Europe after the Euro Crisis and September 2017. Brexit.” European Journal of Political Research Matthijs, M. and K. McNamara. 2015. “The 56 (1): 3-22. Euro Crisis’ Theory Effect: Northern Saints, Ferrera, M., and A. Pellegata. 2017. “Can Southern Sinners, and the Demise of the Euro- Economic and Social Europe Be Reconciled? b on d .” Journal of European Integration 37 (2): Citizen Views on Integration and Solidarity.” 229-45. REScEU Working Paper Series. Available at: Meiers, F. 2015. Germany’s role in the Euro crisis. http://www.resceu.eu/events-news/news/can- Berlin’s Quest for a More Perfect Monetary economic-and-social-europe-be-reconciled- Union. New York: Springer. citizens%E2%80%99-view-on-integration- Olmastroni, F., and A.Pellegata (2018) “Members and-solidarity.html, last accessed 25 August Apart: A Mass-Elite Comparison of Mutual 2017. Perceptions and Support for the European Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung. 2016. “Amici distanti: Union in Germany and Italy.” Contemporary un sondaggio d’opinione sul rapporto tra Italian Politics 10(1): 56-75. Germania e Italia” AbteilungInternationaler- Paterson, W. E. 2011. “The Reluctant Hegemon? Dialog. Available at: http://library.fes.de/pdf- Germany Moves Centre Stage in the European files/bueros/rom/12989.pdf, last accessed 25 Union.” Journal of Common Market Studies 49 September 2017. (1): 57-75. Grabbe, H. 2012. “The EU Must Re-create Trust Pew Research Center. 2012. “European Unity on between Member States if the Benefits of Inte- the Rocks.” Research report. Available at: http://

ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: SUPPORT FOR THE EU AND RECIPROCAL VIEWS 146 Alessandro Pellegata assets.pewresearch.org/wp-content/uploads/ sites/2/2012/05/Pew-Global-Attitudes- Project-European-Crisis-Report-FINAL- FOR-PRINT-May-29-2012.pdf, last accessed 5 August 2017. Pew Research Center. 2013. “The New Sick Man of Europe: the European Union.” Research report. Available atL http://www.pewglobal. org/files/2013/05/Pew-Research-Center- Global-Attitudes-Project-European-Union- Report-FINAL-FOR-PRINT-May-13-2013. pdf, last accessed 5 August 2017. Pew Research Center. 2017. “Post-Brexit, Europeans More Favorable Toward EU.” Research report. Available at: http:// assets.pewresearch.org/wp-content/ uploads/sites/2/2017/06/06160636/Pew- Research-Center-EU-Brexit-Report- UPDATED-June-15-2017.pdf, last accessed 25 September 2017. Rusconi, G.E. 2008. “Die politischenWurzelnder- schleichendenEntfremdung.” In Schleichen- deEntfremdung? Deutcshland und Ital- iennachdem Fall der Maurer, edited by G.E. Rusconi, T. Schlemmer, and H. Woller, 9-16. Munich: Oldenbourg. Stimson, J. A. 1999. Public Opinion in America: Moods, Cycles, and Swings. 2nd ed., Boulder CO: Westview Press.

ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: SUPPORT FOR THE EU AND RECIPROCAL VIEWS 147 Alessandro Pellegata THE POLITICAL SPACE IN Bornschier 2010, 2010a, 2015): from focusing on ITALY AND GERMANY DURING religion, this dimension was reshaped to refer to a new fundamental conflict between universalistic THE CRISIS: (cosmopolitan) and traditionalist-communitarian ITALIAN AND GERMAN (nationalistic) values. POPULISM COMPARED The established mainstream parties have not been able or are not ready to represent the rising Hanspeter Kriesi demands linked to this structural conflict in European University Institute, Florence society, and have also converged on the economic dimension of party competition, which has tradi- 1. Introduction: The General tionally been their home turf. Accordingly, the Background of the Recent representative function of established parties has Rise of New Challenger been weakening: they have become increasingly Parties remote from their constituencies, and their mobi- lising capacity has continued to decline (see Mair There are two sets of factors that determine the 2013). In particular, the fact that the mobilisation vote for new challenger parties from the radical potentials created by the new fundamental conflict left and the radical right in Western Europe. On were largely neglected by the mainstream parties the one hand, there are the structural transforma- created a tension between the political represent- tions of society which create new societal conflicts, atives (“the élites”) and the voters (“the people”). and which are at the origin of a set of new demands This made room forthe rise of new challengers to be represented in the political system. On the within the party system. Mair (2002: 88) has already other hand, there are the political dynamics, espe- pointed to the link between, on the one hand, the cially those within the party system, which create weakening of party democracy, as we knew it and, the supply-side conditions for the representation on the other, the rise of such new challengers. The of these demands within the political system. new challengers not only articulate the new struc- tural conflicts, but they also denounce the estab- The long-term trends in the development of the lished parties for their incapacity to represent cleavage structure constitute the starting-point for the voters’ concerns. They pursue a double logic any discussion of the determinants of the vote for (Rooduijn et al. 2016: 34): on the one hand, they challenger parties. As has been argued by various express the substantive concerns and the demo- authors, north-western Europe has been charac- cratic dissatisfaction of the voters in question, terised by the rise of a “new” cultural divide that while, on the other, they contribute to their voters’ has emerged since the 1970s as the result of succes- discontent by their populist rhetoric which claims sive waves of mobilisation of new social conflicts that the established élites are betraying the people by, first, the new social movements and the New and that the sovereignty of the people ought to be Left (new radical left parties and Green parties) restored. and then by the radical right. The cultural issues politicised by the two waves – issues related, above As a result of the long-term trends, the dominant all, to cultural liberalism, immigration and Euro- competition between the mainstream parties of the pean integration – transformed the meaning of the centre-left (Social Democrats) and the centre-right cultural dimension of the two-dimensional space (Conservatives, Liberals and Christian-Demo- of party competition in north-western Europe crats) on the economic dimension of the political (see Kitschelt 1994, 1995; Kriesi et al. 2008, 2012; space has been supplemented by the competition Hooghe et al. 2002; Hooghe and Marks 2017; between the New Left (Greens) and the New Right (radical populist challengers – AfD in Germany)

THE POLITICAL SPACE IN ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: ITALIAN AND GERMAN POPULISM COMPARED 148 Hanspeter Kriesi on the cultural dimension. While Germany saw lasting authoritarian regimes and strong commu- the rise of a strong Green party, which emerged nist parties, i.e., a strong “old” left) and with the from the massive new social movements and fact that they had been emigration countries until experienced its breakthrough in the federal elec- more recently. By contrast, southern Europe was tions in 1983, the New Right only developed belat- particularly hard hit by the Great Recession – the edly, primarily due to its national-socialist legacy. financial crisis and eurozone crisis in the after- Ultimately, the Alternative für Deutschland (AfD) math of the fall of Lehman Brothers in the autumn broke through in the context of the Great Reces- of 2008. These countries experienced a double sion. At its origin, the AfD opposed the repeated crisis – an economic and a political crisis - which bailouts of Europe’s crisis-ridden debtor coun- provided a unique opportunity for new chal- tries. But rather rapidly, it muted into a typical lengers to articulate classic left-wing economic populist radical right party, focusing on immigra- grievances and the widespread political dissat- tion issues and joining the ranks of the New Right isfaction (see Hutter et al. 2018). The latter had that had already been established in other north- both international and domestic origins. Inter- western European countries for more than thirty nationally, the management of the eurocrisis led years. Even though it had just been founded only to interventions in national politics by suprana- seven months before, and even though it had not tional actors (the “Troika”) and northern Euro- yet developed the typical profile of a radical popu- pean “creditor” countries, and ended up pitting list right party, the AfD obtained 4.7 per cent of them against the southern European “debtor” the votes cast and only barely missed the five per countries. Domestic factors added to the resulting cent threshold to enter the Bundestag in the 2013 political discontent in southern Europe: struc- federal elections. Subsequently, the party gained tural problems, policy errors and misconcep- electoral ground in European and state-wide elec- tions predated the euro crisis and left the southern tions, both in West and East Germany. As argued European countries particularly ill-prepared to by Bremer and Schulte-Cloos (2018), it probably respond to the economic crisis. An overall sense benefited from the fact that it was initially not as of frustration with the political élites captivated a closely associated with outright radical right posi- large share of the population and was translated tions as its predecessors from the New Right. For into a wave of protest that swept across southern the outcome of the 2017 elections, it is important Europe (Kriesi et al. 2018). Moreover, as a result of to keep in mind that Germany does not belong the double crisis, southern Europe saw the rise of to the countries that were most heavily hit by the challengers from the radical left (such as Podemos economic crisis. However, we should also keep in in Spain, Syriza in Greece) or of purely populist mind that, during the euro crisis, Germany became challengers from “neither left nor right” such as the most important representative of the “creditor” the M5S in Italy. countries, and, as such, experienced the accentua- Figure 1 gives an idea of the key political back- tion of domestic conflict over rescue measures for ground conditions for the rise of these challengers the “debtor” countries and institutional reforms – democratic dissatisfaction, which distinguishes of the Eurozone. Moreover, Germany is certainly north-western European countries from southern one of the countries that has been most concerned European countries. As the figure shows, the by the refugee crisis, which first hit Europe in the Great Recession led to a decline in democratic summer of 2015. satisfaction in southern Europe, but not in north- Importantly, the impact of the two waves of mobi- western Europe. While democratic satisfaction lisation had been more limited in southern Europe in Germany never reached the very high levels of – for reasons that have to do with the political Sweden, it was not affected by the Great Reces- legacy of southern European countries (long- sion and, if anything, increased until the refugee

THE POLITICAL SPACE IN ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: ITALIAN AND GERMAN POPULISM COMPARED 149 Hanspeter Kriesi crisis broke. Only during the refugee crisis did it the punishment of the SPD was more a sign of start to decline. By contrast, the level of satisfac- general wear. Th e SPD had suff ered most in the tion in Italy reached German levels only briefl y fi rst crisis-election in 2009, when it lost roughly a in the mid-2000s, but then declined to very low third of its share of the vote, a loss from which it levels in the course of the euro crisis. As is illus- never recovered. In addition to the general trends trated by the case of Spain, the decline in demo- described above, the lack of a distinctive profi le, cratic dissatisfaction during the euro crisis was a series of candidates for Chancellor (Steinmeier, not an Italian speciality, but occurred throughout Steinbrück and Schulz) who lacked any charis- southern Europe. However, given that the level of matic appeal, and the predicament of having to satisfaction was already much lower in Italy before serve as a minority partner in a coalition domi- the crisis than in Spain, the decline of satisfaction nated by Angela Merkel may go a long way to was less precipitous in Italy than it was in Spain explain the decline of the SPD. Th e Liberals and, during the euro crisis. above all, the AfD were the benefi ciaries of the Figure 1: Th e development of satisfaction with punishment of the incumbents in the 2017 elec- democracy in four European countries tions, while the radical and the New Left (Linke and Greens) stagnated. Th e Italian elections resulted in the punishment of the governing PD (Partito Democratico - Demo- cratic Party), the Italian equivalent of the SPD, and of the main centre-right party in opposition (Berlusconi’s re-baptised Forza Italia, formerly Popolo della Libertà), as well as in the rise of the populists from both the radical right (Lega – the League, formerly Lega Nord) and the “neither left nor right” (Movimento 5 Stelle (M5S) - Five Star Movement). Th e PD lost roughly a fourth of its previous vote share (down from 25.4 to 18.7 per cent), Forza Italia more than a third (down from 21.6 to 14 per cent). Berlusconi’s party had already lost more than 40 per cent of its vote share in the 2. The Outcome of the German previous 2013 elections (down from 37.4 to 21.6 per cent). Th e PD’s loss was partly due to a split: 2017 Elections and the the anti-Renziani who split and campaigned Italian 2018 Elections under the name of “Liberi e Uguali” (Free and Equal) obtained 3.4 per cent. Together, the popu- Against this background, let us now consider the lists (M5S and Lega) won half of the vote (50.1 per outcome of the German 2017 elections and the cent in the Chamber vote), and a clear majority Italian 2018 elections. In Germany, both incum- of the seats in both chambers. Note that, in the bents lost about one fi ft h of their respective share Italian case, the results of individual parties do of the vote. In absolute terms, the CDU-CSU not tell us as much as in Germany, because the was, however, punished more heavily, because its parties form pre-electoral coalitions. As a result previous vote share had been far larger (41.5 per of these coalitions, there were actually three main cent) than that of the SPD (25.7 per cent). Argu- electoral forces – the centre-right (“centrodestra”), ably, the CDU-CSU was, above all, punished for the centre-left (“centrosinistra”) and the M5S. Angela Merkel’s welcoming asylum policy, while Interestingly, among the three components of

THE POLITICAL SPACE IN ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: ITALIAN AND GERMAN POPULISM COMPARED 150 Hanspeter Kriesi the centre-right we not only fi nd Forza Italia, but ular and is, however, not fully represented in Figure also the Lega and “Fratelli d’Italia”, an extremely 2. Th e reason for this is the above-mentioned nationalistic off shoot of the old Alleanza Nazio- inclusion of the Lega in the centre-right. Between nale created in 2014. In other words, the Italian 2013 and 2018, a shift in the relative power of the centre-right includes the radical right populists, components of the centre-right occurred in Italy, which would still be unthinkable in Germany. On with Berlusconi’s Forza Italia losing its polar posi- the other side, the centre-left includes, in addition tion to the Lega. Back in 2013, the Lega still had to to the PD, the remnants of the Radical Party (Più recover from a major scandal in its own ranks that Europa), and some other minor components, but dates back to the spring of 2012. By 2018, however, no new populist challengers. its new leader, Matteo Salvini, had succeeded in In order to compare the Italian electoral develop- re-positioning the former regionalist party as a ment with the German one, I propose to compare classic radical populist right party that now mobi- the combination of the CDU-CSU and the FDP lised across the entire country, above all on issues with the Italian centrodestra, the SPD with the of immigration and . centrosinistra, and the combination of die Linke Figure 2: Th e outcome of the four most recent and Grüne with the M5S. Figure 2 presents the German and Italian elections development of these camps over the last four elections. In addition to the development of these camps, the fi gure also presents the develop- ment of the AfD for Germany and the Lega separately. Looking at the two countries from this perspec- tive, it becomes quite clear that what distinguishes the two coun- tries is not so much the rise of the radical populist right, which rose to a similar extent in both coun- tries in the most recent elections. What really distinguishes the two countries is the rise of M5S and the spectacular decline of both the centre-left and the traditional centre-right. While However, the Lega still kept its stronghold in the combined radical and New Left in Germany and met with great scepticism in stagnated throughout the 2000s, its functional the South. In order to appreciate the outcome of equivalent in Italy – M5S – proved to be a spec- the Italian 2018 elections correctly, it is actually tacular success. Coming from nowhere it obtained very important to take into account the regional a fourth of the vote (25.6 per cent) in 2013, and diff erences in the electoral outcome. Figure 3 rose to a third (32.7 per cent) in 2018. Without compares a typical northern district – Lombardia any doubt, it benefi ted from the political dissatis- 3, which includes the cities of Brescia, Bergamo faction of the Italians, which reached new heights and Treviglio, with a central district – Toscana – aft er the experience with the Monti government of and a southern district – Sicilia 2, which includes technocrats (2011-2012) that was supported by all Messina, Catania, Ragusa and Syracusa. In the mainstream parties. Th e decline of the tradi- Lombardy, the centre-right largely dominated, tional centre-right has been particularly spectac- in Sicily, M5S took almost half of the vote, while

THE POLITICAL SPACE IN ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: ITALIAN AND GERMAN POPULISM COMPARED 151 Hanspeter Kriesi in Tuscany the three camps of the current Italian 3. The Structure of the party system were of much more equal strength. Party Systems in Germany and If we add the AfD to the centre-right to make it in Italy comparable to the Italian centre-right, the similar- ities between the electoral outcome in Germany Th e return of the FDP to the German Bundestag and Lombardy are striking, as is also shown in did not change much in the structure of the party Figure 3. Table 1 is added to clarify that the simi- system, but the establishment of the AfD did. As larity between the two is more apparent than real, is shown in Figure 4, the German party system is because the power relations within the centre- structured by an economic and a cultural dimen- right are actually very diff erent in Germany and sion which is closely correlated, and appears to be Lombardy: while the mainstream CDU-CSU multi-polar as well. However, this multi-polarity dominates the centre-right in Germany, it is is more apparent than real: with the exception of the Lega that dominates it in Lombardy (and in the AfD, which occupies a similar position as the Tuscany, too). radical populist right parties in north-western Figure 3: Regional diff erences in the Italian Europe, all the parties are located in the upper left - electoral outcome 2018, and German electoral hand corner of the space, relatively close to the outcome 2017 pro-welfare pole of the economic dimension (with the exception of the FDP) and relatively close to cultural liber- alism. It is the contrast between the New Right and the rest of the parties which serves as the crucial structuring device in the German party system today. We should, however, keep in mind that the AfD still has a somewhat limited electoral weight, which means that it contributes only to a limited extent to the polarisa- tion of the German party system. Compared to the position of the New Right, the diff erences between the remaining parties Table 1: Northern Italy vs Germany, outcome of appear of minor importance. last national elections

Party Germany Lombardia3 centre-right 56.3 52.4 Forza Italia-UDC/CDU-CSU 32.9 13.7 Lega/AfD 12.6 34.3 others 10.8 4.4 centre-left 20.5 23.3 M5S/Grüne-Linke 18.1 18.0

THE POLITICAL SPACE IN ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: ITALIAN AND GERMAN POPULISM COMPARED 152 Hanspeter Kriesi Figure 4: Political spaces in Germany and Italy Th e rather unstructured confi guration refl ects the a) Germany unique role played by Silvio Berlusconi, the leader of Forza Italia in Italian politics. Th e election of 2008 roughly coincides with the apex of Berlusconi’s personal dominance over Italian politics. Th e rather unusual confi guration of the political space at the time is likely to be related to the peculiarities of this unique period, during which polit- ical competition revolved more on the personality of individual leaders than on a programme or manifesto. Th e Berlusconi-factor, in turn, also had an important impact on the 2013 electoral campaign. While, in 2008, political competition tended to be one-dimensional, in 2013, it became two- dimensional. As shown in b) Italy Figure 4, the economic and cultural dimensions only play a marginal role in the structuring of political compe- tition in 2013. What really struc- tures the political space, instead, are political issues, and, in particular, the issue of political renewal. On the one hand, we fi nd the PD and M5S (and Mario Monti’s Scelta Civica) pleading in favour of political renewal. On the other hand, the PdL represents the opposite pole with Berlusconi becoming an issue himself, as the main exponent of a political class that the challengers asked to be replaced. For Italy, we do not have the data for the 2018 elec- Th e crucial role of the political crisis in the 2013 tions yet, which is why Figure 4 presents the struc- Italian elections is confi rmed by an analysis of the ture of the Italian party system before the initial rise determinants of the vote for M5S in the elections. of M5S (2008) and aft er its successive rise (2013) Th is analysis is based upon the ESS6, which went (see Karremans et al. 2018). Before the crisis and into the fi eld in Italy aft er these elections. While before the rise of M5S, the Italian political space voters for parties on the radical left and the radical was structured mostly around a bipolar opposi- right typically make their choice based upon a tion between the centrosinistra (PD, IdV) and the combination of substantive concerns (economic centrodestra (PdL + Lega), with issues of welfare, concerns such as re-distribution for the radical left democratic renewal and cultural liberalism on one voters and cultural concerns such as opposition side, opposed to issues of security on the other. to immigration for the radical right voters) and

THE POLITICAL SPACE IN ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: ITALIAN AND GERMAN POPULISM COMPARED 153 Hanspeter Kriesi of democratic discontent, the voters for M5S did coalition or a CDU-CSU minority government not distinguish themselves from the mainstream remained as the only option. Although the leader voters with respect to any substantive preferences. of the SPD had originally excluded a remake of the Instead, the key determinant for the M5S vote grand coalition between the CDU-CSU and the was general dissatisfaction with the way democ- SPD, aft er the intervention of the President, the racy worked in Italy. Th is is illustrated by Figure SPD’s leadership reluctantly decided to enter coali- 5, which presents the average marginal eff ects tion negotiations nevertheless. Th ese negotiations (estimated with logit models based upon ESS6 dragged on until February and were eventually data) for some key substantive preferences and for concluded with a coalition contract that still had two measures of democratic discontent (general to be approved by the two parties. In the case of the political dissatisfaction and dissatisfaction with SPD, this meant consulting its 460,000 members, government responsiveness). part of whom heavily contested the renewal of Figure 5: Eff ects of cultural/economic prefer- a grand coalition. Aft er a four month stalemate, ences and democratic dissatisfaction on vote for the SPD membership eventually approved the M5S (2013) contract on 4 March 2018 by a two-thirds majority. Th e old and new chancellor, Angela Merkel, has paid a high price for the new coalition government. Although even more weakened in the elections than the CDU-CSU, the SPD obtained important concessions in the coali- tion negotiations and sees its posi- tion strengthened in the future grand coalition. Aft er the installation of the grand coalition, there is the prospect of a sustained period of a stable, albeit weak, government. In Italy, the confi guration in Parlia- ment resulting from the 2018 election made government formation equally diffi cult. No feasible combination of parties seemed to have the number of 4. The consequences of these seats necessary to form a government. Th e centre- election outcomes right, which claimed to have won the elections, fell clearly short of the necessary majority, as did M5S, From these election results, we can observe a which also claimed to have won the elections. A weakening of the government in both countries. coalition between M5S and the centre-left , which Th e German elections resulted in a confi guration was attempted by M5S was vetoed by the Renziani in parliament which made coalition formation in the PD. Aft er a protracted period of negotia- diffi cult and led to the Federal Republic’s longest tions that lasted almost three months and a fi nal period without a government since World War stretch of extremely tense negotiations between II. A fi rst attempt to form a so-called “Jamaica” the prospective coalition partners and the Italian coalition composed of the CDU-CSU, the Liberals President Sergio Mattarella, the originally rather (FDP) and the Greens spectacularly failed in unlikely combination of the two populist parties late November 2017. Aft er this failure, a grand – the Lega and the M5S – succeeded in forming

THE POLITICAL SPACE IN ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: ITALIAN AND GERMAN POPULISM COMPARED 154 Hanspeter Kriesi a government. This government promises to seen how they will react to the economic policies, be weak as well, given its internal contradic- once the new government attempts to implement tions. Thus, the combination of the substantive them. economic demands of the two coalition partners promises to be explosive: while the Lega intends to 5. Conclusion implement the centre-right’s key electoral promise of a flat tax for both individuals and corporations, After the last elections, Germany is once more which will reduce government revenue consider- governed from the centre, while Italy – a first in ably, the M5S intends to implement a very costly Western Europe – is governed by a coalition of social security project, the so-called reddito di populist parties. The German grand coalition cittadinanza (a sort of minimum income for is not so grand after all. It is based upon a tight the unemployed). Moreover, the Lega plans to absolute majority of 53 per cent of the vote. For tighten immigration legislation in a heavy-handed the time being, the challengers from both left and manner, whereas the M5S has been supported by right are marginalised in Germany, and the ques- many former voters from the left, who are rather tion is how they will react to their powerlessness. opposed to such measures. They might get another chance in the not too distant future. The fact that the German govern- The latent Euroscepticism of both of these parties, ment rests on a rather small popular base suggests but especially of the Lega, will make for difficult that the electoral situation in Germany is far from relations with Italy’s European partners. Already, stable. The major conflict between the nationalist- the new cabinet is seeking to re-negotiate the conservative forces defending the nation-state rules for the distribution of refugees as well as the and its citizens and the forward-looking forces rules for economic deficits in the EU. The new promoting cultural liberalism, European inte- Italian government is likely to re-inforce German gration, and openness to immigrants is far from prudence which has already been putting the brake settled in Germany. on the great plans for Europe of the new French President Emmanuel Macron. But given that Italy In Italy, the new populist coalition is articulating is one of the founding members of the EU, the both, the conflict between cosmopolitan and sanctioning capacity of the EU, with regard to the nationalist-conservative forces, and the economic difficulties which are likely to be created by the new conflict between the rich and the poor, which is Italian government, is likely to be rather limited. also a regional conflict between the North and the By contrast, the markets are likely to impose more South. In both of these conflicts, the two compo- strict constraints on this government, as was illus- nents of the governing coalition tend to defend trated during the final phase of the government opposing interests: while the Lega defends the formation: the markets reacted sharply when the nationalistic position, especially with regard to leaders of the two populist parties submitted a immigration, the M5S is more multi-culturally list of prospective ministers to the President of oriented, and, while the M5S defends the poor Italy which included a finance minister who was Southerners, the Lega defends the Northerners an explicit opponent of Italy’s membership in the who are unwilling to pay for the South. How the Eurozone: the two-year yield on Italian govern- two coalition partners intend to square the circle ment bonds jumped from 0.27 to 2.72 per cent remains to be seen, but it is clear that the Italian over three trading days at the height of the negoti- electoral situation is also far from stable. ations between the President and the two populist leaders. When the latter backed down and were prepared to compromise, the markets calmed down to some extent, although it remains to be

THE POLITICAL SPACE IN ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: ITALIAN AND GERMAN POPULISM COMPARED 155 Hanspeter Kriesi References Morisi (2018). Chapter 6: “Italy – The End of Bipolarism: Restructuring in an Unstable Party Betz, Hans-Georg (2015). “The Revenge of the System”, in: Restructuring European Party Poli- Ploucs: The Revival of Radical Populism under tics in Times of Crises, edited by Swen Hutter Marine Le Pen in France”, in: Hanspeter Kriesi and Hanspeter Kriesi, unpubl. Ms, Florence: and Takis Pappas (eds), European Populism in European University Institute. the Shadow of the Great Recession. Colchester: Kriesi, Hanspeter, Jasmine Lorenzini and Silja ECPR Press. Häusermann (eds.) (2018). Contention in Bornschier, Simon (2015). “The New Cultural Times of Crises. Comparing Political Protest in Conflict, Polarization, and Representation in 30 European Countries: 2000-2015, unpubl. the Swiss Party System, 1975-2011”, Swiss Polit- Ms., Florence:European University Institute. ical Science Review 21, 4: 680-701 Kriesi, Hanspeter, Edgar Grande, Martin Dolezal, Bornschier, Simon (2010). Cleavage Politics and Marc Helbling, Dominic Höglinger, Swen the Populist Right. The New Cultural Conflict Hutter and Bruno Wueest (2012). Polit- in Western Europe. Philadelphia PA: Temple ical Conflict in Western Europe. Cambridge: University Press. Cambridge University Press. Bornschier, Simon (2010a). “The New Cultural Kriesi, Hanspeter, Edgar Grande, Romain Lachat, Divide and the Two-Dimensional Political Martin Dolezal, Simon Bornschier, Timotheos Space in Western Europe”, West European Poli- Frey (2008). West European Politics in the Age of tics 33 (3): 419-444. Globalization. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer- Bremer, Björn, and Julia Schulte-Cloos (2018). sity Press. “No Country for the New Right? Restructuring Mair, Peter 2013. Ruling the Void: The Hollowing of British and German Party Politics, in: Restruc- Western Democracy. London, New York: Verso turing European Party Politics in Times of Crises, Books. edited by Swen Hutter and Hanspeter Kriesi, Mair, Peter (2002). “Populist Democracy vs Party unpubl. Ms, Florence: European University Democracy”, in: Democracies and the Populist Institute. Challenge, edited by Yves Mény and Yves Surel. Hutter, Swen, and Hanspeter Kriesi (eds) (2018). Basingstoke: Palgrave, pp. 81-98. Restructuring European Party Politics in Times Roodujin, Matthijs, Wouter van der Brug, Sarah L. of Crises, unpubl. Ms., Florence: European de Lange 2016. “Expressing or Fueling Discon- University Institute. tent? The Relationship between Populist Voting Hutter, Swen, Hanspeter Kriesi and Guillem Vidal and Political Discontent”, Electoral Studies 43 (2018). Old versus New Politics: The Political (1): 32-40. Spaces in Southern Europe in Times of Crises, Party Politics 24 (1): 10-22. Kitschelt, Herbert (1994). The Transformation of European Social Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Kitschelt, Herbert (1995). The Radical Right in Western Europe: A Comparative Analysis. Ann Arbor MI: University of Michigan Press. Karremans, Johannes, Giorgio Malet and Davide

THE POLITICAL SPACE IN ITALY AND GERMANY DURING THE CRISIS: ITALIAN AND GERMAN POPULISM COMPARED 156 Hanspeter Kriesi THE POLITICAL ECONOMY In the short run, growth is driven by a combina- OF RECOVERY IN SOUTHERN tion of consumption, investment, and exports. In the longer run, growth depends on rising produc- EUROPE tivity (and more jobs created than destroyed). In turn, rising productivity depends once again on Manos Matsaganis more (and more productive) investment. Politecnico di Milano On this count, the evidence gives plenty of cause Has Southern Europe recovered from the Great for concern. As explained elsewhere116, in the Recession and the Eurozone crisis? context of harsh, externally imposed austerity, The question is simple, but the answer is complex – national governments (and firms) have found it and differs from the point of view of the economy, expedient to cut investment by more than they cut the social situation, and politics. A laconic assess- consumption spending. ment, valid as of September 2018, would have to This was true in all countries: gross fixed capital be ‘partly’, ‘not much’, ‘not at all’ respectively. For a formation in the EU was cut back by 13.4% in slightly fuller one, read on. 2008-2013, while over the same period final consumption expenditure held constant (-0.1%). 1. The economy In Southern Europe, where consumption fell quite significantly during the crisis, investment In 2017, GDP in the EU grew faster than expected, collapsed spectacularly: comparing 2008 and by 2.4%. This may look rather modest, but repre- 2013, the cumulative decline was 25.5% in Italy, sented, as DG-ECFIN pointed out, “the highest 35.0% and 36.5% in Spain and Portugal respecti- growth rate in 10 years”. Furthermore, for the first vely, and a massive 61.3% in Greece. time since the onset of the crisis, in 2017 growth was positive in all EU member states. In 2013-2017, investment bounced back in Europe, registering an increase of 14.4%, while consump- In 2013-2017, Southern Europe returned to posi- tion rose by half as much (7.1%) in the same tive rates of growth. The economy grew by a cumu- period. By doing so, pre-crisis levels of gross fixed lative 11.5% in Spain, and 7.2% in Portugal. Italy capital formation were almost fully restored (-1.0% (3.4%) and Greece (1.6%) did less well. Over the in 2008-2017 in the EU28). During the recovery, same period, the European economy as a whole investment also fared better than consumption in (EU28) expanded by 8.7%. the four South European member states, but that Nevertheless, Southern European economies have was not nearly enough to make up for the losses not yet regained the ground they lost during the of the previous period. By the end of 2017, gross Great Recession and the Eurozone crisis. By the fixed capital formation in Italy was 20.5% lower end of 2017, only in Spain had GDP surpassed its than it had been in 2008, 21.4% in Spain, 23.9% in 2008 level (by a mere 1.6%). In Portugal, it was Portugal, and as much as 59.1% lower in Greece 1.2% lower. In Italy, the shortfall was 4.4%. In (Table 1). Greece, the size of the economy was 25.1% smaller than it was pre-crisis115. Why is it that the recovery has been so slow and uneven in Southern Europe? 115 See Eurostat “GDP and main components (output, expenditure and income) [nama_10_gdp]”, NA_ITEM: Gross domestic product at market prices, UNIT: Chain linked volu- 116 See Perez S.A. & Matsaganis M. (2018) The political mes, index 2010=100. Last update: 04/09/2018. Extracted on: economy of austerity in Southern Europe. New Political Eco- 05/09/2018. nomy 23 (2) 192-207.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF RECOVERY IN SOUTHERN EUROPE 157 Manos Matsaganis Table 1: Consumption and investment (2008- In terms of export performance, the fortunes of 2017) South European economies began to diverge considerably during the crisis. The fall Final consumption expenditure 2008-2013 2013-2017 2008-2017 in domestic demand presented all firms EU28 -0.1 7.1 7.0 in all countries with a strong incentive to Greece -24.3 -0.4 -24.6 switch to export markets. However, the Spain -9.3 8.8 -1.3 degree to which they actually succeeded Italy -5.7 3.6 -2.3 in doing so differed greatly between Portugal -9.4 7.3 -2.8 countries. In the EU as a whole, exports Gross fixed capital formation 2008-2013 2013-2017 2008-2017 grew by 9.1% in 2008-2013. In Portugal EU28 -13.4 14.4 -1.0 and Spain, a strong export performance Greece -61.3 5.7 -59.1 (+16.4% and +10.2% respectively) Spain -35.0 21.1 -21.4 cushioned the effects of the crisis on Italy -25.5 6.7 -20.5 employment and earnings. In contrast, Portugal -36.5 19.9 -23.9 exports decreased in Italy (-0.7%) and, especially, in Greece (-12.2%) over the Note: The figures are cumulative rates of change in the end of a period relative to the start of the period, as a percentage of same period, contributing to the recession instead the latter. of mitigating its impact. Source: Eurostat “GDP and main components (output, More recently, exports increased significantly expenditure and income) [nama_10_gdp]”, NA_ITEM: Final throughout Europe (+20.7% in the EU28 in consumption expenditure / Gross fixed capital formation, 2013-2017). This was also the case in the four UNIT: Chain linked volumes, index 2010=100. Last update: 04/09/2018. Extracted on: 05/09/2018. South European member states, although again at varying degrees: in 2013-2017, exports grew by vvvReal labour productivity per hour worked 24.7% in Portugal, by 19.5% in Spain, by 16.5% in improved throughout Europe during the crisis Greece, and by 15.8% in Italy. (+5.1% in the EU28 in 2008-2013). This implies Overall, relative to the EU as a whole, exports grew that the jobs destroyed were less productive than faster in Portugal, and just as fast in Spain. On the those saved or created anew. This was even more contrary, in Italy, and especially Greece, exports the case in Spain (+10.0%) and Portugal (+6.7%). failed to provide the necessary stimulus. Compa- However, labour productivity barely increased in ring the latest figures with pre-crisis, in 2017 Italy (+1.1% in 2008-2013), and actually fell in exports were 45.2% higher than they had been in Greece during the crisis (-8.4%). in 2008 in Portugal, and 31.7% in Spain (same as As the economy picked up, creating more jobs the EU28 average). Over the same period, exports (including some less productive ones), advances grew by only 14.9% in Italy, while they barely grew in labour productivity were slower (+3.7% in at all in Greece (+2.2%)118. the EU28 in 2013-2017). Nevertheless, with the Summing up, in terms of a range of economic indi- exception of Spain (+2.8%), real labour produc- cators (economic growth, resumption of invest- tivity per hour worked declined in Portugal and ment, increases in labour productivity, and export Greece (-0.9% and -0.6% respectively), and stag- 117 performance), Spain and Portugal did signifi- nated in Italy (0.0% in 2013-2017) . In view of cantly better than Italy during the recovery, while that, except in Spain, there was little evidence of a Greece fell further behind. shift to a higher-productivity growth model (and, in the case of Greece, clear signs of a retreat to an even lower-productivity growth model). 117 See Eurostat “Labour productivity and unit labour 118 See Eurostat “GDP and main components (output, ex- costs [nama_10_lp_ulc]”, NA_ITEM: Real labour producti- penditure and income) [nama_10_gdp]”, NA_ITEM: Exports vity per hour worked, UNIT: Index 2010=100. Last update: of goods and services, UNIT: Chain linked volumes, index 05/09/2018. Extracted on: 05/09/2018. 2010=100. Last update: 05/09/2018. Extracted on: 05/09/2018.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF RECOVERY IN SOUTHERN EUROPE 158 Manos Matsaganis 2. The social situation in the recovery). Moreover, fewer of the jobs that have been created Th e rise in unemployment was the most characte- since the trough of the recession are full-time ristic feature of the Great Recession and the Euro- than used to be the case pre-crisis. Even though zone crisis. Th ere is no doubt that the unemploy- the share of part-time in total employment is still ment rate is on the decrease in Europe, including lower in the four South European economies than in its Southern periphery. Nevertheless, because of in the EU as a whole, it went up in all four at a recent changes in labour supply (demography and faster rate than average between 2008 and 2013. migration), there has been less net job creation Th ereaft er, it continued to rise in Italy and Greece, than might be thought from inspection of changes though it has fallen back in Spain and, especially, in the unemployment rate alone. Portugal. In 2017, the share of part-time in total In fact, focusing on the total number of workers employment was 4.4 percentage points higher in jobs makes it clear that fewer jobs have been than in 2008 in Italy, 4.3 in Greece, 3.3 in Spain, created during the recovery in Southern Europe while it was practically constant (+0.1 pp.) in than were lost during the crisis (Figure 1). Portugal. In the EU as a whole, the share of part- Specifi cally, in the EU as a whole, there were 13.43 time in total employment rose by 1.9 percentage 120 million more workers in 2018q1 than there had points in 2008-2017 . been in 2013q1. By comparison, there were 12.25 Figure 1: Net job creation (2007-2018) million fewer workers in 2013q1 than there had been in 2008q3. In view of that, the ratio between net job creation in the recovery and net job destruction in the crisis for the European economy as a whole is 1.10 (i.e. 10% more jobs have been created in the recent period than were lost in the previous period)119. Repeating the exercise for the South European economies (and taking into account diff erences in the timing of peak and trough, and the latest data available) shows that none of the four Notes: Th e blue bars show the diff erence in numbers of has yet created as many jobs in the recovery as workers in employment at the trough of the recession, rela- were lost during the crisis. tive to the pre-crisis peak. Th e red bars show the diff erence in numbers of workers in employment at the latest quarter for Portugal, with a ratio of 0.74, implying that 26% which data are available, relative to the trough of the reces- fewer jobs have been recently created than were sion. Both diff erences are normalised as a percentage of the previously lost, comes closest. Th e corresponding number of workers in employment in 2008q3. Pre-crisis peak ratio in Spain is 0.61. In Italy, it is only 0.50 (i.e. was 2007q3 in Spain, 2008q2 in Italy and Portugal, 2008q3 only half the jobs lost have been recently created). in Greece and EU28. Th e trough of the recession was 2013q1 in the EU28 and all South European countries except Greece In Greece, the ratio of net job creation to net job (2013q4). Th e latest quarter for which data are available is destruction is a disappointing 0.20 (i.e. for every 2018q2 in Spain and Portugal, and 2018q1 everywhere else. fi ve jobs lost in the crisis, only one has been created Source: Eurostat “Employment by sex, age and citizenship (1 000) [lfsq_egan]”, SEX: Total, AGE: From 15 to 64 years, 119 Note that job creation and job destruction take place simultaneously at all times in all economies. The difference CITIZEN: Total, UNIT: Th ousand. Last update: 04/09/2018. between the two is ‘net job creation’ (or, when it is negative, Extracted on: 05/09/2018. ‘net job destruction’). Note also that the terms ‘net job creation’ and ‘net job destruction’ are used a bit loosely in the text. Since 120 See Eurostat “Part-time employment as percentage of it is possible for a worker to hold more than one job at the the total employment, by sex and age (%) [lfsa_eppga]”, SEX: same time, changes in the number of workers in employment Total, AGE: From 15 to 64 years. Last update: 03/08/2018. (as reported in the text) need not be identical to changes in the Extracted on: 05/09/2018. number of jobs.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF RECOVERY IN SOUTHERN EUROPE 159 Manos Matsaganis Wage growth remained sluggish. In hourly terms, Summing up, in terms of a range of social indi- taking into account the growth in part-time work, cators (net job creation, real wage growth, and between 2013 and 2016 there was virtually zero income inequality), all four South European growth in real wages in Southern Europe except for economies lost ground relative to the EU as a Spain (1.7%). In the EU as a whole, real compen- whole. Portugal did better in terms of net job crea- sation of employees per hour worked increased tion and income inequality (though not as regards by 3.3%. In 2008-2016, real hourly wages fell by real wage growth), followed by Spain in terms 0.7% in Italy, 1.2% in Spain, 4.4% in Portugal, and of real wage growth and, partly, net job creation 16.1% in Greece. In the EU as a whole, they rose (though not as regards income inequality). Italy by 4.2%121. did less well, and Greece did worst. Poor performance in terms of net job creation and sluggish wage growth contributed to rising 3. Politics inequality (except in Portugal). Between 2008 and This is not the right place (nor, for that matter, 2013, the income quintile ratio (S80/S20) rose the right author) for a discussion of recent poli- significantly in Greece (+0.7 points), Italy (+0.6) tical developments in Southern Europe. However, and Spain (+0.7). In 2013-2016 it continued to it is to see that one common aspect is the rise of grow in Italy (+0.5) and Spain (+0.3), though it new political actors in the context of great poli- remained stable in Greece. In Portugal, the S80/ tical instability. Again, Portugal stands out, with S20 ratio fell by 0.1 points in each period. In the a socialist minority government enjoying the EU28, it increased slightly (by 0.1 and 0.2 points external support of the two left parties in parlia- in 2008-2013 and 2013-2016 respectively), though ment since October 2015. In Spain, two new at 5.2 in 2016 it still remained well below the levels parties, the leftist Podemos and the centrist Ciuda- of Southern Europe (5.9 in Portugal, 6.3 in Italy, danos are challenging the primacy of the socia- 6.6 in Greece and Spain)122. list PSOE and conservative PP, in the context of a Estimates of the Gini index revealed similar constitutional crisis provoked by the ‘declaration trends. In 2008-2016, the value of the index rose of independence’ of . In Italy, the March significantly in Greece, Spain and Italy, and fell 2018 general election brought to power a “souvra- slightly in Portugal. In 2016, all four Southern nist” coalition of the populist Five Star Movement European countries were clustered together near and the anti-immigration Lega. In Greece, a coali- the top of the income inequality league table in tion of the radical left and the nationalist right is the EU, ranking 5th to 8th, that is between 2 and 4 in power since January 2015. In all four count- percentage points above the EU average. Among ries, the political parties that introduced austerity all member states, the Gini coefficient was now policies, usually reluctantly, lost ground and were higher only in , Lithuania, and evicted from power. Latvia – and, in the latter two countries, only very Popular sentiments towards the EU partly reflect slightly so123. that reaction. In October 2008, the share of Euro- 121 See Eurostat “Labour productivity and unit labour barometer respondents who ‘tended to trust the costs [nama_10_lp_ulc]”, NA_ITEM: Real compensation of employees per hour worked based on hCPI, UNIT: Euro (2015 EU’ was 41% in Italy, 50% in Portugal, 55% in prices). Last update: 20/12/2017. Extracted on: 30/12/2017. Spain, and 58% in Greece (relative to 47% across 122 See Eurostat “S80/S20 income quintile share ratio the EU as a whole). Within less than five years by sex and selected age group - EU-SILC survey [ilc_di11]”, (in May 2013), trust in the EU had collapsed: it INDIC_IL: Inequality of income distribution (income quintile share ratio). Last update: 18/01/2018. Extracted on: had fallen to 25% in Italy, 24% in Portugal, 17% 24/01/2018. in Spain, and 19% in Greece (31% in the EU as a 123 See Eurostat “Gini coefficient of equivalised disposable whole). By May 2017, trust in the EU had bounced income - EU-SILC survey [ilc_di12]”. Last update: 08/11/2017. back, especially in Portugal (54%), and Spain Extracted on: 13/01/2018.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF RECOVERY IN SOUTHERN EUROPE 160 Manos Matsaganis (40%), to a lesser degree in Italy (36%), and much less Greece (22%). In the EU as a whole, it stood at 47%. It is difficult to miss the connection between the rise of anti-EU popular sentiments and political actors in Europe’s Southern periphery on the one hand, and the management of the Eurozone crisis by Germany and other core countries on the other hand. For instance, Italy used to be one of the most pro-EU countries in Europe. In 2011-2018, successive Italian governments (headed in turn by Monti, Letta, Renzi, and Gentiloni) failed to find solutions within the constraints of EU commit- ments. Some of the reasons for that failure are obviously domestic. Some but not all: perhaps it is time we recognised that, given external cons- traints, being a pro-EU reformer in the European periphery is next to impossible.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF RECOVERY IN SOUTHERN EUROPE 161 Manos Matsaganis ACCOMMODATING EU‘S As a result of these novelties, the new strategy was INFLUENCE VS PROTECTING initially welcomed as a possible promising step towards a stronger social Europe (cf. Marlier et NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY. al. 2010). However, later contributions have cast doubts on the effectiveness of both the new strategy THE FIGHT AGAINST – and more generally the EU – in combating POVERTY IN ITALY AND poverty and social exclusion (Pochet 2010; Cope- GERMANY AT THE TIME OF land and Daly 2012 and 2014; Armstrong 2012; “EUROPE 2020” Peña-Casas 2012), due to limited progress along several dimensions (cf. Bouget et al. 2015; Frazer Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula and Marlier 2016) and especially towards the University of Milan target which seems, in fact, unreachable. Against such backdrop, this chapter asks whether I. Introduction124 and how Europe has mattered in the fight against poverty and social exclusion under the In the field of anti-poverty policies, which have novel Europe 2020 institutional framework, constituted a major brick of ‘social Europe’ since by comparing the effects entailed in Italy and decades (cf. Armstrong 2010), the EU’s over- Germany, during the first five annual cycles of the arching strategy Europe 2020 has actually marked European Semester. The two countries allow for a a major discontinuity vis à vis the Social OMC particularly stimulating comparative assessement, of the Lisbon phase (2000–10). Not only did the as they represent two rather opposite worlds of new strategy provide an institutional framework implementation (cf. Jessoula and Madama 2018), – the European ‘Semester’ – for stronger (at least featuring distinct domestic patterns and effects formally) integration between social – mainly that call for interpretation. anti-poverty – policies and the broader European The chapter is organised as follows. Section 2 framework for financial-economic governance. It offers a comparative overview of the empirical also replaced the vague objective of ‘eradicating evidence about the reception of Europe 2020 in poverty’, included in the former Lisbon Strategy, the two countries and the national-supranational with a possibly less ambitious but more realistic interactions around the issue of poverty and social and potentially more incisive quantified poverty exclusion over the first five cycles of the Semester. target. Lifting at least 20 million people out of Section 3 deals with the factors affecting the diverse poverty and social exclusion by 2020 is, in fact, one implementation of EU inputs at the domestic level of the five targets as well as the main social innova- in the two countries, emphasising the relevance of tion of Europe 2020. In order to reach the quanti- national politico-institutional contexts, as filtering fied poverty target, in 2012 a key link between the EU’s influence. Section 4 concludes. new strategy and European funds was introduced: within the 2014–20 multi-annual financial frame- II. Accommodating EU‘s work, Member States (MS) are actually required influence vs protecting to allocate at least 20 per cent of European Social Fund’s resources to combating poverty. national sovereignty: two worlds of domestic effects 124 This text elaborates on the findings collected in the volume “Fighting poverty and social exclusion in the EU. A The investigation of EU’s impact in the context of chance in Europe 2020” (Jessoula, M. and Madama, I., eds., non-binding, soft coordination processes is not an Routledge, 2018) and has been written in the context of the RESCEU Project (Reconciling economic and social Europe, easy task. After the launch of the Lisbon Strategy www.resceu.eu), funded by the European Research Council in 2000s, an intense academic debate has flour- (Advanced Grant no. 340534).

ACCOMMODATING EU‘S INFLUENCE VS PROTECTING NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY. 162 THE FIGHT AGAINST POVERTY IN ITALY AND GERMANY AT THE TIME OF “EUROPE 2020” Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula ished around the potential and the limits of policy an effect’ (Graziano and Vink 2007, p. 9), research coordination mechanisms based on soft-law, as strategies must be designed carefully – both those foreween by the social-OMC. The assess- analytically and theoretically – and are required to ments of the effectiveness of such procesess to rely on several methods, such as in-depth process prompt national tracing and careful triangulation of empirical social policy developments in line with common evidences. objectives and/or supranational guidelines and Situating within this strand of research and recommendations have however resulted in drawing from the above mentioned consider- rather contrasting findings. Some authors have ations, the analytical framework used to inves- emphasized the weakness of the Social OMC, tigate the (possible) effects triggered by Europe suggesting that both its non-binding nature and 2020 at the national level aimed at shortening the the lack of sanctions have hampered the attain- causal chain by exploring procedural (i.e. related ment of commonly agreed objectives (i.e. Barbier to governance and policy-making processes), and 2005; Armstrong 2006). Others have interpreted substantive changes at the national level (i.e. policy the lack of coercion as a fruitful condition for reforms), rather than outcomes (i.e. poverty the unfolding of experimentations and learning trends).125 More precisely, the empirical inves- processes through deliberative forms of gover- tigation of national-supranational interactions nance, while respecting MS heterogeneity (for a in the field of anti-poverty policy was driven by review, cf. Heidenreich and Zeitlin 2009) as well five original expectations concerning the possible as sovereignty. impact of the supranational anti-poverty strategy. From an analytical standpoint, it must be acknowl- Drawing from the literature on Social-OMC and edged that the non-binding, soft nature of this on the key institutional novelties of the EU2020 kind of coordination processes, within the realm strategy we expected that, compared to the OMC- of European social policy governance, makes Lisbon phase, the Europe 2020 strategy could more EU’s impact more difficult to capture and isolate, likely produce substantive effects due to the exis- because it tends to unfold gradually and rarely tence of EU’s hard poverty target – also combined impacts on policy decisions, rather affecting ‘less with growing ‘problem pressure’. This may have tangible’ elements such as ideas, values and proce- increased the salience of poverty (substantive dures. Furthermore, as argued by Barcevičius effect no. 1), as well as prompted – under favour- et al. (2014, p. 35), when processes of soft coor- able conditions – agenda shifts and revision of dination are considered, ‘influences on policy- national legislation (substantive effect no. 2). As making must be “domesticated” – that is must pass for procedural effects, we expected an impact on through national policy processes and be adapted both the integration and participation dimen- to national contexts – before feeding into Member sions, but in opposite directions: increased cross- State policy decisions’. This branch of literature sector and cross-department coordination, that is therefore comes with two main and opposite more integration across policy sectors triggered by risks: on the one hand, the risk of downplaying the Semester governance architecture (procedural EU-related factors in explaining domestic change; effect no. 3) versus a step back in (multi-)stake- on the other, causal over-determination. holder involvement (procedural effect no. 4), due to

As argued by Lehmkuhl (2007, p. 342), the disen- 125 From a methodological standpoint, the study relied tanglement of the net effect of Europe from other on qualitative research methods, primarily ‘process tracing’ factors and the re-entanglement of mutually (Collier 2011), based on the analysis of several primary and secondary sources, complemented by a large number of supporting or inhibiting factors remain at the top semi-structured interviews with key informants – i.e. insti- of the Europeanization research agenda. Yet, to tutional, political and social actors at different government avoid making ‘EU influence a cause in search of levels. Interviews were conducted between October 2012 and December 2015. For details, see Jessoula and Madama (2018).

ACCOMMODATING EU‘S INFLUENCE VS PROTECTING NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY. 163 THE FIGHT AGAINST POVERTY IN ITALY AND GERMANY AT THE TIME OF “EUROPE 2020” Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula the switch from the OMC to Europe 2020 gover- social exclusion – and especially the anti-poverty nance framework. Last, we expected that effects target. Chancellor Angela Merkel herself explic- might unfold slowly over time, from the first to itly affirmed, in March 2010, ‘I will not give any the fifth cycle (procedural effect no. 5), as a conse- support for a quantitative target’ to be included quence of both the institutionalization of the iter- in the European strategy against poverty (cf. ative governance processes and on-going supra- Zimmermann and Petzold 2018). The government national actions aimed at reinforcing governance somehow exploited the critical juncture repre- mechanisms and EU’s steering power. sented by the genetic moment of Europe 2020, and Field research has shown that significant varia- especially the launch of the strategy implementa- tion has characterized the implementation of tion at the national level, to strongly filter supra- the Europe 2020 anti-poverty component at the national ‘soft’ but strengthened pressures aimed to national level in Italy and Germany. The main support the achievement of the Europe 2020 ‘hard’ findings are summarized below, starting from poverty target. As further evidence of such resis- substantive effects126. tance against the perceived EU ‘intrusion’ in a field of national sovereignty, not surprisingly Germany Substantive effects: two diverse did not define the national anti-poverty targets implementation patterns in accordance with AROPE indicators agreed at the EU level and opted for quantified targets that With regard to effects in the political sphere better matched national priorities and strategies, entailed by Europe 2020 implementation, setting the reduction of long-term unemploy- Germany and Italy have followed two rather ment as the national objective in the Europe 2020 different implementation patterns. In Germany framework. Therefore, claims about the defense of the launch of Europe 2020 prompted a lively reac- national ‘social’ sovereignty went in parallel with tion by the national government aimed at tack- the domestic reframing and reinterpretation of ling supranational ‘intrusion’ in domestic social the EU anti-poverty target in accordance with the policy-making. Such resistance, as well as oppo- national approach as well as government’ orienta- sition, by national governments was particularly tions to combat poverty and social exclusion. strong in the initial phase of the new overarching The reactions were radically different in Italy, strategy: the inclusion of the poverty target among where the launch of Europe 2020, with its poverty the five main Europe 2020 quantitative objec- target, was much less politically contentious. The tives was actually perceived to have the potential country had broadly supported the introduction of greatly increasing the visibility of the issue at of a common quantified EU anti-poverty target the supranational level, thus legitimizing further (Copeland and Daly 2012), and the politicization interference by European institutions in domestic of the matter during the critical juncture was low. anti-poverty agendas. When drafting the first NRP in 2011, the issue was In the Bundestag, the Conservative-liberal coali- mostly dealt with at the administrative level, with tion (CDU-CSU, FDP) overtly supported the first limited (or no) direct engagement of the main three Europe 2020 headline targets – concerning politico-institutional actors. Italy also complied employment, R&D/innovation and climate with European prescriptions by setting the anti- change/energy – but clearly rejected the social poverty goals in congruence with agreed indica- dimension of the overarching supranational tors: lifting 2.2 million people out of poverty or strategy – addressing education and poverty/ social exclusion by 2020. Interestingly, Italy is one of the countries where 126 The comparative evidence presented here elaborates on the findings of the researches conducted by Zimmermann and the Europe 2020 strategy has produced the most Petzold (2018) and Madama, Natili and Agostini (2018). relevant substantive effects in the subsequent

ACCOMMODATING EU‘S INFLUENCE VS PROTECTING NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY. 164 THE FIGHT AGAINST POVERTY IN ITALY AND GERMANY AT THE TIME OF “EUROPE 2020” Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula cycles. From the first to the fifth cycle, anti- Germany. The shift from the Lisbon-OMC period poverty policies gained momentum and substan- to Europe 2020 actually resulted in very limited, tive effects could be detected in the ideational and in fact diminished, stakeholder involvement sphere, partly percolating into national legisla- – especially NGOs and anti-poverty groups. The tion. This happened, first, through the initiatives drafting of the first NRPs in 2011 constituted a aimed to re-direct the usage of ESF funds in order centralized exercise, which involved ministries to tackle the poverty challenge in accordance with and peak bureaucracy only in both countries. the national anti-poverty target; second, through However, from the second cycle in 2012, things the reform and the gradual expansion of the newly have slightly changed in Germany. This gradual launched anti-poverty national measure (the change is in line with our fifth expectation about Social Card pilot project, soon re-named Support the effects unfolding slowly over time due to iter- for Active Inclusion, SIA). ated multi-level and multi-stakeholder interac- tions. According to an institutionalized national Procedural effects: a mixed procedure known as ‘Social Monitoring’ (Sozial- picture after a weak start monitoring), the Federal Ministry of Labor and Social Affairs invited several actors to hearings When considering procedural effects, the imple- aimed at discussing the preparation of national mentation of the Europe 2020 strategy at the reports. The audience was quite broad – including national level appears heterogeneous, and initial NGOs, social partners, the national network of expectations about both (increased) cross- EAPN and municipalities – and some organiza- sectoral integration and (reduced) multi-level and tions were also asked to comment on draft NRPs multi-stakeholder involvement were only partly (cf. Zimmermann and Petzold 2018)127. confirmed. In Italy, stakeholder involvement and actor partic- With regard to the strategy potential to trigger ipation in drafting NRPs has remained limited, more integration, and possibly coordination, across thus shaping a visible step back compared to the different policy fields and departmental (mainly, Social OMC. The Italian case however is more ministerial) structures, findings are mixed. In complex, and actually two-faced. On the one hand, Germany NRP drafting was a centralized process openness to societal interests was low in drafting in the hands of finance ministries, with only NRPs, especially in the area of poverty and social poor inter-ministerial coordination/integration exclusion; on the other, this was in sharp contrast between economic (and even employment) poli- with the highly participatory approach adopted, cies and social/anti-poverty measures. In Italy, an still within the Europe 2020 framework, but in attempt to strengthen cross-sector policy integra- relation to the planning of structural funds for the tion was made in ESF planning for the 2014–2020 2014–2020 cycle (cf. Madama et al. 2018). budget cycle, a process which registered higher coordination and cooperation across ministries III. Two worlds of domestic and government levels than in drafting NRPs. effects: investigating the With regard to the second dimension of proce- factors behind dural effects, both horizontal (multi-stakeholder) and vertical (multi-level) participation once more The empirical evidence presented in the previous revealed substantial variation. Our initial expecta- section shows that Italy and Germany represent tion about the possible reduction of stakeholder 127 Although the European Semester cycles did actually involvement – in light of the relatively weak provide opportunities to societal interests operating in the area of poverty and social exclusion of being heard by policy mak- Europe 2020 governance structure compared to ers, in some cases stakeholders complained that their chances the Social OMC – was confirmed in both Italy and to influence governments’ decisions remained weak.

ACCOMMODATING EU‘S INFLUENCE VS PROTECTING NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY. 165 THE FIGHT AGAINST POVERTY IN ITALY AND GERMANY AT THE TIME OF “EUROPE 2020” Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula two rather distinct worlds of implementation of ments; (ii) national attitudes towards Europe; and the Europe 2020 anti-poverty strategy. In Germany (iii) domestic politics dynamics are key to explain the elaboration as well as the initial implementa- the implementation of Europe 2020 at the national tion of the supranational anti-poverty strategy level (cf. Jessoula and Madama 2018). substantially increased the political salience of the On that respect, the two countries presented very poverty issue. This did not pave the way, however, different configurations. Germany was charac- for a smooth implementation of the strategy, or terized by robust national institutional legacy the setting of the national poverty target in accor- in fighting poverty and social exclusion and can dance with EU’s guidelines. Nor did increased thus be conceived as a typical case of ‘institutional political salience favour, especially in the initial pre-emption’ with governments actually reacting phase, more actor participation and coordination harshly against the perceived EU ‘intrusion’ in a across the different policy sectors and government sector of national sovereignty. The national govern- levels. Rather, research findings revealed the emer- ment in fact acted as ‘institutional gatekeeper’ gence of a main line of tension between the MS and within the Europe 2020 framework by ‘domes- the EU, related to national sovereignty/autonomy ticating’ the anti-poverty target (Jessoula 2016), vs. European coordination mechanisms in the field limiting both stakeholder involvement and multi- of social and especially anti-poverty policies. The level coordination, centralizing NRP drafting in setting of the quantified poverty target within the hand of economic ministers. Furthermore, the the Europe 2020 institutional framework actu- fact that EU funds are not particularly relevant in ally provoked a government reaction in defense the country, as well as the prevalence of centre- of national social sovereignty. The new Europe right governments in the considered period, 2020 strategy was actually perceived as a potential further contributed to national government ‘Trojan horse’ for competence creep in the social behaviour, and the strategy implementation was field and the government explicitly opposed it. overall weak: effects emerged almost solely in the By contrast, in Italy governments showed a more political sphere, with argumentative/ideational positive attitude vis à vis the new European clashes along the vertical axis (national/suprana- strategy in the field of anti-poverty policies, and tional) and the horizontal one (opposition parties the national-supranational ‘competence clash’ did vs. governing coalitions). not materialize. The strategy implementation was Quite the opposite, in Italy the launch of the novel therefore non-contentious, and its effects turned supranational anti-poverty strategy and especially out more far reaching especially along the substan- the quantitative target did not prompt a polit- tive dimension. ical conflict along the vertical dimension, that How can we solve the puzzle implied by such is along the national sovereignty vs. EU integra- diverse effects, and consequent very different tion (possible) line of tension, in the Europe 2020 implementation, of the Europe 2020 anti-poverty genetic moment. Here, domestic political actors strategy in the two countries? By integrating the and national governments did not act as gate- main findings of the consolidated strand of liter- keepers vis à vis the new European strategy, and ature that has shed light on the major role of the latter actually provided an institutional frame- domestic factors in ‘filtering’ supranational pres- work that was exploited by domestic (institu- sures (cf. Graziano et al. 2011; De la Porte and tional, political and social) actors in order to rein- Heins 2016; Heidenreich and Zeitlin 2009), with force national anti-poverty measures. Why did the more recent studies on the social dimension of national governments in Italy not worry about the Europe 2020 (cf. Jessoula 2015), and insights from reinforced supranational framework and potential comparative welfare state research, we contend EU intrusiveness in a typical national competence that (i) domestic policy/institutional arrange- domain such as anti-poverty policies? The three

ACCOMMODATING EU‘S INFLUENCE VS PROTECTING NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY. 166 THE FIGHT AGAINST POVERTY IN ITALY AND GERMANY AT THE TIME OF “EUROPE 2020” Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula explanatory factors seem to have played a key role compared to 2008. The trend was therefore oppo- in this respect. On the one hand, the absence of site to what was expected and desired. a robust national anti-poverty legacy explains the When looking at the domestic effects triggered lack of institutional pre-emption. On the other, by the EU strategy in terms of policy outputs and empirical investigation revealed that such devel- procedural dynamics – which have been at the core opment must be understood in light of the high of our analysis – the picture is, however, less clear- relevance of EU structural funds for active inclu- cut. sion policies in the country: in a perspective of reciprocal acknowledgement of their respec- Policy coordination based on soft-law mecha- tive institutional roles, the opportunity to access nisms may well be ineffective. Acknowledging the EU funds for social inclusion strategies actually EU’s ‘social competence gap’ also implies recog- pushed national governments to behave as ‘good nizing that overcoming sovereignty and political pupils’, leading to a sort of ‘Europe is where money constraints posed by reluctant MS (i.e. the German is’ effect. Notably, this dynamic fully appeared case) is de facto impossible. Our analysis however only when a pro-EU government came into power suggests that Europe 2020 anti-poverty strategy, in 2011128. under favourable conditions, had the chance to produce more significant effects in the country IV. Conclusive remarks presenting a weaker ‘safety net’ (i.e. the Italian case), where in combination with EU fund allo- The analysis presented in the previous pages cation, Europe 2020 actually provided resources prompts some final reflections on the potential and an innovative institutional framework that relevance of the EU in the fight against poverty contributed to strengthen its national anti-poverty within the novel overarching Europe 2020 insti- model. In particular, such institutional framework tutional framework. First and foremost, it must – resting on soft- law mechanisms, but backed by be said that, when looking at outcomes, figures are a ‘hard’ target – has allowed the EU and especially disappointing. In 2015, that is halfway through the Commission to act as an anti-poverty, social the Europe 2020 decade, the results produced by policy advocate through iterated interactions in the new strategy were not satisfactory. Although the Semester. Parallel to this, supranational target the overall scenario was severely affected by the and agency provided an opportunity for – as well Great Recession and the Euro-crisis, the EU target as strengthened – national actors that exploited of lifting 20 million individual out of poverty and the Europe 2020 institutional framework to ‘voice’ social exclusion was out of reach: indeed, people in favour of more effective measures to achieve in poverty or social exclusion have increased national(/EU) poverty targets. Without indulging between 2008 (the reference year to assess prog- in excessive optimism, adopting a ‘systemic’ ress towards the poverty target) and 2015: 1.8 perspective one could say that were the EU’s social million more individuals were at risk of poverty strategies more effective in pushing policymakers and social exclusion in 2015, and 8.1 per cent of to reinforce welfare arrangements and anti- the EU28 population (40.4 million) experienced poverty policies (at least) where the latter were less severe material deprivation. More recent figures robust, that would be already an important result show a slight improvement, but still 118 million for the Union as a whole. people are at risk of poverty or social exclusion, with an increase of about 800,000 individuals

128 We do refer to the technocratic government led by Monti, in office from November 2011 till April 2013.

ACCOMMODATING EU‘S INFLUENCE VS PROTECTING NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY. 167 THE FIGHT AGAINST POVERTY IN ITALY AND GERMANY AT THE TIME OF “EUROPE 2020” Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula References (ESPN) - Synthesis Reports, Eu rop e an Commission, Brussels. Armstrong, K.A. (2006) “The ‘Europeanisation’ Graziano, P. and Vink, M.P. (eds.) (2007) Europe- of Social Exclusion: British Adaptation to EU anization: new research agendas, Basingstoke Co-ordination”, British Journal of Politics and and New York: Palgrave MacMillan. International Relations, 8: 79-100. Graziano, P., Jacquot, S. and Palier, B. (eds.) (2011) Armstrong, K.A. (2010) Governing Social Inclu- The EU and the Domestic Politics of Welfare State sion. Europeanization through Policy Co- ordi- Reforms. Europa, Europae, Basingstoke: Palgrave nation, Oxford: Oxford University Press. MacMillan. Armstrong, K.A. (2012) “EU social policy and Heidenreich, M. and Zeitlin, J. (eds.) (2009) the governance architecture of Europe 2020”, Changing European Employment and Welfare Transfer: European Review of Labour and Regimes: the Influence of the Open Method of Research,18(3): 285-300. Coordination on National Reforms, London: Barbier, J.C. (2005) `The European Employment Routledge. Strategy: a Channel for Activating Social Protec- Jessoula, M. and Madama, I. (eds.) (2018) Fighting tion?‘, in J. Zeitlin and P. Pochet (eds.) The Open poverty and social exclusion in the EU. A chance in Method of Coordination in Action: the European Europe 2020. London/New York: Routledge. Employment and Social Inclusion Strategies, Jessoula, M. (2015) ‘Europe 2020 and the fight against Brussels: PIE-Peter Lang, pp. 417-46. poverty: beyond competence clash, towards hybrid” Barcevičius, E., Weishaupt, J.T. and Zeitlin, J. governance solutions?’, Social Policy and Adminis- (eds.) (2014) Assessing the Open Method of tration, Europeanization of welfare regional Issue, 49(4): 490-511. Coordination: Institutional Design and National Influence of EU Social Policy Coordina- Jessoula, M. (2016) Killing, domesticating or feeding tion, Basingstoke: Palgrave. the snake. The implementation of the Europe 2020 anti-poverty component at the national level, in Bouget, D., Frazer, H., Marlier, Sabato, S. and R. Halvorsen and B. Hvinden (eds), Combating Vanhercke, B. (2015) Social Investment poverty in Europe: Active inclusion in a multi-level in Europe , A study of national policies 2015, and multi-actor context, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, European Social Policy Network (ESPN) - pp. 133–156. Synthesis Reports, European Commission, Lehmkuhl, D. (2007) Some Promises and Pitfalls of Brussels. Eureopeanization Research”, in P. Graziano and Copeland, P. and Daly, M. (2012) ‘Varieties of poverty M. P. Vink (ed.), Europeanization: New Research reduction: Inserting the poverty and social exclu- Agenda, New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. sion target into Europe 2020’, Journal of European 337-353. Social Policy, 22(3): 273–287. Madama, I., Natili, M. and Agostini, C. (2018) Lucky Copeland, P. and Daly, M. (2014) ‘Poverty and social timing and propitious conditions: Italy’s anti- policy in Europe 2020: Ungovernable and ungov- poverty policy under Europe 2020, in M. Jessoula erned’, Policy and Politics, 42(3): 351–366. and I. Madama, I. (eds.) Fighting poverty and social De la Porte, C. and Heins, E. (eds) (2016) The sovereign exclusion in the EU. A chance in Europe 2020. debt crisis, the EU and welfare state reform, London: London/New York: Routledge, pp. Palgrave. Marlier, E. and Natali, D. with R. Van Dam (eds.) Frazer, H. and Marlier, E. (2016) Minimum Income (2010) Europe 2020: Towards a More Social Schemes in Europe - A study of n a t i o n a l EU?, Brussels: P.I.E. Peter Lang. policies, European Social Policy Network Peña-Casas, R.(2012) Europe 2020 and Fight

ACCOMMODATING EU‘S INFLUENCE VS PROTECTING NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY. 168 THE FIGHT AGAINST POVERTY IN ITALY AND GERMANY AT THE TIME OF “EUROPE 2020” Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula against Poverty and Social Exclusion: Fooled into Marriage?, in D. Natali and B. Vanhercke (eds.), Social Development in the European Union 2011, Brussels: OSE, ETUI, pp. 159-185. Pochet, P. (2010) “What’s wrong with EU2020?”, European Social Policy, ETUI Policy Brief Issues, 2: 1-7. Zimmermann, K. and Petzold, N. (2018) The German way: reaffirming sovereignty, while accommodating the EU anti-poverty strategy in M. Jessoula and I. Madama, I. (eds.) Fighting poverty and social exclu- sion in the EU. A chance in Europe 2020. London/ New York: Routledge, pp.

ACCOMMODATING EU‘S INFLUENCE VS PROTECTING NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY. 169 THE FIGHT AGAINST POVERTY IN ITALY AND GERMANY AT THE TIME OF “EUROPE 2020” Ilaria Madama and Matteo Jessoula EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND that facilitate risk-sharing across the Member POLITICAL OWNERSHIP: States is completely unrealistic. At the same time, demanding risk sharing in the absence of struc- FICTION AND REALITY tural reforms is simply unsustainable. BEHIND STRUCTURAL Therefore, if we want to accelerate the path of REFORMS AND RISK-SHARING structural reforms at the national level, we have to increase the pace of risk-sharing at the European 129 Filippo Taddei level in at least one of the crucial areas. If, vice versa, Johns Hopkins School of Advanced International we want to increase the degree of risk-sharing and Studies (SAIS) make this sustainable, we have to strengthen the “In politics, nothing happens by accident. If it economic fibre of member countries by speeding happens, you can bet it was planned that way.” up structural reforms. The bottom line is that risk-sharing and structural reforms must advance Franklin D. Roosevelt hand-in-hand in order to happen. In the absence of their co-ordinated advancement, neither can Introduction persist and European integration cannot advance. In order to make sure integration does happen, we It has been some years since Europe lost its central have to correct the general perspective on what role in world affairs. While the economic rise structural reforms and risk-sharing really entail. of Asia is mostly responsible for this outcome, Let us analyse each of these issues in turn. today Europeans are facing a new challenge: the combination of unfavourable demography, vola- Structural Reforms Taken tile migration flows and technological disruption, which questions the traditional economic identity Seriously: The Importance of of the European economy and the sustainability Political Ownership of the social standards that we take for granted. If European integration requires structural Enhanced European integration is often presented reforms, structural reforms are the result of polit- as an effective tool to respond to these challenges. ical decisions at the national level and their often This article discusses what is missing in our complex dynamics. Although structural reforms policy perspective in order to develop integration are one of the pre-requisites of European inte- seriously and make sure it helps to address the gration, the reasons behind them are deeper and combined challenges of globalisation and techno- broader: the European socio-economic model is logical change. under threat and urgently needs to be reformed to European integration advances only if it secures retain a satisfactory level of social protection. As stability and comparable economic development member countries struggle to change their econo- across Member States and regions. Both stability mies and welfare states, changes are progressing and economic growth are fed by structural reforms slowly. By today, Europeans have been talking and risk-sharing. This is easier said than done: the about reforms for so many years that the European discussion that follows wants to advance two very political discourse has developed its own rhetoric simple, fundamental and related points. The first is about the importance and centrality of structural that advocating structural reforms at the national reforms.130 level without improving the European institutions 129 I am grateful to Mark Gilbert, Erik Jones and Alberto 130 For a discussion of the current prospects, it is useful to Martin for comments and discussions on an earlier draft. Con- refer to Erik Jones and Anand Menon, “Europe: the Once and tact info:SAIS Europe, Johns Hopkins University, Via Andre- Future Union”, 2018 Annual Meetings American Political Sci- atta 3, 40125 Bologna, Italy. Email: [email protected]. ence Association.

EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND POLITICAL OWNERSHIP: 170 FICTION AND REALITY BEHIND STRUCTURAL REFORMS AND RISK-SHARING Filippo Taddei As is often the case, this rhetoric is not helping. structural - because it is instrumental to provide It is creating a perception of a continent split a proper answer to the second question – why are between a group of member countries that appears structural reforms so difficult. In order to illus- more eager to change and take responsibility, and trate the point, it may be useful to draw from another group that is doing anything it can to some of the latest experience of reform-making in postpone the reforms and relies on others to bail Europe during and after the Great Recession. Italy them out. Although it is true that political will can provide a very insightful dichotomy with two varies across countries, this perception is actually reforms that were deemed structural: the pension confusing our discussion rather than helping us reform in December 2011, and the Jobs Act in focus to on the nature, the benefits, and the costs 2015. As I will argue, only one, though- the Jobs of reforming a country. Let us abstract from this Act - possesses the degree of political ownership misleading rhetoric to take two steps back and that makes it truly structural. make an effort to ask two apparently simple ques- tions. First, what is necessary for a reform to be The Italian Pension Reform structural? Second, why are structural reforms so difficult and slow? In December 2011, only three weeks after Senator Mario Monti had been sworn in as Italian Prime We should refer to a structural reform as any Minister following Silvio Berlusconi’s resigna- change in institutions or legislation that is thor- tion, his new government presented to the Italian ough enough to deal with a fundamental factor Parliament a radical pension reform - the Fornero in the economy or society, a factor that we could Reform, named after the Minister of Labour, Social identify as an existing legacy. Negative legacies Policies and Gender Equality, Elsa Fornero. The are the result of consolidated forms of behaviour reform increased, with immediate effect, the stat- that accumulated their effects through the years utory retirement age to 66 years of age and linked and turned out to be detrimental to either equality it, from that moment onwards, to the evolution or growth or both. Rents inherited by groups or of life expectancy. If Italians, as is the case today, individuals, rules and incentives detrimental to continue to be one of the most longevous people equality of opportunities, large public debt, retire- in the planet, their retirement age will continue to ment requirements responsible for generational rise together with life expectancy. inequality, welfare benefits addressed to politi- cally active minorities rather than to those in need The changes in 2011 put the Italian pension and inconsistencies in the tax system would all system among the most sustainable across devel- fall into the broader category of negative legacies. oped economies and certainly as one of the most Although a reform needs to address a negative forward looking in Europe. The Italian Parlia- legacy in order to be structural, I want to argue ment, on the brink of political collapse and under that this is not a sufficient condition to define it as pressure by the threat of rising government debt such. In the general political discourse, this is very spread, weak growth and unsustainable public often a point of confusion. Any change – reform finances, approved the Government proposal with -of a negative legacy is considered a structural virtually no changes and with one of the largest reform. This is conceptually misconceived and it majorities in the history of the Italian republic. is an important mistake. In fact, this perspective By any metric, this reform addressed a negative is delaying the reform of European governance, legacy in the Italian economy and, thus, it fulfilled and it is generating ineffective policies to support the necessary condition to be defined as struc- national reforms. tural: retirement rules have always overprotected the interests of the incumbent old generations It is important to spend some time on this issue at the expense of the young generations. Since – what is sufficient to define a reform as being

EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND POLITICAL OWNERSHIP: 171 FICTION AND REALITY BEHIND STRUCTURAL REFORMS AND RISK-SHARING Filippo Taddei 2011, this overprotection is definitely more diffi- Political Ownership, the cult, although the Italian government has recently Emergency Threat and Structural announced a partial reversal of the reform, which Reforms highlights, as we will discuss below, that a reform cannot be easily categorised as structural if it lacks As problematical as the political process behind political ownership.131 the Jobs Act was, it delivered political ownership of the labour market reform. A political party – The Italian Jobs Act in this case, the Italian Democratic Party, which was ruling at the time – claimed ownership of Few years later, in December 2014, following the the reform and invested the political capital (i.e., initiative of Prime Minister , leader consensus) raised in the political market (i.e., elec- of the Democratic Party, and his government, the tions) in a change in legislation that could produce Italian Parliament approved the framework legis- the desired effects and rebuild the political capital. lation determined to reform labour market insti- This is a striking difference with the pension tutions comprehensively – the Jobs Act. The vote reform. In fact, the pension reform was intro- in Parliament came after a very heated debate, duced after almost no discussion and voted within one that divided the Democratic Party and which three weeks by an overwhelming majority ranging could only be recomposed through party loyalty. from left to right parties. Apparently uncontrover- While the Pension reform was approved by a super sial and solid, it did not seek any popular support majority, the Jobs Act was passed in the Senate with but was pushed through by the urgency created by a very small margin. Shortly before and after this the growing financial tensions surrounding Italian approval, the Prime Minister had organised and public debt. As a result of this process, the pension supervised, together with the Minister of Labour reform had no political capital invested in it and, and Social Policies, Giuliano Poletti, a small group therefore, could not have any political owner- of policy experts to achieve a quick implementa- ship. Since no political group owns it, no political tion of the framework legislation. subject is responsible for its survival and everyone In the nine months that followed, at a pace unpar- may feel tempted to modify it or even cancel it, as alleled in other structural reforms in Europe, the the currently ruling coalition is already proposing Italian labour market experienced the introduc- to do in the budgetary plan for 2019. As current tion a new paradigm: protection of workers would events show, when no political actor is ready or be delivered in the market rather than centred in willing to defend a reform, its persistence over the job post. Dismissal rules were changed and time becomes uncertain. simplified to increase flexibility, unemployment It therefore seems quite misleading to define these insurance was extended in both coverage and kinds of reform, even if they address an impor- duration, wage supplementation scheme were tant negative legacy, as “structural”. They lack better protected from abuses and moral hazard, the necessary political ownership to survive over and active labour market policies were brought time. The Italian Pension Reform, soon to become under national co-ordination for the first time. a political orphan, was implemented and is still The reform was thorough and fast while the polit- producing its effects. It is nonetheless continu- ical process that led to it was cumbersome and ously under threat of cancellation and contributes divisive. to produce a sense of disenfranchisement in the citizens of its country. This is a common outcome: 131 As this paper is being finalised, the Italian Budgetary Plan for 2019 is in preparation. Although the policy reversal lack of political ownership quickly translates into has not been finalised yet, the Italian Government and the lack of national ownership. This generates a disen- parties in the supporting coalition have made clear announce- franchisement that fails to overturn the practices ments regarding their intention to reverse this reform.

EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND POLITICAL OWNERSHIP: 172 FICTION AND REALITY BEHIND STRUCTURAL REFORMS AND RISK-SHARING Filippo Taddei and forms of behaviour of citizens which lie at legacy – how severe problems are - and will – how the root of the legacy that the reform was set to quickly political capital can be invested to address correct. them. The question that we should be asking is Comparing two Italian reforms – the Pension therefore how we can facilitate the emergence of Reform and the Jobs Act – highlights a general the political will necessary to produce structural point and a crucial distinction: a reform cannot be reforms in countries that are hampered by nega- considered “structural” unless a sufficiently large tive legacies. share of the citizens feel to have a stake and a say In the face of the severe economic shock that in the process that determined it. Otherwise, the hit the continent, the weaknesses of individual reform lacks the national ownership that only a member countries have emerged, in some cases fully-fledged democratic process may provide and dramatically. We have observed the emergence of remains inherently fragile. Incidentally, this also important regional asymmetries both as a conse- helps to answer our second question: why struc- quence of the common shock and in the policy tural reforms are so difficult and slow. The reason responses that have emerged. It should be clari- is that building up sufficient political capital to fied that this heterogeneity is mostly due to the avoid citizen disenfranchisement is a costly and different legacies present in the different Euro- often lengthy process. There are no short cuts, pean countries. These legacies are the reasons for though. Relying on the push of emergencies to reforms, structural reforms, but we have to eval- facilitate structural reforms is only an apparent uate whether mechanisms such as fiscal conver- short cut: it is a misconception that comes from gence or the capital market union that insure and confusion in the definition of structural reforms. protect member countries from the asymmetric Reforms motivated by some perceived national and country-specific effects of common shock can emergency are always at risk of being withdrawn accelerate the domestic reform process. once the perception of the emergency fades away. Politics, like economics, forces decision-makers to If we want to incentivise the development of address many objectives with limited resources. properly defined structural reforms, capable of In policy-making, structural reforms remain a changing – both in depth and permanently - the matter of prioritising medium- and long-term fundamentals of society, we must understand that results over short-term responses. Some Euro- such reforms require the political ownership that pean policy-makers seem to believe that the pres- only a thorough and often controversial political sure of national emergencies could fast-forward process may offer. As this process is already diffi- structural reforms in member countries. As cult per se, it is worthwhile thinking about how previously argued, this point of view is due to a European institutions can help this. We turn to conceptual mistake: such reforms, even when they this issue now. happen, remain inherently fragile. Only reforms investing political capital and gathering consensus Risk-Sharing and Uneven in their scope can persist in time and affect ordi- Recovery: The European Level nary economic and social behaviour. Only these reforms can have the ambition to become struc- The Great Recession has been followed by an tural. This paper has argued that enhancing risk- uneven economic recovery within the European sharing to offer protection to the member coun- Union. This inequality is slowing down structural tries from the severe effects of common shocks reforms. It is also hindering the development of a allows European countries to focus resources and common and consistent perspective regarding the efforts in raising the political capital necessary to role of European institutions. When we ponder the advance structural reforms. likelihood of national reforms, we often confuse

EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND POLITICAL OWNERSHIP: 173 FICTION AND REALITY BEHIND STRUCTURAL REFORMS AND RISK-SHARING Filippo Taddei European Integration Taken Seriously: Combining Risk- Sharing and Structural Reforms

Not a single month goes by without an informal or formal invitation by some branch of the European institutions to increase the “pace of structural reforms” in the different Member States. Almost not a single day goes by without a national govern- ment responding to this invitation with more or less eagerness. Notwithstanding this, Europe is not changing at the pace we had hope for, democratic institutions are perceived as being less effective at addressing citizens’ demands, and concomitantly citizens feel increasingly disenfranchised from the political process and discourse. We have been here before in our common history: these are the funda- mental factors and policy mistakes behind the rise of populist movements and parties, a rise that is taking place – unsurprisingly – in almost every major European country as European integration seem troubled and regional disparities consoli- date. This state of European affairs is not random but rather the consequence of a conceptually flawed definition of what a structural reform really means. It is not enough for structural reforms to address a fundamental weakness, they must also be char- acterised by political ownership. It is very difficult for member countries to raise political capital if they are dealing with the tail-effects of the most severe economic recession since World War II. This is the reason why risk sharing at the Euro- pean level and structural reforms at the national level can only progress together: by supporting each other, only their combination can advance European integration.

EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND POLITICAL OWNERSHIP: 174 FICTION AND REALITY BEHIND STRUCTURAL REFORMS AND RISK-SHARING Filippo Taddei D THE LEGACY OF THE WELFARE STATE IN EUROPE AN ALTERNATIVE TO THE hurdles are not based solely or primarily upon CONSTITUTION OF THE EU’S the provincial narrow-mindedness of the political representatives of the Member States. Rather, they SINGLE MARKET? are rooted in the complex heterogeneity of the 28 Member States, which, for their part, do not Florian Rödl operate in a vacuum but within the framework of FU, Berlin a globalised world economy. Upon this basis, many political and scientific 1. The “European Pact for observers have realised that – whatever form the Social Progress” Union may take in the more distant future – at present, a policy of strengthening social issues For decades the question of whether, and, if so, in the Union must always focus on the necessity how, the European Union can become not only that, at the very least, the law of the Union does an economic and subsequently a currency union, not limit welfare state options at the national level perhaps also a community of shared values, but too severely.132 There is every reason for this focus. also a social union, has been the subject of political After all, the pursuit of the common good in the and scientific debate. For a long time, a predomi- Member States, particularly the labour and social nantly optimistic scenario dominated. This was law of the Member States, and finally parties to based upon the conviction that the steps towards collective-bargaining agreements, have to comply integration in the internal market and then the with the strict requirements of the constitution common currency would simply compel further of the internal market, in other words, market and substantial integration steps in social areas freedom and competition law. In addition, there (including labour law and collective-bargaining are the functional imperatives of the euro, which agreements). In this phase, it was appropriate impose strict compliance burdens on the deficit for unions and Social Democratic parties in countries, which they must fulfil not least by particular to welcome every move towards inte- re-structuring their collective-bargaining systems gration, because, with each deepening, the overall at the expense of the trade unions and by reducing dynamics would also be propelled forward. Ulti- social security. mately, this would lead to the “United States of 133 Europe”, to a “European Republic”, in other words, Only rather naïve observers oppose this. to a state entity that would be politically and demo- However, they do not support their arguments by cratically integrated and able to act effectively referring to current developments or structures, in the social domain. Finally, the social control but rely on the texts of the EU treaties: The Union capacity lost in the meantime at the national level is said to be a social market economy (Article 3 (3) would be successfully recovered at a higher level. (2) TEU); the social cross-sectional provision is argued to enshrine a kind of welfare state principle After the Constitutional Treaty failed, the labels (Article 9 TFEU); the EU Charter of Fundamental of the “United States of Europe” or a “European Republic” initially ceased to be used in the polit- 132 Sacha Garben, in: European Constitutional Law Review 13 (2017), 23 ff.; Christian Joerges, Social Justice in an ever ical sphere and in the meantime have also fallen more diverse Union, in: Vandenbrouke, Barnard, De Baere out of use in scientific discourse. Furthermore, (eds.), A European Social Union after the Crisis, 2017, 92 ff.; the view that the emergence of a democratic and groundbreaking: Fritz Scharpf, Regieren in Europa: Effektiv und demokratisch, 1999. social union is not a necessity for the integration 133 Among them are, specifically, the judges of the Second dynamic, but which is confronted by serious obsta- Senate of the Federal Constitutional Court, who made the cles, has gained ground. It has become increas- decision on the : BVerfG, ruling dated June 30, ingly clear to open-minded observers that these 2009, 2 BvE 2/08 at al., in: BVerfGE 123, 267, 427 ff. – Treaty of Lisbon.

AN ALTERNATIVE TO THE CONSTITUTION OF THE EU’S SINGLE MARKET? 176 Florian Rödl Rights is claimed to contain fundamental social by the European Court of Justice. But the Euro- rights (Articles 27-38 EU-GRC), and recently a pean Parliament has had no political access to the new “European Pillar of Social Rights”134 has been juridical mode of integration from the outset, at proclaimed; there is a chapter on employment least when – as is often the case – the application (Articles 145-150 TFEU); there is a social chapter of primary law is concerned. (Article 151 TFEU) and related EU legislation; Given the impracticality of these typical pro- equal pay is guaranteed (Article 157 TFEU), European responses, unions and social-demo- and so on. These rather naïve observers seek to cratic parties from Austria, Sweden and Germany counter the limitations of social achievements want to adopt a different course. At a summit under EU law with the usual demands for “more meeting in late November 2016, they decided on integration”, i.e., the transfer of further powers to the “European Pact for Social Progress”.138 This the Union, and “more democracy”, meaning the 135 pact builds on the demand of the European Trade strengthening of the European Parliament. But Union Confederation (ETUC) for the adoption this does not work in the social field. This has 139 136 of a “Protocol on Social Progress”. The ETUC been explained many times and will thus only had initiated this demand in 2008 in response to be briefly repeated here: ECJ rulings on EU-law restrictions on collective- The economic, regulatory and political heter- bargaining autonomy, in order to correct these ogeneity in the Union is too great for a social decisions by amending primary legislation. The policy to be formulated at Union level, let alone, demands of the social progress protocol have now enforced, which could even approach the levels been taken up by trade unions and social demo- in the developed welfare states within the Union. crats in the three-country initiative, and specified Consequently, it would be of no help if the Union and further developed in the “European Pact for acquired very comprehensive powers in the field Social Progress” just mentioned. of social affairs as well. The Union would not be In Section 2, the European Pact emphasises the able to use them. In addition, developments that following demands based upon primary legisla- are problematical for social issues are often the tion: product of “integration through law”,137 and this means integration not through political legisla- 1) The obligations of the Union regarding tion but through judicial application of the law social market economy and social progress must be formulated so that these concepts 134 Available at https://ec.europa.eu/commission/publica- tions/european-pillar-social-rights-booklet_en. clearly include strong workers’ rights, and 135 HaukeBrunkhorst is representative of this in his article should exclude competition at the expense “Auswegeaus der technokratischenFalle,” in: Leviathan 42 of wages and working conditions. (2014), 508 ff. 2) The economic freedoms of the 136 For example: Wolfgang Streeck, GekaufteZeit: Die vertagteKrise des demokratischenKapitalismus, 2013, 141 ff.; internal market should not be understood Claus Offe, The European Model of “Social Capitalism”: Can it as a ban on unjustified restrictions but Survive European Integration, in: Journal of Political Philoso- instead they should only ensure rights to phy 11 (2003), 437 ff.; Alexander Somek, Concordantia Cath- olica. Exploring the Context of European Anti-Discrimination equal treatment. Law and Policy, in: Transnational Law and Contemporary Problems 15 (2005), 959 ff.; Florian Rödl, Arbeitsverfassung (labor constitution), in: Bogdandy/Bast (eds.), Europäisches- 138 Alliance for a Social Europe formed from the SPD, Verfassungsrecht, 2009, 855 ff., see especially 877 ff. SPÖ, SAP, DGB, ÖGB, and LO, A European Pact for So- cial Progress, Vienna 2016, available at: http://www.dgb.de/ 137 The title of the anthology Mauro Cappelletti/Monica themen/++co++14093cce-b620-11e6-a970-525400e5a74a. Seccombe/Joseph Weiler (eds.), Integration Through Law, makes the point. Vol 1, 1986; see Ulrich Haltern, Integration 139 The fully worked out proposal is available here: by Law, in: Bieling/Lerch (eds.), Theories of European integra- https://www.etuc.org/sites/default/files/social_progress_proto- tion, 2006, 399ff. colEN_1.pdf.

AN ALTERNATIVE TO THE CONSTITUTION OF THE EU’S SINGLE MARKET? 177 Florian Rödl 3) In cases of conflict, fundamental Like every previous amendment to primary law, social rights must take precedence over the enforcement of a future treaty change will economic freedoms of the market and depend crucially on the approval of European competition rules.140 trade unions. The history of the recent amend- These demands constitute a political programme ments made to the treaties, notably the failure to strengthen social rights and protect social of popular referendums, has demonstrated this achievements. However, they require further legal impressively: if the trade unions (and social elaboration. This can be specifically gauged by democratic parties that are not in power) do not whether or not they really do provide remedies stand up in the Member States for the necessary for the problematical development of the legal changes, ratification will be very difficult. integration dynamics identified here. Upon such This constellation actually provides the unions a basis, the demands of the “European Pact for with a strong negotiating position. All that is Social Progress” may eventually become a well- needed is for them to mobilise their power for founded negotiating position. a politically convincing and legally sustainable The history of the previous dispute over anchoring programme. The accusation of having switched the claim of a more social orientation of the over to the anti-European camp need not be feared. Union has shown the need for such an examina- For a commitment to the programme of the Euro- tion. For example, with social democratic govern- pean Pact for Social Progress would certainly not ments predominating in the European institu- be an expression of a nationalist attitude. Against tions, a chapter on employment was inserted into the backdrop of the legitimacy crisis of the Union, the Treaty of Amsterdam (1997). It had no effect. which is reflected not least in the political gains Especially in the negotiations on the Constitu- of right-wing populist parties, the programme tional Treaty (2003), much effort was devoted to of the European Pact is decidedly pro-European, individual treaty provisions, such as the specifica- because only upon this basis will it be possible to tion that the Union is a social market economy or preserve what has been achieved and avoid squan- the so-called social cross-sectional provision, or dering the opportunity for further integration. even the social rights in the EU Charter of Funda- mental Rights. At no point has there been system- 3. Outline atic examination of what legal force the relevant The following outlines the results of a study standards could actually develop. The results were concluded in 2018 which was conducted to elabo- ultimately sobering. rate the demands of the “European Social Progress Protocol” in legal terms: 2. Implementation Prospects 1. In November of 2016, the EU Mem- The prospects of enforcing the programme are ber States Sweden (LO and SAP), Austria better than might be expected, given the political (ÖGB and SPÖ) and Germany (DGB and will on the part of unions and social-democratic SPD) signed a European Pact for Social parties, for a further deepening of economic and Progress, which seeks to carry out a reform monetary union (as such) is on the agenda. With of the constitution of the internal market the presidency of Emmanuel Macron in France of the Union. and a, certainly also in the future, pro-European 2. In concrete terms, the European Pact government, new political scope has been created calls for the law of the internal market to for this. be adjusted in such a way as to give its employees strong rights and priority over 140 A European Pact for Social Progress, 2016, p. 3.

AN ALTERNATIVE TO THE CONSTITUTION OF THE EU’S SINGLE MARKET? 178 Florian Rödl market freedoms and competition rules. required by a supranational internal mar- Furthermore, transnational competition ket. On the other hand, they would lose upon the basis of labour costs should be their de-regulatory prevalence, a general excluded. Finally, it demands that the mar- shift in emphasis at the expense of the ket freedoms that are constitutive for the common good and social compensation. internal market should be reduced to a 6. The conception of market freedoms legitimate level, and that they should no as super-civil liberties for companies is longer be regarded as banning restrictions, particularly difficult in the area of labour but only as requiring equal treatment. and social , which are primar- 3. Thus, the “European Protocol for So- ily structured by Member State law. While, cial Progress” is a response to a social and at the Member State level, the respective democratic problem of the integration purview of economic constitutions, on process that has long been diagnosed in the one hand, and labour and social con- politics and political science. This has its stitutions, on the other, is determined by origin in the liberalistic form of the legal simple legislation and thus upon the basis constitution of the internal market. Con- of political-democratic decision-making, sequently, it cannot be remedied by deep- within the framework of the Union‘s in- ening integration or by strengthening the ternal market the economic constitution rights of the European Parliament. takes legal priority over the labour and 4. The European Court of Justice has social constitutions of the Member States. subjected the constitution of the inter- The national regulations that have been nal market of the Union to liberalisation overturned cannot normally be compen- through its case law on market freedoms. sated for by EU legislation, mostly because It has conceived market freedoms as super of the lack of jurisdiction of the Union, but freedoms for companies, which they may also because of the wide institutional and use, in addition to their guarantees, in the economic diversity of the Member States. constitutions of Member States, of owner- 7. Development is driven to the extreme ship and freedom of acquisition, to bring by the fact that not only state law, but also down Member State rules for promoting – through a questionable binding of pri- the common good and social equality. vate interests to market freedoms – the Such a shift of emphasis in favour of en- processes of setting collective agreement terprises and at the expense of the com- standards within the framework of the au- mon good and social balance was neither tonomy of collective bargaining guaran- intended nor provided for by European teed by EU law are equally obliged to re- market integration. spect market freedoms. 5. A conception of market freedoms as 8. The liberalist transformation of the principles of equal treatment would be Union’s single market constitution has correct: No company based in another given market freedoms considerable de- Member State and no cross-border entre- regulatory power, and thus today limits preneurial service should be treated less the social and democratic powers of the favourably than domestic companies and Member States to a considerable degree. domestic services. Thus, on the one hand, This is also seen everywhere in European market freedoms would prevent protec- law. The legal proposals in this context to tionism on the part of Member States, as contain this de-regulatory force of market

AN ALTERNATIVE TO THE CONSTITUTION OF THE EU’S SINGLE MARKET? 179 Florian Rödl freedoms (the keywords are “Keck exemp- 12. The conception of fundamental free- tion” and “market access criterion”) have doms as principles of equal treatment is already proved ineffective. Therefore, a compatible with the basic structure of es- correction of the internal market constitu- tablished internal market law. In particu- tion in primary law is needed. lar, it does not undermine the principle 9. The proposal by the former constitu- of mutual recognition. On the contrary, it tional judge Dieter Grimm for a “de-con- ensures that it only comes into effect if the stitutionalisation of the internal market” interests of the receiving Member State are does not remedy the situation. Even if mar- already completely fulfilled by the regula- ket freedoms were to fall within the scope tions of the Member State of origin. Nor of secondary legislation, the restrictions does it undermine the so-called free move- on regulatory freedoms of Member States ment of persons within the internal mar- would continue, because secondary legis- ket (freedom of movement for workers, lation also takes precedence over Member freedom of establishment), but it restricts State law. A subsequent more regulatory- the guarantee to a legitimate level which friendly re-adjustment of market freedoms complies with the guarantee of domestic by means of ordinary EU legislators is not freedom of movement. to be expected given the divergence of in- 13. Such a reduction of market freedoms terests of the Member States. to the principles of equal treatment would 10. One remedy would be to scale back also remove the concern of the ETUC’s market freedoms from fundamental en- “Social Progress Protocol”, which main- trepreneurial rights to equal treatment. In tains that social rights, and, in particular, this case, Member State rules would have the exercise of collective bargaining, would to justify market freedoms only if they re- remain unaffected by market freedoms. sulted in discrimination. A mere restric- 14. Alternatively, the reduction of mar- tion of transnational enterprise, irrespec- ket freedom to equal treatment principles tive of unequal treatment in comparison could be confined to the field of employ- to domestic companies or services, would ment and social legislation of Member automatically be lawful. States, as defined in the competence stand- 11. Discrimination that continues to be ard of Article 153 TFEU. This would con- prohibited can occur openly (direct dis- tinue to address the concerns of the ETUC’s crimination) or covertly (indirect discrim- “Social Progress Protocol”, but Member ination). Conceiving indirect discrimina- State arrangements for the common good tion as factual discrimination fits in with and social equality beyond those under the the anti-discrimination law for the protec- labour and social constitution of the Mem- tion of socially-disadvantaged groups, but ber States would remain difficult. not with the rule of equal treatment in a 15. Although it lies outside the focus of supra-state internal market. However, the the “European Pact on Social Progress”, reproach of covert discrimination is not considering the interests of employees in dispelled by the defence by Member States the Union, it would be very urgent to re- that they had good intentions, but instead move the labour and social constitution of when the arrangement pursues a rational the Member States from the scope of com- purpose (public interest or social compen- petition law and from actions sanctioned sation) and is appropriate and necessary by macro-economic surveillance to stabi- for this purpose. lise the euro.

AN ALTERNATIVE TO THE CONSTITUTION OF THE EU’S SINGLE MARKET? 180 Florian Rödl 16. The principle of territorial equal pay, which is expressed by the formula “equal pay for equal work in the same place”, is central to preventing transnational compe- tition based solely upon labour costs. This, in turn, is a pre-requisite for the continu- ation of, or at least slow development in Member States of the welfare state, which can continue provided the internal market does too. 17. Market freedoms and current second- ary legislation (Posting of Workers Direc- tive, Regulation on Co-ordination of Social Security Systems) place legal limits on the implementation of the principle of territo- rial wage equality. On the one hand, the principle requires, in part, treatment that is openly different and which would not allow market freedoms even after a reduc- tion to equal treatment principles. On the other hand, secondary legislation exists which does not acknowledge the signifi- cance of the principle of territorial wage equality. 18. Anchoring the principle of territorial wage equality in primary law promises jus- tification for open differences in treatment. It must be added to the existing justifica- tions for open differences in treatment provided by the applicable primary law for each of the market freedoms (Articles 36, 52 (1), 62, 65 (1) (b) TFEU). In order to correct the misaligned secondary legisla- tion as well, Member States would have to be allowed, by way of a protocol statement, to deviate from these rules, to the extent that they serve to implement the principle of territorial wage equality.

AN ALTERNATIVE TO THE CONSTITUTION OF THE EU’S SINGLE MARKET? 181 Florian Rödl INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS Economic and Monetary Union (TSCG) by 25 142 AND LABOUR LAW IN THE Member States. These reforms strengthened the rules that guarantee budgetary discipline and EU ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE changed the way in which decisions are taken at MECHANISMS: various stages of the surveillance procedures. In THE CASES OF ITALY AND particular, the Six Pack established that sanctions GERMANY in the context of the Excessive Deficit Procedure were to be decided by reverse qualified-major- 143 Francesco Costamagna141* ity. This means that Commission recommen- dations proposing to sanction a Member State is University of Turin & Collegio Carlo Alberto adopted unless a qualified-majority of Member States within the Council votes against it. 1. The Reform of the European Economic The hardening of budgetary rules and procedures was associated with the revamping of economic Governance: Strengthening policy co-ordination through the creation of the the Disciplinary Powers European Semester. The Semester brings under of EU Institutions the same umbrella different strains of EU policy co-ordination and surveillance that touch upon 1.1 The Co-ordination of both economic and social policies. Economic Policies within the If compared with previous co-ordination European Semester processes, the Semester sensibly enhances the capacity of policy formulation, guidance and When the crisis struck, the Commission, backed monitoring of EU institutions in virtually the by some Member States, was swift to point to the entire spectrum of Member State economic and defects of the EMU legal framework as the main social policies. This is mainly due to the combi- cause for the instability of the common currency. nation of soft co-ordination processes with hard This argument, which conveniently overlooked surveillance mechanisms. Despite nominally the structural economic imbalances affecting the retaining a non-binding character, the recommen- EMU, quickly became part of the dominant narra- dations adopted in this context engender a level of tive and paved the way for subsequent reforms compliance that is higher than that which may be which aimed at strengthening the disciplinary inferred from Article 288 TFEU. Indeed, hard-law powers of EU institutions. processes can be used to put pressure on national In 2011, the European Parliament and the Council authorities so as to make them adopt the recom- adopted a package of six legal acts − the so-called mended reforms in the social and labour fields. As Six Pack – in order to strengthen budgetary disci- plainly put by the Commission: pline, introduce a new surveillance mechanism “[i]t is primarily in Member States’ own on macroeconomic imbalances and enhance the interests to implement the reforms that co-ordination of economic policies. The reform of will help them recover from the crisis the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) went hand- and create the foundations for sustainable in-hand with the adoption of the Treaty on the Stability, Co-ordination and Governance in the 142 Signed on 2 March 2012 and entered into force on 1 January 2013. 141* The paper has been written in the context of the RES- 143 Article 6(2) Regulation (EU) 1173/2011. See, generally, cEU project (Reconciling Economic and Social Europe, www. Rainer Palmstofer, “The Reverse Majority Voting Under the resceu.eu), funded by the European Research Council (grant ‘Six Pack’: A Bad Turn for the Union?”, (2014) 20 European no. 340534). Law Journal, 186-203.

INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND LABOUR LAW IN THE EU ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS: 182 THE CASES OF ITALY AND GERMANY Francesco Costamagna growth. […] As a last resort, there is the tion was problematical, and, in 2009, the Council prospect of sanctions if Member States formally opened an excessive deficit procedure repeatedly fail to take action on public against France.147 Little happened until 2013, finances or macroeconomic imbalances when the Commission and the Council started (under the Excessive Deficit Procedure to put greater emphasis on the link between the and the Excessive Imbalance Procedure, “correction of the fiscal imbalances” and “a cred- respectively).”144 ible implementation of ambitious structural reforms to increase the adjustment capacity and Furthermore, the Semester allows EU institu- 148 tions to exercise quasi-normative functions, by boost growth and employment”. In particular, issuing recommendations that are very detailed France was recommended to reduce the cost of and that are not just “broad guidelines”, as envis- labour and to “ensure that developments in the minimum wage are supportive of competitiveness aged by Article 121 TFEU. For instance, in 2017, 149 the French government was recommended to: and job creation”. The same occurred, with only minor terminological variations, in 2014150 and “Consolidate the measures reducing the 2015.151 All these recommendations were adopted cost of labour to maximise their efficiency upon the basis of Article 6 Regulation (EU) No. in a budget-neutral manner and in order 1176/2011. In February 2015, the French Govern- to scale up their effects on employment ment bowed to the pressure, passing a law that and investment. Broaden the overall tax aimed at rendering the labour market more busi- base and take further action to implement ness-friendly. The law was adopted by an execu- the planned decrease in the statutory tive order,152 so as to avoid the possibility of the 145 corporate-income rate.” Assemblée Nationale rejecting it and thus sending These recommendations constrain the autonomy “the wrong signal to the European Commission, of national authorities, leaving non-compliance as a week before deciding whether to fine France for the main way out. Yet, this option is not readily missing its deficit targets”.153 The decision paid available to all Member States. Due to its power- off as the Commission refrained from penalising based nature, the effectiveness of the mechanism 147 Council Decision No. 2009/414/EC of 27 April 2009 depends on the vulnerability of the Member State on the existence of an excessive deficit in France, OJ L 135 of to this threat. Those Member States at risk of being 30.05.2009, 19-20. put under an excessive deficit procedure have few 148 Council Recommendation of 9 July 2013 on the Nation- other options but to comply with the suprana- al Reform Programme 2013 of France and Delivering a Council Opinion on the Stability Programme of France, 2012-2017, OJ C tional recommendations. 217 of 30.07.2013, 31. The case of France and, more specifically, the adop- 149 Ibid. tion of the so-called Loi Khomri (or Loi Travail) 150 Council Recommendation of 8 July 2014 on the offers a good example in this regard.146 After the National Reform Programme 2014 of France and Delivering a Council Oopinion on the Stability Programme of France, 2014, onset of the crisis, the French budgetary posi- OJ C 247 of 29.07.2014, 47-48. 151 Council Recommendation of 14 July 2015 on the 2015 144 http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_MEMO-14-388_ National Reform Programme of France and Delivering a Council en.htm. Opinion on the 2015 Stability Programme of France, OJ C 272 of 18.08.2015, 55. 145 Council Recommendation of 11 July 2017 on the 2017 National Reform Programme of France and Delivering a Council 152 The Loi Travail was published in the Journal officiel Opinion on the 2017 Stability Programme of France, OJ C 261 only on 6 August 2016, after several versions had been rejected of 09.08.2017, 39. either by the Assemblée Nationale or by the Senat. 146 R. Erne, “A Supranational Regime that Nationalizes 153 A-S. Chassany, “French Government Overrides Social Conflict: Explaining European Trade Unions’ Difficul- Parliament to Ram though Reforms”, Financial Times, online ties in Politicizing European Economic Governance”, (2015) 56 edition, 17 February 2015, available at: https://www.ft.com/ Labor History, 345, 348. content/3e2f4314-b67b-11e4-a5f2-00144feab7de.

INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND LABOUR LAW IN THE EU ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS: 183 THE CASES OF ITALY AND GERMANY Francesco Costamagna France, despite its failure to bring the deficit under 2017, nine years after the launch of the first bailout the 3 per cent threshold.154 programme, that the CJEU made it clear that the MoU is mandatory and “constitutes an act of an 1.2 Financial Assistance EU institution”, according to Article 267 TFEU.156 Programmes and Conditionality However, the case in question concerned a specific financial assistance programme that, directed The strengthening of capacity of supranational towards a non-euro Member State facing diffi- institutions to intrude into the regulation of culties with its balance of payments, was set up national labour markets is even more intense in upon the basis of Article 143 TFEU and Regu- the context of financial assistance programmes. lation 332/2002. As for non-EU-based bailout As is well known, each bailout entailed that the programmes, the CJEU has traditionally adhere beneficiary Member State respected a set of policy to the vision according to which the Memoran- conditions agreed with EU institutions, acting dum’s provisions fall outside the EU legal frame- on behalf of the donors. Conditionality entrusts work. Upon this basis, the CJEU rejected all the supranational institutions with an unprece- annulment actions brought by private applicants dented capacity to engage in close surveillance against these provisions and all the requests for and micromanagement of social policy, placing preliminary rulings which sought to ascertain powerful constraints on the autonomy of national the compatibility, with the EU Charter on Funda- authorities in managing their social systems. This mental Rights, of national measures adopted to capacity hinges upon the uncertain legal location implement the conditions set out in the MoU. The of the instruments governing the definition of the Court has recently been given the chance to shed conditions attached to financial assistance pack- more light on this issue, but it deliberately avoided ages.155 This allows EU institutions to exploit fully it.157 the political and economic power asymmetries between them and any Member State that is facing 2. The Subordination of extreme financial difficulties. Social Objectives to The main legal source of bailout programmes is Economic Ones: the Memorandum of Understanding (MoU), Labour Reforms as Tools which details the requirements that the benefi- for Pursuing EMU-Related ciary Member State must meet in order to receive Objectives financial assistance. The legal nature of this docu- ment, and even its capacity to set legally-binding Both the European Semester and bailout mech- obligations, has long been – and, to some extents, anisms were created to consolidate the EMU, by still is – highly controversial. It was just in June filling structural gaps. Thus, it is hardly surprising that they tended to focus on a narrow set of objec- 154 European Commission, Recommendation for a Council Recommendation with a View to Bringing an End to the tives − such as budgetary discipline and competi- Excessive Government Deficit in France, 27 February 2015, tiveness − that are directly linked to the consoli- COM(2015) 115 def. dation of the EMU. Other conflicting objectives, 155 Claire Kilpatrick, The EU and its Sovereign Debt such as social ones, have been mainly relegated to Programmes: The Challenges of Liminal Legality, (2017) EUI Working Paper 2017/14, 3-8. See, also, Agustín José Mené- second-tier status, in a way that flies in the face of ndez, “The Crisis and the European Crises: From Social and Democratic Rechtsstaat to the Consolidating State of 156 Florescu [2017] ECLI:EU:C:2017:448, para. 35. See (Pseudo-)technocratic Governance”, (2017) 44 Journal of Law Menelaos Markakakis and Paul Dermine, “Bailouts, the Legal and Society, 74-78 (hereinafter Menéndez, “The Crisis and the Status of Memoranda of Understanding, and the Scope of European Crises”); Francesco Munari, “Crisi dell’Euro e crisi Application” (2018) 55 Common Market Law Review 643, 643- delle regole: Rule of Law o ragion politica? Il diritto dell’Unio- 671; Alberto Miglio, “La condizionalità di fronte alla Corte di ne europea dinanzi a nuove sfide”, in: Ornella Porchia (ed), Giustizia”, (2017) 11 Diritti umani e diritto internazionale 763, Governance economica europea. Strumenti dell’Unione, rapporti 763-770. con l’ordinamento internazionale e ricadute sull’ordinamento 157 Judgment of 27 February 2018, Associação Sindical dos interno, (Torino: Giappichelli, 2015), pp. 33-56. Juizes Portugueses, C-64/16.

INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND LABOUR LAW IN THE EU ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS: 184 THE CASES OF ITALY AND GERMANY Francesco Costamagna the equal ranking model enshrined in the Treaties. 2011, the Council recommended Italy to “rein- In this context, labour market reforms have been force measures to combat segmentation in the mostly conceived as tools that should contribute labour market, also by reviewing selected aspects to the pursuit of EMU-related objectives. The of employment protection legislation including cases of Italy and Germany make no exception in the dismissal rules and procedures and reviewing this regard, even though the recommendations the currently fragmented unemployment benefit directed at the two countries are divergent as far system taking into account the budgetary as their content is concerned. constraints”. For greater certainty, the Council made clear that these reforms, to be carried out 2.1 The Case of Italy in consultation with the social partners, had to be primarily aimed at ensuring that “wage growth Italy was put under strong pressure to adopt better reflects productivity developments as well reforms that could remove those elements that as local and firm conditions, including clauses were perceived as “rigidities”, so to make its regu- that could allow firm level bargaining to proceed latory framework more flexible and, thus, capable in this direction”. of contributing to enhance the competitiveness The situation changed in 2015: from that cycle of the national economic system. These reforms onwards, supranational institutions started to pay should foster internal devaluation, which, in a greater attention to other issues, such as promoting monetary union in which currency devaluation active labour market policies or enhancing labour is no longer an option and in which there is no market participation by women. This change is centralised fiscal capacity, has seemingly become due to two main factors. the only adjustment variable to respond to struc- tural imbalances. First, it reflects the push toward the so-called “socialisation” of the Semester, a process that This was the case of the (in-) famous letter158 sent to started in 2013, which touches upon both its the Italian Government by the ECB President and organisational and its substantive components. the Governor of the Bank of Italy in August 2011. In particular, the letter urged “to further reform With regard to the first aspect, since 2013, there has the collective wage-bargaining system allowing been an attempt to make the drafting of the CSRs firm-level agreements to tailor wages and working more collaborative, involving Commission Direc- conditions to firms’ specific needs and increasing torates General other than just ECOFIN. More- their relevance with respect to other layers of over, the Commission has tried to enhance the negotiations”, and to engage in a “thorough review participation of national and EU social partners of the rules regulating the hiring and dismissal of in various supranational phases of the co-ordina- employees [that] should be adopted in conjunc- tion process, establishing new venues for involve- tion with the establishment of an unemploy- ment and providing better access to decision- ment insurance system and a set of active labour making fora. These changes, while potentially market policies capable of easing the reallocation interesting, have had only a limited impact on the of resources towards the more competitive firms way in which the Semester works, at least to date. and sectors”. For instance, looking at the involvement of the social partners, a recently paper published warns A similar approach was followed in the context against the risk that all these reforms may well end of the co-ordination of national economic poli- up increasing the opportunities for the social part- cies, especially in its early cycles. For instance, in ners to be listened to, while leaving their capacity 158 The letter can be found here: http://www.corriere.it/ economia/11_settembre_29/trichet_draghi_inglese_304a5f1e- ea59-11e0-ae06-4da866778017.shtml?refresh_ce-cp.

INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND LABOUR LAW IN THE EU ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS: 185 THE CASES OF ITALY AND GERMANY Francesco Costamagna to be heard substantially unchanged.159 tition-enhancing reforms of the labour market is Turning to the substantive dimension, the due to the fact that, in 2014 and 2015, Italian law- Commission sought to reinforce and deepen social making authorities adopted a series of statutes and and employment surveillance and co-ordination decrees commonly known as the “Jobs Act”. This within the Semester. This mainly materialised in reform transposed most of the recommendations the introduction of new scoreboards and indica- issued by EU institutions into the Italian system, tors to monitor employment and social develop- especially with regard to the flexibilisation of the ments, confirming the Commission’s highly tech- labour market. nocratic approach towards social policy and its 2.2 The Case of Germany continuous faith in numbers as governing tools. For instance, in 2014, the Commission included The recommendations addressed to Germany a number of auxiliary employment and social confirm the tendency to subordinate labour indicators within the group informing the Alert market reforms to the logic and objectives of Mechanism Report of the macroeconomic imbal- EMU, even though, in contrast to the case of ance procedure (MIP) to complement the only Italy, they do not aim to make the labour market social indicator already existing in that context, more flexible or to reduce wages. On the contrary, which focused on unemployment.160 This evolu- Germany has been considered a role model for all tion is set to be bolstered by the adoption of the the other Member States with regard to the adop- European Pillar of Social Rights, proclaimed with tion of labour market reforms primarily directed much fanfare in November 2017.161 According to at enhancing the competitiveness of the national the Annual Growth Survey (AGS) 2018, the Pillar economic system. Indeed, in 2003 and 2005 the should “serve as a point of reference for the further German authorities had already adopted sweeping implementation of the European Semester”, measures increasing the flexibility of the labour as it is “a compass for renewed convergence market through, inter alia, the de-regulation of towards better working and living conditions”.162 mini-jobs. Concretely, the document is set to inspire a further set of indicators aiming at “monitor[ing] However, starting from the 2013 cycle of the ‘societal progress’” and detecting “the most signifi- Semester in particular, the EU institutions began cant employment and social challenges facing the to put pressure on the German authorities to adopt Member States, the EU and the euro area, as well measures that could enable wage growth and facil- as progress achieved over time”.163 itate the transition from non-standard employ- ment, such as mini-jobs, into more sustainable Second and, to some extent, more importantly, forms of employment. These recommendations the decision to reduce the pressure on the Italian were issued upon the basis of Article 6 of Regu- government with regard to the adoption of compe- lation 1176/2011, in the context of the preventive 159 S. Sabato, B. Vanhercke and S. Spasova, Lis- arm of the Macroeconomic Imbalances Procedure. tened, but not Heard? Social Partners’ Multilevel Involvement in The main aim of these recommendations is not to the European Semester, OSE Paper Series, Paper No. 35/2017. improve the situation of mini-workers, although 160 European Commission, Alert Mechanism Report 2014, this would be an inevitable side-effect, but to stim- Brussels, 13 November 2013, COM(2013) 790 final, 10. ulate internal demand and, consequently, reduce 161 S. Garben, “The European Pillar of Social Rights: 164 Effectively Addressing Displacement?”, (2018) 14 European the current account surplus run by Germany. Constitutional Law Review 215. The adoption of expansive measures with regard to 162 European Commission, Annual Growth Survey 2018, 22 164 As confirmed by the 2018 In-Depth Review carried November 2017, COM(2017) 290 final, 3. out by the Commission, the German current account surplus 163 Commission Staff Working Document, Social Score- is edging down, but it remains well above the 6 per cent MIP board, Brussels, 26.04.2017, SWD(2017) 200 final, 2. threshold.

INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND LABOUR LAW IN THE EU ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS: 186 THE CASES OF ITALY AND GERMANY Francesco Costamagna labour market regulation is, thus, primarily meant to address these imbalances, thereby contributing to reinforce the stability of the EMU. The main problem lies with Germany’s compli- ance with these recommendations and, more in general, with the credibility of the whole process. An assessment carried out by the Commission in March 2018 admitted that Germany has made only limited progress in promoting the transi- tion towards more stable forms of work and in promoting real wage growth, among the other things. This could be partially attributed to the choice made by the EU institutions, and the Commission in particular, to consider Germany to be in a situation of “macroeconomic imbal- ances” and not in one of “excessive macroeco- nomic imbalances”. This means that there are no signs that Germany might be placed under an Excessive Deficit Procedure any time soon and, thus, be forced to adopt corrective actions. From a legal perspective, there are no obstacles for this step to be taken: the notion of “excessive imbal- ances” is vague enough to cover situations such as the one in hand.

INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND LABOUR LAW IN THE EU ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS: 187 THE CASES OF ITALY AND GERMANY Francesco Costamagna WHAT TO EXPECT FROM billion in 2017 to 335.5 in 2018), (Bundesfinan- GERMANY FOR THE EUROPEAN zministerium 2017) Germany has every reason to feel assured of the aptness of its social market PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS economy, the success of its growth model and its AND BEYOND? economic policies. With the current budget, it can thus confidently respond to calls for both fiscal Marcel Hadeed prudence and more investments and continue Hertie School of Governance, Berlin the status quo politics Angela Merkel has attained notoriety for (Kohler 2013; Sirleschtov 2017). “Everywhere in Europe I said: a German finance minister is a German finance minister, regardless Accordingly, strengthening the EMU’s social of his party card. I believe the message was well dimension is not a policy priority for the German received”165 government. In his speech in May 2018, the German minister for Labor and Social Affairs, -Olaf Scholz, German finance minister, 22.03.2018 Hubertus Heil, identified four priorities for his It is my aim to highlight some of the guiding prin- department: reserves for cyclical unemployment; ciples of the German position towards the EMU’s structural unemployment; digital upskilling of social dimension in order to ascertain what can the labor force; and the integration of people with be expected from the German government for its disabilities into the labor market (Heil 2018). development. The paper begins by contextualizing None of them relate to the EU. Germany’s current macroeconomic position. It Beyond these issues of system maintenance and then elaborates on cornerstones of Germany’s incremental improvements, forward-looking policy towards the EMU’s social dimension. These debates are taking place in German ministries. are exemplified in the case study of the German These revolve around broader considerations position towards the European Pillar of Social about the future sustainability of the German Rights (EPSR). It concludes with expectations this social market economy. Managing digitalization position raises for the future of German efforts and coping with demographic change are priority towards strengthening the EMU’s social dimen- issues, as evident from constant debates about sion. the sustainability of the pension systems and the comprehensive consultation activity in connec- Background – Germany’s tion with the “forth industrial revolution” (e.g. position and priorities “Work 4.0”; “Industry 4.0”; “Mittelstand 4.0”). The necessity to update employment- and social policy In order to assess the German position, it is impor- for the also informs Germany’s posi- tant to first realize the current socio-economic tion towards the European level, where it calls for reality in Germany. The employment statistic a comprehensive update of the European Social looks historically well. 2017 not only marked the Acquis (Bundesregierung 2016). Any revision record year in terms of employment – with 44.28 of the social model on national level, or further million employed – but also a record low in terms development on the European level has to pay due of unemployment (2.53 million or 5.7%)(Bundes- diligence to the trends that are expected to trans- regierung 2017a). With growth of 2.3% of GDP form the world of work. projected for 2018 and 2.1% for 2019 (Bundes- ministerium für Wirtschaft und Energie 2018), Nonetheless, whoever had hoped for the pro- decreasing sovereign debt (Reiermann 2018) and European focus the SPD appeared to promise in increasing national budget (increase from €329.1 the run-up to the elections was left disappointed. Not only the lacking portfolios from the Ministry 165 Translation by the author

WHAT TO EXPECT FROM GERMANY FOR THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS AND BEYOND? 188 Marcel Hadeed of Labour and Social Affairs, but the reassurance member states as virtuous savers or undeserving of finance minister Scholz that “a German finance rule-breakers (Offe 2015). Ordoliberalism thus minister is a German finance minister, regardless of lent the theoretical justification of German crisis his party card“ (Scholz 2018) confirm the Grand politics that focused on austerity and structural Coalition’s outlook on the Eurozone has not reforms. changed much since its reelection. In its coalition Germany invested much political capital in agreement, the relevant portfolio remains meager 166 upholding these imperatives: both domestically – and vague. the contestation of which brought forth the Alter- Ascertaining that Germany’s position will likely native für Deutschland as anti-Euro party, and in not change significantly leads to the question of Europe - where its approach reaped particular what this position rests on. The next section iden- scorn from southern Europeans (for the Italian tifies cornerstones of the German position towards case see Olmastroni and Pellegata 2018). Compat- developing the EMU’s social dimension and relate ibility with it is the underlying theme was a there- them to current debates. fore a precondition for any measure in social- and employment policy. Any initiative in this domain Cornerstones of the German has to be evaluated on terms of financial sustain- position towards the EMU’s ability and international competitiveness, and social dimension must not relieve pressures for national structural reforms or induce moral hazard (Bundesregierung The German position towards the EMU’s social 2016). dimension shaped by a number of constraints The protection of the post-crisis architecture as first on the national and European level that prevent cornerstone is reflected in the German policy it from taking meaningful action to address the priorities, (Scholz 2018) and in its discourse. asymmetry between economic and social integra- Whereas the completion of the Banking Union tion. On the European level, one core dictum is is an often-discussed priority, distinctly social compatibility with its overall approach towards portfolios receive very little attention.167 Instead, the governance of the EMU. the German discourse about a more social The German imprint on the EMU is often said to be Europe draws on a variety of portfolios, such as ordoliberal (Blyth 2013; Dullien and Guérot 2012; the Banking Union and the transformation of Stiglitz 2015). Although clear differences between the ESM to an EMF that are regarded as instru- the post-crisis EMU and the ordoliberal ideal type ments for “help to help themselves”168 (Schäuble can be distinguished (Hadeed 2017; Hien and 2014), and thus contributing indirectly to social Joergesn 2018), the strengthening of the osten- justice. Secondly, dossiers with questionable social sible rule-based system that marked crisis-resolu- implications receive a distinctly social framing. tion adheres on first glance to the de-politicization This became clear in the debate surrounding the of economic decisions already envisioned by the Posted Workers Directive, which was hailed by the ordoliberal founding fathers (Böhm, Eucken, and government as an advancement of the social rights Grossmann-Doerthe 1989[1936]). Regardless of of posted workers (Bundesregierung 2017b). The the ideological (in)coherence of those reinforcing alternative view that the aim of the revision was measures, they fit the pervasive German narrative the protection of domestic workers from “undue”

166 It includes the vague calls for fair conditions for work- 167 Incidentally, Angela Merkel abstained from the Go- ers, better coordination of employment policies, a framework thenburg Social Summit to oversee the coalition talks, leaving for minimum wage and national basic social security schemes, Germany without a representative at the occasion (Riegert as well as better comparability of education standards (Coali- 2017) tion Agreement 2018, 7) 168 Translation by the author.

WHAT TO EXPECT FROM GERMANY FOR THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS AND BEYOND? 189 Marcel Hadeed competition and indeed impeding on the social Transfers are interpreted broadly, spanning not rights of posted workers – a position articulated only direct payments but also those that result by seven particularly affected Member States169 from differences in the quality of social structures. in an open letter to the Commission (Kalfin et al. An ardent argument against a European Unem- 2015) – received rather little attention. ployment Insurance has long been that it would The second principle shaping Germany’s general disproportionately benefit member states with outlook on the EMU’s social dimension revolves weaker active labor market policies. This would around the protection of its national socio-economic not only relieve reform pressures but also induce system from outside reform pressures. Its insis- moral hazard (Feld and Osterloh 2013). tence on the primacy of national competencies Combined these constraints result in a reluctant relies on three distinct concerns. Legal limitations Germany that focuses on maintaining and consol- arise not only in view of the Treaties, but also of idating its own socio-economic model, as well as the German Basic Law. This insistence is backed the general thrust of the EMU post-crisis gover- by the German Constitutional Court in the EMU nance. case: As long as there is no democratic equivalent Nonetheless, drivers for reform also exist. the to national parliaments on EU level and an expan- German government is not unaware of the social sion of competencies through new legal bases, a challenges and the need for socio-economic transfer of competencies in employment- and convergence in the EU. It sees the social challenge social policy cannot be compatible with Germa- on the European level as twofold: (1) coping with ny’s democratic character (Bundesverfassungs- the persistent challenges of the crisis and diver- gericht 1998). Neither can it change the consti- gence; and (2) making employment- and social tutional identity, in which pillars of the social policy future-proof with regard to globalization, market economy are enshrined (ibid). Particularly, digitalization and demographic change (Bundes- the status of the social partners, which have the regierung 2016). constitutional right to free collective bargaining (Tarifautonomie) limits the instruments that can To address the former, Germany argues for be used to foster convergence by excluding the continued structural reforms, particularly in possibility of wage-coordination regimes, a vital Member States with persistent struggles. The tool to address divergence in the Eurozone (e.g. recent proposals by Angela Merkel for a new Johnston, Hancké, and Pant 2014; Manow 2016). investment budget and the development of the ESM into and EMF are the core of the German Beyond these legal concerns, the German govern- vision for convergence (Gutschker and Lohse ment fears forced convergence might lead to down- 2018). In contrast, realigning social- and employ- ward pressure on the German social system, and ment policies, convergence of social standards and disregard the institutional particularities in which living conditions and “future-proofing” of social policies must be evaluated (Bundesregierung systems should be pursued through softer instru- 2016). In an environment of such institutional ments, particularly the development of bench- divergence, fear of such pressures is a powerful marks and best-practice exchange (Bundesr- constraint on German policy. Lastly, a red line for egierung 2016). The constraints elaborated above the German government is the idea of a transfer prevent any meaningful action towards addressing union (Bollmann and Kloepfer 2018). It opposes the EMU’s social imbalance with the same type of German economic orthodoxy (Sachverständi- rigidity as issues of competitiveness. genrat zur Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftli- chen Entwicklung 2017), and is politically toxic. The result is a German approach towards the development of the EMU’s social dimension that 169 Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Estonia, , Latvia, Lithuania, , Romania, Slovakia is both, endorsing in principle, and rejecting in

WHAT TO EXPECT FROM GERMANY FOR THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS AND BEYOND? 190 Marcel Hadeed effect. The elaborated drivers and constraints This can be viewed as an encouraging sign for create the following dilemma: Germany’s a more accommodating German vision for the constraints prevent it from committing to strong future of the Eurozone, but it is only one of three instruments for convergence, which is – by alle- concrete proposals of the German government, viating concerns of downward pressure or trans- and the remaining, the ESM’s transformation into fers – simultaneously a precondition to agree on an EMF, and the investment budget for the Euro- binding measures. The failure of convergence is zone reinforce the mantra of the cash-for-reform thus at the same time the source and the result of approach as path towards improved living condi- the German inhibition (Bundesministerium der tions in the EMU (Gutschker and Lohse 2018). Finanzen and DIW Berlin 2018). This circular This is in line with the overall German mantra of reasoning has yet to be broken. boosting competitiveness and consolidating the Naturally, there are also political drivers. The “achievements” of crisis politics. The German posi- uptick in populism in recent years, not least the tion towards the Commission’s initial proposal for elections in Italy, combined with an ambitious and a European Pillar of Social Rights (EPSR) exem- increasingly impatient French president Macron plifies the discussed factors and gives a compre- undoubtedly pressure the German government hensive view on a German vision for fostering to “do more”. Between the ongoing MFF-negoti- social convergence. ations, the upcoming European Parliament elec- tions in 2019, and the official British withdrawal, a The German assessment of the window of opportunity is for decisive action is still EPSR open, but quickly closing. In April 2016, the European Commission published The extent to which these political consider- a Communication introducing a first draft for the ations motivate Germany to agree to concessions EPSR, kicking of a comprehensive consultation in its position is yet unknown. Movement can be process to which stakeholders, member states observed on the dossier of a European Unem- and ordinary citizens could contribute (Euro- ployment Reinsurance scheme. The German pean Commission 2016). In December that year, government had consistently rejected proposals the government of the previous Grand Coalition made first by then Commissioner László Ándor submitted its comprehensive assessment of the (Wettach and Krumrey 2014) and later Italian EPSR to the Commission. It welcomed the Pillar’s finance minister Pier Carlo Padoan (Maggiore basic orientation as a step towards strengthening and Leontopoulos 2017). With its labor market in and operationalization the EMU’s social dimen- excellent shape, the German government fearing sion (Bundesregierung 2016). This endorsement that such an arrangement would induce moral was, however, conditional on keeping the current hazard and result in permanent transfers, thusly division of competencies and the absolute preven- rejecting the proposal – a position shared by the tion of pooling of costs for social systems. This German Council of Economic Experts (Sach- relates to the constraints of preventing outside verständigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesam- reform pressure and being drawn into financial twirtschaftlichen Entwicklung 2017). The recent obligations. A categorical no was directed at any endorsement for an unemployment reinsurance transfer of competences to the European level by finance minister Scholz (Reiermann and Sauga and the primary “Gestaltungskompetenz” was to 2018) might be a nod to the elaborated polit- remain with Member States (Bundesregierung ical drivers, and skepticism about the economic 2016). It concluded that therefore the EPSR could benefit still exists in the German finance ministry only take the form of a recommendation, (ibid.) (Bundesministerium der Finanzen 2017). which is by nature non-binding. The pillar is

WHAT TO EXPECT FROM GERMANY FOR THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS AND BEYOND? 191 Marcel Hadeed viewed as useful to foster upwards convergence tion of active employment policy and minimum of social security systems in specified domains, standards of social security.170 Here, Germany improve coordination between Member States sees great potential for improvement, primarily and identify common principles. Crucially, this not with its own institutional structures, but espe- upward convergence is understood to be achieved cially in those countries that suffer most from through structural reforms targeting efficiency high unemployment (ibid.). Other policy fields, and effectiveness of national social systems. This chief among the pension systems, would not lend speaks to the alignment of social policy port- themselves to any kind of coordination, due to folios with the general thrust of the post-crisis the difference in their institutional anchoring. EMU. The government therefore ensured that Outright rejected are those proposals concerning no binding measures could exert pressure on its the coordination of wage-setting processes, such social system, while encouraging such pressures in as on minimum wages. Both of the elaborated other Member States. It saw austerity politics and cornerstones of German policy thus become efficient social policy as intrinsically linked with visible in the approach and substance endorsed by each other. Only fiscal sustainability, achieved the German position. through structural reforms, can guarantee effi- cient social systems. Conversely, the efficiency of Conclusion – what to social systems contributes to competitiveness and expect from Germany for thus fiscal sustainability of member states(ibid.). the EPSR and wider social In this view, austerity and social convergence are integration? compatible. The government made a compelling leap to connect conceptually what opposed each What can be drawn from these considerations to other empirically: austerity and social progress. assess what can be expected from Germany for the Thereby moving into a policy stance in which it future of the EPSR and the social dimension of the could well declare its support for the initiative EMU more broadly? while insisting on its compatibility with the domi- Boosting the EMU’s social dimension is not a nant governance regime. priority for the German government, and is not In this light, the EPSR’s integration into the Euro- featured in the coalition agreement, the rele- pean Semester via the Social Scoreboard can be vant ministry’s list of priorities, or the increas- viewed as a consolidation of the structural reform ingly visible vision for reforming the EU in the approach. Its integration and its non-binding legal coming years. The example of the EPSR shows character ensure both the general thrust of the how the dilemma of the German position towards post-crisis EMU governance structure remained social convergence prevents it from commit- unchallenged by social considerations, ostensibly ting to binding measures. Consent for dossiers to resolving the dichotomic relationship between strengthen the EMU’s social dimension can only fiscal and social demands. This position equally be expected where German particularities and secured the maintenance of Eurozone governance’ national competencies remain shielded, and the character and safeguarded the German social overarching goals of convergence through struc- market economy from outside pressure, adhering tural reforms remains unchallenged. These are the to the German cornerstone of system mainte- preconditions for purposeful German endorse- nance. ment. They dim hopes for German efforts towards In substance, too, the German position follows a meaningful social convergence in the EMU. Polit- 170 This is not surprising insofar as Germany had previ- logic of safeguarding its own institutional struc- ously also supported the Youth Guarantee, the Recommenda- tures. Endorsement was given to the coordina- tion on the integration of the long-term unemployed into the labor market, and the Skills Agenda.

WHAT TO EXPECT FROM GERMANY FOR THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS AND BEYOND? 192 Marcel Hadeed ical drivers, and a window of opportunity have led to limited movement on the issue of a Euro- pean Unemployment Reinsurance scheme, but the main thrust of Germany’s recent proposal underscores its insistence on the primacy of struc- tural reforms, and the preference for non-binding measures as the core mechanisms to achieve social convergence in the EMU. It falls in line with and must be compatible with the German overall approach towards the Eurozone and must protect the German social market economy from outside pressures. The verdict is thus a rather gloomy one: without resolving the constraint dilemma, one cannot expect much from Germany in the quest for a more social EMU.

WHAT TO EXPECT FROM GERMANY FOR THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS AND BEYOND? 193 Marcel Hadeed References Content/DE/Artikel/2018/01/2018-01-03-ar- beitsmarkt-jahresbilanz-2017.html (June 14, Blyth, Mark. 2013. Austerity: The History of a 2018). Dangerous Idea. New York: Oxford University ———. 2017b. “Gleicher Lohn Für Gleiche Arbeit.” Press. https://www.bundesregierung.de/Content/DE/ Böhm, Franz, Walter Eucken, and Hans Gross- Artikel/2017/10/2017-10-24-entsendericht- mann-Doerthe. 1989. “The Ordo Manifesto of linie.html (June 14, 2018). 1936.” In Germany’s Social Market Economy: Bundesverfassungsgericht. 1998. Beschluss Des Origins and Evolution, eds. Alan Peacock and Zweiten Senats Vom 31. März 1998 - 2 BvR Hans Willgerodt. NewYork: St. Martin’s Press, 1877/97 Und 2 BvR 50/98. 292. Dullien, Sebastian, and Ulrike Guérot. 2012. The Bollmann, Ralph, and Inge Kloepfer. 2018. “Inter- Long Shadow of Ordoliberalism : Germany ’ s view Mit Olaf Scholz: ‘Europa Muss Schneller Approach to the Euro Crisis. London. Reagieren Können.’” Frankfurter Allgemeine Sonntagszeitung. https://www.bundesregie- “Ein Neuer Aufbruch Für Europa, Eine Neue rung.de/Content/DE/Interview/2018/04/2018- Dynamik Für Deutschland, Ein Neuer Zusam- 04-15-scholz-fas.html. menhalt Für Unser Land - Coalition Agree- ment between the CDU, CSU and SPD.” 2018. Bundesfinanzministerium. 2017. “Eckwerte Zum https://www.bundesregierung.de/Content/DE/ Bundeshaushalt 2018 Und Finanzplan Bis StatischeSeiten/Breg/koalitionsvertrag-inhalts- 2021.” https://www.bundesfinanzministerium. verzeichnis.html (June 14, 2018). de/Content/DE/Bilderstrecken/Mediathek/ Infografiken/bundeshaushalt-2018-2021-re- European Commission. 2016. “Communication gierungsentwurf.html?notFirst=true&do- Launching a Consultation on a European Pillar cId=120660#photogallery (June 14, 2018). of Social Rights.” SWD(2016)(50, 51). Bundesministerium der Finanzen. 2017. Non- Feld, Lars P, and Steffen Osterloh. 2013. Is a Fiscal Paper for Paving the Way towards a Stability Capacity Really Necessary to Complete EMU? Union. Freiburg im Breisgau. Bundesministerium der Finanzen, and DIW Gutschker, Thomas, and Eckart Lohse. 2018. Berlin. 2018. Finanz- Und Sozialpolitik - Ein “Interview with Angela Merkel: Existenzfragen Spannungsfeld Im Europäischen Binnenmarkt. Für Europa.” Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung. Berlin. Hadeed, Marcel. 2017. “The Ordoliberal Ghost.” Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Energie. Social Europe. https://www.socialeurope.eu/ 2018. “Wirtschaftliche Entwicklung Und the-ordoliberal-ghost (September 4, 2018). Konjunktur.” https://www.bmwi.de/Redaktion/ Heil, Hubertus. 2018. “‘Mit Vereinten Kräften.’” DE/Dossier/wirtschaftliche-entwicklung.html http://www.bmas.de/DE/Presse/Reden/ (June 14, 2018). Hubertus-Heil/2018/rede-2018-05-18. Bundesregierung. 2016. “Stellungnahme Der html;jsessionid=8EDF44BA738150AD7EC- Deutschen Bundesregierung Im Rahmen Der B7C204EAD25EF. Konsultation Zur Europäischen Säule Sozialer Hien, Josef, and Christian Joergesn. 2018. “Dead Rechte.” : 1–61. Man Walking? Current European Interest ———. 2017a. “Ein Starkes 2017 Am Arbeits- in the Ordolierbal Tradition.” European Law markt.” https://www.bundesregierung.de/ Journal 24(2–3): 142–62.

WHAT TO EXPECT FROM GERMANY FOR THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS AND BEYOND? 194 Marcel Hadeed Johnston, Alison, Bob Hancké, and Suman Pant. Hat Eine Besondere Verantwortung.” Spiegel. 2014. “Comparative Institutional Advantage in http://www.spiegel.de/plus/olaf-scholz- the European Sovereign Debt Crisis.” Compar- deutschland-hat-eine-besondere-verantwortun ative Political Studies 47(13): 1771–1800. g-a-00000000-0002-0001-0000-000157769163. Kalfin, Ivailo et al. 2015. “Letter to Commissioner Riegert, Bernd. 2017. “EU Social Summit: Fair for Employment, Social Affairs, Skills and Jobs, Fair Growth Must Be a Priority.” DW Labour Mobility.” (July). News. http://www.dw.com/en/eu-social- Kohler, Berthold. 2013. “Die Schutzherrin Des summit-fair-jobs-fair-growth-must-be-a- Status Quo.” Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung priority/a-41430438 (June 14, 2018). (online). http://www.faz.net/aktuell/politik/ Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der inland/kommentar-zur-wiederwahl-von-an- gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. gela-merkel-die-schutzherrin-des-sta- 2017. 2017/18 Für Eine Zukunftsorientierte tus-quo-12715473.html (June 14, 2018). Wirtschaftspolitik. Wiesbaden. https://www. Maggiore, Maria, and Nikolas Leontopoulos. sachverstaendigenrat-wirtschaft.de/fileadmin/ 2017. “Italiens Finanzminister Forder Eine dateiablage/gutachten/jg201718/JG2017-18_ Europäische Arbeitslosenversicherung.” Tages- gesamt_Website.pdf. spiegel. https://www.tagesspiegel.de/politik/ Schäuble, Dr. Wolfgang. 2014. “Noch Nicht Über pier-carlo-padoan-italiens-finanzminister-for- Den Berg - Zur Krise in Der Eurozone.” https:// dert-eine-europaeische-arbeitslosenversiche- www.bundesfinanzministerium.de/Content/ rung/20328310.html. DE/Reden/2014/2014-07-11-Stiftung- Manow, Philip. 2016. “Uniform Monetary Policy Ordnungspolitik.html. , Non-Uniform Wage Policy : How Rules and Scholz, Olaf. 2018. “Re­gie­rungs­er­klä­rung von Olaf Discretion Get into Conflict in the Eurozone ( Scholz, Bun­des­mi­nis­ter Der Fi­nan­zen, Zur Fi­ and What – If Anything – Ordoliberalism Has nanz- Und Haus­halts­po­li­tik Der Bun­des­re­gie­ to Do with It ).” rung Am 22. März 2018 Im Deutschen­ Bun­des­ Offe, Claus. 2015. “Narratives of Responsibility: t a g .” https://www.bundesfinanzministerium. German Politics in the Greek Debt Crisis.” de/Content/DE/Reden/2018/2018-03-22- Cassa della Cultura: 1–30. http://www.casadel- Aussprache-Regierungserklaerung.html. lacultura.it/pdfarticoli/Claus-Offe-Narratives- Sirleschtov, Antje. 2017. “Wahlprogramm of-Responsibility.pdf. Der Union: Eine Politik Für Bewahrer Des Olmastroni, Francesco, and Alessandro Pellegata. Status Quo.” Tagesspiegel. https://www. 2018. “Members Apart : A Mass-Elite Compar- tagesspiegel.de/politik/wahlprogramm-der- ison of Mutual Perceptions and Support for union-eine-politik-fuer-bewahrer-des-status- the European Union in Germany and Italy.” quo/20014452.html (June 14, 2018). Contemporary Italian Politics 10(1): 56–75. Stiglitz, Joseph. 2015. “Europe’s Lapse of Reiermann, Christian. 2018. “Deutschlands Staats- Reason.” project-syndicate.org. https://www. verschuldung Sinkt 2019 Unter 60 Prozent.” project-syndicate.org/commentary/european- Spiegel Online. http://www.spiegel.de/wirt- union-austerity-backlash-by-joseph-e-- schaft/soziales/deutschland-staatsverschul- stiglitz-2015-01. dung-sinkt-2019-unter-60-prozent-a-1201557. Wettach, Silke, and Henning Krumrey. 2014. html (June 14, 2018). “Andors Pläne Stoßen Auf Breite Ablehnung.” Reiermann, Christian, and Michael Sauga. 2018. Wirtschaftswoche. “Interview Mit Olaf Scholz: Deutschland

WHAT TO EXPECT FROM GERMANY FOR THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS AND BEYOND? 195 Marcel Hadeed THE EU POLITICAL CULTURE However, the optimism of the EU institutions, OF TOTAL OPTIMISM IS NOT which accompanied the creation of the Social Pillar from its first announcement by President Juncker DEAD: REFLECTIONS ON to the Proclamation of the final text in Gothen- THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF burg, might seem not to be coherent with what SOCIAL RIGHTS their ultimate accomplishment has to offer.176 The final result strongly resembles a non-legally-bin- Vladimir Bogoeski ding declaration of rights which, for the most 177 Hertie School of Governance part, already exist, and raises scepticism about the Pillar’s capacity to remedy the problems that it has identified effectively.178 Thus, this contribution Introduction looks behind the enthusiasm accompanying the In his “State of the Union Address” of September Pillar, and sets out to examine its value through 2015 the President of the Commission Jean- the concept of the “EU political culture of total optimism”, as defined and elaborated by Giando- Claude Juncker made a sincere confession, admit- 179 ting that the Union was not in a good state.171 But menico Majone. The contribution argues that his speech was not entirely pessimistic, not even the Social Pillar is another example of the EU poli- when he addressed the economic crisis. Rather, tical culture of total optimism, rather than being he announced a set of ambitious proposals, one of capable of adding a genuine social dimension to which was the European Pillar of Social Rights.172 the European integration project. The argument Reminiscent of the Maastricht pillars and their will proceed in three steps. (1) First, the EU culture not so long history, it drew the attention of stake- of political optimism and its three main features, holders, civil society and academics to speculate according to Majone, will be outlined. (2) The about what was behind this pompous announ- second section analyses the Pillar’s objectives and cement. By now, almost three years from its first its capacity to meet them, showing why it reflects announcement, the Social Pillar has not only been the EU political culture of total optimism in exem- pinned down in an official Document, with stated plary fashion. (3) The last section concludes by principles and rights, but it has also been solemnly considering the possible consequence. proclaimed by the Commission, the Council, and the European Parliament.173 The intention behind 176 See Florian Rödl, Soziale Rechte in Europa: Von the Social Pillar, as initially expressed by the irreführenden Versprechen und notwendigen Kämpfen, WSI- Herbstforum 2017; Martin Höpner, “Mogelpackung: Warum Commission, is to respond to the social conse- soziale Individualrechte die Europäische Union nicht sozialer quences of the economic crisis, on the one hand, machen”, 25 May 2017, available at: http://www.ipg-journal. and to contribute to the completion of a deeper de/rubriken/europaeische-integration/artikel/mogelpack- and fairer EMU, on the other,174 for which a ung-2047; Simon Deakin, “What Follows Austerity? From So- 175 cial Pillar to New Deal”, in: Frank Vandenbroucke, Catherine social dimension is understood to be necessary. Barnard and Geert De Baere (eds), A European Social Union 171 President Jean-Claude Juncker, State of the European after the Crisis, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Union (SOTEU) Address, European Parliament, Strasbourg, 9 2017). September 2015. 177 The Pillar does introduces a few new rights; see more 172 Ibid. in Zane Rasnaca,̌ “Bridging the gaps or falling short? The Eu- 173 Proclamation of the European Pillar of Social Rights ropean Pillar of Social Rights and what it can Bring to EU-level (EPSR), Gothenburg, 17 November 2017. Policymaking”, ETUI Working Paper 2017.05. 174 COM(2016) 127 final, Launching a consultation on a 178 See note 6 above. EPSR, at 3. 179 Giandomenico Majone, “The Deeper Euro-Crisis 175 EPSC Strategic Note No. 5, (2015) “The Social Dimen- or: The Collapse of the EU Political Culture of Total Opti- sion of Economic and Monetary Union: Towards Convergence mism,” Working Paper, 2015, http://cadmus.eui.eu//han- and Resilience”. dle/1814/35281.

THE EU POLITICAL CULTURE OF TOTAL OPTIMISM IS NOT DEAD: 196 REFLECTIONS ON THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS Vladimir Bogoeski 1. The EU Political Culture potential to strengthen the social dimension of the of Total Optimism EU and tackle the problems that it identifies.

In a paper entitled “The deeper Euro-crisis or: 2. The European Pillar The collapse of the EU political culture of total of Social Rights as a optimism”, Giandomenico Majone argues that Reflection of the EU one of the multiple dimensions of the euro-crisis Political Culture of Total has been its impact on the political culture of EU Optimism leaders.180 His central thesis is that, during the euro-crisis, the previously dominating EU poli- The optimistic aura of the Social Pillar has been tical culture of total optimism was replaced by evident since it was first mentioned by Presi- 181 “panic-driven austerity”. Majone understands dent Juncker as a way forward after a decade of the concept of political culture as a collective economic crisis.185 The term Pillar, which apart property, “a system of empirical beliefs, expressive from the reminiscence of the Treaty of Maastricht symbols, and values which defines the situation in pillars might bring to mind the biblical pillar of 182 which political action takes place”. As the Euro- strength,186 also implies that it is an instrument with pean Union (still) consists of 28 Member States, in a certain political weight and with certain ambi- which political culture varies greatly both across tions, which should bolster and mean progress for and within polities, he recognises that it would be Social Europe. Europe-wide consultations took misleading to speak of a political culture of the EU place over the course of ten months in 2016, stake- as a whole. In Majone’s understanding the concept holders provided around 200 position papers, and of political culture, in the case of the EU, makes 16,500 replies to the online dedicated question- sense only if it is applied to the élites operating in naire were received, upon the basis of which the 183 the EU framework. Commission has recommended a final text for Majone identifies three defining characteristics of the Pillar.187 This provided for a wide presence of the EU political culture of total optimism amongst the Pillar in various EU and Member State level the political élites, which also constitute the debates. Finally, the optimism came full circle at outcomes of the same mindset: 1) the emphasis the Social Summit in Gothenburg on 17 November on the process rather than the results; 2) the igno- 2017, where the EU institutions expressed support rance of feasibility constraints and possible risks; for and commitment to the Pillar in signing the and 3) the disregard for the limits of collective official Proclamation.188 But what is actually in action.184 The following section analyses the goals the final text of this instrument, which has, for a and the content of the European Pillar of Social moment, raised the hopes of affected stakeholders, Rights in accordance with these characteristics of civil society and Social Europe advocates? Did the total optimism, in order to answer the question of mountain that shook bring forth a mouse? What whether the Pillar itself is a reflection of this polit- can the final instrument, which we now call the ical culture, or whether it entails some genuine Social Pillar - a non-legally-binding declaration of (mostly) already existing individual rights – actu- 180 Ibid., Abstract. ally do? 181 Ibid. 182 Majone relies on Verba’s definition of political culture as in Sidney Verba, “Comparative Political Culture”, in: Lucien 185 SOTEU Address in note 1 above. W. Pye and Sidney Verba (eds), Political Culture and Politi- 186 “The Lord is my pillar, and my fortress …”, Psalm 18:2- cal Development, (Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press, 4, The Holy Bible, Modern English Version. 1965), pp. 512-60. 187 SWD(2017) 206 final, Report on the public consulta- 183 Majone, note 9 above, at 2. tion, Brussels, 26.4.2017, at 5. 184 Ibid. 188 Note 3 above.

THE EU POLITICAL CULTURE OF TOTAL OPTIMISM IS NOT DEAD: 197 REFLECTIONS ON THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS Vladimir Bogoeski The Social Pillar as a Process convergence as a process overshadows the concrete goal to which all the Member States and the EU The consultations that took place between March itself should converge. This paradigm seems to be and December 2016 identified four broad trends the contested “flexicurity” model that the Pillar that the Pillar should address: (i) the social conse- intends to petrify as the European recipe for quences of the crisis, including increasing poverty balancing social rights and economic freedoms,193 and exclusion, inequalities and unemployment, by fostering the already well-known discourse of, and low growth and competitiveness; (ii) the in the words of Ruth Dukes, the “overestimation of future of work and the emerging digital labour the extent of shared interest between workers and market; (iii) demographic developments, that is employers”.194 Nonetheless, it becomes clear that to say, the ageing of Europe’s population; and (iv) the Pillar intends to activate a continuous process, economic divergence across the Member States.189 but what remains unclear is its operative part, as Their common denominator is the Pillar’s ambi- well as when and what kind of concrete results tion to complement the existing EU “social should be expected. acquis” by “giving new and more efficient rights to citizens, which set an agenda for better perfor- The (In-) Feasibility of the ming economies and more equitable and resilient Pillar societies”.190 This ambition becomes more flawed and ambiguous in the course of development of The question of results requires an inquiry into the several documents accompanying the Pillar. the feasibility of the Pillar’s goals. The feasibi- At certain point, in a contradictory manner, one lity problem that Majone identifies with the EU of the documents says that the recognition of political culture of total optimism arises due to new rights is not the focus, but rather the enfor- the ignorance of the existing constraints and the cement of rights (the take up).191 However, the possible risks when political decisions are made. documents repeatedly state that the Pillar needs In the case of the Pillar, we could talk of the factual to be seen as an instrument which will serve as a or given constraints, on the one hand, and the compass of convergence within the Euro area,192 feasibility constraints directly attributable to the which brings us to the first feature of Majone’s Pillar’s approach, on the other. As to the factual culture of total optimism, namely, the focus on or pre-existing constraints, the Pillar does recog- the process, rather than the outcome. The Pillar nise the limits to common European social policy aims to steer a process of further social conver- due to the high level of diversity of the national gence among the Member States of the Eurozone, social models and the different levels of economic which should eventually lead to deeper economic development among the Member States.195 It even and monetary integration. The Pillar should guide emphasises that the diversity of Member States’ both the EU’s and the Member States’ social policy social models needs to be respected, thus alloca- choices towards achieving the ideals of the social ting most of the implementation tasks to the rights that it contains, and they should - one day - Member States themselves.196 Notwithstanding converge under this guidance. The focus on social this, the most relevant constraint to the Pillar’s

189 COM(2017) 250 final, Establishing a European Pillar of 193 COM(2016) 127 final, at 5; SWD(2017) 201 final, at 22 Social Rights, Brussels, 26.4.2017, at 4. ff. 190 Note 19 above, at 4. 194 Ruth Dukes, “From the Labour Constitution to an Eco- 191 Ibid, at 7. nomic Sociology of Labour Law”, final draft of a contribution to a Book Symposium, forthcoming in the journal Jurispru- 192 SOTEU Address in note 1 above; COM(2016) 127 dence. final, note 4 above; COM(2017) 250 final, note 19 above; COM(2018) 130 final, Monitoring the implementation of the 195 Rec. 19, Preamble, EPSR. European Pillar of Social Rights. 196 COM(2017) 250 final, at 2.

THE EU POLITICAL CULTURE OF TOTAL OPTIMISM IS NOT DEAD: 198 REFLECTIONS ON THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS Vladimir Bogoeski objectives to countervail successfully the social resources.202 The Social Pillar could neither make consequences of the economic crisis, market inte- a considerable contribution to the establishing of gration and labour market developments, is its the required legal framework and institutional inadequate approach to remedy these problems by structure, nor could it respond to the most crit- declaring individual social rights. ical point of weakness of such previous declara- Despite its solemn proclamation, the Pillar none- tions of social rights, namely, that Member States could still invoke the pretext of “maximum avail- theless remains a non-legally-binding document 203 that declares 20 principles containing 35 individual able resources”. social rights.197 Many of these can be found in pre- As the effectiveness of most of the Pillar’s rights and existing documents, such as the EU Charter of principles will depend on creating the necessary Fundamental Rights, the European Social Charter institutional set up mainly at Member State level, of Turin 1961, and the Community Charter of the both the diversity of the national social models Fundamental Social Rights of Workers of 1989.198 and the differences in economic development The language interchangeably referring to princi- will probably be echoed in the Pillar’s outcome. ples and rights is itself obscure.199 However, it is not The Pillar itself acknowledges that judicial recog- its non-legally-binding nature, but its approach nition and enforcement will not be enough to to addressing the structural challenges of market realise its programmatic principles effectively,204 integration and the years of austerity policies, such but does not give a clear lead as to how Member as inequality, poverty and inclusion, through indi- States are to establish and sustain the structures vidual rights, that is the Pillar’s main weakness. imperative for actualising rights and entitlements, In his latest book, entitled Not Enough: Human such as childcare and support for children, social protection, unemployment benefits, minimum Rights in an Unequal World, Yale’s professor of 205 Law and History, Samuel Moyn, argues that income, old age income and pensions, etc. These economic and social rights have failed to chal- concerns question the Pillar’s capacity to deliver lenge inequality and distributive fairness both in on its commitment to social convergence in the the national and in the global political economy.200 Eurozone and/or the EU in general. In a similar manner, the Pillar fails to recog- The Limits of Collective Action nise the constraints of the rights approach, thus possibly foreclosing on searching for other visions As Majone submits, collective actors face limit- for serious re-distributive politics. Florian Rödl ations compared to individual decision-makers, describes the pursuit of structural social objec- and “the larger the group, the further it will fall tives merely through the language of rights as short of providing an optimal amount of a collec- the “juridical misconception” of social rights.201 tive good”.206 In the case of the Pillar, however, we Social rights are different in nature from civil could not talk of a total disregard of/for the limits and political rights, as their effective realisation of collective action. What its approach finally requires not only absence of arbitrary state action, shows us is the acknowledgement of the contra- but also elaborate legal structures and material diction between the accepted diversity of national 197 See Höpner, note 6 above. social models and the advancement of the idea of 198 Rec. 3, Preamble, EPSR. a fully-harmonised social sphere at supranational 199 Frank Hendrickx, “Editorial: The European Pillar of Social Rights: Interesting Times Ahead”, (2017) 8 European 202 Ibid. Labour Law Journal, 191-92. 203 SWD(2017) 201 final, at 4. 200 Samuel Moyn, Not Enough: Human Rights in an Unequal World, (Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 204 Preamble recital (14), EPSR. 2018). 205 Chapter III “Social Protection and Inclusion”, EPSR. 201 Florian Rödl, note 6 above. 206 Majone, note 9 above, at 6.

THE EU POLITICAL CULTURE OF TOTAL OPTIMISM IS NOT DEAD: 199 REFLECTIONS ON THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS Vladimir Bogoeski level.207 It is not only the budgetary constraints, result of the necessity to act against the rising EU but also the accepted varieties of capitalism208 scepticism, attempting to countervail the argu- and socio-economic cultures within the EU that ments that the EMU, on the one hand, and the have lead researchers to recognise that full social single market, on the other, have had negative harmonisation will not be the blueprint solution consequences for social justice at both EU and for the European social model.209 In the light of Member State level.211 The ubiquity of the debate this, in the pursuit of the collective good, defined on the Social Pillar together with its inter-institu- as upward social convergence for better perfor- tional proclamation, have, without doubt, raised ming economic and monetary integration, the hopes, as we can, for example, observe in an official Pillar might downplay the diversity of the chal- statement from a recent conference of trade union lenges that the different Member States are facing. leaders from the Visegrád countries,212 where, in Promoting this collective good of social conver- support of their plea for an upward wage conver- gence, the Pillar fails, first of all, to offer concrete gence and reduction of the East-West gap, they and adequate protection to the existing Member explicitly referred to Principle 6 of the Pillar.213 States’ social models from the potential negative However, as the disappointment of broken prom- effects of economic and monetary integration. It ises may easily result in increasing, rather than provides clear and concrete response to none of decreasing, Eurosceptic sentiments, the future of the two most pressing issues, namely, neither to the EU’s social dimension will largely depend on the Viking-Laval controversy which has accom- both the EU’s and the Member States’ capacity to panied the decade of austerity policies, nor to the go beyond the Pillar when developing and imple- scenario in which future austerity policies could menting concrete social policies in order to set override national social objectives.210 and achieve social objectives. The Pillar leaves us with more questions than answers, but the polit- Conclusion ical actors and stakeholders should nonethe- less explore further the possible productive ways As decision-makers in a political culture of total of using it, which should in no way foreclose on optimism would focus on the process rather than pursuing more progressive alternatives, following on concrete results, lessening the relevance of the the latest example of the “European Pact for Social existing feasibility constraints and the limits of Progress”.214 collective action, offering some kind of a response might seem preferable to not offering a response at all. The Social Pillar represents this political culture in an exemplary fashion. It has come as a

207 See Höpner, note 6 above; Christian Joerges, “Social 211 On the context of the Pillar, see Sacha Garben, “The Justive in an Ever More Diverse Union”, in: Frank Vanden- European Pillar of Social Rights: Effectively Addressing Dis- broucke, Catherine Barnard and Geert De Baere (eds), A placement?”, (2018) 14 European Constitutional Law Review, European Social Union after the Crisis, (Cambridge: Cambridge 210-230, at 212 ff. University Press, 2017). 212 Statement, Meeting of trade union leaders of the Viseg- 208 Peter Hall and David Soskice, Varieties of Capitalism: rád countries, , 10-11 May 2018. The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, (Ox- 213 Principle 6, EPSR: “Workers have the right to fair wages ford: Oxford University Press, 2001). that provide for a decent standard of living.” 209 See more on the concept of European Social Union in 214 A European Pact for Social Progress, Vienna, 29 Vandenbroucke et al., note 6 above. November 2016. See Florian Rödl, “Austerity and Marketisa- 210 See Marcel Hadeed, “What to Expect from Germany tion: Viking, Laval and the Proclamation of the New Social for the European Pillar of Social Rights?”, Paper presented at Dimension”, Paper presented at the conference“Responses of the conference, “Responses of European Economic Cultures European Economic Cultures to Europe’s Crisis Politics: The to Europe’s Crisis Politics: The Example of German-Italian Example of German-Italian Discrepancies”, Villa Vigoni, 26-27 Discrepancies”, Villa Vigoni, 26-27 June 2018. June 2018.

THE EU POLITICAL CULTURE OF TOTAL OPTIMISM IS NOT DEAD: 200 REFLECTIONS ON THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS Vladimir Bogoeski A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ Given the legitimation crisis that has been aff ecting LEADERSHIP FOR THE the European Union in the last years, the way in which EU institutions, and in particular, the Presi- PRESIDENT OF THE dent of the Commission as the EU main represen- COMMISSION? A MIXED- tative, communicate with the public plays a funda- METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED mental role in fostering reclaiming legitimacy not ANALYSIS only for EU decisions, but for the EU integration process as a whole. Accordingly, the aim of this Pamela Pansardi, University of Pavia paper is to study the communicative strategies of the two latest Presidents of the Commissions to Th e multiple crises that have been aff ecting the EU investigate their active role in reclaiming legiti- since 2008 – the Eurozone crisis, the refugee crisis, macy and support for the EU. the Brexit, to name a few – and the failure of EU Since the onset of the Eurozone crisis, the leader- institutions in eff ectively addressing them have ship role of the Commission amongst EU insti- posed a severe challenge to very foundations of tutions has been deemed to be in decline (Bauer the project of European integration (Börzel 2016: and Becker 2016). On the one hand, the diffi cult 25) and have led to what Juncker described as an governance of the crisis witnessed the relative ‘existential crisis’ (Juncker 2016). A crisis, fi rst of weakening of the supranational vis-a vis the inter- all, in legitimacy and support, made more severe governmental approach, with the emergence of by the ‘blame-shift ing’ model that permeates the the European Council as the key political player rhetoric of Eurosceptic parties and movements. (Dinan 2016; Fabbrini 2015). On the other hand, In spite of this, the registered level of support for the political governance of the crisis has been to the EU and EU institutions varies greatly among an extent replaced by an economic governance, member states. When comparing Germany and strengthening, and to an extent, ‚politicizing‘ Italy, we immediately notice that these two count- (Verdun 2017), the role of the European Central ries align themselves on the opposite side of the Bank (Tortola and Pansardi 2018). continuum between a full and a scarce support. A number of commentators (Christiansen 2016; Data from EP Eurobarometer 2018 allow for an Dinan 2016; Kassim 2017; Kassim et al. 2017), immediate comparison: While, between 2010 and however, have highlighted a change of direction 2018, Germany steadily attests itself above the in the leadership role of the Commission aft er the means of EU countries, Italy constantly shows a appointment of Jean-Claude Juncker as its Presi- level of support inferior to the average level (and, dent. In particular, the literature suggests the even more signifi cantly, always below the 50%). emergence of a visible diff erence between Barro- Figure 1 presents the results for these two count- so’s and Juncker’s overall approaches to the Presi- ries contrasted with the EU overall level. dency (Kassim 2017; Kassim et al. 2017). Juncker Figure 1. Support for the EU: comparison himself, in the fi rst of his State of the Union between Italy and Germany Addresses (2015), appeals to the Treaties in clai- ming for his mandate a ‚more political‘ role - impli- citly intending, according to Dinan (2016), ‚more political‘ than the leadership style adopted by his predecessor, José Manuel Barroso, oft en accused of lacking assertiveness and being too deferential in dealing with national leaders, in particular those of Germany and France (Dinan 2016: 103). What has changed with Juncker‘s presidency, however,

Source: Socio-demographic trendlines -EP Eurobarometer 2017-2018. Item: Membership of the European Union.

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 201 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi does not entirely derive from personal styles and dents‘ communication, and the results of these choices: the introduction of the Spitzencaditaten two strains of analysis will jointly allow us to system, in fact, and the President‘s possibility empirically verify the claims of a greater ‚politici- to claim for a personal, and more ‚democratic‘, zation‘ of Juncker‘s Presidency in terms of the use mandate, has somehow contributed in strengthe- of language. ning the role of the President. While individual The paper is structured as follows. In the first agency, characterized by differences in personality section, I present the theoretical framework and individual leadership style certainly has an and main results of the analysis of the discur- effect on the role that leaders claim for themselves, sive legitimation strategies developed in Pansardi the introduction of the Spitzencaditaten procedure and Battegazzorre (2018) based on a qualitative undoubtedly had an effect of Juncker‘s interpre- analysis of the ‚symbols‘ included in the speeches. tation of his role, providing him with a different In the second section, I introduce the methodo- opportunity structure than the one of his prede- logical perspective that shape the original soft- cessor. ware-based quantitative analysis of ‚charismatic In this paper, my aim is to empirically investigate language‘ in details. In the third sections, I present and assess the presence of visible differences in the results and offer a first assessment of the empi- the leadership styles of the two latest Presidents of rical findings. The last section discusses the results the Commission as they emerge from their use of and concludes. language in official speeches. While the content - in terms of topics touched and the relevance given 1. The study of the to each of them - is undoubtedly fundamental in discursive legitimation assessing the political perspective of a leader and strategies (SOTEU 2010-2017) his/her political goals, in this paper my focus will be rather on the rhetorical aspects of the speeches, As expounded in Pansardi and Battegazzorre with a particular focus on the tone of the language (2018), a way to investigate the Presidents‘ role used: in particular, whether the language can be in communicating the EU is to analyse how they deemed to be a neutral, descriptive and unemo- have attempted to discursively represent and tional language or whether it is closer to the ideal- reclaim legitimacy for the EU in a particularly type of charismatic, politicized language that often significant institutional setting: the delivery of the accompanies political leadership. While starting State of the Union Address (SOTEU). The SOTEU by summarizing the main points of previous work speech, first introduced in 2010, is the institutional (Pansardi and Battegazzorre 2018) on the so-called occasion on which the President of the Commis- ‚discursive strategies‘ of the two Presidents - based sion openly addresses the past achievements, the on a qualitative content analysis of a small number most pressing challenges that the EU is currently of highly significant speeches (the seven State of facing, and sets the Union’s priorities for the years the Union Speeches from 2010 to 2017) aimed at to come. It is thus a public occasion for reflection investigating the rhetorical strategies used by the on the identity and the future of the European speakers in defining and reclaiming legitimacy for Union. Accordingly, the SOTEU speech provides the EU -, the current work focuses on a quantita- the paramount opportunity for the President of tive assessment of the tone of the language used the Commission to speak not only to EP members by the two Presidents in all of their official spee- and national governments, but also – to an extent – ches (2010-2017) thanks to a dictionary-based directly to European citizens, and to communicate analysis performed with the software DICTION 7. his/her view on the nature and legitimacy of the The paper will accordingly offer a mixed-method European project, as well as to engage in rhetorical interpretation of the changes in the two Presi- attempts to reclaim legitimacy for the EU.

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 202 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi Whilst legitimacy concerns the actual assessment conceptions of the EU’s legitimacy present in the of a particular state of affairs, legitimation consists literature and the four discursive legitimation in the process by which the belief in the right- strategies listed by Van Leeuwen. While the prev- fulness of the authority is claimed or conferred alence of references to goals and effects, which (Barker 2001; Hurrelman 2016). Top-down legi- indicates legitimation through rationalization, may timation strategies should be understood as acti- reveal an output-based conception of legitimacy, vities – institutional or discursive (Gronau and the prevalence of references to (democratic) rules Schmidtke 2016) – distinct, at least in analytical and procedures, which indicates a case of legiti- terms, from the other activities of a political body. mation through authorization, may be seen in Following Gronau and Schmidtke, Pansardi and connection to an input-based conception of the Battegazzorre (2018) define top-down legitimation EU’s legitimacy. Moreover, an extensive reference strategies as: “goal oriented activities employed to to moral values – which characterizes legitima- establish and maintain a reliable basis for diffuse tion through moral evaluation – and the presence support for a political regime by its social consti- of mythopoetic elements may denote an under- tuencies” (Gronau and Schmidtke 2016: 541). standing of legitimacy of a substantial, Weberian The particular need for top-down legitimation kind (Cerutti 2008: 10; Schmidt 2013:11). activities in the case of the EU, sometimes inter- The investigation of the discursive legitima- preted in terms of “political community-buil- tion strategies in the SOTEU speeches proposed ding and/or mythical foundations of identity” by Pansardi and Battegazzorre (2018) consists (Hansen and Williams 1999: 235) has always in a qualitative content analysis of the evalua- been recognized, and it proves of the utmost tive aspects of a speech, which includes: “assi- importance in dealing with the current crises. gnment of categories to text as qualitative step, As Theiler writes: “fostering political legitimacy working through many text passages and analysis always has a ‘top-down’ symbolic dimension. This of frequencies of categories as quantitative step” entails elite-driven construction and dissemina- (Mayring, 2014: 10). In practice, the method tion of symbolic categories which, if successful, consists in the manual coding of the evaluative stimulates more ‘bottom-up’ communicative content of speech transcripts in light of a classi- and deliberative processes” (2005: 4). Legitimi- ficatory grid.215 The grid – the coding scheme – zing discourses are an integral aspect of political was built on the basis of a deductive and inductive communication, and they consist of references to process. General distinctions derived from overall “specific linguistic resources and configurations accepted categories in the study of politics. The of linguistic resources” (Van Leeuwen 2007: 92). distinction among the political (at the EU level In order to analyze the discursive legitimation and at the Member State level), economic, social strategies employed by the two Presidents of the and intellectual spheres was based on the Webe- Commission, Pansardi and Battegazzorre (2018) rian classification of the value-spheres, unders- employed a typology formulated by Van Leeuwen tood as the loci of value rationalization in which (2007; see also Vaara 2014) that differentiates individual action is shaped through the capacity to among four legitimation strategies. These strate- take a position on the world and ascribe a meaning gies can be present separately or in combination, to it (Weber 1949; Oakes 2003). Specific categories and consist in: 1) Authorization; 2) Moral evalua- resulted from the analysis and identification of tion; 3) Rationalization; 4) Mythopoiesis. significant recurrent elements in the seven Spee- The conception of legitimacy that the speaker ches on the State of the Union and a number of endorses undoubtedly affects how s/he shapes his/ 215 Texts were coded with NVivo 10. The work of the two independent coders showed a good degree of inter-coder her discursive strategies. In particular, in this case, reliability, with a Kappa coefficient ranging from 0.76 to 0.94 it is possible to identify a relation among the three for the various symbols categories.

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 203 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi other speeches by the Presidents of the Commis- minance of symbols belonging in the ‘goals’ cate- sion. Definition of the categories and sub-cate- gory, especially ‘economic goals’. The legitimacy of gories and the allocation of ‚symbols‘ (the unit the EU is asserted through ‘rationalist’ and ‘util- of analysis) among the relevant categories allows itarianist’ arguments (Thelier 2005: 22), and it for quantification and overall comparison of the is attested insofar as the EU produces beneficial content of the speeches. outcomes for the ‘political community’. To investigate the understandings of legitimacy Barroso’s speeches, moreover, present elements present in the seven SOTEU speeches delivered of authorization. The kind of authority evoked, between 2010 and 2017216, Pansardi and Battegaz- however, is predominantly the authority of zorre (2018) rely on the frequency217 of specific economic expertise (Reyes, 2011) supported by categories and sub-categories of symbols in the the high frequency of references to economic total of symbols registered in the single speech. values. The choice of the relevant symbolic categories is What emerges from Barroso’s choices in terms of guided by the intent to operationalize Van Leeu- discursive legitimation strategy is an underlying wen’s (2007) typology of discursive legitimation output conception of legitimacy (Scharpf 1999; strategies in light of the three different concep- Schmidt 2013): the community is not the source of tions of legitimacy (input; output; substantial) power per se; it is, by contrast, the ultimate recip- expounded in the previous section. The catego- ient and judge of the activities and decisions of the ries identified as relevant to the study of legiti- EU. In this perspective EU authority and proce- macy are: 1) values; 2) goals; 3) sources of legiti- dures are then motivated and justified in light of macy; 4) interpretations of the political commu- their capacity to make ‘good decisions’ for EU citi- nity (Pansardi and Battegazzorre 2018: 9). zens. In Barroso’s speeches, the legitimazing prin- The empirical study of the frequency of symbols ciple is accordingly the classic, functionalist inter- conducted by Pansardi and Battegazzorre (2018) pretation of the ‘rationality’ of the EU’s decisions allows us to identify clear differences, in terms in terms of, mainly, economic outputs, supported of symbolic content, between the speeches by by reference to merely economic principles and Barroso and the more recent speeches delivered values – as well as by a non-conflictual, techno- by Juncker. Barroso’s speeches make predomi- cratic language (Olsson and Hammargård 2016: nant reference to economic goals and values, while 552-3): Barroso’s attempt to reclaim legitimacy for devoting little attention to symbols concerning the the EU in times of crises thus goes in the direction sources of the EU’s legitimacy – privileging, in this of the depoliticization of current conflicts in light case, the reference to ‘Treaties’ – and providing an of the rationality of EU decisions. interpretation of the political community as a bene- The findings for the SOTEU speeches delivered ficiary of the EU’s decisions and of the European by Juncker allow us to depict a quite different integration process. Referring to the typology of picture. Juncker’s speeches devote little atten- discursive legitimation strategies identified by tion to the economic sphere in general, and to Van Leeuwen (2007), Barroso’s speeches comprise symbols concerning economic goals and values a discursive strategy mainly directed at legitima- in particular. Juncker’s reference to values is made tion through rationalization given by the predo- predominantly in terms of ethical, social and, 216 Speeches were downloaded from the European Com- especially in the last two speeches, political values. mission Press Release Database: http://europa.eu/rapid/search. Symbols concerning the EU political sphere are htm overall predominant, and particular reference is 217 The relative frequency of a category is obtained in relation to the entire symbolic content of the speech. Symbols made to symbols concerning the sources of legiti- that do not pertain to any of the categories relevant to this in- macy. Despite differences between Juncker’s three vestigation are included in the category ‘Other’.

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 204 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi SOTEU speeches – concerning mainly the 2016 want to live in is illustrated by those who are helping. speech, where was registered a slight increase in The Europe I don’t want to live in is a Europe refu- the reference to economic values and goals and a sing those who are in need (Juncker 2015: 6). decrease in the reference to the sources of legiti- The use of these two latter discursive strategies macy – the overall similarities hold in the compar- seems intended to provide and reinforce thicker ison with Barroso’s speeches. symbols of identification and narratives for legiti- The discursive legitimation strategies employed by mizing the EU, and upholding, as well as repro- Juncker can thus be described as rather different ducing, a substantial conception of legitimacy of from those used by Barroso. Firstly, the frequency the Weberian kind described by Cerutti (2008) of symbols of the sub-categories ‘political commu- as based on collective identification and shared nity’ and ‘popular sovereignty’ as sources of legi- beliefs. timacy indicates a legitimation through authori- On the basis of these findings, we can thus high- zation in terms of (democratic) rules and proce- light a clear shift in the overall legitimizing stra- dures, where authority is understood in terms of tegies of the two Presidents. Whereas Barroso’s the classic repertoire of democratic legitimacy. speeches are designed to depoliticize conflicts The underlying conception of legitimacy that and reproduce the commonly held assumption of shapes Juncker’s discursive strategies thus seems to the EU as “a polity based on rationality and func- consist in an input-based understanding of legiti- tional interests, not emotional appeals” (Della Sala macy whereby citizens are not only the judges of, 2010: 2), Juncker’s speeches are ‘more political’ but also the prime actors in, the decision-making and characterized by ‘a marked assertiveness’ and process. ‘bold proposals’ (Dinan 2016: 103) associated with Secondly, the frequent reference to symbols stronger legitimacy claims. in the ‘values’ category, in particular the refe- rence to values pertaining to the ethical sphere 2. The study of the - almost absent in Barroso‘s speeches - high- Presidents‘ of the lights the presence of a strategy of legitimation Commission charismatic through moral evaluation, where actions and deci- language (2010-2017) sions are explained and justified by reference to a commonly shared set of values. Lastly, Juncker’s While the discursive legitimation strategies chosen speeches include also elements of legitimation by the Presidents (together with their speech- through mythopoesis, supported by the high rate of writers and presumably attesting the line of the symbols concerning the ‘common historical expe- Commission as a whole) in the particular occa- rience and memory’ (especially in the SOTEU sion of the State on the Union Addresses tell us 2015) and by the inclusion of actual mythopoetic part of the story of their attempts to have a public narratives. The following passage from Juncker’s political impact on national governments‘ and EU 2015 speech exemplifies this point: citizens‘ attitudes on the EU project as whole and Pushing back boats from piers, setting fire to refugee on the role of the Commission in particular, the camps, or turning a blind eye to poor and helpless assessment of the overall tone of the Presidents‘ people: that is not Europe. Europe is the baker in communication is fundamental in understan- Kos who gives away his bread to hungry and weary ding the styles of leadership that the Presidents souls. Europe is the students in Munich and in reclaim for themselves. In particular, in the inves- Passau who bring clothes for the new arrivals at the tigation of leadership styles, whether the language train station. That’s those at the Munich rail station used can be claimed to proximate an idealtype of applauding and welcoming refugees. The Europe I charismatic, politicized language, or whether it

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 205 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi should be deemed to consist in a neutral, descrip- The studies by Shamir have been the basis for a tive and technical language devoid of emotional number of empirical analyses of charismatic appeals, may allow to provide a fuller picture of leadership in times of crisis (e.g. Bligh et al. the leadership role that the President choses for 2004; Bligh & Hess 2007; Davis & Gardner 2012; himself, and accordingly, allows us to test, for Bastardoz et al. 2015). Recently, this theoretical one, whether the ‚more political‘ role that Juncker framework has also been applied to the case of claimed for himself is attested by the tone of his the euro crisis to study the charismatic rhetoric overall communication. and leadership of the President of the European While charisma, in the classical Weberian inter- Commission (Olsson and Hammargård 2016). pretation, consists in exceptional qualities of the The study of Olsson and Hammargård, which leader, which manifest themselves especially provides an analysis of all the speeches delivered in his/her action, language represents a funda- by Barroso between 2006 and 2011, offers some mental aspect of charisma, because only through unexpected result. In contrast with the common language the charismatic actor is able to attest and theoretical assumption of a positive effect of reclaim its leadership role. It is primarily through crises on charismatic leadership, they found that communication that charismatic leaders represent in the cases under investigation the language of themselves as such, and transmit their values and President Barroso became less charismatic in the vision to followers (Tucker 1968; Antonakis et al. periods of manifest exacerbation of the Eurozone 2011; 2016). crises. This finding is even more significant if read together with the study of Tortola and Pansardi Shamir, House and Arthur (Shamir et al. 1993; (2018), which, for the same period of time, attests 1994), have identified seven principal traits that an increase in the charismatic language of another distinguish charismatic language: central player in the dealing of the Eurozone crisis, 1. More references to collective history namely the President of the European Central and to the continuity between the past and Bank (at the time, Jean Claude Trichet). the present; 2.1 Methods and research design 2. More references to the collective and to collective identity, and fewer references While the manual coding of the SOTEU speeches to individual self-interest; allows for the investigation of the discursive legi- 3. More positive references to followers’ timation strategies used by the two Presidents, worth and efficacy as individuals and as a the study of the overall degree of charisma of the collective; Presidents‘ communication relies on a compu- 4. More references to the leader’s ter-assisted analysis of all speeches delivered similarity to followers and identification between 2010 and 2017. Accordingly, I conducted with followers; an analysis of the entire corpus of speeches from the inception the second Barroso Commission on 5. More references to values and moral 9th February 2010 to 31 December 2017.218 The justifications, and fewer references to corpus consists of 783 speeches, of which 709 deli- tangible outcomes and instrumental vered by President Barroso, and 74 by President justifications; Juncker. Considering that the time spans under 6. More references to distal goals and investigation for the two Presidents are not extre- the distant future, and fewer references to mely dissimilar - around four and half years for proximal goals and the near future; and President Barroso, and a little more than three

7. More references to hope and faith 218 Speeches were downloaded from the European (Shamir et al. 1994: 29). Commission Press Release Database: http://europa.eu/ rapid/search.htm

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 206 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi years for President Juncker -, the difference in the Relying on a well-established method (Bligh et al. number of speeches is quite surprising (please note 2004; Bligh & Robinson 2010; Davis & Gardner that a consistent number of speeches by Juncker 2012; Bastardoz et al. 2015; Olsson & Hammar- were excluded from this investigation - around 60 gård 2016; Tortola and Pansardi 2018), I have - because they were delivered in a language diffe- analyzed the corpus of speeches by combining rent from English, mostly in French or in a mix of DICTION variables into seven composite cons- French, German and English; yet, this exclusion tructs, building on the linguistic characteristics does not account for this extreme difference in of charisma listed in the previous section. Table number). 2 summarizes the seven constructs and the corre- To analyze the texts I have relied on the use of the sponding formulas of DICTION variables, along DICTION 7 software (Hart 2001). Created speci- with sample words for each variable. fically to analyze the tone of political discourse, in speeches and other types of texts, DICTION codes text on 31 pre-defined variables using in-built dictionaries and assigning scores reflecting the presence and weight of dictionary terms.

Table 2. The seven charismatic constructs and operationalization in DICTION 7 (Tortola and Pansardi 2018)

Construct DICTION 7 variables Sample terms Collective focus: charismatic leaders show a Collectives Assembly, cabinet, humanity, mankind, nation. collective orientation and describe their ac- + People references Crowd, residents, constituencies, majority, tions and goals as directed towards common citizenry, population achievements and interests. - Self-reference I, I’d, I’ll, I’m, I’ve, me, mine, my, myself, race, union Temporal orientation: charismatic leaders use Present concern Become, care, desire, make, need, request, take more temporal references and tend to highlight + Past concern Became, cared, desired, made, needed, re- continuity between the past and the present. quested, took, wanted want Follower’s worth: charismatic leaders high- Praise Admirable, brave, delightful, intelligent, kind, light the positive aspects of the followers and lovely, respected reinforce their sense of awareness vis-à-vis the + Inspiration Ambition, devotion, ideals, leadership, merit, achievement of collective goals (collective self- optimism, promise, reassurance efficacy). + Satisfaction Comfort, cherish, delight, fascinate, gratify, laugh, love, pleasure, rejoice Similarity to followers: charismatic leaders Levelling Anybody, everybody, fully, obvious, perma- highlight their own similarity to followers by nent, totally, unquestionably describing themselves as “one of them”. + Familiarity About, between, for, on, past, than, who, with + Human interest Children, family, friends, parents, relatives, widows, yours, charity, blessing, eternal, faith, hope, mercy Tangibility: charismatic leaders devote less at- Concreteness Animal, baseball, cancer, factory, household, tention to concrete and short terms goals, and movie, school, silk, sugar are more prone to discuss their expectations + Insistence Score calculated on the basis of repetition of and goals in abstract and general terms. key terms. - Variety Score calculated by dividing the number of dif- ferent words in a passage by the total words

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 207 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi Action; charismatic leaders use an action-ori- Aggression Attack, challenge, combat, dominate, furious, ented language in order to mobilize followers hurt, kill, oppose, preempt and describe themselves as “proactive”. + Accomplishment Achieve, aspire, create, fi nish, motivate, pur- suit, resolution, succeed - Passivity Accept, acquiesce, complacent, disinterested, hesitate, lackadaisical - Ambivalence Blur, confound, hesitate, puzzle, quandary, vacillate, wonder Adversity: charismatic leaders describe the situ- Blame Contemptible, desperate, guilty, incompetent, ation as intolerable with the aim of supporting mediocre, rash, senile the proposed alternative “visionary future” and + Hardship Confl ict, crisis, death, fear, insecurity, loss, moving to action. outrage, sorrow, tension + Denial Didn’t, hadn’t, never, wasn’t, wouldn’t

2.2 Findings Figure 2. Charisma indicator mean per year Th e next step in answering the research question about an increase in the ‚politicization‘ of Juncker‘s communication in compa- rison to Barroso‘s is to analyze the results obtained aft er running DICTION 7 on the whole corpus of the Presidents of the Commission speeches between 2010 and 2017. Th e charismatic constructs presented in Table 2 are aggregated in a single indicator of charismatic rhetoric, by subtracting the value of tangibility from the sum of the six remaining cons- tructs.219 Figure 2 presents a fi rst over- view of the charismatic content of the corpus under To assess the statistical signifi cance of a change exam by plotting the year-by-year mean value of in charismatic rhetoric, so as to establish whether the speeches’ aggregate indicator of charisma. A an actual variation occur between the rhetorical fi rst visual inspection is not very telling: while two styles of the two Presidents, I follow the litera- peaks can be immediately detected (a high peak in ture on charismatic rhetoric (e.g. Bligh et al. 2004; 2013 and a low peak in 2017), the remaining years Bligh et al. 2010; Davis & Gardner 2012; Schroedel under investigation present a degree of charisma et al. 2013; Olsson & Hammargård 2016, Tortola of the Presidents‘ speeches that seems overall cons- and Pansardi 2018), and rely on a multivariate tant, and accordingly not aff ected by the change in analyses of co-variance (MANCOVA), a technique the occupant of the presidency. Overall, however, for testing the signifi cance of mean diff erences in a this fi rst investigation does not seem to depict the dependent variable of interest (in our case charis- increase in charismatic rhetoric with the passage matic language) across samples, while also cont- from Barroso to Juncker that we were expecting in rolling for a number of factors (covariates) that light of Juncker‘s own assumption of a ‚more poli- might be related to that variable. In the absence of tical‘ interpretation of his role as President of the statistical signifi cance, the null hypothesis that the Commission, nor to replicate the fi ndings of the underlying populations are the same, and that any qualitative analysis of the SOTEU speeches. increase is due to sheer chance, cannot be safely 219 The aggregation formula follows Bligh et al. discarded. (2004: 225).

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 208 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi I accordingly run a one-way multivariate analysis The multivariate test, as a result, does not allow us of covariance (MANCOVA) comparing the to obtain straightforward answer to the question measure of the speeches seven charismatic cons- of which of the two Presidents make use of a more tructs taken individually (the dependent vari- charismatic rhetoric. Nonetheless, if we take into ables) for the two Presidents (the independent account only the statistically significant results, we variable), including the total number of words in should consider that, in contrasts to our expecta- each speech as a covariate, to control for speech tions, the tone of Juncker‘s speeches appear to be length. The multivariate test shows a significant less charismatic than the one found in the spee- difference between the two Presidents‘ overall ches by Barroso, leaving us with a finding that charismatic rhetoric: Wilks’s Lambda = 0.941, F goes against the results obtained by performing (7, 774) = 6.976, p < 0.001. However, the direc- the qualitative analysis of the SOTEU speeches. tion of the difference - namely, which President scores the best in terms of overall charisma - is 3. Discussion and conclusion more difficult to assess. As Table 3 shows, the test determined that four out of the seven cons- By relying on the qualitative analysis of the SOTEU tructs present statistically significant differences speeches reported in the first part of this paper, for the two Presidents: Followers’ worth, Similarity we can highlight a radical change in the two Presi- to followers, Action and Adversity. However, while dents‘ interpretation of their role as key actors in President Barroso scores higher on the first three the promotion and support of the project of Euro- variables, Juncker scores higher on the last one, pean integration. On the specific occasion of the namely Adversity. Moreover, if we look at the other delivery of the SOTEU speech, the two Presidents variables that do not show a statistically significant did not only rely on extremely different strategies variation, we see that Juncker scores higher (and for top-down legitimation, but also adopted diffe- lower, in the case of Tangibility, which is expected rent vision of the nature of the legitimacy of the to decrease to attest charismatic rhetoric) in two EU. The growing attention reserved by the Euro- out of three. pean community to the SOTEU speeches may have the result of rendering these speeches the Table 3. The charismatic rhetoric of the two paramount opportunity for expressing rhetorical Presidents. Results by single construct strategy, charisma, and vision, and accordingly, to Barroso Standard Juncker Standard Univariate Sign. Partial eta concentrate the rhetorical MEAN error MEAN error F (1, 780) squared efforts of the President in Collective 1.015 .223 1.484 .835 .245ns .621 .000 that particular event. Focus A possible explanation of Temporal 13.614 .181 12.540 .532 3.224ns .073 .004 the differences between Orientation Barroso‘s and Juncker‘s Follower’s 22.759 .322 17.571 1.076 19.708*** .000 .025 SOTEU speeches may Worth come from taking seri- Similarity to 163.626 .763 157.291 1.871 7.324** .007 .009 Followers ously into account the Tangibility 95.145 2.133 89.455 6.745 .215 .643 .000 role of the Spitzencadi- daten system in changing Action 5.126 .330 0.705 1.391 13.522*** .000 .017 the President‘s perspec- Adversity 6.690 .167 8.461 .616 5.950* .015 .008 tive about the legitimacy Notes: Barroso N = 709; Juncker N = 74. *p < 0.05; **p < and nature of his/her own mandate. If, on the 0.01; ***p < 0.001; ns = non-signficant value. one hand, the content and the discursive strate- gies employed in the speeches highlight the role

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 209 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi of agency in attesting Juncker’s willingness to on his new appointment procedure, Juncker has present himself and communicate as a ‘more poli- been able to include in his speeches discursive tical’ President than Barroso – the latter being strategies directed at the legitimation of his own often criticized for a lack of political assertive- role and of the EU’s policy proposals in terms of ness (Dinan 2016: 102) – on the other hand, the democratic authorization, thus offering an overall differences in the communication style of the two interpretation of the EU’s legitimacy in terms of Presidents may be interpreted as also related to input. Moreover, in light of his stronger leader- changes in the political and institutional context. ship, Juncker has been able to reinforce his legiti- While agency is certainly central in the selection macy claims by including discursive strategies of of the discursive strategies, Pansardi and Battegaz- top-down legitimation through moral evaluation zorre (2018) highlight how the introduction of the and mythopoesis, overall contributing to an inter- Spitzencandidaten system has been fundamental pretation of the EU as a ‘community of values’ in in providing the two Presidents with a different terms of a substantial, Weberian, conception of discursive opportunity structure. the legitimacy of the EU (Pansardi and Battegaz- Firstly, the different procedure of appointment zorre 2018). has undoubtedly endowed the two Presidents However, the quantitative analysis of the tone of with a different symbolic repertoire. As sugge- the language of the two Presidents depicts a quite sted by Christiansen, the introduction of the Spit- different picture. Not only the tone of Juncker‘s zencandidaten procedure “provided a powerful speeches is not more charismatic then the one symbolic change” (2016: 993) – that may also found in Barroso, but can - with a few precau- be interpreted, following Gronau and Schmidke tions - be described as overall less charismatic. (2016), as an institutional strategy for legitima- This accounts for two possible explanations. A tion – in the nature of the Presidency. While the first explanation may assume the peculiar nature appointment of Barroso and his predecessors was of the State of the Union Addresses as the reason the result of intergovernmental negotiations and why Juncker concentrates his efforts - in terms of merely ‘approved’ by the European Parliament, rhetorical language and top-down discursive legi- the new appointment procedure allows Juncker to timation - on these specific speeches. To support claim a sort of electoral mandate, and, as a conse- this explanation, there is also the great and unex- quence, offers him the opportunity to resort more pected difference in the overall number of speeches directly to the symbolic repertoire of democratic of the two Presidents in the period under scru- legitimacy. Secondly, the nature itself of the Spit- tiny. Overall, it may appear that Juncker prefers zencandidaten system has allowed Juncker to to contract the number of occasions in which he claim a sort personal mandate (Kassim 2017; see openly speaks to the public, and - with the exclu- also Dinan 2016), offering him the opportunity to sion of the SOTEU - to reserve his open commu- claim more legitimacy for his role and enabling a nication to more ‚coordinative‘ and less ‚commu- stronger leadership. As Christiansen points out: nicative‘ speeches. A second, not alternative expla- “The President of the Commission, less encum- nation, refers to the new opportunity structure bered than his predecessor by the need for support offered by the institution of the Spitzencaditaten and approval from the majority of member states, system: differently from Barroso, Junckers‘ may has been able to assume a leadership role unseen not see the need to negotiate the legitimacy of its since the days of Jacques Delors” (2016: 1007). own role in each single occasion, and accordingly, Accordingly, the new opportunity structure not only ‚speaks less‘, but when he does, he goes to created by the introduction of the Spitzencan- the heart of the matter in a more ‚direct‘ and less didaten system has allowed Juncker to shape his ‚emotional‘ language. discursive strategies in a way just precluded to his predecessor. ‘Building’ (Dinan 2016: 103)

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 210 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi With regard to the overall research question guiding this analysis, we have to conclude that, at least in terms of the analysis of language and communication, we cannot describe Juncker as ‚more political‘ than Barroso. Rather, we should see their use of language as strongly affected by the institutional changes introduced with the Spit- zencaditaten system which also affects the way in which language is politicized.

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 211 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi References 992-1010. Della Sala, V. 2010. Political Myth, Mythology Antonakis, J., N. Bastardoz, P. Jacquart & B. and the European Union. Journal of Common Shamir (2016). Charisma: An ill-defined and Market Studies 48(1): 1-19. ill-measured gift. Annual Review of Organiza- tional Psychology and Organizational Behavior Dinan, D. 2016. Governance and Institutions: 3: 293-319. A More Political Commission. Journal of Common Market Studies 54 (Annual Review): Bauer, M.W. and Becker, S. 2016. Absolute Gains 101–116. are Still Gains: Why the European Commission is a Winner of the Crisis, and Unexpectedly So. Fabbrini S. 2015. Which European Union? Europe A rejoinder to Eugénia da Conceição-Heldt. after the Euro Crisis. Cambridge: Cambridge Journal of European Integration, 38(1): 101–6. University Press. Bligh, M. C., J.C. Kohles & J.R. Meindl (2004). Gronau J., Schmidtke H. 2016. The quest for legi- Charisma under crisis: Presidential leader- timacy in world politics – international institu- ship, rhetoric, and media responses before and tions’ legitimation strategies. Review of Interna- after the September 11th terrorist attacks. The tional Studies 42 (3): 535-557. Leadership Quarterly 15(2): 211-39. Hansen, L., Williams, M.C.. 1999. The Myths Bligh, M. C. & G. D. Hess (2007). The power of of Europe: Legitimacy, Community and the leading subtly: Alan Greenspan, rhetorical “Crisis” of the EU. Journal of Common Market leadership, and monetary policy. The Leader- Studies 37(2): 233–249. ship Quarterly 18(2): 87-104. Hart, R. P. (2001). Redeveloping DICTION: Theo- Bligh, M., J. Merolla, J.R. Schroedel, and R. retical Considerations. In M. West (ed.) Theory, Gonzalez (2010). Finding her voice: Hillary Method and Practice of Computer Content Clinton’s rhetoric in the 2008 presidential Analysis. New York: Ablex. campaign. Women’s Studies 39(8): 823–50. Hurrelman A. 2016. Empirical legitimation Bligh, M. C. & J. L. Robinson (2010). Was Gandhi analysis in International Relations: How to “charismatic”? Exploring the rhetorical leader- learn from the insights – and avoid the mistakes ship of Mahatma Gandhi. The Leadership Quar- – of research in EU Studies. Contemporary Poli- terly 21(5): 844-55. tics (forthcoming). Börzel T. 2016. From EU Governance of Crisis to Kassim H. 2017. What’s new? A first appraisal of Crisis in EU Governance. Regulatory Failure, the Juncker Commission. European Political Redistributive Conflict, and Eurosceptic Science 16 (1): 14–33. Publics. Journal of Common Market Studies. 54 Kassim, H., Connolly, S., Dehousse, R., Rozenberg, (S1): 8-23. O., Benjaballah, S. 2017. Managing the house: Cerutti F. 2008. Why political identity and legiti- The Presidency, agenda control and policy acti- macy matter in the European Union. In Cerutti vism in the European Commission. Journal of F. and S. Lucarelli (eds), The Search for a Euro- European Public Policy 24 (5): 653-674. pean Identity: Values, Policies and Legitimacy of Mayring, P. (2014) Qualitative content analysis. the European Union. London: Routledge. Theoretical foundation, basic procedures and Christiansen, T. (2016). After the Spitzenkandi- software solution. Social Science Open Access daten - Fundamental Change in the EU‘s Poli- Repository SSOAR, URN: http://nbn-resol- tical System? West European Politics, 39(5), ving.de/urn:nbn:de:0168-ssoar-395173 .

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 212 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi Oakes G. 2003. Max Weber on Value Rationality ration 39(2): 207-21. and Value Spheres. Journal of Classical Socio- Vaara, E. 2014. Struggles over legitimacy in the logy 3(1): 27–45. Eurozone crisis: Discursive legitimation stra- Olsson E., Hammargård K. 2016. The Rethoric of tegies and their ideological underpinnings. the President of the European Commission: Discourse & Society 25(4) 500–518. charismatic leader of neutral mediator?. Journal Van Leeuwen, T. 2007. Legitimation in discourse of European Public Policy 23(4): 550-570. and communication. Discourse and Communi- Pansardi P., Battegazzorre F. 2018. The discur- cation 1(1): 83-118. sive legitimation strategies of the President of Weber, M. 1949a. “Objectivity” in Social Science the Commission: a qualitative content analysis and Social Policy. In Shils E.A. and Finch H.A. of the State of the Union Addresses (SOTEU), (eds). The Methodology of the Social Sciences. Journal of European Integration (First published New York: Free Press. online: doi.org/10.1080/07036337.2018.148228 6). Reyes, A. 2011. Strategies of legitimation in poli- tical discourse: From words to action. Discourse and Society 22(6): 781-807. Shamir, B., M. B. Arthur & R. J. House (1994). The rhetoric of charismatic leadership: A theore- tical extension, a case study, and implications for research. The Leadership Quarterly 5(1): 25-42. Shamir, B., R. J. House & M. B. Arthur (1993). The motivational effects of charismatic leader- ship: A self-concept based theory. Organization Science 4(4): 577-94. Schmidt, V.A. 2013. Democracy and Legitimacy in the European Union Revisited: Input, Output and “Throughput”. Political Studies 61(1): 2–22. Theiler, T. 2005. Political Symbolism and European Integration. Manchester: Manchester Univer- sity Press. Tortola P.D., Pansardi P. 2018. The charismatic leadership of the European Central Bank presi- dency. A language-based analysis, European Journal of Political Research (First published online: doi/10.1111/1475-6765.12272). Tucker, R. C. 1968. The theory of charismatic leadership. Daedalus: 731-56. Verdun, A. 2017. Political leadership of the Euro- pean Central Bank. Journal of European Integ-

A ‘MORE POLITICAL’ LEADERSHIP FOR THE PRESIDENT OF THE COMMISSION? 213 A MIXED-METHODS LANGUAGE-BASED ANALYSIS Pamela Pansardi E THE DEMISE OF LAW THE EU AS “HONEST debates about alternatives – as the bureaucratic BROKER”? and technocratic conception of the EU Commis- sion still inhibits debate about political alterna- GERMAN AND ITALIAN tives. PERSPECTIVES ON AN ADMINSTRATIVE BODY 1. Historical origins of the Commission Anna Katharina Mangold220* Goethe University, Frankfurt am Main When the British considered joining the Euro- pean Community of Coal and Steel (ECSC) that From its very beginning in the European Commu- French Foreign Minister Robert Schumann had nity of Coal and Steel (ECSC), the leading organ suggested be built among European nation states, of European integration, that was later to become Prime Minister Clement Attlee explained on the the EU Commission, was designed as a merely 27 June 1950 in the House of Commons: bureaucratic, a-political agency, and an “honest “We on this side are not prepared to accept broker” between the Member States. From these the principle that the most vital economic early days, this has been a blunt lie about the nature forces of this country should be handed over and inner workings of the then High Authority of to an authority that is utterly undemocratic the ECSC and later the European Commission. In and is responsible to nobody.” 221 this paper, I argue, that nothing has changed very much over time. In fact, I argue that we need to a. The High Authority of the ECSC get rid of the understanding that there is such a thing as a “neutral”, “merely bureaucratic”, Euro- It is surely true that the High Authority of the pean Commission. ECSC can be considered the truly supranational Two recent scandals surrounding the Juncker element of the first Treaty on European Integra- Commission may shed some light on the current tion – the very term “supranational” was intro- state of affairs in the EU Commission: the promo- duced to describe both the functioning of the tion of Martin Selmayr as Secretary-General of High Authority and the competences of its the Commission, and the interview of Commis- sioner Günter Oettinger on the Italian elections. Drawing on these two recent scandals within the EU Commission, I try to show how a more polit- ical understanding of the role of the EU Commis- sion could help to bring about a more nuanced and politicised vision of European integration. Such a vision is necessary to make room for political

220* This paper is part of an ongoing project trying to trace 221 Prime Minister Clement Attlee replying to MP Winston the origins of current understandings and theoretical con- Churchill in a debate about the Schumann plan, Hansard, 27 ceptualisations of the organs and institutions of the European June 1950, p. 2169 (Italics added), available at: https://api.par- Union. In a previous paper, I looked into the exclusive right to liament.uk/historic-hansard/commons/1950/jun/27/schuman- initiate legislation conferred upon the EU Commission which plan-1 . The British had intentionally been left out of this plan the European Court of Justice has turned into a veritable veto from the very beginning, as can be gathered from the fact that position in the informal Trilogue legislative mechanism. I now the British Foreign Minister, Ernest Bevin, was only informed want to trace the historical origins of the Commission as an about Schumann’s proposition on the morning of the very institution of the EU and its theoretical conception in the Trea- same day that Schumann anounced his plan; see, with further ties, in political life, and in European Studies. I am very grate- references, A.K Mangold, Gemeinschaftsrecht und deutsches ful for all suggestions and hints ([email protected]. Recht, (Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck, 2011), p. 35 fn. 14. de).

THE EU AS “HONEST BROKER”? GERMAN AND ITALIAN PERSPECTIVES ON AN ADMINSTRATIVE BODY 215 Anna Katharina Mangold members.222 Jean Monnet famously envisaged the competences. Historical research has again the High Authority as a technocratic administra- and again shown how especially the legal service tion free from parliamentary and political over- of the Commission was the driving force behind sight, and, indeed, any control whatsoever.223 the ECJ’s seminal decisions of the 1960s225 and Thus, Attlee was certainly right in stating that the also the 1970s.226 The ECJ could only perform High Authority was not in any traditional under- its activist role in European integration because standing of the term “democratically” elected or it could rely on the Commission to provide well responsible. prepared cases, and in fact test cases that were laboriously drafted to bring about jurisprudence b. The Commission of the EEC that would allow for enhancing the competences of the Commission.227 The Commission of the European Economic Despite Attlee’s complaints about the ECSC Community (EEC) partly was less powerful than High Authority, no major changes took place in the High Authority of the ECSC in that the Treaty the conception of the Commission in the EEC. of Rome was much broader in its wording and The Commission’s composition228 and account- conferred less precisely defined competences ability229 were not very convincing when pitched to the newly established Commission. Partly, against the powers of this institution. The worries however, the Commission became much more deepened over time as the Commission took an powerful because the Treaty of Rome comprised activist and teleological approach to interpreting everything “economic”. Over time, the Commis- its own competences, which the ECJ backed in sion interpreted the term “economic” in a very nearly all cases.230 broad sense so that it came to encompass liter- ally everything from cultural performances to In the case of the Commission, the “law in the the disposal of waste, from radio broadcasting to books” and the “law in action”231 never added the protection of the environment. This approach 225 A. Boerger-de Smedt and M. Rasmussen, “The Mak- was to some extent foreseen and envisaged in ing of European Law: Exploring the Life and Work of Michel 224 the Treaty itself. The progressive narrative was Gaudet”, (2017) 57 American Journal of Legal History, pp. 51- bound to lead to a teleological understanding of 82. 226 Unpublished paper by Bill Davies and Walter Much 222 Art. 9 paras. 5 and 6 TECSC (1951): “(5) The members presented at the conference of the Max-Planck-Institute for of the High Authority shall exercise their functions in com- Legal History Frankfurt/Main “Key Biographies in the Legal plete independence, in the general interest of the Community. History of European Union, 1950-1993”, 21-22 June 2018 (on In the performance of their duties, they shall neither seek nor file with the author). take instructions from any Government or from any other 227 1960s: It has been argued that van Gend en Loos was body. They shall refrain from any action incompatible with the in fact a test case. 1970s/1980s: The Defrenne litigation both supranational character of their functions. gave Art. 157 TEEC (equal pay for men and women) a new (6) Each Member State undertakes to respect this supranational and much broader meaning, thus bringing this dorment Treaty character and not to seek to influence the members of the High provision to life, and provided a new policy field to the Com- Authority in the performance of their tasks.” (Italics added.) mission, namely establishing non-discrimination in labour 223 A. Boerger-de Smedt, “La Cour de Justice dans les relations which in eventually would lead to the far reaching négociations du traité de Paris instituant le CECA”, (2008) antidiscrimination directives of the early 2000s. 12 Journal of European Integration History, pp. 7-33 (passim, 228 Art. 158 TEEC: appointment by the Member States. expressly p. 12). 229 Art. 160 TEEC: removal of Commissioners from office. 224 Art. 2 TEEC (1957): “It shall be the aim of the Com- munity, by establishing a Common Market and progressively 230 The notorious exception was the Tobacco advertise- approximating the economic policies of Member States, to pro- ment directive which, in its first version, was not upheld by mote throughout the Community a harmonious development the ECJ, C-376/98, 5 October 2000, and was accepted only in of economic activities, a continuous and balanced expansion, the second attempt by the Court, ECJ, C-380/03, 12 December an increased stability, an accelerated raising of the standard of 2006. living and closer relations between its Member States.” (Italics 231 R. Pound, “Law in Books and Law in Action”, (1910) 44 added.) American Law Review, pp. 12-36.

THE EU AS “HONEST BROKER”? GERMAN AND ITALIAN PERSPECTIVES ON AN ADMINSTRATIVE BODY 216 Anna Katharina Mangold up. Room for charismatic leadership existed, and 2. The Promotion of Martin it was filled in a memorable way by the famous Selmayr as Secretary-General “Delors Commission” in the 1980s.232 of the EU Commission: Independence from c. The Commission of the EU Parliamentary Oversight

The same is still true for the Commission of the The first scandal surrounds the promotion of Lisbon Treaty. Article 17 TEU is a lengthy article Martin Selmayr from Chief of Staff to the Presi- which tells law students little about the actual dent of the European Commission, Jean-Claude workings of the EU Commission. The number Juncker, to the position of Secretary-General of Commissioners has not been decreased as of the European Commission, the most senior foreseen in Article 17 para. 4 TEU because the civil servant position in the Commission, and, Member States decided to maintain their respec- 233 basically, the right hand of the President of the tive “national” Commissioner. The composition Commission.235 in itself seems paradoxical: according to Article 17 para. 3 TEU, the Commission’s term of office is As is well known by now, in a meeting of the five years and has, thereby, adjusted to the legisla- EU Commission in early February 2018, Martin tive term of the European Parliament (EP). None- Selmayr was first promoted to the position of Vice theless, it is not the EP which has the decisive say Secretary-General of the Commission. In the same in the composition of the Commission, but the meeting, the then Secretary-General resigned, to European Council, even though Article 17 para. the surprise of everybody except Juncker, who 7 TEU requires that it take “into account the elec- had known that he wanted to resign for some tions to the European Parliament”. time. Selmayr was appointed Secretary-General. A pro forma alternative candidate, later to become The ensuing “Spitzenkandidaten” or “Lead/Top 234 Juncker’s Chief of Cabinet, withdrew her candida- Candidates” process was hotly debated in 2014 ture. Hence, Selmayr was promoted twice within and is far from established as the guiding political just nine minutes.236 principle for the selection of the President of the Commission following the elections to the Euro- Criticism followed suit. Juncker remained adamant pean Parliament next year (2019). and even threatened high-ranking members of his own party, the conservative EPP, with his resigna- tion if Selmayr was forced to step down.237 Criti- cism was directed both at the opaque procedure and at the fact that yet another German is now holding a top position in the EU bureaucracy.

235 The history of this position shows that the relationsship 232 See, e.g., White Paper “Completing the Internal Mar- between Commission Presidents and secretary-generals was ket”, COM(85)310, Brussels, June 1985. always politically important. Émile Noël and Walter Hallstein 233 European Council Decision 2013/272/EU of 22 May had a very trusting relationship. Noël served as secretary-gen- 2013 concerning the number of members of the European eral from 1957 until 1987. Jacques Delors replaced him with Commission, OJ L 165, 18.6.2013, p. 98. the British David Williamson and in doing so tried to involve a possible antagonist in his far reaching project for the Commis- 234 See, for example, the debate on Verfassungsblog in sion. April 2014, available at: https://verfassungsblog.de/category/ debates/spitzenkandidaten-fuer-die-europawahl, and later in 236 http://www.deutschlandfunk.de/europaparlament- June 2014 between Matthias Kumm (https://verfassungsblog. milde-resolution-zum-fall-selmayr.1773.de.html?dram:article_ de/der-europaeische-rat-ist-verpflichtet-juncker-vorzuschla- id=415846. gen) and Kenneth Armstrong (https://verfassungsblog.de/ 237 https://www.politico.eu/article/martin-selmayr-juncker- european-council-legal-duty-appoint-jean-claude-juncker). goes-i-go/.

THE EU AS “HONEST BROKER”? GERMAN AND ITALIAN PERSPECTIVES ON AN ADMINSTRATIVE BODY 217 Anna Katharina Mangold There are many questions to be asked about this albeit informally.242 particular promotion, and indeed the EP asked 238 Implicitly, the idea of national belonging appar- several, 134 to be precise. However, in the end, ently has a strong foothold in the conception of the EP could only mildly admonish the Commis- both parts of the Commission, the College of sion for the intransparency of the whole proce- 239 Commissioners and the Commission bureau- dure. This partly has to do with the still flawed cracy. If Jürgen Habermas argues, for the demo- wording of the Treaty on the European Union. cratic setting, that the EU bridges Union citizen- Article 17 para. 8 TEU only enables the EP to ask ship, on the one hand, and Member State citizen- for the resignation of the Commission “as a body”. ship, on the other,243 this may well be criticised The EU Ombuds”man”, Emily O’Reilly, re-elected for being overly optimistic and in need of being for five years in December 2014, will look further legal implementation.244 For the organisation of into the affair.240 Franklin Dehousse, former Justice the EU Commission, Member State citizenship is, at the CJEU, predicts that this scandal will haunt apparently, still the decisive factor. As long as this both the Commission and the EU as a whole for remains the case, the Commission will not become months, and possibly years, to come.241 a politically independent “government of the EU”. If we were to consider the position of Secretary- General just as an ordinary civil servant posi- 3. The Interview of tion, then, of course, the procedure employed in Commissioner Oettinger on promoting Martin Selmayr warrants heavy criti- the Italian elections: cism: for the lack of transparency, the missing Italy as Periphery? advertisement of the position, and the ensuing low number of (alleged) candidates. However, if we In an interview on the 29 May 2018 with Deutsche think of the Secretary-General as a clearly polit- Welle, Budget Commissioner Günter Oettinger ical position, it becomes self-evident why Juncker was asked about the outcome of the Italian elec- would want a loyal follower in this key position. tions of March 2018. The Interview took place at a time, in May, when Italy was still without a However, the appointment procedures put government because of the outcome of the elec- Member State interests centre stage, not the polit- tion. Oettinger said the following:245 ical allegiances of the College of Commissioners, which is not a government cabinet in the tradi- “It is my worry and expectation that the tional sense of a national government organisa- next weeks will show that the markets, that tion; rather, Commissioners are chosen according the government bonds, that the economic to Member State preferences. development of Italy could be so radical that this possibly turns into a signal for The same is true for positions in the Commission voters not to vote for left and right populists. bureaucracy, even – and maybe especially – for 242 U. Haltern, Europarecht I, 3rd ed. 2017, p. 222 marg. high-ranking positions. National quotas still play no.479. a decisive role in the promotion of civil servants, 243 J. Habermas, Zur Verfassung Europas: Ein Essay, (Ber- 238 https://www.tagesschau.de/ausland/selmayr-eu-parla- lin: Suhrkamp Verlag, 2011), pp. 86 et seq. ment-101.html. 244 A.K. Mangold, “Democratic Legitimacy of EU Law. 239 http://www.europarl.europa.eu/committees/en/cont/ Two Proposals to Strengthen Democracy in the European Union”, in: Johan van der Walt and Jeffrey Ellsworth (eds), subject-files.html?id=20180326CDT02181. Constitutional Sovereignty and Social Solidarity in Europe, 240 https://www.politico.eu/article/eu-watchdog-ombuds- (Baden-Baden-London: Nomos-Bloomsbury, 2015), pp. 165- man-emily-oreilly-confirms-martin-selmayr-promotion- 192. probe/. 245 In my account of the events, I follow a report of 241 https://verfassungsblog.de/european-council-legal- Tagesschau, available at: https://www.tagesschau.de/ausland/ duty-appoint-jean-claude-juncker/. oettinger-italien-wirbel-101.html.

THE EU AS “HONEST BROKER”? GERMAN AND ITALIAN PERSPECTIVES ON AN ADMINSTRATIVE BODY 218 Anna Katharina Mangold … Even now, developments on bond fate does not lie in the hands of the financial market, the market value of banks, and markets. Regardless of which political Italy’s economy in general have darkened party may be in power, Italy is a founding noticeably and negatively. This has to do member of the European Union that with the possible government formation. I has contributed immensely to European can only hope that this will play a role in integration. President Juncker is convinced the election campaign and send a signal that Italy will continue on its European not to hand populists on the right and left path. The Commission is ready to work any responsibility in government.”246 with Italy with responsibility and mutual 249 The interviewing journalist of , respect. Italy deserves respect.” Bernd Riegert, captured this in a short Tweet, Interestingly and maybe surprisingly, later that which read: same week, in a Q & A Session in Brussels on 31 “The markets will teach the Italians to vote May 2018, Juncker was cited by : for the right thing”, #EU commissioner “Italians have to take care of the poor #Oettinger told me [….].”247 regions of Italy. That means more work; 250 The now Italian Minister of Economic Develop- less corruption; seriousness.” ment and Labour, Luigi Di Maio, responded on These events, I argue, show that, even though Twitter that Oettinger’s allegations were “absurd” Italy and Germany were founding members of the and continued: ECSC, they are no longer on equal footing when it “These people treat Italy as a summer camp comes to their current position both in the EU and where they can spend their holidays.”248 vis-à-vis the EU Commission. Rather, these events highlight a perception in the Commission of the Swiftly, on the very same day, the President of the relationship between Germany and Italy as one of EU Commission, Jean-Claude Juncker, issued a “centre and periphery” where Germany is a centre statement implicitly castigating Oettinger for his state and Italy a mere peripheral state. It is, I hold, interview remarks: not coincidental that the German Commissioner “The President of the European Oettinger was the one to state bluntly what can be Commission, Jean-Claude Juncker, wishes taken to be a general sentiment in the Commission to put on record his conviction that Italy’s when it comes to Italy.251 In the Commission, there 246 English translation at https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/ seems to be an understanding that there are more Günther_Oettinger#Intervention_in_Italian_politics. In the important and less important Member States. This original German: “Meine Sorge und meine Erwartung ist, calls into question whether the Commission can dass die nächsten Wochen zeigen, dass die Märkte, dass die really play the role of an “honest broker” between Staatsanleihen, dass die wirtschaftliche Entwicklung Italiens so einschneidend sein könnten, dass dies für die Wähler doch ein competing Member States among themselves, and mögliches Signal ist, nicht Populisten von links und rechts zu between Member States and the EU. Again, a truly wählen. … Schon jetzt ist die Entwicklung bei den Staatsan- political institution could take political positions leihen, bei dem Marktwert der Banken, beim wirtschaftlichen Verlauf Italiens generell deutlich eingetrübt, negativ. Dies hat openly if the Commission were to be democrati- mit der möglichen Regierungsbildung zu tun. Ich kann nur cally elected and accountable. hoffen, dass dies im Wahlkampf eine Rolle spielt, im Sinne eines Signals, Populisten von links und rechts nicht in die 249 http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_STATE- Regierungsverantwortung zu bringen.” MENT-18-3982_en.htm. 247 The tweet of 29 May 2018 has since been deleted. 250 https://www.theguardian.com/world/2018/may/31/ However, it is still depicted as a screen shot in several tweets, italy-cancelled-league-rallies-signal-political-impasse-may- most notably in one of the now Italian Interior Minister soon-end. Matteo Salvini: https://twitter.com/matteosalvinimi/sta- 251 The former Justice at the CJEU rather cruelly charac- tus/1001437881880272896. terised Oettinger thus: “Oettinger’s explanations are generally 248 My translation. In the original Italian: “Questa dumb and contradictory, but occasionally honest.” https:// gente tratta l’Italia come una colonia estiva dove venire a pas- verfassungsblog.de/selmayrs-appointment-why-this-juncker- sare le vacanze”, available at: https://twitter.com/luigidimaio/ crisis-is-much-more-dangerous-for-the-eu-commission-than- status/1001474208269045760. the-santer-crisis-in-1999.

THE EU AS “HONEST BROKER”? GERMAN AND ITALIAN PERSPECTIVES ON AN ADMINSTRATIVE BODY 219 Anna Katharina Mangold INTEGRATION-THROUGH- able institutions. In the absence of opportunities CRISIS AS A DISTINCT for open contestation, EU emergency governance oscillates between moments of heightened politi- INTEGRATIVE MODE: cisation, in which ad hoc decisions are justified as PLACING EXPEDIENCY AHEAD necessary, and the (sometimes coercive) appeal to OF DEMOCRACY? the depoliticised rule of rules.

Nicole Scicluna Introduction The University of Hong Kong One of the many consequences of the euro crisis, which began in 2010, has been the politicisation Abstract of policy areas and decision making processes in which most Europeans previously had little Integration-through-crisis has affected EMU interest - including the decisions and policies of governance in myriad ways. This paper focuses the European Central Bank (ECB). However, on two trends, both of which have negative impli- it has not lead to any meaningful democratisa- cations for democratic legitimacy in the EU and tion of monetary policy making, nor of any other its member states. Firstly, the crisis has led to an aspect of the crisis response. On the contrary, the increased reliance on non-majoritarian modes of regulatory space in which the ECB operates has policy-making, at the expense of democratically expanded during the crisis years. This expansion accountable institutions and processes. Secondly, was driven by the Bank itself, which, for a variety the crisis has led to a new emphasis on coercive of reasons, seized the initiative at the height of the enforcement in EMU, at the expense of the volun- crisis, including by taking decisions that have rede- tary cooperation that previously characterised fined what constitutes a monetary policy measure. (and sustained) the EU as a community of law. Moreover, the euro crisis has revealed deficien- The ECB is implicated in both of these trends. In cies and pathologies in EU governance that go far relation to the first, while the ECB was already beyond the intricacies of monetary policy making. unusually independent - even by the standards In short, I argue that the EU has moved from a of central banks - this could be justified, prior to mode of governance centred on law as agent and the crisis, by the specificity, technicality and low object (integration-through-law, ITL), to one salience of its monetary policy mandate. However, predicated on expediency (integration-through- the crisis has resulted in both the politicisation of crisis, ITC). I use the ECB as a point of depar- the Bank’s mandate and its de facto expansion, in ture to illustrate that transformation. How and ways that render its insulation from democratic why did a highly independent, deliberately-insu- politics highly problematic. Indeed, it is made all lated and narrowly-mandated body become such the more problematic by the ECB’s involvement in a powerful political actor? The answers reveal the second trend; the coercive turn in EMU gover- shortcomings in the EU’s institutional architec- nance. In this connection, the ECB, in its role as ture and political culture. The former include the provider of liquidity to eurozone banks, has been difficulty of formally amending the EU’s trea- instrumental in pushing debtor states towards ties, and the incomplete construction of EMU as acceptance of harsh austerity policies. a monetary union without a fiscal counterpart. Thus, the ECB’s (over-)empowerment may be These, in turn, hint at the latter: National and viewed as a synecdoche of a wider problem: The EU leaders are reluctant to attempt treaty reform EU’s tendency to resort to technocratic gover- because doing so would require referendums nance in the face of challenges that require political in at least some member states, the outcomes of contestation mediated by democratically account- which would be highly uncertain. Similarly, there

INTEGRATION-THROUGH-CRISIS AS A DISTINCT INTEGRATIVE MODE: PLACING EXPEDIENCY AHEAD OF DEMOCRACY? 220 Nicole Scicluna are major disagreements among national govern- dissemination of EC/EU legal norms. The Court ments about how best to proceed - e.g. on whether of Justice created the legal framework for this the eurozone ought to have its own budgetary dissemination through its groundbreaking artic- resources, or on the creation of a eurozone finance ulation of the principles of direct effect and EC minister. legal supremacy in the 1960s. Combined with The paper is organised as follows. The first section the preliminary reference procedure, direct effect discusses ITC as a distinct integrative mode, and legal supremacy enabled the CJEU to issue contrasting it with ITL. In the second section, I binding treaty interpretations, the normative continue the elaboration of ITC via a focus on force of which was amplified by the fact that they the role of the ECB as a regulatory body that is were incorporated into the judgements of national both very powerful and highly insulated from courts in cases brought directly by member state majoritarian democracy. In particular, the ECB nationals. It is in this way that the EU’s founding has come to symbolise two key characteristics treaties were constitutionalised (Weiler 1994). of ITC: Firstly, the exacerbation of the EU’s pre- ITL’s crucial insight concerned the dual nature of existing tendency to concentrate power in the law in the then-EC: Law was both object and agent hands of executives and non-majoritarian bodies. of integration (Cappelletti et al. 1986). In other Secondly, the belated and misguided turn to coer- words, ITL conceptualised a project of integration cive enforcement of EMU’s rules. These tenden- by law (court-driven constitutionalisation of the cies are discussed in the third and fourth sections, treaties) and towards law (a closely integrated and respectively. legally bound union of people and peoples). Again, what makes the crisis-driven empower- EMU, as framed by the Maastricht Treaty, adapted ment of the ECB so significant is what it tells us the logic of ITL, but did not adopt it completely. about more serious deficiencies of EU governance, Like the single market, EMU was to be a ‘commu- which leaves insufficient space for the kind of open nity of law’, with fiscal discipline guaranteed by political contestation that is necessary for demo- formally binding rules. However, EMU norms do cratically legitimate policy-making. It is telling, not have direct effect, and are not subject to the for example, that the ECB’s bold redefinition of its kind of judicial dissemination that so effectively own mandate was legally ratified by the Court of constitutionalised the single market. Instead, Justice of the European Union (CJEU), rather than implementation of EMU norms required the kind through any legislative process. Herein lies the of concerted legislative and administrative action connection between ITL and ITC: Both prioritise that, prior to the crisis, was often lacking. In sum, non-majoritarian modes of policy making in the EMU was a political project, framed by formal advancement European integration, but with an rules, but without giving law the kind of agency it emphasis on different types of ‘experts’ (e.g. judges had enjoyed in relation to the single market. as opposed to bankers). Thus, the concluding The financial crisis became a European crisis in remarks reflect on the implications of ITC for the 2010. Initially framed as a problem caused by EU’s democratic legitimacy. excessive and unsustainable sovereign debt (a narrative that has since been shown to have been From integration-through- inaccurate, but which continues to colour the law to integration-through- response), the crisis manifested most urgently in crisis relation to Greece. In May 2010, Greece received the first in what was to become a series of bail- ITL describes the dynamic whereby courts drive outs, the initial one taking the form of bilateral the integration process forward through their loans from European partners (Louis 2010). I will

INTEGRATION-THROUGH-CRISIS AS A DISTINCT INTEGRATIVE MODE: PLACING EXPEDIENCY AHEAD OF DEMOCRACY? 221 Nicole Scicluna not recapitulate the story of the euro crisis and a new governing coalition in Italy between the its evolution here. The important point, for our populist Five Star Movement and the eurosceptic purposes, is that the crisis precipitated a transition Lega, or by fractures within the German governing to a new mode of integration, which I term Inte- coalition. gration through Crisis (ITC) (Scicluna 2017). The key characteristics of ITC may be summarised as The ECB as an agent of follows: integration-through-crisis • It is ends-driven; the end being the preservation of EMU, with its current membership, and It is in the context of the transition from ITL to ITC without turning it into a transfer union, that the ECB took centre stage. Since its creation in 1998, the ECB has been an important compo- • It is extra-constitutional, in the sense of nent of the EU’s regulatory state. It is an indepen- avoiding treaty reform by going outside the dent agency, insulated from direct majoritarian treaty framework, pressure, which has been mandated by member • It exacerbates pre-existing tendencies in states to set monetary policy for the eurozone. the EU to avoid political contestation by As is common with regulatory bodies, the ECB’s concentrating power in the hands of executives mandate (constitutionalised in the Maastricht and non-majoritarian bodies, Treaty) is explicitly circumscribed in some areas, but vague, or ‘incomplete’ in others. • It places more emphasis on the coercive enforcement of EMU’s rules (including In the case of the ECB, two key aspects of its those adopted through ad hoc and extra- mandate are made explicit. Firstly, the Bank is constitutional processes) on debtor states, confined to monetary policy making and excluded from the realm of economic policy making, • And, finally, it is justified through emergency which is left to individual national governments. rhetoric. Secondly, the Bank is given an explicit hierarchy of Thus, ITC does not abandon law. On the contrary, objectives to pursue - price stability is its primary the ‘rhetoric of rules’ (i.e. the emphasis on the goal, though it may also act to support the general importance of following the rules) has been economic policies of the Union so long as such pervasive throughout the crisis response. In fact, actions do not conflict with the objective of price this rhetoric mirrors the dominant, though inac- stability. Yet, there are other, equally important curate, narrative of Northern ‘saints’ and Southern aspects, in which the principal-agent contract is ‘sinners’ - the latter got themselves into trouble incomplete. ‘Price stability’ is not defined, and precisely because they did not follow ‘the rules’. neither are the policy instruments by which the ECB may pursue its mandated objectives. ITC might provide short term fixes, but it does not provide long term solutions to the EU’s myriad The crisis offered an opportunity to fill in some crises because it is an integration mode that specif- of those gaps. Faced with possible collapse of the ically relies on avoiding the kind of major institu- eurozone in 2010-2012, the ECB began to adopt tional and legal reform that EMU needs. Moreover, a number of unconventional policy instruments, the highpoint of ITC may already have passed. including the Outright Monetary Transactions ITC relies on there being an elite consensus, or (OMT) programme, and to take a bigger role in something close to an elite consensus, in order to providing much-needed finance to euro area circumvent the popular constraining dissensus. banks via the Emergency Liquidity Assistance But that elite consensus is breaking down, as may (ELA) programme. The Bank’s actions over the be evidenced, for example, by the formation of crisis years have often been described as ‘neces- sary’ (though cf. Sinn 2014: 280-293). But how are

INTEGRATION-THROUGH-CRISIS AS A DISTINCT INTEGRATIVE MODE: PLACING EXPEDIENCY AHEAD OF DEMOCRACY? 222 Nicole Scicluna we to understand and evaluate necessity under Gauweiler, and others was couched in constitu- these circumstances, and how does it relate to tional terms. It centred on the claim that the ECB legitimacy? Indeed, notwithstanding the rhetoric had acted ultra vires in announcing OMT, since of necessity, the policy problems addressed by the this was an economic policy, outside of the Bank’s ECB are very much distributional in their effects monetary policy remit, and, furthermore, that the and, therefore, not suitable for technocratic reso- programme breached Article 123 TFEU’s prohibi- lution. Consequently, the ECB’s empowerment tion of monetary financing of government debts. has contributed to the crisis-hit EU’s ‘politicisa- The case came first to the German Federal Consti- tion without democratisation’ (Scicluna 2014), as tutional Court (FCC), which referred certain may be illustrated by reference to the Gauweiler questions to the CJEU - the first time in its history litigation over the OMT programme. that the FCC had used the preliminary refer- ence procedure. In this respect, the constitu- The Gauweiler litigation: tional significance of the case extended beyond its Constitutionalisation of particular subject matter to take in the relation- regulatory overreach ship between national courts and the CJEU in the EU’s informally constitutionalised judicial order The Gauweiler litigation marked, perhaps, the (Scicluna 2015). For, although the FCC’s utilisa- most significant test of the constitutionality of tion of the preliminary reference procedure could the euro crisis response (Fabbrini 2016: 3). The be regarded as indicating acceptance of the CJEU’s case concerned the compatibility with EU law of exclusive competence to interpret EU law, the text the OMT programme, an initiative announced by of the referral made it clear that the situation was the ECB in September 2012, according to which not so settled (Fabbrini 2016: 4). the Bank would purchase the debt instruments of eurozone member states on secondary markets, Indeed, the potential for direct conflict between in exchange for the affected state entering into a the two courts was flagged by the German Court’s programme of financial assistance with the Euro- invocation of its own previously established test of pean Stability Mechanism (ESM), the eurozone’s whether an EU institution has exceeded its compe- 252 permanent bailout fund. The OMT programme tences. That is, the FCC suggested that the OMT was, thus, the policy manifestation of Mario programme constituted a ‘manifest violation’ Draghi’s famous pledge, made in July 2012, that of the ECB’s powers that caused a ‘structurally the ECB would do ‘whatever it takes’ to guarantee significant shift’ in the allocation of competences 253 the eurozone’s survival. Measured against its aim between the national and supranational levels. of calming markets so as to ensure the smooth The FCC’s very ability to articulate such a test is transmission of ECB monetary policy, the OMT not accepted by the CJEU, which claims for itself programme was highly successful. So successful, sole competence to find the act of an EU institu- in fact, that it was never used. Its mere announce- tion ultra vires. Hence, the Gauweiler case was an ment had the desired effect. opportunity to test not only the legality of the euro crisis response - particularly its expansion of the Nevertheless, the fact that it was never used did space available for technocratic decision making at not allay concerns over the programme’s alleged the expense of democratically-accountable policy illegality. This was especially so in Germany, where most steps in the crisis response have elicited 252 BVerfG, 2 BvR 2661/06 vom 6.7.2010, Absatz-Nr. fears that, notwithstanding the provisions put in (1 – 116), available at www. bverfg.de/entscheidungen/ place in the Maastricht Treaty, EMU is becoming rs20100706_2bvr266106en.html (Honeywell case). a transfer union. The complaint brought by the 253 BVerfG, 2 BvR 2728/13 vom 14.1.2014, Absatz-Nr. (1 – 105) available at www.bverfg.de/entscheidungen/ Christian Social Union (CSU) politician, Peter rs20140114_2bvr272813en.html (OMT referral), paras. 36-43.

INTEGRATION-THROUGH-CRISIS AS A DISTINCT INTEGRATIVE MODE: PLACING EXPEDIENCY AHEAD OF DEMOCRACY? 223 Nicole Scicluna modes - but also either to reaffirm or reconfigure for the Court to make clear that while the EU trea- core features of the EU’s constitutional settlement. ties may interpreted flexibly, their letter and spirit The CJEU announced its decision in the Gauweiler cannot be blatantly disregarded (see e.g. Joerges case on 16 June 2015.254 The Court affirmed the 2016). legality of the OMT programme, applying an As it is, the Gauweiler decision has left the ECB’s objectives-based, rather than effects-based, test. discretion to interpret its own mandate effectively This allowed OMT to be qualified as a mone- unchecked. Now that the CJEU has endorsed the tary policy measure, owing to the ECB’s over- Bank’s unorthodox policy manoeuvres, only treaty arching price stability objective, notwithstanding reform - with all of its prohibitively high barriers the programme’s potentially significant economic - could reintroduce constraints. Thus, while the policy effects, including its requirement that a ECB’s unprecedented empowerment was driven beneficiary state undertake a macroeconomic by the circumstances of the euro crisis, it will adjustment programme (Louis 2016: 60-1). long outlast the ‘state of emergency’ (White 2015: What are the consequences of the Gauweiler 593–9). Meanwhile, the FCC declined to follow up verdict? Formally, the ECB’s mandate has not on its implied threat to overrule a binding inter- changed. It retains its exclusive monetary policy pretation issued by the CJEU. In its final ruling competence, while eurozone member govern- on the Gauweiler case, delivered in June 2016, ments retain their economic policy competences. the German Court cast doubt upon the CJEU’s Yet, de facto, the ECB has expanded the scope of reasoning, including its uncritical acceptance its powers considerably - an expansion that the of the ECB’s interpretation of the purposes and nature of the OMT programme, but it neverthe- CJEU has gone some way towards constitutional- 256 ising. In particular, the objectives-based test takes less accepted the Court of Justice’s conclusion. the ECB at its own word. OMTs must be a mone- Thus, a clash between two of Europe’s most tary policy measure because the Bank’s stated aim powerful courts, which could have threatened the in announcing the policy was to safeguard the basic tenets on which the EU as a community of ‘singleness’ of eurozone monetary policy, itself a law was founded, was avoided. Despite its occa- prerequisite of the Bank’s effective pursuit of its sionally strong rhetoric, the FCC continues to will- core goal of price stability. ingly endorse the supremacy of EU law, embodied The CJEU’s deferral to the ECB’s expertise on the in the CJEU’s extensive and exclusive power to question of what constitutes monetary policy is determine the outer limits of the competence of neither surprising nor without justification (see e.g. EU institutions. Zilioli 2016). As the Court itself pointed out, since However, at the same time, the Gauweiler liti- preparation and implementation of a programme gation, by constitutionalising the ECB’s regula- such as OMT requires the ECB ‘to make choices of tory overreach, contributes to a deeper and much a technical nature and to undertake forecasts and more serious crisis of EU constitutionalism: That complex assessments’, the Bank ‘must be allowed, is, the EU’s shift from a Europäische Rechtsgemein- in that context, a broad discretion’.255 Certainly, it schaft (European community of law), premised would not make sense for the Court to attempt to on voluntary cooperation, to a Zwangsgemein- substitute its own judgement on the highly tech- schaft (community under duress), which places nical questions involved in the case for that of the more emphasis on coercive forms of integration ECB. Yet, deferral to expertise cannot be limitless, (Bogdandy 2017). This idea is explored further and the Gauweiler case was surely an opportunity below. 254 Case C-62/14, et al. v Deutscher Bun- destag (Gauweiler case) 256 BVerfG, 2 BvR 2728/13, 2 BvR 2729/13, 2 BvR 2730/13, 255 Case C-62/14 Gauweiler, para. 68. 2 BvR 2731/13, 2 BvE 13/13 decision from 21.06.2016.

INTEGRATION-THROUGH-CRISIS AS A DISTINCT INTEGRATIVE MODE: PLACING EXPEDIENCY AHEAD OF DEMOCRACY? 224 Nicole Scicluna The ECB and the coercive ated between the government and the ‘Troika’ turn in EMU governance of creditors (comprising the European Commis- sion, the IMF and the ECB itself), which contro- The second characteristic of ITC on which this versially required the imposition of a tax on all paper focuses is its tendency to emphasise coer- Cypriot bank deposits over 20,000 euros. The ECB cive enforcement of ‘the rules’, however those responded by issuing an ultimatum on 21 March rules may have come into existence. As Chris- that either secure a new bailout before tian Kreuder-Sonnen (2018: 452-4) has noted, the 25 March, or lose its ELA funding (Wearden and crisis years have produced an ‘authoritarian turn’ Amos 2013). The amended bailout package was in European politics that afflicts both EU-level duly adopted a few days later, in a form that did and national-level governance. At the EU level, not require parliamentary approval (Smith 2013). ‘traits of authoritarianism’ manifest in an emer- Thus, the ECB was able to use the ELA programme gency politics that privileges non-democratically to pressure the Cypriot government into accepting accountable discretion in policy making. Again, an austerity-linked bailout that the Bank itself, as the ECB is heavily implicated in this ‘authoritarian part of the Troika, had helped to design and would turn’, as three examples shall suffice to illustrate. help to oversee. It contributed to the undermining We may firstly point to the ECB’s decision, in of democratic oversight in Cyprus by encouraging mid-2015, not to increase the level of ELA to Greek the Cypriot government to adopt policy in a way banks to a level that would be necessary to counter that bypassed the parliament. the capital flight that the country’s banking system The final example concerns the infamous Trichet- was experiencing. This decision was taken in the Draghi letter that was sent to the Italian govern- midst of fierce contestation between Greece and ment of Silvio Berlusconi on 5 August 2011. In the its creditors over whether it would receive further letter, which was intended to be confidential but financial assistance and under what conditions. In was later published by an Italian newspaper, Jean- fact, the ECB made its decision on 28 June 2015 Claude Trichet, then ECB president, and Draghi, - the day following Greek Prime Minister Alexis his heir, outlined a number of reform measures, Tsipras’s announcement of a referendum on the which they urged the Italian government to bailout terms offered by the creditors. It resulted undertake with the utmost speed.257 The ECB in a three-week closure of Greek banks, which had, and has, no legal basis make such a request, began days before the referendum was held. which called for comprehensive and detailed It is debatable whether the ECB was simply legal reform in areas including the labour market, applying the ELA eligibility rules in a technical public administration and pensions - all areas of manner (with unfortunate timing), or whether it national competence. It was, rather, a coercive was deliberately signalling to Greeks the conse- form of ‘implicit conditionality’, enabled by the quences of voting to reject austerity. In some ways, ECB’s leverage over national banking systems and it does not matter. A decision that shuts down a justified by the prevailing atmosphere of emer- country’s banking system days before a major vote gency (Sacchi 2015). in that country is a political decision. The ECB What all three examples have in common is that simply lacks the legitimacy resources to take such they involve the technocratic, non-democratically a consequential action. accountable ECB playing the role of teacher and The second example concerns the ECB’s interven- disciplinarian in order to ‘discipline and punish’ tion in Cyprus two years prior to the Greek ELA the eurozone’s delinquent member states (Kund- decision. On 19 March 2013, the Cypriot parlia- 257 The letter is available at https://www.corriere.it/econo- ment rejected a ten-billion euro bailout negoti- mia/11_settembre_29/trichet_draghi_inglese_304a5f1e-ea59- 11e0-ae06-4da866778017.shtml?fr=correlati.

INTEGRATION-THROUGH-CRISIS AS A DISTINCT INTEGRATIVE MODE: PLACING EXPEDIENCY AHEAD OF DEMOCRACY? 225 Nicole Scicluna nani 2018). Such attempts at coercive enforce- They impoverish democracy and fuel the turn to ment betray the EU’s purposes and values, and populism within member states, and they under- contribute significantly to the degradation of mine the legitimacy on which the EU rests. democracy in Europe, particularly in the coun- More broadly, the idea that the EU could regu- tries of the eurozone’s periphery. late itself out of crisis; that restoring confidence As noted above, there is a tendency among and stability to the eurozone was primarily a scholars and observers of the EU to allow the ECB matter of putting the right policy settings in place; considerable room to manoeuvre on the grounds was misplaced and misguided. The regulatory of ‘necessity’. However, even if the Bank’s actions approach to the euro crisis - of which the ECB has are deemed necessary, it is worth asking why this been at the forefront - overestimated fidelity to the is so. The fact that no other EU institution could rules and to the idea of the ‘rule of rules’ amongst act so decisively exposes the EU’s lack of actor- member states. It underestimated the extent to ness; its weakness as a political construct. It also which acceptance of, and adherence to, rules was exposes the anti-democratic, market-beholden contingent on there being a virtuous circle of logic that has driven the crisis response: The need cumulatively causal integration (Jones 2018). In to placate ‘the markets’ (explicitly invoked, e.g., short, the regulatory approach to crisis was based in the Trichet-Draghi letter) is treated as consid- on a misunderstanding of the nature of the EU erably more important than the need to placate as a community of law. The EC/EU worked rela- disaffected voters. tively well as a voluntary community of law - elic- A recent illustration of this phenomenon occurred iting compliance through powerful instrumental in May 2018, when it looked like Italians would and normative logics without the need for hard have to return to the polls for the second time in a enforcement. However, the euro crisis has severely matter of months to resolve a government forma- disrupted the economic benefits-driven virtuous tion deadlock. In an interview with Deutsche Welle, circle that powered European integration. EMU’s Günther Oettinger, the European Commissioner ‘coercive turn’ has only made the integration proj- for Budget and Human Resources, suggested that ect’s problems worse. the markets would teach Italians not to vote for populists. Such sentiments, however carelessly Concluding remarks expressed, reflect the underlying teleological The euro crisis has created a ‘postfunctionalist assumptions that many practitioners, as well as dilemma’ for European elites. Functional pres- scholars, continue to hold about the purpose and sures continue to push national executives towards end point of European integration. These assump- integrative steps - bailout mechanisms, banking tions may be summarised in the idea that more union, fiscal surveillance, etc. However, growing integration is the solution to any and all of Europe’s popular resistance to ‘more Europe’ has made it problems. Deviations from the path towards ever impossible to adopt and embed crisis initiatives closer union are exactly that - deviations; mistakes into the existing framework of EU constitution- in need of correction. alism via treaty change. Consequently, emergency It is in this context that regulators take on ever- politics in the EU has taken on a distinctly extra- expanding political roles. If national publics, and legal character (Hooghe and Marks 2017: 8-9). even national governments, are fickle and short- To put it differently, over the last several years, sighted, then it is for regulators - dispassionate, extraordinary policies have been adopted via objective, far-sighted - to keep the process of extraordinary means. These policies are then European integration on the right track. However, embedded via a ritualistic insistence (usually these attitudes are very much part of the problem. made by EU institutions and creditor states

INTEGRATION-THROUGH-CRISIS AS A DISTINCT INTEGRATIVE MODE: PLACING EXPEDIENCY AHEAD OF DEMOCRACY? 226 Nicole Scicluna towards debtor states) on the need to follow the rules - an insistence which ignores the dubious ways in which the ‘rules’ that make up the EU’s emergency politics came into existence. Both ITL and ITC are problematic from a democratic stand- point – the former empowered courts to decide on fundamentally political questions, while the latter empowers executives and technocratic experts. Combined with politicisation and disregard for maintaining the coherence of EU constitution- alism, ITC further damages the EU’s legitimacy. As I have argued in this paper, the case of the ECB is particularly illustrative. Without any formal change to its narrow, monetary policy-focused mandate, its role has been significantly expanded and politicised. The ECB is guarantor of the euro’s continued existence. It is lender of last resort for the eurozone’s troubled banks and sovereigns. And it is teacher and disciplinarian to those governments and publics that attempt to escape the dictates of austerity. Perhaps national executives and EU leaders judged the regulatory approach to the euro crisis to be the ‘path of least political resistance’ (Hooghe and Marks 2017: 9). However, this judgement is likely to prove incorrect over the longer term. Just as European integration is cumulatively causal, so too is disintegration (Jones 2018). As domestic- level political resistance - expressed, for example, via the election of eurosceptic populists - accumu- lates, the constraining dissensus that operates at the European level is strengthened. As European elites continue to push against the constraining dissensus, so national-level democracy is under- mined, and EU-level legitimacy weakened.

INTEGRATION-THROUGH-CRISIS AS A DISTINCT INTEGRATIVE MODE: PLACING EXPEDIENCY AHEAD OF DEMOCRACY? 227 Nicole Scicluna Bibliography Scicluna, N. (2015) European Union Constitution- alism in Crisis, London: Routledge. Cappelletti, M., Seccombe, M. and Weiler, J.H.H. Scicluna, N. (2017) ‘Integration through the disin- (1986), Integration Through Law, Berlin: De tegration of law? The ECB and EU constitution- Gruyter. alism in the crisis’, Journal of European Public Fabbrini, F. (2016) ‘The European Court of Policy, DOI: 10.1080/13501763.2017.1362026. Justice, the European Central Bank, and the Sinn, H.-W. (2014) The Euro Trap: On Bursting Supremacy of EU Law’, Maastricht Journal of Bubbles, Budgets, and Beliefs, Oxford: Oxford European and Comparative Law 23(1): 3-16. University Press. Hooghe, L. and Marks, G. (2017) ‘Cleavage Von Bogdandy, A. (2017) ‘Von der technokrati- theory meets Europe’s crises: Lipset, schen Rechtsgemeinschaft zum politisierten Rokkan, and the transnational cleavage’, Rechtsraum’, MPIL Research Paper Series No. Journal of European Public Policy, DOI: 2017-12. 10.1080/13501763.2017.1310279. Wearden, G. and Amos, H. (2013) ‘Cyprus Crisis: Joerges, C. (2016) ‘Pereat Iustitia, Fiat Mundus: Politicians Race to Agree Details of “Plan B”’, What is Left of the European Economic Consti- The Guardian, 22 March 2013. tution after the Gauweiler Litigation?’ Maas- tricht Journal of European and Comparative Weiler, J.H.H. (1994) ‘A quiet revolution: The Law 23(1): 99-118. European court of justice and its interlocutors’, Comparative Political Studies 26(4): 510–34. Jones, E. (2018) ‘Towards a theory of disintegra- tion’, Journal of European Public Policy 25(3): White, J. (2015) ‘Authority after emergency rule’, 440-51. The Modern Law Review 78(4): 585–610. Kreuder-Sonnen, C. (2018) ‘An authoritarian Zilioli, C. (2016) ‘The ECB’s Powers and Institu- turn in Europe and European Studies?’, Journal tional Role in the Financial Crisis: A Confirma- of European Public Policy 25(3): 452-64. tion from the Court of Justice of the European Union’, Maastricht Journal of European and Kundnani, H. (2018) ‘Discipline and Punish’, Comparative Law 23(1): 171-84. Berlin Policy Journal, 27 April 2018. Louis, J.-V. (2010) ‘The No-Bailout Clause and Rescue Packages’, Common Market Law Review 47(4): 971–86. Louis, J.-V. (2016) ‘The EMU after the Gauweiler Judgment and the Juncker Report’, Maastricht Journal of European and Comparative Law 23(1): 55-78. Sacchi, S. (2015) ‘Conditionality by other means: EU involvement in Italy’s struc- tural reforms in the sovereign debt crisis’, Comparative European Politics 13(1): 77-92. Scicluna, N. (2014) ‘Politicization without democratization: How the Eurozone crisis is transforming EU law and politics’, International Journal of Constitutional Law 12(3): 545–71.

INTEGRATION-THROUGH-CRISIS AS A DISTINCT INTEGRATIVE MODE: PLACING EXPEDIENCY AHEAD OF DEMOCRACY? 228 Nicole Scicluna SHOULD THE SPECIFICS 1. The Failures of the OF NATIONAL “Integration through Law” POLITICAL CULTURES Orthodoxy BE CHARACTERISED AS As late as 1990, the former President of the EUI, “DEMOCRATIC ACQUIS” AND Joseph Weiler, and his successor to the presidency, CAN THEY BE DEFENDED BY Renaud Dehousse, co-authored an article on the “legal dimension” of the integration project in a LAW? prestigious collection of essays edited by William BEYOND THE NOSTALGIA- Wallace.1 The law, so the most famous and much CONTROVERSY BETWEEN cited sentence of the article reads, is both “the JÜRGEN HABERMAS AND object and the agent” of integration.2 Nearly eve- rything that went wrong in the integration project WOLFGANG STREECK is summarised in this perplexing pronouncement. The famous motto was coined at the height of the Christian Joerges American law and society movement, which pro- Berlin / Bremen moted the sociological study of law and all sorts of interdisciplinary “law and …” explorations. How Two Introductory Remarks could European law scholarship defend views and visions on the potential of “law as such” which had These introductory remarks will define the ob- long since been discredited? These methodologi- jectives of my intervention. They are ambitious cal irritations coincide with substantive concerns. but this may not be so readily apparent and may On what grounds could the unity of law in the hence require some explanations. The difficulty is (then) Community be understood as an end in twofold: My disciplinary focus is on law but my itself? To be sure, the implicit assumption of the type of argument does not comply with the rules unity doctrine that “one size would fit all” and “be prevailing in legal studies. On the other hand, the best for all” was not as implausible in the foun- announcement of a discussion of a legal problem dational period as it has now become. However, tends to disappoint non-legal quarters from the even in the relatively homogenous orders of the very outset. I hope to explain why my legal queries former EEC, any unification at European level mirror conceptual and theoretical issues of general had disintegrative effects within national legal importance, namely the mainstream understand- orders. The reference procedure of the EEC Treaty ing of the functions of law and the judiciary in the cannot accomplish anything beyond some poin- integration process. The critique which I submit tillist “harmonisation” here and there. The inte- is related to the big names in my subtitle and the gration-through-law agenda is therefore deficient fierce controversy over the relationship between where “positive integration”, i.e., the replacement the nation state and the Union (Section I.). The of national legislation by a comprehensive Euro- follow-up section will turn to the implications of my critique. My argument will be as immodest as the announcement in the conference agenda. We have to abandon, so I will submit, the “ever more Europe” mantra, take instead the fortunate motto of the ill-fated Draft Constitutional Treaty 1 Renaud Dehousse and Joseph H.H. Weiler, “The legal of 2004 seriously, and explore what it might entail dimension”, in: William Wallace (ed.), The Dynamics of Euro- pean Integration, (London: Pinter, 1990), 242-260, at 243. for Europe to be “united in diversity (“in Vielfalt 2 Ibid., 243. geeint”) (Section II.).

SHOULD THE SPECIFICS OF NATIONAL POLITICAL CULTURES BE CHARACTERISED AS “DEMOCRATIC ACQUIS” AND CAN THEY 229 BE DEFENDED BY LAW? BEYOND THE NOSTALGIA-CONTROVERSY BETWEEN JÜRGEN HABERMAS AND WOLFGANG STREECK Christian Joerges pean scheme is envisaged.3 To be sure, such piece- sphere of social norms within which the law oper- meal steps have been undertaken from early on, ates and upon which its functioning depends.7 in particular in the field of consumer protection, Gunther Teubner has re-published his essay in the but they could not transform the pointillist modes legendary Hall and Soskice volume on the Vari- of legal integration. The reasons should have been eties of Capitalism.8 This is indeed, in my view, obvious. Back in 1982, the America scholar and the background for the disintegrative effects of judge Guido Calabresi had examined the ten- integration through law. What seems so irritat- sions between the common law system and prob- 4 ing to the community of European lawyers hardly lem-specific legislative corrections. It is obvious requires any explanatory exercises in the present that what is difficult to accommodate within the context. If there is a kernel of truth in the message common legal culture of the US is more problem- about the varieties of the socio-economic systems atical in a Community of six or more Member of the Member States of the EU, it is simply in- States with diverse legal traditions. And last, but conceivable that their integration can be brought not least, on what grounds can one argue that an about “through law”. It is totally unsurprising that ever more uniform legal order deserves the same the orchestrators of Europe’s crisis politics argue degree of recognition throughout the entire Com- that they have to impose a convergence of the munity? economies and policies of the Member States in The “Integration through law” agenda tends to order to ensure the functioning of the “new modes cause the disintegration of national legal systems of economic governance”. This is, of course, not without establishing a European substitute because to suggest that these efforts will overcome the dif- “the logic of integration” (as practised through ficulties of the integration-through-law agenda. “negative integration”) is at odds with the “logic of Teubner’s “irritants” make themselves felt in the post-classical private law”.5 In a seminal essay, enti- resistance of legal and economic cultures.9 tled “Legal Irritants: Good Faith in British Law, Or Our conference has explored these issues more How Unifying Law Ends up in New Differences”,6 Gunther Teubner has made comparative lawyers 7 Karl-Heinz Ladeur, “‘Conflicts Law as aware of this phenomenon, which is both unsur- Europe’sConstitutional Form’ … and the Conflict of Social Norms as its Infrastructure”, in: Christian Joerges and Carole prising and unavoidable, as Karl-Heinz Ladeur Glinski (eds), The European Crisis and the Transformation of has added, because European law cannot reach the Transnational Governance: Authoritarian Managerialism versus Democratic Governance, (Oxford-Portland OR: Hart Publish- 3 Locus classicus: Friedrich A. von Hayek, “The Econom- ing, 2014), 383-396. ic Conditions of Interstate Federalism”, in: Friedrich A. Hayek, Individualism and Economic Order, (Chicago IL: University of 8 “How Unifying Law Ends up in New Differences”, in: Chicago Press, 1949), 255-272 (reprinted from the New Com- Peter Hall and David Soskice (eds), Varieties of Capitalism: The monwealth Quarterly V. 2 (September 1939), 131-149. Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage., (Oxford: Oxford UP, 2001), 417- 441. 4 Guido Calabresi. A Common Law for the Age of Statutes, (Cambridge, MA/London: Harvard UP 1982). 9 See Gunther Teubner, “Eigensinnige Produktionsregimes: Zur Ko-evolution von Wirtschaft und Recht 5 See Christian Joerges, “The Impact of European Integra- in den varieties of capitalism”, (1999) 5 Soziale Systeme, 7-26 tion on Private Law. Reductionist Perceptions, True Conflicts [Idiosyncratic Production Regimes: Co-evolution of Economic and a New Constitutional Perspective”, (1997) 3 European Law and Legal Institutions in the Varieties of Capitalism, in: John Journal, 378-406. Gert Brüggemeier and Christian Joerges, Ziman (ed.), The Evolution of Cultural Entities: Proceedings of the “Europäisierung des Vertrags- und Haftungsrechts“, in: Peter- British Academy 112. (Oxford: Oxford UP, 2002), 161-182], and Christian Müller-Graff (ed.), Gemeinsames Privatrecht in der the works of Werner Abelshauser, e.g., “Europa in Vielfalt einigen. Europäischen Gemeinschaft (Baden-Baden: Nomos 1993, 2nd. Eine Denkschrift”, in: A.B. Atkinson, P.M. Huber, H. James and ed. 1999), 301-360.; Christoph Schmid, Die Instrumentalisier- F.W. Scharpf (eds), Nationalstaat und Europäische Union. Eine ung des Privatrechts durch die Europäische Union. Privatrecht Bestandsaufnahme, (Baden-Baden: Nomos, 2016), 275-294; W. und Privatrechtskonzeptionen in der Entwicklung der Eu- Abelshauser, D. Gilgen and A. Leutzsch, “Kultur, Wirtschaft, ropäischen Integrationsverfassung (Baden-Baden: Nomos, Kulturen der Weltwirtschaft”, in: Wener Abelshauser, David 2010), passim. Gilgen and Andreas Leutzsch (eds), Kulturen der Weltwirtschaft, 6 Modern Law Review 61 (1998), 11-32. (Göttingen: Vandenhoek und Ruprecht, 2013), 9-29.

SHOULD THE SPECIFICS OF NATIONAL POLITICAL CULTURES BE CHARACTERISED AS “DEMOCRATIC ACQUIS” AND CAN THEY 230 BE DEFENDED BY LAW? BEYOND THE NOSTALGIA-CONTROVERSY BETWEEN JÜRGEN HABERMAS AND WOLFGANG STREECK Christian Joerges thoroughly. My objective as a lawyer, however, is “The social” became more deeply engrained in the distinct. I am primarily concerned with the nor- discourse theory of law and democracy. mative – legal and constitutional – implications The nation state and its welfare accomplishments, of Europe’s diversity. It is this concern which the Habermas submits, is merely a nostalgic option, debate between Habermas and Streeck, to which a hideaway in the sovereign powerlessness of the my subtitle refers, illustrates quite instructively. overrun nation (eine “nostalgische Option für eine Their exchange10 builds on well-known arguments Einigelung in der souveränen Ohnmacht der über- and is somewhat repetitive.11 There is a strong rollten Nation”).16 There is some unity in the di- legal dimension in their controversy, which fits versity of the two opponents. Both invoke the well into the agenda of our conference. Streeck interdependence of facticity and validity. They questions the potential of Europe to establish, share the premise that economic liberalism is far at a transnational level, an equivalent to the na- too insensitive to the quests for social justice and tional Sozialstaat. In Streeck’s understanding, should therefore be subjected to political correc- which is informed by the constitutional theory tions. They disagree about “the level of govern- of Hermann Heller,12 Sozialstaatlichkeit, as it has ance” at which such corrections can be realised. been endorsed by the eternity clause of the Basic This, however, is anything but a trivial disagree- Law, is a democratic essential.13 Because of the ment. It is one which reveals a deep lacunae in ongoing erosion of social protection provisions in extensive legal debates on what has been charac- the integration process, he opts for a defence of the terised in ever more intensity as “Europe’s Justice nation state and its institutions against a deepen- Deficit”.17 This notion is of a revealing vagueness. ing of economic integration.14 Habermas shares a What exactly is Europe supposed to do? Should commitment to Hermann Heller – small wonder, it compensate justice failures with the Member as Wolfgang Abendroth, with whom he wrote his States, for example, by imposing a uniform “Eu- habilitation thesis, wrote a famous defence of Hel- ropean Social Model”? Should it, instead, super- ler’s in the first great post-war Verfassungsstreit.15 vise the inter-state relations and ensure “justice between” its Members? 10 Jürgen Habermas, “Demokratie oder Kapitalismus? Vom Elend der nationalstaatlichen Fragmentierung in einer Streeck’s political and normative conclusion builds kapitalistisch integrierten Weltgesellschaft”, (2013) 5 Blätter für coherently on his sociological analysis – including deutsche und internationale Politik, 59-70; Wolfgang Streeck, his extensive discussion of the varieties of capital- “Small-State Nostalgia? The Currency Union, Germany, and 18 Europe: A Reply to Jürgen Habermas”, (2014) 21 Constellations, ism. His logic is both sociologically and legally 213-221. compelling: under European rule, the social state 11 The earliest encounter of which I am aware is Streeck’s cannot survive. We have hence to replace the su- – unpublished -- reaction to Habermas’ plea for a European premacy of European law by a primacy of the constitution in his “Hamburg Lecture” of 26 June 2001 on “Warum braucht Europa eine Verfassung?”, published in DIE nation state. His argument is also richer than the ZEIT and still available at: http://www.zeit.de/2001/27/200127_ usual rejection of European claims to supremacy: verfassung.xml/seite-7. “Voluntarism” is the core objection in Streeck’s paper (“Das ‘soziale Europa’ und seine Verfassung: 16 Jürgen Habermas, “Demokratie oder Kapitalismus. Fragen zu einem politischen Projekt“, on file with author). Vom Elend der nationalstaatlichen Fragmentierung in einer 12 See, e.g., his recent “Heller, Schmitt and the Euro”, kapitalistisch integrierten Weltgesellschaft”, Blätter für deutsche (2017) 21 European Law Journal, 361-370. und internationale Politik 5/2013, 59-70 (“Nostalgische 13 Art. 79 III GG. Kleinstaaterei”, 62). 14 Wolfgang Streeck, “Small-State Nostalgia? The 17 Europe’s Justice Deficit?, co-edited by Dimitry Currency Union, Germany, and Europe: A Reply to Jürgen Kochenov, Gráinne de Búrca and Andrew Williams, (Oxford: Hart Habermas”, (2014) 21 Constellations, 213-221. Publishing, 2015). 15 See Christian Joerges, “The Rechtsstaat and Social 18 Streeck, MPIfG Discussion Paper 10/ 12; Blätter Europe: How a Classical Tension Resurfaces in the European 2013: Was nun, Europa? Kapitalismus ohne Demokratie oder Integration Process”, (2010) 9 Comparative Sociology, 65-85.. Demokratie ohne Kapitalismus.

SHOULD THE SPECIFICS OF NATIONAL POLITICAL CULTURES BE CHARACTERISED AS “DEMOCRATIC ACQUIS” AND CAN THEY 231 BE DEFENDED BY LAW? BEYOND THE NOSTALGIA-CONTROVERSY BETWEEN JÜRGEN HABERMAS AND WOLFGANG STREECK Christian Joerges “[W]hat I would suggest to call the acquis- 2. Institutionalising the es démocratiques of the national demoi in United in Diversity Vision Europe … importantly comprises a wide range of political-economic institutions The observations just submitted are somewhat that provide for democratic corrections of emphatic and abstract. I should not proceed with market outcomes – for democracy as social their defence without mentioning Habermas’ ob- democracy.”19 jections. His three main points are (I reproduce This is one of the very few suggestions to take the only the substance of his messages; his German is insights of the studies of the varieties of capital- impressive and would get hurt by a translation of ism both normatively and seriously. I am aware of mine): only three German jurists – there will be more! There is a concession to the diversity vision: -- who have submitted like arguments, namely, “In keinem demokratischen Gemeinwesen Anna Beckers,20 Ulrich K. Preuß.21and Gunther darf das historisch gewachsene politisch- Teubner22 They have all understood the legal im- kulturelle Selbstverständnis nationaler plications of the varieties studies. Legal rules and Minderheiten der Assimilation an die institutions do not operate in splendid insulation, Mehrheitskultur geopfert werden.” but constitute interdependencies. The deeper level However, we should not equate cultural of the gist of the matter can be explained with the identities with economic cultures: “Aber help of a famous dictum of the German constitu- können wir den wohlbegründeten tional scholar and judge Ernst-Wolfgang Böck- Rechtsschutz für kulturelle Identitäten enförde: secularised democracies, he held, live umstandslos auf Wirtschaftskulturen, on normative resources, which they cannot gen- 23 auf die, wie Wolfgang Streeck sagt, erate themselves. In the European context, the ‘parochialen’ Formen des Kapitalismus, z.B. integration project lives on cultural and norma- auf Systeme von Arbeitsbeziehungen oder tive resources, which cannot be produced wilfully auf sozialpolitische Regime ausdehnen? or by some political or legislative fiat. In a more “Ich sehe nicht, wie sich ein kultureller mundane version, democratic legitimacy in the Naturschutz für ein jeweils bestehendes EU lives on the quality of the democracies in the Ensemble von sozioökonomischer Member States, their historical experiences, idea- Praktiken begründen ließe.” tional traditions, and political preferences. Europe can promote and protect these accomplishments. We should instead trust that a postnational To replace national endeavours by the prescrip- identity and solidarity will emerge: “Es ist tion of some uniform political rule risks their de- nicht unrealistisch anzunehmen, dass sich struction. die, im Laufe der Nationalstaatsbildng sehr allmählich etablierte staatbürgerliche 19 Wolfgang Streeck, How Will Capitalism End?, (London: Solidarität in dem Maße über die Grenzen Verso Books, 2016), 198, n. 20. des Nationalstaates hinaus erweitert, 20 Anna Beckers, Enforcing Corporate Social Responsibility Codes. On Global Self-Regulation and National wie die Bürger von supranationalen Private Law, Oxford, Hart Publishing, 2015, 50 ff. Entscheidungen nicht nur betroffen, 21 Claus Offe and Ulrich K. Preuß, “The Union’s Course: sondern daran nach demokratischen Between a Supranational Welfare State and Creeping Decay”, Verfahren auch beteiligt werden.” in id. and Claus Offe, Citizens in Europe. Essays on Democracy, Constitutionalism and European Integration, Colchester: ECPR Never take Habermas lightly. Fortunately enough, Press, 2015, 15 ff. however, I can invoke the authority of another 22 Teubner above, n. 8. classic, namely, the founding father of economic 23 Ernst-Wolfang Böckenförde, “Die Entstehung des Staates als Vorgang der Säkularisation”, in id. Staat, Gesellschaft, sociology, Karl Polanyi, for my critique of his ar- Freiheit. Studien zur Staatstheorie und zum Verfassungsrecht, gument. Frankfurt a.M.: Suhrkamp 1975, 42-64.

SHOULD THE SPECIFICS OF NATIONAL POLITICAL CULTURES BE CHARACTERISED AS “DEMOCRATIC ACQUIS” AND CAN THEY 232 BE DEFENDED BY LAW? BEYOND THE NOSTALGIA-CONTROVERSY BETWEEN JÜRGEN HABERMAS AND WOLFGANG STREECK Christian Joerges Karl Polanyi’s Great Transformation is concerned to envisage a better future. Polanyi’s considera- with the emergence of “market societies”, where tions deserve attention for three additional and “instead of the economy embedded in social re- interrelated reasons. For one, he re-states his lations, social relations are embedded in the foundational argument that the capitalist market economy”.24 Writing at the end of the Great War, economy is not an evolutionary given, but a politi- Polanyi had witnessed the destruction of liberal cal product – “laissez-faire was planned”27 – which economic ordering by Fascism and . requires institutional backing and continuous However, by now, at the end of the Second World political management. To put it slightly differ- War, the rebirth of alternative counter-movements ently, “the political” is inherent in “the economic”; was in sight and nurtured hopes in a better na- market economies “are polities”.28 A second insight tional and international future: alternatives to the of topical importance follows from this: capital- Fascist transformation, namely, social counter- ist market economies will exhibit varieties which movements which would undermine the working mirror a variety of political preferences, historical of the market system (“the tension between a con- experiences, and socio-economic configurations. stant push towards self-regulating markets and This is what we can expect, and, so I conclude, spontaneous resistance to the subordination of should respect, once our societies have gained the society to market forces”, Dorothee Bohle). His “liberty to organise national life at will”. The third somewhat enigmatic views are difficult to deci- point is only alluded to in half a sentence. It is an pher. “The Great Transformation can legitimately implication of the new freedom. Polanyi predicts be read either as an anti-capitalist manifesto or and advocates “collaboration”; diversity, we can as a social democratic bedtime story.”25 Be that as assume, is there to stay. it may, my shortcut is a passage in which Polanyi Three follow-up queries have to be addressed: considers that: Even if we concede that the diversity “… with the disappearance of the of the institutional infrastructures of automatic mechanism of the gold standard, the European economies deserves, in governments will find it possible to […] principle, recognition, we have to concede tolerate willingly that other nations shape that these infrastructures are not written their domestic institutions according to in stone. Endogenous democratic change their inclinations, thus transcending the must remain possible, and insulation pernicious nineteenth century dogma of the against the impact of Europeanisation necessary uniformity of domestic regimes and globalisation is inconceivable. What within the orbit of world economy. Out of precisely distinguishes a variety of an the ruins of the Old World, cornerstones of economic culture from a Habermasian the New can be seen to emerge: economic “Schrebergarten”? collaboration of governments and the liberty to organize national life at will.”26 Query (1) assumes implicitly that both Streeck’s defence of the nation state and Was this just wishful thinking? The passage was Habermas’ defence of European rule written at a time when Keynes and the like-mind- are going a step too far. What we need ed American economist and politician Harry instead is a channelling of change. It is Dexter White were working towards the post-war settlement of Bretton Woods. There were reasons 27 “… planning was not”, Polanyi, at 147. 28 For a very dense re-construction, see Fred Block, 24 Polanyi, The Great Transformation, 57. “Towards a New Understanding of Economic Modernity”, in: 25 Gareth Dale, Karl Polanyi. A Life on the Left, New York: Bo Stråth, Peter Wagner, Christian/Joerges (eds), The Economy Columbia UP, 2016, 286. as Polity: The Political Constitution of Contemporary Capitalism, 26 Polanyi, 253-254. London: UCL Press 2005,, 3-16.

SHOULD THE SPECIFICS OF NATIONAL POLITICAL CULTURES BE CHARACTERISED AS “DEMOCRATIC ACQUIS” AND CAN THEY 233 BE DEFENDED BY LAW? BEYOND THE NOSTALGIA-CONTROVERSY BETWEEN JÜRGEN HABERMAS AND WOLFGANG STREECK Christian Joerges precisely this which is the objective of the law and security policy, but rather into conflicts-law approach which promises far more fundamental constitutional to institutionalise the united-in-diversity structures of political representation vision, thereby offering an alternative to and democracy, as well as regulatory both Streeck’s nation state nostalgia and frameworks of national economic steering Habermas’ European utopia. and social re-distribution. And it is here, in The normative credentials of this the unravelling of the nationally-bounded, alternative deserve special attention. It majoritarian politics and policies of seems noteworthy that the conflicts-law economic and social integration through approach is by no means as idiosyncratic intensified globalisation that political as my terminology may insinuate. populism has found its niche, and that academic thought struggles to identify Ad (1) The first query is the easiest to cope with. the new paradigms of political, social and It seems obvious that Habermas reproduces his economic organisation,30 which might famous dual of “system and lifeworld”, that is, his bridge the gap between a traditional, “two-level theory of society, which distinguishes spatially-delineated world and a post-war the lifeworld reproduced through communicative globe of universalising aspirations and action from the functional integration of the ad- complex interdependencies.”31 ministrative and economic subsystems, narrows the capitalist economy to exchange mediated Ad (2) The second is by no means more demand- by money”. The economy is not “a polity”, but a ing, but, due to the technicalities of its structure, purely functional machinery?! I restrict myself to more difficult to restate. A very brief summary citing an essay by the Tilburg legal theorist Hans must suffice here. Lindahl, who reminded European lawyers of the Back in 1997, Jürgen Neyer and I submitted the enduring currency of Hannah Arendt’s concept of core ideas of the conflicts-law approach (“delib- “spatiality” as: erative” as opposed to orthodox supranational- 32 “[N]ot merely a geographical term. It ism) in an essay on European comitology. Our relates not so much, and not primarily, basic premise and intuition was very simple: it to a piece of land as to the space between is a core premise of theories of democracy, most individuals in a group whose members are notably of Habermas’ discourse theory of law and bound to, and at the same time separated democracy, that we, the citizens, must be able to and protected from each other by all kinds understand ourselves as the authors of the legal of relationships, based on a common provisions with which we are expected to comply. language, religion, a common history, Under conditions of Europeanisation and globali- customs, and laws.”29 sation and ever more growing interdependences, As Michelle Everson commented: 30 Christian Joerges, “Brother, can you Paradigm?”, Review Essay of Kaarlo Tuori and Klaus Tuori, The Eurozone “For lawyers, the complex of sociological Crisis: A Constitutional Analysis, (Cambridge: Cambridge UP, and cultural artefacts that are called 2014), (2014) 12 International Journal of Constitutional Law, 769- 785. upon to instantiate spatial community 31 “A Very Cosmopolitan Citizenship: But Who Pays may appear opaque, but they translate the Price?”, in: Michael Dougan, Niamh Nic Shuibhne, Eleanor not simply into jurisdictional notions, Spaventa, About Empowerment and Disempowerment of the or territorial instruments of nationality European Citizen, (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 2012), Chapter 6.. 32 Christian Joerges and Jürgen Neyer, “From 29 Hans Lindahl, “Finding a Place for Freedom, Security Intergovernmental Bargaining to Deliberative Political Processes: and Justice: The European Union’s Claim to Territorial Unity”, The Constitutionalisation of Comitology”, (1997) 3 European Law (2004) 29 European Law Review, 461-484, at 466. Journal, 273-299.

SHOULD THE SPECIFICS OF NATIONAL POLITICAL CULTURES BE CHARACTERISED AS “DEMOCRATIC ACQUIS” AND CAN THEY 234 BE DEFENDED BY LAW? BEYOND THE NOSTALGIA-CONTROVERSY BETWEEN JÜRGEN HABERMAS AND WOLFGANG STREECK Christian Joerges this is no longer conceivable. To cite Habermas er that we have to distinguish “justice within” con- himself: solidated polities, on the one hand, and “justice between” them, on the other - and that we have “Nation-states … encumber each other 34 with the external effects of decisions that to work in both spheres. Last, but not least, it impinge on third parties who had no say in should be underlined that the conflicts approach the decision-making process. Hence, states seeks to defend the idea of the law-mediated legit- imacy of public rule. A lot more on the conflicts- cannot escape the need for regulation and 35 coordination in the expanding horizon of law approach can be said and has been said. We a world society that is increasingly self- focus here on the third query. programming, even at the cultural level Ad (3) Again, my terminology is only seemingly ...”33 idiosyncratic. As long as there is diversity in the It is difficult to reject these insights. The impli- EU, the law will have to cope with differences. cations are, of course, controversial. Among the Conflicts law is simply the name of the discipline three just-named alternatives – state-building, doing this. Europe can, in the foreseeable future, down-scaling of integration, and co-operation - not live without it. It can only consider design, I opt for the third. In the European case, we can its principles and methodology. The norma- build on European law’s potential to compensate tive intuitions which my version of conflicts-law for the legitimacy deficits of national rule. Euro- seeks to institutionalise are certainly outside the pean law can derive its own legitimacy from this mainstream of European studies. But I can point to similar approaches. Among them is Daniel In- function: its mandate is to implement the commit- 36 ments of the Member States towards each other by nerarity’s concept of “inter-democracy”. Two of two legal claims, namely, the requirement to take his insights are particularly important for my ar- the interests and concerns of their neighbours into gument. The first concerns Europe’s heterogene- account when designing national policies, and by ity, which excludes all “one-size-fits-all” recipes. imposing a duty to co-operate. The very notion Instead, “If the EU is going to be more democratic, of co-operation indicates that this kind of rule it will be so in the style of complex democracies. cannot be some “command and control” exercise, And that complexity is not only related to the di- but must rely on the deliberative quality of co-op- versity of its citizens but to the variety of issues erative interactions. Two important implications about which it needs to decide, some of which may require proximity, but others that demand a should be underlined. The first: there is no in- 37 built-guarantee that such co-operative efforts will, certain distance”. “Inter-democracy” is his key in the end, be successful; but such limitations need concept: the democratisation of interdependen- not be damaging per se; quite to the contrary, they cies must replace state-like or federal hierarchical may document mutual respect of essential, yet dis- models, he argues forcefully. And, tinct, values and commitments of the other (the “The states are increasingly more incapable ordre public in the parlance of conflict of laws and of democratic action because they cannot private international law). The second implication 34 Christian Joerges, “Social Justice in an Ever More is more drastic: socio-economic, institutional, po- Diverse Union”, in: Frank Vandenbroucke, Catherine Barnard and litical and cultural diversity is particularly strong Geert De Baere (eds), A European Social Union after the Crisis, and difficult to overcome. This, however, is by no (Cambridge UP 2017), 92-119; available at: SSRN: http://ssrn. means a plea for inactivity; it is, instead, a remind- com/abstract=2697440. 35 References to FS Petersmann and TLT Special Issue. 33 Jürgen Habermas, “Hat die Konstitutionalisierung des 36 Daniel Innerarity, Democracy in Europe. A Political Völkerrechts noch eine Chance?“, in id., Der gespaltene Westen, Philosophy of the EU, (London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2018). Frankfurt a.M.: Suhrkamp, 2004, 113-193, at 175. 37 See the Introduction “Understanding European Complexity”, at 7.

SHOULD THE SPECIFICS OF NATIONAL POLITICAL CULTURES BE CHARACTERISED AS “DEMOCRATIC ACQUIS” AND CAN THEY 235 BE DEFENDED BY LAW? BEYOND THE NOSTALGIA-CONTROVERSY BETWEEN JÜRGEN HABERMAS AND WOLFGANG STREECK Christian Joerges include everyone affected by their decisions of the primacy of the economic liberties over the in the electoral process and, on the flip side, democratic Rechtsstaat (“economic constitution- citizens cannot influence the behaviour of alism” in my parlance) towards a principle of re- those who are making decisions in their straint, namely, to respect the limits of European name. This is the principal democratic competences” which requires that “the law of the deficit that the European Union should Union does not limit welfare state options at the rectify. Extraterritorial effects and the national level too severely”.41 We will hear more burdens that one state imposes on others from Florian directly. cannot be justified by recourse to domestic democratic procedures and require Instead of an Epilogue another type of legitimacy. That is why we can affirm that the fact that national It may not be so readily apparent how all this is actors keep outside interests in mind related to the agenda of this conference and to the may improve the representation of true search for a new future. It is, in fact, although cer- domestic interests, since they are no longer tainly not in perspectives which would be shared circumscribed by the state arena either. by everybody. “United in Diversity” is an anti- In this sense, we might think that the EU centralist, con-federal, rather than federal vision, helps strengthen the democratic authority a defence of political autonomy against imposed of the member states, to the extent to convergence, combined, however, with duties to which it can serve as a measure to manage co-operative problem-solving. How much realism externalities in an efficient fashion.”38 is in this “united in diversity” vision? It is to be conceded that the praxis which this vision envis- A second one, so it seems to me, is Damian Chal- ages certainly depends, to invoke Böckenförde’s mers’ still unpublished essay on the “Democrat- famous dictum again,42 on cultural and normative ic Authority and the Resettlement of EU Law”.39 resources, which cannot be produced wilfully or This quest for a resettlement is ground-breaking by some political or legislative fiat. European inte- and much more elaborated than my own: “EU law gration research used to be aware of such depend- allows [Chalmers departs from Article 2 TEU] … encies and has sought to identify them. for another approach in which the European Union’s mission become resettled around the promotion of democratic authority within Europe. The central 41 The “European Pact for Social Progress” Program”, at 2. question would be whether a measure has sufficient 42 Böckenförde, “Die Entstehung des Staates”, .n. 23 democratic credentials to warrant obedience over above. its alternatives, with EU law only justified where it would promote the quality of democracy within a Member State. EU law would, thereby, become an instrument for the cultivation of politics and the values of political community rather than some- thing which suppresses these to secure a policy.”40 The third is a contribution to this conference, namely, Florian Rödl’s suggestion to re-orient the jurisprudence of the CJEU from its promotion

38 See Chapter 3 (“What Should Be Democratized? The Peculiarity of Democracy in Europe”, at 73. 39 Ms. Singapore 2018 (on file with author) 40 Ibid., 1 (italics in the original).

SHOULD THE SPECIFICS OF NATIONAL POLITICAL CULTURES BE CHARACTERISED AS “DEMOCRATIC ACQUIS” AND CAN THEY 236 BE DEFENDED BY LAW? BEYOND THE NOSTALGIA-CONTROVERSY BETWEEN JÜRGEN HABERMAS AND WOLFGANG STREECK Christian Joerges THE END OF THE permanent co-operation with the relevant indus- UNIVERSALITY OF NORMS AS tries. There is a new tendency towards hybrid public-private interconnected systems or platform A MODEL FOR EUROPE: markets that undermine the difference between THE ERROR OF “SEEING public and private, between customer and whole- LIKE A STATE” (J.S. sale services. In my view, this is not only relevant SCOTT) IN THE POSTMODERN for the specific markets to which I refer but this also demonstrates for Europe that universality as CONDITION a constitutional principle that extends its effects beyond the economic system has lost at least some Karl-Heinz Ladeur of its integrative power. More and more, we are Hamburg challenged by the rise of “modular technologies” for complex information services that are difficult 1. Universality of Norms to assess beforehand and no longer lend them- and the Emergence of More selves to the construction of steady state markets, Complex Markets and, as a consequence, the rather stable regula- tory strategies of the past begin to move on slip- The financial crisis of 2008 has exacerbated the pery ground. At the same time, the interests of differences within the economic systems of the Member States are becoming much more hetero- Member States. As one of the less visible conse- geneous. This development requires a more open quences of this crisis, there is no longer a paradig- network-like model of regulation. Technologies matic market that can serve as model for a Euro- develop more within “ecosystems” of different pean policy of an economic dynamic. This, in my networks that allow for experimentation and do view, is due to the fact that the new market for not follow established paradigms of organisa- information services, in particular, is much more tion. The focus of the European project should no complex than the telecommunications market. longer be the super-state, but a more focal model The difficulties consist in the fact that these new that is meant to push the technological processes emerging markets do not follow a stable universal- of the future, i.e., nano-technology, smart energy ising trajectory. Universality - as an order building technologies, but also the ecological transforma- principle - may have had its time in general. The tion of agriculture, the future of ageing popula- new markets follow a more network-like experi- tions, ideas for rural development, etc. I think that mental path of trial and error upon the basis the ongoing economic and technological transfor- of complex knowledge that is difficult both to mation of postmodern societies is crucial for the access and to use in regulatory strategies. In such conception of a European constitutional order, a constellation, there is no single trajectory of as well: universality is no longer a guiding prin- development that is carved out by a central regu- ciple for the organisation of regulatory strategies latory agent upon the basis of technology and at the level of the nation state, nor for the manage- market observation. The difficulty is exacerbated ment of difficult economic questions. Regulation by the fact that Europe is weak in the develop- can only follow a trend towards differentiated ment of new computer technologies and software. “network governance”. And, more generally, one The “Lisbon Process” which should have brought might take the view that a model of a “consocia- Europe to the top of technological development tional governance” is necessary. That is to say, the has been a complete failure. This drawback finds organisation model can no longer be conceived as its repercussions in the missing knowledge base uniform and stable for every kind of market, but that can only be generated and understood in should get involved in regulatory strategies that

THE END OF THE UNIVERSALITY OF NORMS AS A MODEL FOR EUROPE: 237 THE ERROR OF “SEEING LIKE A STATE” (J.S. SCOTT) IN THE POSTMODERN CONDITION Karl-Heinz Ladeur rely more on a mixture of principles (“métissage”) 2. The Change of Political and for different types of governance according to Causalities within an the technology or the issue that is at stake. We need Incomplete Federal System more project-like regulatory strategies that are to be formulated by a limited number of Member All this demonstrates that the idea of a universal States according to their interests with differen- order for Europe - or even the world - that is tiated models of action involving private interest modelled on the example the traditional nation groups. Uniformity should not be imposed on state is outdated. A system like the EU that still Member States that do not consent to potential follows the “one size fits all” rule is doomed to fail. common strategies. Universality may work on paper, but, in reality, We need organisational strategies that experiment it deepens the cleavages within the EU. It even with the eclecticist “métissage” of components of creates a perverse expectation of a universal rule different, even contradictory, political reperto- that should guarantee equal outcome of different ries and the management of conflict of norms as a sovereign strategic action. One cannot take the response to the emergence of ill-structured social view that it is the construction of the EU that is and economic problems. A paradigm for the latter fine and that the problems are to be attributed is the Euro crisis. to the bad policies of Member States. Once a “union” has been established, a logic that distrib- Apart from creating worrying problems and the utes responsibility in a haphazard and irrational almost unmanageable complexity of an emer- way is unavoidable. Despite the different polit- gency regime (Joerges 2016) that has given enor- ical options left to the Member States, one can, mous power to the ECB, the Monetary Union has of course, demand a re-distribution of the profits also opened the Pandora’s box of a transfer union that have been collected unevenly by the Member which, to a certain extent, has to be accepted States. And this is what happens in the European by the northern states. At the same time, the debate. However, this will, of course, meet with the southern states should be more aware of the errors opposition of the richer Member States that will that they themselves have committed in the past: claim that their advantage is due to more intelli- The northern states (not just Germany) are more gent sovereign policy. The incomplete model of advanced because of the technological reform of the “union” changes the political causalities, which their production and organisation – it is not the leaves the hitherto established rationality of the myth of the (relative) social dumping of salaries. nation state behind without having the power to The limits to the conception of a universality of develop a new consistent pattern of the attribution rules and principles can also be observed in the of responsibilities that is characteristic for a federal field of regulation of other data-driven tech- state with its strong position of the federation. The nologies. Such a regulatory strategy can itself state of the “union” instead allows for a perverse only follow a model of “evolutive networks” combination of sovereignty and the claim for a (M. Amstutz). Under conditions of uncertainty, federalist responsibility for the negative conse- stable goals for the regulatory process can only quences of sovereign decision-making. Under the be formulated to a limited extent. Such a strategy present legal conditions, Member States cannot is useful in so far as certain risks can be analysed impose claims for a transfer union on opposing and described beforehand – and these are the risks Member States, although they can threaten to of the past. This is why, first of all, the internal “communitise” a factual risk by overburdening the risk management of firms (financial services in common monetary system even if they themselves particular) should be strengthened. will suffer from such a strategy more than other Member States (“raise your neighbours costs”). In

THE END OF THE UNIVERSALITY OF NORMS AS A MODEL FOR EUROPE: 238 THE ERROR OF “SEEING LIKE A STATE” (J.S. SCOTT) IN THE POSTMODERN CONDITION Karl-Heinz Ladeur my view, the change of political causalities is the modes of finding “arrangements” in late-night most devastating consequence of uniform law that bargaining processes. This development should touches Member States in increasingly divergent not just be reduced to a momentary difficulty. This modes. The implementation of norms needs, first is a symptom of a transformation that will not pass of all, a common idea of its social and technical away within a short lapse of time. It asks for a new pre-conditions, and, secondly, a common idea of strategy of a management of diversity also with the its implementation, one that is - at least in part EU. Moral appeals will not work. - generated in “real time” ex post. This approach demands a common knowledge base and an idea 4. The “Instituted” and the of shared political causalities. Causality in politics “Constituted Society” (V. does not mean an objective factual relationship Descombes) between input and output. Causalities are more or less social constructions that allow for variation Rather, the tenacity of “Seeing like a state” (J.S. and contestation, but they pre-suppose some form Scott) – as opposed to indulging in the observa- of consensus – which apparently does not exist tion of the fragmented realities of different socie- in many fields of European law. Uniform laws or ties with their own multiple histories that are full uniform strategies may even deepen the inequality of specific hidden intricacies of implicit social among the Member States. This is also true beyond norms, patterns of behaviour, forms of life, memo- economic policy: the German push for a (tempo- ries, etc., seems to determine the rationale of the rary) “refugees welcome” option probably gave EU. The facticity of social norms is characteristic the Brexit votes the one or two per cent that they for the “instituted society”, as opposed to the “cons- needed for their victory. The victory of the Polish tituted society” which is based upon explicit (legal) national-conservative party is also attributed to norms. This seems to be a productive distinction Angela Merkel’s refugee policy. that has been introduced by the French philoso- pher Vincent Descombes. 3. The Role of Social Norms The idea of progress leads to a superimposition as Opposed to Legal Rules of the forward looking “horizon of expectation” Becomes more Visible (“Erwartungshorizont”) on the backward looking “space of experience” (Reinhart Koselleck 2004)). The role of the social norms, the rules of action, Many of the conflicts over European “constitu- the patterns of “how things are done” (Charles tionalism” can be explained with a view to the Taylor 2004: 55), have all, from the outset, been dominance of the “Erwartungshorizont” of a new very different in the Member States, but, for a political constitution and the establishment of a rather long time, the market regimes have had new “constituted society”: the “Erwartungshori- the power to function as a kind of liberal consti- zont” can be broadened: it is already less certain tutionalism that has been able to impose a certain that one can give up the “Erfahrungsraum” of the level of uniformity and consensus on fragile nation state and, as a consequence, the nation- processes of compromise-finding (cf., gener- based society. However, the nation state cannot be ally, Joerges 2016). The rise of economic hetero- reduced to a nationalist ideology and state-based geneity among the Member States and the deep- constitution that can be given up or just fade away. ening of the differences of interests, for example, Pierre Manent (2008) has opposed “la raison des in the “refugee crisis”, while the markets them- nations” to the illusionary assumption that we have selves are increasingly fragmenting at the same just to expand the territorial base of the demo- time; the market regime and the universality of cratic state in order to regain its historical role rules in general have undermined the established as rule giving rational power. One might call this

THE END OF THE UNIVERSALITY OF NORMS AS A MODEL FOR EUROPE: 239 THE ERROR OF “SEEING LIKE A STATE” (J.S. SCOTT) IN THE POSTMODERN CONDITION Karl-Heinz Ladeur the “acquis étatique” that, according to observers (2016: 29 et seq.). The economic heterogeneity of such as Jürgen Habermas, can be and should be Europe is undeniable, but the normative idea of re-established in conditions of globalisation which the Eurocrats (including the majority of specialists undercut the state’s authority because of the split of European law) pre-supposes a smooth adapta- between its territorial limitation and the unlim- tion of weaker states to a more rational form of ited economic networks of transactions. Clearly, economic behaviour – naturally, with the benevo- Habermas (2011; and others) have a point, but it is lent help of the different “programmes” of the EU only one point (for critique cf. Grimm 2016). – this is their “Erwartungshorizont”. “La raison des nations”, in the sense of Pierre Manent (2008), is not to be interpreted as a 5. The Unavoidable nationalist idea that is focused on the nation as an Difference of European Law “imagined community” (Benedict Anderson) – a in Member States concept that is based upon the constructivist idea that societal imagination is mainly the product of One of the illusions of the “Eurocrats” – in this an intersubjective construction. Instead, it refers case, the term is legitimate – and of the special- to a deeper “social imaginary” that consists in the ists of European law is the assumption that Euro- mainly practical “repertory” of decision models, pean law is the same in all countries: equal law patterns of action, etc., in a society (Charles Taylor leads to equal conditions of life, at least in the long 2004) – the “instituted society”, as one may put it run. The possibility that equal law imposed under according to V. Descombes (2004). In the market unequal conditions of life can even deepen differ- related field of law, co-ordination is, to a certain ences is discarded. Countries such as Germany and extent, mainly managed by economic actors them- other “northerners” have reacted to the “uniform selves, be it spontaneously or via the mediation internal market” by modernising their formal and brought about by the lex mercatoria or other self- informal institutional rules (e.g., of industrial rela- organised private institutions. However, this looks tions). Countries such as France and Greece have completely different in fields where co-ordination reacted to pressure by expanding their civil service has to absorb and mitigate much more conflicts – financed by public debt. This has deepened the such as in industrial relations, administrative heterogeneity between the Member States, as we action, budgetary discipline, welfare practices, etc. can now observe. This would be an example for the In these domains, law - to a large extent - plays different “repertories” of political and economic a secondary role, as compared to societal norms action in Member States. and patterns of action. At the same time, the EU tries to impose a The “instituted society” is, in many respects, uniform rule of free movement of workers on all regarded by progressive political scientists as based Member States in spite of the fact that the social upon power relations – which is true. However, and economic situation is completely different this is not the whole story: it is also a network of in every Member State: just take the UK with its societal rules, life forms, patterns of action, which long history of different waves of immigration, or even left-wing political scientist should acknowl- Bulgaria, whose health system will be confronted edge as being characterised by different power rela- with a catastrophe in the near future if the emigra- tions according to “varieties of capitalism” (Peter tion of medical doctors and other qualified people A. Hall & David Soskice 2001). Clearly, variety continues at the present rate. One rule fits all? The matters! Astonishingly, in the controversy over the same is true for immigration. Can and should the EU, this matters only for (political) economists. “Eurocrats” just force citizens to accept immigra- In the “Eurocrats” book, this finds an expression tion according to the rules? Is “free movement in (political scientist) Fritz W. Scharpf’s analysis of workers” a dogma that can only be called into question by “exit”? Some Member States might be

THE END OF THE UNIVERSALITY OF NORMS AS A MODEL FOR EUROPE: 240 THE ERROR OF “SEEING LIKE A STATE” (J.S. SCOTT) IN THE POSTMODERN CONDITION Karl-Heinz Ladeur willing to follow the British example in the future. At present, the situation in the UK is difficult to handle – much more so than the Brexiteers could ever have imagined. Immigration is different in all Member States, in spite of uniform laws. Shouldn’t we think about just adapting the law to different social constellations? We should think about more heterogeneity!

6. The Exhaustion of the Simple Market Regime and the Need for New Ideas for the EU

One may criticise the early market orientation (“Ordnungspolitik”) or the rise of diverse regula- tory approaches as being too technocratic and not open to democratic deliberation. However, there was still room for deliberation at a meta-level about alternatives. At the same time, the market regime has at least worked satisfactorily to bring about a certain level of uniformity, and it has, in a way, established some kind of political integra- tion as a side-effect. It has limited the effects of the divergence of the European law at Member State level. It has always been an illusion that the EU suffers from a “democratic deficit”. It has been the strength of the EU that it was not supposed to be a super-state. Deliberation alone, that is, without a common “political grammar” (de Ligio 2018), without a common cause, will not compensate for the lack of a common project, and, at the same time, a sense of shared practical life-forms. The emergence of more heterogeneity by the new tech- nological and economic dynamic and other ill- structured problems of postmodernity such as the immigration problems, clearly do not lend them- selves to solutions based upon uniform, universal rules. The introduction of EMU, in particular, has completely changed the game: the EU is just stuck in a stalemate, it cannot go on forwards towards more integration (it would be a complete illusion that the treaties can be changed in this respect – and although this could work as an institutional solution), and it cannot stay where it stands. The only possibility that might open a new perspective is, as a consequence, to take a step back.

THE END OF THE UNIVERSALITY OF NORMS AS A MODEL FOR EUROPE: 241 THE ERROR OF “SEEING LIKE A STATE” (J.S. SCOTT) IN THE POSTMODERN CONDITION Karl-Heinz Ladeur Bibliography: European Diversity, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 29-49. Amstutz, Marc (2001), Evolutorisches Wirtschafts- Taylor, Charles (2004), Modern Social Imaginaries, recht: Vorstudien zum Recht und seiner Methode Durham NC: Duke Univerity Press. in den Diskurskollisionen der Marktgesellschaft, Baden-Baden: Nomos. Descombes, Vincent (2004), Le complément de sujet, Paris: Gallimard. Grimm, Dieter (2016), Europa ja, aber welches? Zur Verfassung der europäischen Demokratie, Munich: Beck. Habermas, Jürgen (2011), Zur Verfassung Europas: Ein Essay, Berlin: Suhrkamp. Hall, Peter A., and David Soskice (2001), Vari- eties of Capitalism: The Institutional Founda- tion of Comparative Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Joerges, Christian (2016): “Integration Through Law and the Crisis of Law in Europe’s Emer- gency”, in: Markus Jachtenfuchs, Damian Chalmers and Christian Joerges (eds), The End of the Eurocrats’ Dream: Adjusting to European Diversity, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 299-338. Koselleck, Reinhart (2004), Futures Past: On the Semantics of Historical Time, New York: Columbia University Press. Ligio, Giulio de (2018), “Indétermination et stéri- lité dans la démocratie post-totalitaire”, Le Philosophoire 2018, Nr. 49, 261-291. Manent, Pierre (2008), La raison des nations. Enquête sur la souveraineté nationale et les fondements de la démocratie, Paris: Gallimard. Möllers, Christoph (2015), “Krisenzurechnung und Legitimationsproblematik in der Europäi- schen Union”, Leviathan 43, 339-364. Reiling, Katharina (2016), Der Hybride. Administ- rative Wissensorganisation im privaten Bereich, Tübingen: Mohr. Scharpf, Fritz W. (2016), “The Costs of (Non-) Disintegration: The Case of the European Monetary Union”, in: Markus Jachtenfuchs, Damian Chalmers and Christian Joerges (eds.), The End of the Eurocrats’ Dream: Adjusting to

THE END OF THE UNIVERSALITY OF NORMS AS A MODEL FOR EUROPE: 242 THE ERROR OF “SEEING LIKE A STATE” (J.S. SCOTT) IN THE POSTMODERN CONDITION Karl-Heinz Ladeur F JUSTICE DEFICITS AND SOLIDARITY IS THE EU UNJUST? eignty or that the EU was insufficiently demo- cratic. The argument that the EU is fundamentally Glyn Morgan unjust is quite new. (Collegio Carlo Alberto, Torino, and Maxwell Any adequate response to claims about the EU’s School, Syracuse University) alleged injustice requires, I think, a two-fold stra- tegy. First, it is necessary to provide some justi- Fans of the EU often forget that the single market fication for the project of European integration is basically just Thatcherism on a continental scale (Why bother? Why not get rid of it in favour of a …. It was built by business, for business. Europe of sovereign nation states, as Brexiters and The best trick the Commission ever played was to Italian populists demand?) Second, it is necessary convince the easily led that the EU is an avatar for to justify a conception of justice within the EU. diversity, multiculturalism, inclusion and all those In an earlier work, I tried to justify the project of fluffy things that appeal to „progressives.“ European integration in terms of a conception of In fact the Commission … realised that those security (Morgan 2005). The point or purpose of same „progressives“ are almost all middle class, the EU, so I argued, is to make its members more and therefore neatly aligned with the interests of secure, less exposed to domestic and international big business (being as they are far bigger benefi- threats to the basic liberal values that define the ciaries of it than the working class). European way of life. In that work, I didn’t have much to say about the distributive consequences The real losers every single time are the worst of the project of European integration. Nor did off, and of course the countries who lose all of I have anything to say about the duties owed to their young (Poland, Romania, Portugal etc). It‘s people who might be wrongfully harmed (if indeed a genuine disgrace, and every EUphile on here there are such people) in the course of the Euro- abusing Brexiters as racists, bigoted etc are a big pean project. To address these issues, a concep- part of the problem. tion of justice that includes both distributive and “CodeIs4500” [Random anti-EU leftist Guardian rectificatory components is needed. In this paper, Commentator] I want to summarize part of an argument that addresses the “justice deficit,” as it has been called, In recent years, Eurosceptics have voiced a new of my earlier argument (de Burca, 2015). type of argument against the EU: it’s unjust. The project of European Integration benefits My paper proceeds in two sections. Section One the wealthy at the expense of the poor, business restates and updates my earlier argument that the at the expense of labour, liberal cosmopolitans principal justification of the project of European at the expense of conservative nationalists, the integration is to deliver security for its members. Northern European countries at the expense of The EU, I argue, is first and foremost a security the South, and the Western European countries to project; the effort to construct a Single Market the detriment of the East. The angry post above regulated by an overarching legal and regulatory (from somebody called CodeIs4500) contains the system is secondary — a means -- to that end. In essence of this criticism. order to realize this security project, the EU needs greater state capacity. Section Two examines one The claim that the EU is unjust – a claim that could argument—that of John Rawls—in support of be heard throughout the Eurozone Crisis, the the claim that a Federal Europe (the very type of Brexit debate, and the recent Italian elections— Europe needed, I think, to deliver for its members marks a shift in the focus of Eurosceptics. The security) is incompatible with justice. traditional complaint of such people was either that the EU was incompatible with national sover-

IS THE EU UNJUST? 244 Glyn Morgan I ming regulatory system.258 Others think that the point and purpose of the EU is and ought to be to The modern history of Europe is a history of rescue the European welfare state. It is impossible violent conflict and war. Wars of plunder and mili- to draw a normatively compelling justification of tary glory; wars of dynastic succession; religious the European project out of this contested history. wars; imperial wars; vastly destructive industrial Not only did different states--and political actors wars; genocidal wars; wars that lasted one hundred within those states--have different goals in mind years: Europe has seen them all. And then war (Lacroix and Nicolaides 2012). But these goals stopped--at least on a large scale. One reason, changed over time. It’s a social scientific fallacy to although certainly not the only one, is European think that the factors decisive in the formation of integration. The EU was initially envisaged by its a phenomenon in one period must be decisive in Founding Fathers as a Peace Project in the tradi- another. tion of Abbe de Saint Pierre and others (Bideleux, Notwithstanding the contested nature of the Euro- 2012). The very structure of the EU – Council, pean project, we have to recognize the salient role Commission, Court, etc.— was taken over from played by economic processes in driving this the League of Nations, which Jean Monnet served project forward. But again merely because the EU in the inter-war period as Deputy Secretary relied upon the spill-overs from different forms General. Even the decision in the post-war era to of economic integration, we should still leave focus the initial steps of European integration on open a space for a normative argument that chal- a Coal and Steel agreement were done with a view lenges the salience of this way of making Europe. to controlling the raw materials that might fuel Perhaps the process of European integration—i.e. a military arms race. It’s certainly true that after the mechanism of European Union formation— the failure of the Pleven Plan and the European ought to be turned over to Europe’s citizens, orga- Defence Community in 1952, the history of Euro- nized as a bottom-up, grass-roots movement. One pean integration set in motion by the Schuman of the dangers the EU currently faces is that it is Plan (ratified in 1957 in the Treaty of Rome) has so closely tied to the Euro and to the laws gover- been primarily a history of economic integration. ning the Single Market that any threat to the latter But it is important not to lose sight of this alter- endangers the former. In short, we can disagree native track—call it the peace or security track— both about the project of European integration which, even if it has played a secondary role, has (what is its telos?) and the process of European inte- never wholly disappeared and resurfaces in such gration (how much should we rely upon economic institutions and policies as the European External processes?) Action Service, the Common Foreign and Secu- rity Policy, and even the Galileo Project. So far as the telos of the European project is concerned, it is certainly possible to view Euro- From an analytical point of view, it is helpful to pean integration as a peace project. But peace as a have available some categories that allow us to normative value has some significant drawbacks. approach the EU as a contested project. People The trouble with peace is that it can be achieved at disagree about the importance—both historically the price of independence and influence. Liechten- and normatively—of the economic and peace or stein is small, peaceful and without any influence security tracks. Likewise, they disagree—again in the wider world. Europe (whether measured in both historically and normatively—about the terms of the EU or the Council of Europe) has a process by and through which the post-war project of European integration has (and can) come about. 258 The Single European Act of 1986 was primarily the Some maintain that the point and purpose of the creation of Mrs Thatcher’s neo-liberal trade expert, Arthur EU is and ought to be to produce a market-confor- Cockfield, who was Vice President of the European Commis- sion from 1985-1989.

IS THE EU UNJUST? 245 Glyn Morgan population and GDP larger than the United States. security is perfectly sensible so far as it goes. But For Europe to go the same way as Liechtenstein it doesn’t tell us enough about the form of secu- would be a betrayal of, what Max Weber had in rity worth possessing. Here I can do no more than mind, when he spoke of the responsibility of a stipulate a position that draws upon the type of great power (Weber 1994 [1916]).259 security that people today enjoy in Europe. Euro- Embedded in the public culture and shared pean security has, I think, five dimensions. We history of Europe—embedded in the lifeworld, are only full secure when all five dimensions are as it were--is a conception of itself as one of the present. great world Civilizations, a repository of unmat- 1. An individual is secure when he or ched culture and learning, a distinctive and most she enjoys an adequate range of personal pleasing way of being in the world. At the core of and political rights necessary for liberal the European way of life lies a set of fundamental democratic citizenship; and universal values, which are nicely captured by 2. An individual is secure when he or Article 2 of the Treaty of European Union: she has the opportunity to acquire wealth The Union is founded on the values of respect for (which I understand in the Smithian sense human dignity, freedom, democracy, equality, the of “the necessaries and conveniences of rule of law, and respect for human rights, including life”) through the sale of his or her labour, the rights of persons belonging to minorities. skills, property, and/or products in a well- I mention the idea of Europe as a Civilizational ordered market economy; power that possesses a distinctive way of life not 3. An individual is secure, when he because I think that this settles anything norma- or she is guaranteed an adequate level of tively, but because it provides the ideational social welfare (including access to health framework that any justification for the project of care, housing, and pensions), which can European integration must incorporate—at least be relied upon to compensate for the if it is to have any persuasive purchase. Partly for uncertain rewards of the market economy; this reason, I think it is better to conceptualize the 4. An individual is secure when he or she project of European integration less in terms of has adequate safeguards against violence, peace than in terms of security, which envisages whether from individuals, criminal gangs, an altogether more active role in the creation and terrorists, officers of his or her own state, maintenance of peaceful global relations. and foreign powers; Security is, as John Stuart Mill noted, the most 5. An individual is secure, only when fundamental and universal of all individual human he or she is not dependent on an arbitrary interests. Without security, individuals can’t enjoy public or private power. any other pleasure (Mill 1860). Mill’s claim about This barebones account of security begs a lot of 259 Weber was, of course, especially in this questions, including what counts as adequate in period, a German nationalist. It is, however, (1. ), (2.), (3.), and (4.). But probably the most possible to reject the nationalist reasons Weber controversial of these five dimensions is the last himself relied upon to justify Germany’s world one. (5.) In some respects, this injunction against historical role, while accepting that “good states” arbitrary power is merely a corollary of the first with the potential to become great powers ought one (1). But (5.) goes a lot further than (1) in to become so—especially if the alternative is for recognizing that an adequate range of domestic “bad states” to be the only great powers in the rights might itself prove insufficient protection international system. For a discussion of this against threats to security arising from internati- point, see (Morgan 2018b).

IS THE EU UNJUST? 246 Glyn Morgan onal society (including foreign powers, whether is roughly equivalent to a US Constitution that enemies or allies.) In other words, we need, as would allow the 50 state governors the right to neo-Republicans like Philip Pettit argue, “a certain veto US foreign and defence policy. independence in relation to the state; … control of If the EU is to provide Europeans with an adequate its doings in such a way that [we] are not unpro- level of security, the EU needs to acquire greater tected in relation to imperium or public power” state capacity. This is no easy task. I conclude (Pettit 2014, p.77). Yet, as Pettit and other neo- this section with a couple of remarks about state republicans neglect to mention, it’s not just our capacity. own state that we need a certain independence from; we also need to avoid dependence upon The modern state—first conceptualized in the foreign states—including our nominal allies who seventeenth century by Thomas Hobbes, albeit have very different agendas from our own, whose a long time before it actually existed in modern reliability is questionable, leadership erratic, and Europe—has two components that together prone to swing wildly between isolationism and constitute a form of impersonal public power: (i) adventurism. a system of representation; and (ii) a system of administrative infrastructure. Notwithstanding the underspecified account given here of security, I want to argue—or, so far (i) The system of representation allows as the present paper goes, stipulate—that a Euro- the modern state to legitimate itself by way pean polity (whether a Europe of nation-states, of a myth that the people (the represented) an Intergovernmental Europe, a more central- are themselves the authors of everything ized Federal Europe) that provides security for the state does—it acts in their name. If a its members thereby constitutes “a Good Polity;” state cannot successfully deploy this myth, conversely “a Bad Polity” fails to provide secu- then it is in trouble. State capacity is thus rity for its members. By the same token, I want to partly a function of the ability to deploy argue that members of a Good Polity have duties the myth of popular representation. to each other to support and sustain the condi- (ii) The system of administrative tions of security. infrastructure allows the state to structure One of the great weaknesses of the EU in its current the lives of the people that fall within form is that it lacks any capacity to play anything its boundaries. An administrative other than a subaltern role in international affairs. infrastructure includes inter alia a public European states depend for their security on an bureaucracy capable of extracting revenue, asymmetrical military alliance funded largely by a system of laws and regulations, and some an increasingly reluctant United States. It is widely enforcement agencies. accepted that the European states need to spend Whether we are referring to (i) or (ii), the EU in its a lot more on their defense capabilities. It is less present form is weak—indeed, it is so weak that no widely noted that no matter how much money one could sensibly describe the EU as a modern European states devote to this task, the EU is state (Morgan 2018a). The EU’s system of repre- unlikely to be able to play much of an indepen- sentation allows only for a mediated form of citi- dent role in global affairs without centralizing its zenship. The EU Constitution recognizes as the foreign, security, and defense policy. The Euro- EU’s component entities member states and indi- pean level of government is in charge of Europe’s viduals. We are members of the European Union, Agricultural Policy, its Foreign External Trade only insofar as we are citizens of a Member State. Policy, and (at least for Eurozone countries) its This point is further confirmed by the nature of Monetary Policy. Foreign and defense policy is civic identification within the EU. Most people in largely decentralized to 27 member states. This

IS THE EU UNJUST? 247 Glyn Morgan most member states think of themselves first and of economic growth, onwards and upwards, with foremost as nationals (French, German, Italian no specific end in sight, fits this class perfectly. If etc.) and only secondarily as Europeans. A lot they speak about distribution, it is [al]most always could be said about the conditions conducive for in terms of trickle down. The long–term result of greater form EU civic identification. But clearly this — which we already have in the United States one condition not conducive is a widespread belief — is a civil society awash in a meaningless consu- that the EU in its present form is unjust. merism of some kind. I can’t believe that that is what you want. (Van Parijs, 2003; Morgan 2008). II Although expressed in a personal exchange of letters rather than as a considered philosophical One of John Rawls’s most distinctive contribu- position, Rawls’s judgement is fully compatible tions to political theory is the argument that diffe- with the basic idea that the European Union—a rent principles of justice apply to different social Union of different nation-states—is one thing; the and institutional arrangements (Ronzoni, 2009, United States, a Federal Union, is another. The Sangiovanni 2013). As Rawls put is, “the correct sting in this observation is the suggestion that regulative principle for a thing depends on the if the EU were to move in a Federal direction— nature of that thing (Rawls 1999, 25).” This basic to become, in short, a Federal Union--it would idea forms one of the grounds of Rawls’s contro- acquire the deficiencies, the forms of injustice, versial approach to global justice. We owe a lot that we see in the United States. Rawls’s claim here more to our fellow citizens--indeed, we owe certainly does not exhaust the repertoire of those them duties of distributive justice—than we do who allege EU’s injustice, whether actual or poten- to foreigners (no matter how poor they might tial. But it’s an important argument—echoed in be). Our thing is not, as it were, their thing. This some respects by Wolfgang Streeck (Streeck 2015) position also helps explain Rawls’s surprisingly and other Eurosceptics--and deserves a response. Eurosceptic position on the European Union. In a passage that CodeIs4500 might well have been Viewed more closely, Rawls’s argument about the proud to have authored himself, Rawls writes (in a EU seems to have not two things in mind-- the letter to Philippe Van Parijs) nation-state and the Federal Union--but four or even five different things: One question the Europeans should ask them- selves, if I may hazard a suggestion, is how far– • (i) the European nation-state as it now is; reaching they want their union to be. It seems to • (ii) the EU as it now is (call it an me that much would be lost if the European union Intergovernmental Europe); became a federal union like the United States. Here there is a common language of political discourse • (iii) the EU as Rawls fears it might become and a ready willingness to move from one state to (call it a Bad Federal Europe); another. Isn’t there a conflict between a large free • (iv) the US as a Federal Union (also Bad); and open market comprising all of Europe and the individual nation-states, each with its separate And lurking in the background—although not political and social institutions, historical memo- specifically mentioned by Rawls--there is: ries, and forms and traditions of social policy. • (v) A Good Federal Europe Surely these are great value to the citizens of these countries and give meaning to their life. The large The position that Rawls wishes to defend with open market including all of Europe is [the] aim respect to the EU might be elaborated as follows: of the large banks and the capitalist business class • (a) We owe duties of distributive justice only whose main goal is simply larger profit. The idea (or primarily) to fellow citizens (i.e. members of our nation-state);

IS THE EU UNJUST? 248 Glyn Morgan • (b) The European nation-state is good insofar European level of governance, it might be as it sustains duties of justice; argued that an Intergovernmental Europe is inherently flawed and beyond reform. And either Streeck (2014, 2015, 2016) comes close • (c) The current Intergovernmental Europe to holding this position. Many Brexiters is good, because it supports and sustains the draw the same conclusion. Yet rather than good European nation-state (b); drawing the conclusion that the flaws of an Intergovernmental Europe justify a Or regression to a Europe of independent • (d) A reformed Intergovernmental Europe is sovereign nation-states, it would be good, insofar as it can support and sustain the possible to accept the premise but draw good European nation-state (b);260 the conclusion that an Intergovernmental Europe must be replaced by a Federal • (e) An Intergovernmental Europe—whether Europe—ideally a Good Federal Europe (c) or (d) -- is durable in the face of shifting (g). In other words, Eurosceptics and global power relations; Federalists could find common cause in • (f) Any attempt to turn an Intergovernmental their misgivings about Intergovernmental Europe into a fully-fledged Federal Europe Europe (whether actual or reformed), but will lead to a Bad Federal Europe (i.e. a Europe hold very different views of the type of where neither the nation-state nor the Federal polity that ought to replace it. Federalists level of government will be able to sustain must then then find some way of denying duties of distributive justice). (f) and (g). Of course, the Federalist argument raises various difficult questions • (g) There is no realistic possibility of a Good about feasibility. But there is no obvious Federal Europe (i.e. a Europe whose members reason why Rawls must reject the very sustain duties of justice). idea of a long-term progression towards If this argument were to go through, then Rawls a European level of government with the would have a convincing argument against the kinds of social interaction and cultural project of European integration. similarity sufficient to sustain duties of justice. Indeed, Rawls himself allows that There are, I think, four different (although not “relations of affinity are not a fixed thing, mutually exclusive) ways of responding to an but may continually grow stronger over argument of this type. time as people come to work together in Counterargument One—reject (a). This is cooperative institutions” (Rawls, 1999, the move of liberal cosmopolitans (Caney 112).261 2001, 2005). I do not discuss this move here. Instead I will assume that (a) is, for 261 Although I can’t pursue the argument here in the length one reason or another, valid. I will also, for that it needs, a similar type of counterargument might be made against Sangiovanni’s rich and nuanced argument concerning the sake of argument, accept (b) the status of the current institutional arrangements of Europe Counterargument Two—reject (c) and (d). (Sangiovanni 2013). Yes, it might be said, the EU in its present form sustains different kinds of social interactions. Yes, they Against the claim that the EU in its present are at present denser, richer, and so forth at the national rather form either currently constitutes (or than the European level. But there is no obvious reason why can be reformed to produce) a desirable this current arrangement cannot (and ought not) change. If I am right about the non-sustainability of this current arrange- balance between the nation-state and the ment; if, in other words, I am right to think that even a refor- 260 This is the position, I think, that Sangiovanni (2013) med Intergovernmental Europe is incompatible with security defends. For him, the central task of a normative theory of the (as I have defined it), then it would be better to replace this EU is to justify a fair distribution among member states of the type of Europe with (what I have called) a Good Federal Euro- collective goods that an Intergovernmental Europe produces. pe.

IS THE EU UNJUST? 249 Glyn Morgan Counterargument Three—reject (e). An this gap by assuming greater state capacity. alternative route to the same conclusion This will likely entail a transition towards a reached in Counterargument Two is more Federal Union. If my argument here to focus attention on (e), the more is correct then we must reject the idea of an or less unstated assumption that an Intergovernmental Europe as a stable and Intergovernmental Europe is sustainable in secure place. We must by extension reject the face of shifting global power relations. (c) and (d). This assumption is highly debateable, not Counterargument Four -- reject (f) least because of some of the problems that and (g). In rejecting (e), we are left Rawls’s own argument against European with the dystopian possibility that an integration mentions. The US is, in his Intergovernmental Europe (whether account, a Bad Federal Union, which actual or reformed) is unstable in the face lacks a fair distribution of goods and is of shifting global power relations and awash in “meaningless consumerism.” If its alternative—some form of a Federal those terms exhausted its predicates, then Union—is incapable of sustaining the Europe could ignore the United States. The duties of distributive justice to qualify it trouble for Europe is that the United States as a Good Federal Europe. Are there any is a hegemon, the bulwark of the global grounds to reject (f) and (g)? liberal order, and an asymmetrical supplier of Europe’s security. More than this, the US This brings me to my (unfortunately rather incon- variety of capitalism has deeply penetrated clusive) concluding point. European societies, whose individual A Federal European Union will mark a funda- governments are relatively powerless mentally different type of polity from the modern whether in conflicts with the largest US democratic nation-state. It will probably be as diffe- tech. companies or the US state.262 The rent from the nation-state as was the nation-state notion that individual European states can from the early modern dynastic kingdom. If we gain leverage against this concentrated accept the Rawlsian argument that different types form of power is a fallacy--call it the of political association have different regulatory Brexiters’ fallacy. It is only by acting as a principles, then we can infer that a Federal Euro- unitary actor--as happens when the EU’s pean Union will have different regulatory princi- Trade Commission acts--that Europeans ples than the nation-state. I have argued in this have any leverage at all. paper that in order for a Federal European Union The difficulty for an Intergovernmental to account as a good polity is must guarantee its Europe comes when the United States, its members security. Members of such a polity owe protector, becomes unwilling to supply each other the duty to guarantee the conditions of the collective good of European security, security. This duty will have distributive implica- a good for which the United States pays tions, but different distributive implications than a disproportionate amount of the cost. I within a nation-state. argued earlier that the EU could only fill In the long transition to a Federal Europe—in all likelihood, a multigenerational project—Europe 262 One can gain some sense of the scale of Europe’s will experience many different challenges to the problem here, when one realizes that the market cap of the top four US internet companies (Google, Apple, Amazon, and changes underway. From the point of normative Facebook) are roughly 3 trillion dollars—larger than every political theory, I doubt that any grand theory can European member state other than Germany and 60 times be of much help here, not least because normative greater than the combined value of Europe’s top four internet companies (Spotify, Adyen, Zalando, Asos). arguments need to be pitched at a level of comple-

IS THE EU UNJUST? 250 Glyn Morgan xity not too far above the grasp of ordinary citi- zens. Among the different challenges that will likely need to be addressed are the following. 1. Some people contend that the European project embodies a distinctively liberal way of life hostile to traditional forms of religion and ethnic conceptions of belonging. 2. The challenge from people who seek to secede from a European member state or seek a form of representation within Federal Europe commensurate with that of a member state. We are already seeing demands of this sort, first in in 2014 and more recently in Catalonia. 3. The challenge from people demanding restrictions on freedom of movement, both within Europe and from outside. This challenge raises the broader question of how far a Federal Europe based on the primary good of security must involve itself in the internal affairs of neighbouring countries in, say, Northern Africa and the Middle East. 4. The challenge from people who contend that the EU’s current economic architecture is unfair. In recent years, the central complaint of this nature has arisen in the context of the Eurozone Crisis. 5. A final challenge to consider concerns the range of acceptable ways that a Federal Europe might deploy its trade regulations. In the context of the Brexit debate, a common argument made by Brexiters is that the EU has “bullied” the UK and in its Withdrawal Agreement is imposing a range of so-called Level Playing Field Conditions that will reduce the UK to “a vassal state” (Morgan 2018b).

IS THE EU UNJUST? 251 Glyn Morgan Bibliography Columbia University Press. Rawls, John. 1999. The Law of Peoples. Cambridge, Bideleux, Robert. 2012. “European Integration: Mass.: Harvard University Press. The Rescue of the Nation-State,” Dan Stone ed., The Oxford Handbook of Postwar European Ronzoni, Miriam, 2009. “The Global Order: A History. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Case of Background Injustice,” Philosophy and Public Affairs 37: 229-256. Caney Simon. 2005. Justice Beyond Borders: A Global Political Theory. Oxford: Oxford Univer- Sangiovanni, Andrea. 2013. “Solidarity in the sity Press. European Union,” Oxford Journal of Legal Studies 33. 213-241. Caney, Simon. 2001. “International Distributive Justice” Political Studies. 49: 974-997. Streeck, W. (2013) ‘Vom DM-Nationalismus zum Euro-Patriotismus? Eine Replik auf Jürgen De Burca, Grainne, et al eds. (2013), Europe’s Habermas’s’, Blätter für deutsche und internati- Justice Deficit, Oxford: Hart onale Politik 58(9): 75–92. Habermas, Jurgen. 2013. “Democracy, Solidarity, Streeck, W. (2014) “‘Small-state nostalgia? The and the European Crisis,” Social Europe 7 May. currency union, Germany, and Europe: A reply Mill, John Stuart 1861, “Utilitarianism,” Collected to Jürgen Habermas,” Constellations 21(2): Works of John Stuart Mill Volume 10 Toronto: 213–221. University of Toronto Press. Streeck, W. (2015) ‘Why the Euro divides Europe’, Morgan, Glyn. 2005. The Idea of a European Super- New Left Review 95 (September/October state: Public Justification and European Integra- 2015): 5–26. tion. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Streeck W. (2017). “What about Capitalism? Jürgen Morgan, Glyn. 2008. “John Rawls: Euro- Habermas’s Project of a European Democracy,” sceptic? European Integration as a Realistic european political science: 16 Utopia” http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers. Van Parijs, Phillipe (and John Rawls). 2003. “Three cfm?abstract_id=1113223 Letters on “Law of Peoples” and the Euro- Morgan, Glyn. 2018a. “Alexis de Tocqueville, pean Union,” https://cdn.uclouvain.be/public/ The Modern Democratic Nation State, and Its Exports%20reddot/etes/documents/Rawls- Competitors.” The Tocqueville Review VanParijs1.Rev.phil.Econ.pdf https://www.academia.edu/36790198/Alexis_ Weber, Max. 1994 [1916]. “Between Two Laws,” de_Tocqueville_the_Modern_Democratic_ in Peter Lassman ed., Max Weber: Political Nation-State_and_Its_Competitors Writings, Cambridge: Cambridge University Morgan, Glyn. 2018b. “On Brexit, Citizenship and Press. Vassal States.” https://www.academia.edu/37316827/On_Brexit_ Citizenship_and_Vassal_States Pettit, Philip. 2014. Just Freedom. New York: W. W. Norton and Co. Rawls, John. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Rawls, John. 1993. Political Liberalism. New York:

IS THE EU UNJUST? 252 Glyn Morgan A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF to provide the euro area with more fiscal policy ECONOMY AND FINANCE: competences cannot be separated from the ques- tions of which institution(s) should exercise them. ASSESSING THE Secondly, the position of two large Member States COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL (MS) – Germany and Italy – that are founding AND COMPARING THE members of the EU and have followed all the steps POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND of integration taken to date, is key to any attempt to reform the euro area. When dealing with EU ITALY reform proposals, the literature tends to focus on the contraposition between Germany and France. Tiziano Zgaga Thirdly, Germany and Italy are of particular Luiss, Rome interest because they developed a different reading of the euro crisis. The timeframe of the analysis Introduction goes from when the idea of an EMEF first emerged to the positions of the current German and Italian The following paper deals with the proposal to governments. provide the EU with a European Minister for the Economy and Finance (EMEF). The EMEF is part 1. The Proposal for a of the long debate on granting the EU more powers European Minister of Economy 263 on fiscal policy, thus aligning integration to the and Finance level that has been reached in monetary policy. To complete the economic side of the Economic and The EMU launched in the Maastricht Treaty (MT, Monetary Union (EMU) raises the issue on which 1992) foresaw full delegation of monetary policy institution(s) should be involved in this process. to the European Central Bank (ECB). No corre- The paper focuses on the proposal, put forward by sponding supranational institution was estab- the European Commission in December 2017, to lished for fiscal policy, which was kept in the hands create an EMEF. of the MS. The new policy regime was thus born The paper aims to answer two research questions: incomplete, because the euro area had – and still 1) How to assess the Commission’s proposal for an has – one single monetary policy and 19 different EMEF?; and 2) What is the position of Germany fiscal policies. The EU has only a small budget and Italy on this proposal? The paper is divided with comparatively few resources (De Feo 2017). as follows. The first section re-constructs when Because of this, it is prevented from adopting the discussion about an EMEF was first launched, counter-cyclical policies during times of crisis which actors pushed it ahead, and how the 2017 and, more generally, from fostering public goods European Commission’s proposal finally came that benefit all the MS. European institutions do out. The second section presents the Commis- not have the power or the means to exert a stabili- sion’s proposal and the third section evaluates it. sation function (De Grauwe 2014). The fourth section analyses Germany’s position, This is why it has repeatedly been argued that the while the fifth section does the same for Italy. The EU needs to become a fiscal union.264 Fiscal unions sixth section assesses the position of the two coun- can vary according to the tools and competences tries. The last section concludes. that are assigned to the centre. They can display There are at least three reasons why these research different kinds of fiscal capacity. The fiscal power questions are important. Firstly, the debate on how 264 The term “union” refers to a certain relationship that territorial entities (usually states) establish among themselves 263 For the sake of brevity, in the paper, I often use the ex- on the basis of an agreement. Unions have a centre and some pression “fiscal policy” to refer to “fiscal and budgetary policy”. constitutive units (states).

A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF ECONOMY AND FINANCE: 253 ASSESSING THE COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL AND COMPARING THE POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND ITALY Tiziano Zgaga of the centre may consist in regulating the fiscal member of the Commission (one of its Vice-pres- policy of the units (as is the case of the EU) or in idents) and the President of the Eurogroup. More- managing a budget made up of own resources. over, he or she would have a second intergovern- mental role as chair of the Board of Governors of Here is where the debate on the EMEF comes in. 266 The rationale is to create an institution that could the European Stability Mechanism (ESM). manage the EU budget in a more efficient way. The The Commission stressed that political account- proposal for an EMEF goes hand in hand with the ability would be established between the EMEF reform of the EU budget. The debate on an EMEF and the European Parliament (EP). The EMEF gained momentum with the so-called “Five Presi- would be subject to the same provisions foreseen dent’s Report” in 2015, in which the Commission for the Commission. Regarding appointment, called for a stronger president of the Eurogroup, starting with the 2014 EP elections, the Spitzen- taking into account the possibility of making him kandidaten267 system applies. The EP has to grant or her a full-time president with a clear mandate, a vote of consent to the President of the Commis- inter alia representing the euro area on the global sion, to the High Representative of the Union stage (European Commission 2015). for Foreign Affairs and Security Policy (HR)268 In May 2017, the Commission published a “Reflec- and to the other commissioners. After obtaining tion Paper on the Deepening of the Economic and the consent, the European Council appoints the Commission by qualified majority (TEU, Art. Monetary Union”. It discussed the possibility of a 269 “full-time permanent chair” (European Commis- 17.7). As for dismissal, the EP can also approve sion 2017a: 27) of the Eurogroup and of merging it a motion of censure that forces the Commission as with the Commissioner for Economic and Mone- a whole, including the HR, to resign. The duty to tary Affairs and the euro. The paper then deals with resign also occurs by request of the Commission’s a euro area Treasury that “could be placed under President (ibid., Art. 17.6c). the responsibility of an EU Finance Minister, who Accountability of the EMEF towards the EP would would also be Chair of the Eurogroup/ECOFIN” take place through so-called economic dialogues (ibid., p. 28). envisaged by EU legislation,270 which may also The debate around the EMEF intensified in 2017, involve hearings in front of the EP. In addition and in December the Commission put its first to this, “national Parliaments could request the proposal into concrete terms. 266 The ESM is an intergovernmental institution that grants financial assistance to MS in crisis provided they “implement tough reform programmes” (ESM.eu). Currently, 2. The Commission’s Proposal the President of the Eurogroup chairs the ESM. for an EMEF 267 When proposing a candidate to the EP, the European Council must take into account the results of the EP elections. On 6 December 2017, the Commission outlined Every party presents its candidate for the role of President of the Commission. The European Council must then propose to the rationale, the appointment and the tasks of the the EP the candidate of the party that got most votes (seats). EMEF (European Commission 2017b). First and 268 The HR is Vice-President of the Commission. foremost, it specified that the creation of the EMEF 269 In order to be approved, the motion of censure needs would not require amendments to the European “a two-thirds of the votes cast, representing a majority of the component members of the European Parliament” (TFEU, Art. treaties. The treaties already allow the Eurogroup 234). 265 to elect a president. The EMEF would be both a 270 The Six Pack (five regulations and one directive), approved in 2011, states that the EP can start an economic 265 See Art. 2 of the Protocol Nr. 14 on the Eurogroup. dialogue with other EU institutions (i.e. including single com- This has been interpreted as if the president should be elected missioners) on the prevention (Reg. 1174/2011), the surveil- among its members, i.e. should be a national minister of lance (Reg. 1175/2011) and the correction (Reg. 1176/2011) finance. However, according to the Commission, this is part of of excessive macroeconomic imbalances. The EMEF would the informally agreed working methods of the institution and interact on a regular basis not only with the EP but also with could be changed by simple majority. national Parliaments.

A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF ECONOMY AND FINANCE: 254 ASSESSING THE COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL AND COMPARING THE POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND ITALY Tiziano Zgaga Minister to present the Commission opinion on The merger between the figure of Vice-President the respective Draft Budgetary Plan to them” of the Commission and President of the Euro- (European Commission 2017b: 7). group is meant to assure the organic represen- As the EMEF would be part of both a supranational tation of the euro area and the EU (European and an intergovernmental institution, he or she Commission 2017b). But are the interests of euro would have a number of tasks. The first would be and non-euro area countries always coinciding? to represent the common interests of the EU and Not necessarily. If there is a conflict of interest, it the euro area. Secondly, the EMEF could support might not be easy for the EMEF to mediate. To economic policy co-ordination between the MS this, one has to add his or her role as chair of the and the EU institutions, particularly the Commis- board of Governors of the EMF, which is to say sion. It could oversee the implementation of the that he or she has to reconcile differences between existing economic, fiscal and financial rules. This the MS on crucial decisions regarding financial entails close co-operation with national authori- assistance programmes. ties and the EP, with the view to promote reforms As Xanthoulis (2018) underlines, the EMEF is not in the MS. Thirdly, the EMEF could lay down accompanied by an extension of EU competences fiscal policy decisions to support and complement nor does it transfer of new ones from national monetary policy by the ECB, working to “find a to EU level. Hence, from a legal point of view, balance between the fiscal interests of the Member the European treaties seems not to stand in the States and the best solution for the euro area as way of the Commission’s proposal. The fact that a whole” (ibid., p. 4). This also includes co-ordi- the Commission’s proposal passed the legal test nating the “surveillance of Member States’ fiscal does not mean that it will also stand the political policies, ensuring fiscal sustainability and applying one. The person elected as Vice-President of the the Stability and Growth Pact […]” (ibid., p. 4). Commission might not be the same that is elected Finally, he or she could oversee the EU and euro as President of the Eurogroup. Each electing insti- area budgetary instruments (European Commis- tution might have a veto power depending on sion 2017b: 7). who first completes the selection/election process: in the former case, it is the Council, in agree- 3. Assessing the ment with the President-elect of the Commis- Commission’s Proposal sion regarding the appointment, the EP regarding approval; in the latter case, the national finance This section assesses the Commission’s proposal ministers sitting in the Eurogroup. with the aim of identifying potential drawbacks. The Commission proposed the EMEF as a step Fromage (2018) argues that the three different towards deepening integration after the euro roles of the EMEF (Vice-President of the Commis- crisis. But what this crisis has proved is that the sion, President of the Eurogroup, and chair of MS have different perspectives on what they want the ESM Board of Governors) would limit his from the EU. Some are willing to go further into or her accountability towards the EP. According the process of integration. Others want to partici- to Xanthoulis (2018), the powers of the EMEF pate only in the single market (Fabbrini 2015). The are not clearly specified. Most importantly, “the way the EMEF is designed does not consider the Minister appears not to have authority to adopt different perspectives. It follows a one-size-fits-all decisions, formulate policy or enforce rules” approach. Although it differentiates between the (ibid., p. 10). Concerning external representation, euro area and the EU as a whole, this distinction the EMEF would probably have to divide this task is not adequately reflected in the tasks assigned to with the existing actors that already exert it, i.e., the EMEF. It is not clear how the EMEF will be the Commission and the European Council. able to identify a general interest that fits both the euro area and the non-euro area Member States.

A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF ECONOMY AND FINANCE: 255 ASSESSING THE COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL AND COMPARING THE POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND ITALY Tiziano Zgaga On the one hand, the EMEF might be under polit- But the Commission’s proposal assigns him or ical pressure by national finance ministers in the her the task of co-ordinating “the use of relevant Eurogroup. This is true particularly with regard EU and euro area budgetary instruments and to the stronger (creditor) MS. On the other hand, maximis[ing] their impact in support of shared the President of the Commission could force the priorities” (European Commission 2017b: 5). EMEF to resign individually, while the EP could This sentence is quite vague and does not seem to dismiss him or her together with the whole College imply real budgetary decision-making powers of of Commissioners. Formally, the Eurogroup does the EMEF. In sum, the EMEF does not prove able not have this power. It could exert it only through to solve the situation of “representation without political pressure. However, in this case, the taxation” that currently applies to the EU. President of the Commission and the EP might not agree. As for the appointment, also for the 4. Germany’s Position on the dismissal there will always need to be consensus EMEF between the intergovernmental and the suprana- tional side. But this cannot be taken for granted. The following section re-constructs the German The role of the EMEF in assuring compliance with position on the EMEF. Since the beginning of the SGP would be crucial, in particular within the euro crisis, Germany has showed “fear of the framework of the excessive deficit proce- provoking moral hazard and lowering incentives dure (EDP). How the function of overseeing and for reforms” (Schwarzer 2018: 50). It has managed co-ordinating this procedure could be carried out to make sure that financial assistance is condi- by the EMEP is not clear. Since he or she has a tional on domestic structural reforms. linkage to both institutions involved, but the final The German position on the EMEF emerged only decision in the EDP is political, he or she might recently, when the issue entered the debate. In end up aligning with the relevant actors and find order to infer this position, it is useful to look at it difficult to bring in his or her own position. In the traditional stances of the country towards the sum, it is unclear how the EMEF will be able to EMU. The 2013 coalition agreement states that the move between different countries and different allocation of competences in the EMU must follow institutions. the principle that the level (EU or national) that The proposal for an EMEF is not able to enhance takes decisions must also bear the responsibility the EMU’s fiscal capacity towards a complete (i.e. for them (Koalitionsvertrag 2013). The document political) union significantly. It must be accom- is clear in stating that “national budgetary respon- panied by an increase in the EU’s own resources. sibility and supranational, shared liability are However, it seems unlikely that this process will irreconcilable” (Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung 2014: happen soon, considering the strong resistance 103). in some of the MS. A transfer of more resources The then Finance Minister, Wolfgang Schäuble, to EU level also opens the door to a transfer of and the President of the German Bundesbank, further competences. In the light of the different Jens Weidmann, argued that establishing a fiscal preferences that the MS have on the integration union was a viable integration process because it process, only some countries, if any, might agree. would mean that decisions in and responsibility But this would show the limitations of an EMEF for fiscal policy rests at EU level. However, this that should represent both the euro area and the implies national transfer of this competence to non-euro area countries. the EU. The EU could then intervene in national The EMEF would have a sufficient degree of legit- fiscal policy and the MS would ultimately have imacy for playing a role in budgetary decisions. to comply with European decisions. The alterna- tive would be to maintain national responsibility

A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF ECONOMY AND FINANCE: 256 ASSESSING THE COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL AND COMPARING THE POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND ITALY Tiziano Zgaga for fiscal policy and strengthen the existing set of national central bank272 and the Federal Constitu- rules (Der Spiegel 2012 and Weidmann 2015). tional Court.273 Germany’s stance in the first years of the euro crisis was marked by doubts and uncertainty. 5. Italy’s position on the Actually, the country “did not, for instance, EMEF provide any answer or devise an ensuing initia- tive to the Four Presidents’ Report of 2012 […] or The following section re-constructs the Italian the Five Presidents’ Report of 2015” (Schwarzer position on the EMEF. As for Germany, Italy’s 2018: 51). Angela Merkel is not against an EMEF. position on the EMEF can be inferred from the She underlined that the question is which compe- country’s more general position on the reform of tences he or she would have, how he or she would the euro area governance. In turn, this position is be appointed, how his or her relationship with the also influenced by the country’s reading of the euro other institutions and the MS would be regulated, crisis. Italy has interpreted the crisis as a being etc. (Bundeskanzlerin 2017). caused by abrupt speculative attacks of financial markets. This is why the key aspects of its stance The 2018 coalition agreement again takes up are greater solidarity and risk-sharing at EU level. the traditional view of the country. EMU should Increasing the EU budget to promote investments, (continue to) work through a linkage between to support domestic reforms and to absorb asym- risk (in the sense of control over competences) metric shocks would probably find the support and liability (Haftungsverantwortung, Coalition of any Italian government (right-wing, left-wing, agreement 2018: 9). The document suggests that technocratic or populist) (Jones 2018). Germany will also apply its rule-based approach to EMU with regard to the EMEF. It is in favour In the 2016 document “A Shared European Policy of an EMEF that controls and supervises MS Strategy for Growth, Jobs, and Stability”, the compliance with the rules of the SGP (Schwarzer Italian government called for a finance minister 2018). In particular, it wants him or her to have for the euro area, who should adopt an aggregate an apolitical role, focusing on the enforcement of fiscal policy and manage the European budget 271 (IAI 2016). Managing the budget would primarily the existing regulatory framework. The govern- 274 ment is not likely to support the part of the mean creating public goods. The budget should Commission’s proposal that foresees the EMEF’s result in a “fiscal capacity based on specific revenue use of budgetary resources for countering asym- sources as well as a mutualized funding mecha- nism which could entail issuance of common metrical shocks. The concern that EMU could 275 move from a stability union (Stabilitätsunion) to bonds” (MEF 2016b: 6). The Italian proposal a transfer union (Transferunion) is deeply rooted does not assign the role of supervising European in the Germane élite (see, for instance, Fuest 2018, fiscal rules to the EMEF. and König 2018). Both before and during the The EMEF should have a political mandate and euro crisis, this concern has been shared by the should be accountable to EU citizens. He or she

272 See, for instance, Weidmann (2014) and Weidmann (2018). 271 Germany criticises the EDP as being too political 273 See, for instance, the Lisbon Treaty judgement (2009) because, although the process starts following a Commission’s and the ESM/Fiscal Compact judgement (2012). recommendation, it is the Council that takes the final decision (Schwarzer 2018). During the euro crisis, attempts to depoliti- 274 Reference is made to “borders, security, large scale cise the EDP led to the adoption of so-called “reverse qualified investments, defence” (MEF 2016b). majority voting” (RQMV): If, within 10 days, the Council does 275 This is considered the most “visible and constrain- not reject or amend the Commission’s recommendation by ing commitment that can convince the markets that member RQMV, the latter is “deemed to be adopted” (Reg. 1173/2011, countries are serious about the future of the euro” (De Grauwe Art. 4.2). 2014: 224).

A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF ECONOMY AND FINANCE: 257 ASSESSING THE COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL AND COMPARING THE POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND ITALY Tiziano Zgaga should be a member of the Commission and have With regard to Germany, the analysis has outlined “a strong link with both the European Parliament that its stance towards the EMEF is connected and Council” (MEF 2016b: 3). The proposal sees with the country’s traditional attitude towards the EMEF as chair of the Eurogroup. Institution- EMU. Emphasis is placed on risk reduction, crisis ally, it would be similar to the High Representa- prevention, and solidarity through condition- tive for Foreign Affairs and Security Policy, even ality (i.e., in exchange for structural reform). In though no reference is made to an administrative Germany, the debate is centred on the compe- structure as is the case of the EEAS for the HR. tences that the EMEF should have. In Italy, it is The Italian Minister of Finance and Economy, Pier centred on the policies that he or /she could adopt, Carlo Padoan, endorsed the EMEF because the particularly with regard to the provision of public EU needs institutional improvement (Il Sole 24 goods. Ore 2017). Germany would support the EMEF if he or she As for Germany, the position in Italy of the were to supervise and enforce fiscal rules. The aim national central bank (Banca d’Italia) was also in is to depoliticise the surveillance of national fiscal line with the government: its governor, Ignazio policies. The EMEF should primarily be account- Visco, argued that an EMEF would have to manage able to the German Parliament. The centrality of common resources and tools that would differ- the Bundestag in fiscal and budgetary policies has entiate him or her from the Commission. The repeatedly been stated by the German Constitu- EMEF should not only vouch for the rules, but tional Court. The stress on fiscal regulation and also politically interpret them. He or she should supervision (EDP) also implies that Germany manage a common budget, acting as counterparty would prefer to reform the economic governance to the monetary policy of the ECB (Economia.rai. of the EU as a whole, rather than deal separately it 2016). with the euro area. After political elections held on 4 March 2018, the In contrast to Germany, Italy has different priori- Five Star Movement and the League signed a coali- ties: risk sharing, crisis mitigation, and solidarity tion agreement. As in the German coalition agree- in the face of financial turmoil, with less or no ment, there is no explicit mention of the EMEF. emphasis on conditionality. The Italian proposals As far as the EU budget is concerned, the parties for the EMEF are referred to the euro area. The state that it has to be renegotiated in order to idea is that this group of states would be willing make it compatible with the coalition agreement. to accept institutional reforms because they have The most important part is where Five Star Move- already reached a certain degree of integration. ment and League affirm that European economic The proposal is centred on the policies that the governance has to be changed, together with the EMEF could contribute to adopt. Italy wants other MS. In particular, amendments should be the EMEF to have some discretionary power in introduced to monetary policy, the SGP, the Fiscal deciding how to spend EU resources. The aim is to Compact, the ESM and the EDP (Contract for a politicise this figure with regard to spending deci- Government of Change 2018). sions. No reference is made to his or her role of supervisor of fiscal rules. The EMEF should relate 6. Germany’s and Italy’s to national parliaments but its main accountability Position on the EMEF should be to the EP. Compared: An Assessment Interestingly, neither of the two strictly opposes The last section compares the position of the two further delegation of competences on economic countries on the EMEF and tries to see whether and fiscal policy to the EU. Germany calls for at least a common denominator can be identified what has been defined a “surveillance model” between them. (Hinarejos 2013: 1634). The Member States hold

A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF ECONOMY AND FINANCE: 258 ASSESSING THE COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL AND COMPARING THE POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND ITALY Tiziano Zgaga fiscal policy competence while the EU has regu- ferring to him or her liability for decisions taken at latory power (Genschel and Jachtenfuchs 2015): national level. For example, he or she could decide it enforces a number of legal rules aimed at to spend EU money to make up for the effects of constraining the fiscal policy discretion of the MS. (profligate) national fiscal policies. This would be Italy calls for a “classic fiscal federalism model” equal to a decoupling of control and liability. In (Hinarejos 2013: 1635). Here, both the EU and the the German view, it entails the risk that the EMEF MS retain fiscal policy competence with taxing would use common EU resources to compensate and spending powers, but in different realms. The for fiscally irresponsible decisions of the MS. EU would retain this competence for the creation This is why, for Germany, the EMEF should only of public goods, which is precisely what the Italian perform supervisory tasks. The Italian proposal, proposal states. The MS would keep fiscal compe- which is focused on public goods, does not take this tence on those policies/goods that they can better “either/or” position between the levels to which a deliver themselves. certain competence is assigned. By dividing fiscal The dividing line between the two countries is policy competence according to the type of goods clearly visible in Schäuble’s “Non-paper for paving to be produced, the proposal also implies that part the way towards a Stability Union”: “we must keep of this competence continues to be exercised at fiscal responsibility and control together, to avoid national level. Currently, the MS are not ready to moral hazard” (Schäuble 2017: 1). In the German transfer fiscal policy competences fully to the EU. view, this is the position that applies to any transfer Hence, in the German view, as long as they main- of competences to the European level. If the actor tain control of their fiscal policy, they have to be that takes decisions is not the same person who is liable for it. If competences and political discre- liable for those decisions, the risk of moral hazard tion moved to the EU level, this would imply that emerges. Why is this position so deeply rooted the MS have given them up. in Germany? Because it belongs to the German 276 Clearly, the German ordoliberal attitude is missing ordoliberal tradition. in Italy. The debate over decoupling liability and The above-mentioned models – surveillance and control does not play the same role in that country. fiscal federalism – do not fully take account of Germany’s approach to the EMEF. More precisely, Conclusions what the country follows is a model that one could define competence-liability. Germany would This paper has analysed the proposal for an EMEF agree to an EMEF equipped with regulatory presented by the Commission on 6 December and spending budgetary powers only if the MS 2017. accepted to transfer fiscal sovereignty completely The EMEF would be President of the Eurogroup 277 to the EU beforehand. If this were not the case, and Vice President of the Commission. He or she granting the EMEF the power to make use of would have four main tasks: 1) external economic resources from the EU budget would mean trans- representation (euro area/EU); 2) policy co-ordi- 276 The basic idea can be found in Walther Eucken’s book nation and supervision of fiscal rules (euro area/ The Principles of Economic Policy (1952/04). According to EU); 3) fiscal policy decisions (euro area); and 4) the so-called liability principle (Eucken 1952/04), who takes advantage of something, must also bear the costs (Wer den the overseeing of budgetary instruments (euro Nutzen hat, muß auch den Schaden tragen, Eucken 2004: 279). area/EU). The EMEF would be accountable to the From this stems that who is responsible for an action, is also E P. liable for it. The rationale is that this should foster prudent decisions. Ordoliberalism is against any decoupling of control While this would not raise legal problems, from from liability. In the EMU control and liability are at national a political point of view, there are some critical level for economic and fiscal policy and at European level for monetary policy. The no-bailout clause makes sure that this aspects. To perform three different roles (President situation remains unchanged. 277 This would also imply that the EU could intervene in national budgets.

A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF ECONOMY AND FINANCE: 259 ASSESSING THE COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL AND COMPARING THE POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND ITALY Tiziano Zgaga of the Eurogroup, Vice-President of the Commis- hand. As long as the MS want to retain compe- sion, and also chair of the Board of Governors of tence, they must continue to be liable for the the EMF) would not be easy to combine. One the consequences of their decisions. If the EMEF were one hand, the EMEF might be subject to pressure allowed to use political discretion with regard to from the supranational or, more probably, from the EU budget, he or she would be liable for what the intergovernmental side of his or her role. On MS have done at national level. The model that the the other hand, the fact that his or her tasks are not country supports can more properly be defined as clearly specified further complicates this point. By competence-liability. making the EMEF the representative of the euro The German attitude represents a hindrance to the area and the EU as a whole, the proposal does establishment of the EMEF. Completing the EMU not take clearly into consideration the different can and will not happen overnight. Particular perspectives that have emerged on the integration attention has to be given to the composition of the process. Last, but not least, it is doubtful whether EU budget. The EMEF and the reform of the EU it could really contribute to complete the EMU. budget must go hand in hand. Because of this, it In the absence of a larger EU budget that he or should also not be faced through an all-or-nothing she can somehow control, an EMEF with no clear approach. The focus should be on those parts of defined powers risks undermining the potential of fiscal policy where the MS might be willing to give the reform. up competences. Germany’s position on the EMEF is in line with its That would be as easy as the process would serve traditional approach to EMU. The EMEF is seen the creation of European public goods. Following as an institution that should primarily supervise a step-by-step approach would perhaps make it and enforce fiscal rules, with the aim of (further) possible also to preserve the link between the level depoliticising the SGP and the EDP. The country (EU or MS) that takes decisions and the level (EU supports a surveillance model. In contrast, Italy or MS) that is responsible for the consequences of sees the EMEF as an institution that should manage those decisions. By doing so, Germany and Italy a (larger) EU budget in order to face EU-wide would overcome what is currently the deepest asymmetric shocks. The focus is not primarily discrepancy in their positions towards the EMEF. on the EMEF as the watchdog of the regulatory framework. The country supports a classical fiscal federalism model. Although, in principle, both Germany and Italy would accept further transfers of economic and fiscal competence to the EU, the real discrepancy between them seems to be the relationship between the level (national or European) that takes deci- sions and the level (again national or European) that bears responsibility for these decisions. The relationship between control and liability, which is part of the German ordoliberal tradition, is a red line for the country, whereas it does not have the same importance in Italy. Germany would support an EMEF responsible for European fiscal policy only if competence on this policy were entirely transferred to EU level before-

A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF ECONOMY AND FINANCE: 260 ASSESSING THE COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL AND COMPARING THE POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND ITALY Tiziano Zgaga Selected Bibliography sites/beta-political/files/5-presidents-report_ en.pdf, last accessed 5 September 2018. Bundeskanzlerin (2017). “Strategische Zusam- (2017a). “Reflection paper on the deepening of menarbeit vertiefen“, available at https:// the Economic and Monetary Union”, available www.bundeskanzlerin.de/Content/DE/Arti- at https://ec.europa.eu/commission/sites/beta- kel/2017/09/2017-09-15-merkel-empfa- political/files/reflection-paper-emu_en.pdf, engt-philippe.html, last accessed 4 September last accessed 5 September 2018. 2018. (2017b). “Communication from the Commis- Bundesregierung (2013). “Deutschlans Zukunft sion to the European Parliament, the European gestalten. Koalitionsvertrag zwischen CDU, Council, the Council and the European Central CSU und SPD“[Coalition agreement], avai- Bank. A European Minister of Economy and lable at https://www.bundesregierung.de/ Finance”, available at https://ec.europa. Content/DE/_Anlagen/2013/2013-12-17-ko- eu/info/sites/info/files/economy-finance/ alitionsvertrag.pdf?__blob=publicationFile, com_823_0.pdf, last accessed 5 September last accessed 5 September 2018. 2018. Bundesregierung (2018). “Ein neuer Aufbruch Fabbrini, S. (2015). Which European Union? Europe für Europa. Eine neue Dynamik für Deutsch- After the Euro Crisis, Cambridge: Cambridge land. Ein neuer Zusammenhalt für unser University Press. Land. Koalitionsvertrag zwischen CDU, CSU und SPD“ [Coalition agreement], available at Fromage, D. (2018). “The European Parliament in https://www.bundesregierung.de/Content/ the post-crisis era: an institution empowered DE/_Anlagen/2018/03/2018-03-14-koalitions- on paper only?”, Journal of European Integra- vertrag.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=2, last tion 40:3, pp. 281-294. accessed 15 June 2018. Fuest, C. (2018). “Is the Grand Coalition Leading De Feo, A. (2017). ‘The European Budget: Motor Germany towards a Transfer Union? The Euro or Brake of European Integration’, in: Becker, Junktim”, ifo Viewpoint No. 193. S., Bauer, M.W. and De Feo, A. (eds.) The New Genschel, P., and Jachtenfuchs, M. (2015). “More Politics of the European Union Budget, Studies integration, less federation: the European inte- on the European Union, Baden Baden: Nomos. gration of core state powers”, Journal of Euro- De Grauwe, P. (2014) Economics of Monetary pean Public Policy 23:17, pp. 42-59. Union, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hinarejos, A. (2013). “Fiscal Federalism and the Economia.rai.it (2016). “Visco, Bankitalia: Un European Union: Evolution and Future Choices ministro delle Finanze europeo? Sì ma dotato for EMU”, Common Market Law Review 50, pp. di unico bilancio”, available at http://www. 1621-1642. economia.rai.it/articoli/visco-bankitalia-un- Istituto Affari Internazionali [IAI] (2016). ministro-delle-finanze-europeo-sì-ma-do- “Rapporto sulla politica estera italiana: il tato-di-unico-bilancio/33727/default.aspx, last governo Renzi”, available at http://www.iai.it/ accessed 15 June 2018. sites/default/files/iaiq_17.pdf, last accessed 5 Eucken, W. (2004). Grundsätze der Wirtschaftspo- September 2018. litik, Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck. Jones, E. (2018). “Italy and the Completion of the European Commission (2015). “Completing Euro Area”, in: J. Erikkson (ed.), The Future Europe’s Economic and Monetary Union”, of the Economic and Monetary Union. Reform available at https://ec.europa.eu/commission/ Perspectives in France, Germany, Italy and the

A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF ECONOMY AND FINANCE: 261 ASSESSING THE COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL AND COMPARING THE POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND ITALY Tiziano Zgaga Netherlands, Swedish Institute for European area reform”, in: J. Erikkson (ed.), The Future Policy Studies, Report Nr. 1, pp. 26-38. of the Economic and Monetary Union. Reform König, J. (2018). “Mehr Transfer als Stabilität? Perspectives in France, Germany, Italy and the Bewertung aktueller Reformvorschläge für die Netherlands, Swedish Institute for European Euro area”, Argumente zu Marktwirtschaft und Policy Studies, Report Nr. 1, pp. 49-59. Politik, Nr. 140. Il Sole 24 Ore (2017). “Padoan: un supermini- Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung e.V. (2014). “Shaping stro Ue darebbe un’accelerazione efficace”, Germany’s Future. Coalition treaty between available at http://www.ilsole24ore.com/art/ CDU/CSU and SPD”, available at http:// notizie/2017-09-15/padoan-superministro-ue- www.kas.de/wf/doc/kas_36853-544-2-30. darebbe-un-accelerazione-efficace--093926. pdf?140212155238, last accessed 5 September shtml?uuid=AEvQ6bTC, last accessed 4 2018. September 2018. Levrat, N. (2015). “The European Union: From Der Spiegel (2012). “Perfekte Lösungen brauchen International Relations to Intergovernmental lange“, available at http://www.spiegel.de/ Relations”, in J. Poirier, C. Saunders and J. spiegel/finanzminister-schaeuble-ueber-die- Kincaid (eds.), Intergovernmental Relations in geburtsfehler-des-euro-a-840867.html, last Federal Systems: Comparative Structures and accessed 5 September 2018. Dynamics, Oxford: Oxford University Press, Xanthoulis, N. (2018). “The Commission’s pp. 174-205. proposal for a European Minister of Economy Ministero dell’Economia e delle Finanze (2016a). and Finance: Institutional empowerment, “A Shared European Policy Strategy for constitutional tensions and the ministerial Growth, Jobs, and Stability” available at taboo”, CERiM Online Paper Series. http://www.governo.it/sites/governo.it/files/ Weidmann, J. (2014). “Die Währungsunion als ASharedPolicyStrategy_20160222.pdf, last Stabilitätsunion” (07.04.2014), available at accessed 1 September 2018. https://www.bundesbank.de/Redaktion/DE/ (2016b). “Italian contribution on deepening the Reden/2014/2014_04_07_weidmann.html, last EMU”, available at http://www.mef.gov.it/ accessed 18 June 2018. inevidenza/documenti/Proposal_CL_23_May. Weidmann, J. (2015). “Der Euro am Schei- pdf, last accessed 4 September 2018. deweg zwischen Souveränität und Soli- Official Journal of the European Union (2016). darität” (12.11.2015), available at https:// “Treaty on European Union [TEU] and Treaty www.bundesbank.de/Redaktion/DE/ on the Functioning of the European Union Reden/2015/2015_11_12_weidmann.html, last [TFEU]”, available at http://europa.eu/pol/pdf/ accessed 4 September 2018. consolidated-treaties_en.pdf, last accessed 5 Weidmann, J. (2018). “Für Anleihekaufe wäre September 2018. Enddatum vertretbar gewesen“ (07.01.2018), Schäuble, W. (2017) “Non-paper for paving the available at https://www.bundesbank.de/ way towards a Stability Union”, available at Redaktion/DE/Interviews/2018_01_07_el_ https://www.sven-giegold.de/wp-content/ mundo.html, last accessed 15 June 2018. uploads/2017/10/17-10-10-Non-Paper-BMF- on-Reforming-ESM-09-10-2017.pdf, last accessed 15 June 2018. Schwazer, D. (2018). “Germany’s approach to euro

A EUROPEAN MINISTER OF ECONOMY AND FINANCE: 262 ASSESSING THE COMMISSION’S PROPOSAL AND COMPARING THE POSITIONS OF GERMANY AND ITALY Tiziano Zgaga RE-SOLIDARIZING EUROPE Italian economies as they functioned under the AND DEFUSING THE CRISIS drachma or lira. Likewise, Brexit shows that it is very difficult for a Member state to disentangle Maurizio Ferrera, University of Milan itself from the EU order and certainly costlier than staying out altogether – or having stayed out in Carlo Burelli, University of Piemonte Orientale the first place rather than joining and then exiting The very existence of the European Union is today altogether. As aptly noted by Bauböck, ‘the Euro- under attack by an increasingly virulent Euroscep- pean Union has become in this – prosaic and not ticism. In our view, the prime root of this “deep” at all romantic – sense a community of destiny’ political crisis is the sharp misalignment between (2017, p.33). the new nature of the EU after the establishment Yet, precisely because causal dynamics inter- of EMU, its authority structure, and the norma- sect in complex and chaotic ways, the European tive order which underpins cooperation and the Union remains vulnerable to collapse, as each “sharing code” among the member states. Dange- crisis becomes exponentially more difficult to rous centrifugal forces feed on the apparent lack disarm. In complex systems, nonequilibrium is of awareness among national and European poli- the norm rather than the exception. Steering a ticians about the “deep” causes of prolonged insta- complex adaptive system like the European Union bility and existential threats. Yet survey evidence is thus difficult and demanding: a change in the signals that a “silent majority” would be potenti- policy making mindset is required. Complex ally available to support a far-sighted project of systems should focus on resilience, i.e. the capa- institutional reforms and of solidarization of the city to adapt to external and internal shocks even EU. under severe adversity. Contrary to mainstream economics and economic policy - emphasizing EMU as a complex adaptive equilibrium, determinacy, rule-based deductions system without adequate - complexity economics recommends ‘putting steering carefully thought-out controls in place’ in order to safeguard a systemic resilience based on heteroge- EMU has produced an unprecedented fusion of neity and dynamic adaptation. national economies by bringing to completion the Conceiving the EU as a CAS allows us to better single market and introducing a common currency. diagnose a prime root of the existential crisis, When the degree of interconnection and the pres- namely the misalignment between its irreducible sures to mutual adjustment among the parts of a properties and its authority structure. The latter collective goes beyond (or is made to go beyond, as is today unsuited to steer the EU qua complex with the formal establishment of EMU) a critical system as it lacks adequate instruments for addres- level, such collective becomes a complex adaptive sing the common risks generated by integration as system (CAS). This is the key notion of comple- such, as well as the negative externalities arising xity theory. The emergent properties of a CAS are from democratic interdependencies. These flaws not merely causally active but become irreducible make polity maintenance an extremely difficult and irreversible. Irreducibility means that it is task, continuously exposed to the risk of existen- virtually impossible to disentangle systemic from tial failure. sub-systemic causal dynamics: systemic proper- ties are non-localizable and non-aggregative. Irre- EMU is still largely steered within the traditional versibility means that initial conditions cannot be frame of ‘methodological nationalism’, i.e. treating reconstituted via decomposition. The breakup of the Member States and their political economies the euro (strongly advocated by some Eurosceptic as intrinsically self-determined units. But this parties) would not bring back to life the Greek or summation logic can no longer serve as an effec-

RE-SOLIDARIZING EUROPE AND DEFUSING THE CRISIS 263 Maurizio Ferrera tive compass (let alone as the only compass) for A faulty moral order making policy choices and, even prior to that, for arriving at correct causal imputations. Public poli- Aligning the fact of EMU-induced “fusion” in the cies always suffer from interaction effects which economic and monetary spheres with an authority are difficult to disentangle. Yet, with the advent of structure capable of effective functional steering EMU, interaction effects have grown exponenti- and polity maintenance requires the mediation of ally: local outcomes have multiple roots and some an adequate symbolic framework or, more preci- of them are not local, but systemic. It must also be sely, a ‘moral order’. Moral orders are sets of prin- noted that interaction effects also result from hori- ciples defining ‘what is proper to do and reaso- zontal ‘democratic externalities’ (Nicolaïdis, 2013, nable to expect’ (Wuthnow, 1989, p. 14) in asso- p. 351). Domestic leaders face problems for their ciational relationships, accompanied by clear own demos which are the consequence - some- normative criteria ‘by which people and their acti- times quite visibly - of other EU demoi’s deci- vities are valued’ (Harré, 1987, p. 219). In the poli- sions and policies (Cheneval and Nicolaidis, 2016) tical sphere, a key component of the moral order and, in turn, adopt solutions that are very likely are principles and criteria about sharing, i.e. what to generate cross-border effects (Bellamy, 2013, - and why- the members of the collectivity owe to p. 505). National self-determination is obviously each other. A certain degree of adequacy between still possible and can make a great difference in such norms and the facts of socio-economic terms of functional performance. But in a growing cooperation and institutionalized “togetherness” number of sectors, the separation of responsibi- must obtain in order to buffer legitimation dyna- lities between supranational, transnational and mics. national actions and dynamics has turned into a Togetherness evokes ideas such as continuity and difficult balancing act, subject to major epistemic compactness: in a word, solidarity (from the Latin constraints (after a point, we just cannot know). term solidus, which refers to ‘a firm and compact A second root of inadequacy is that this delicate body’). Solidarity is a contested concept, but its balancing act is largely performed by non-majori- prime meaning is relatively straightforward: it tarian institutions, entrusted with the task of iden- connotes, precisely, the set of feelings of belon- tifying and applying rules and technical formulas ging together, which supports attitudes of mutual for steering national fiscal policies (Chalmers acceptance, cooperation and support. Solidarity in et al., 2016). The belatedly acknowledged chal- this sense is partially grounded on the interest in lenge of interdependence has been met, in other the integrity of a shared form of life that includes words, by adopting a technocratic mode of gover- one’s own well-being, which gradually becomes nance based on strict surveillance, discipline and ethically charged and turns into a moral commu- sanctions and aimed at an ever-closer top-down nity, whose members feel ‘co-responsible’ for the harmonization of the standards and practices of actions and desires, faults and merits of each other. Member States. The early architects of the EU were aware that The institutional reforms adopted during the economic integration required a solidaristic euro-crisis have not only proved ineffective in ethos to activate mutual feelings of community terms of outcomes but have also been eroding and sustain EU integration. TheThomson Report the necessary conditions for polity maintenance, prepared with the view of establishing the Euro- unleashing the demons of populism and pushing pean Regional Development Fund (set up in them into attacking the EU as such: for its lack of 1975), stated in turn that a harmonious develop- democratic representation, its constraining rules ment of the Community as a whole was a ‘moral on budgetary decisions and its erosion of territo- and human requirement’: without sustaining local rial sovereignty and border controls (Hutter et al., communities, the ‘idea of European unity’ would 2016; Kriesi et al., 2012). be doomed to ‘disenchantment’. In 1977, the Euro-

RE-SOLIDARIZING EUROPE AND DEFUSING THE CRISIS 264 Maurizio Ferrera pean Commission appointed a high-level working Solidarization: how group on the budgetary implications of EMU, feasible? chaired by Donald MacDougall. The final report suggested that a future ‘Federation in Europe’ The difficulty of further strengthening and solida- should in principle adopt a public budget of rizing the EU is often imputed to the shift from ‘around 20-25% of aggregate GDP, as in the U.S.A. ‘permissive consensus’ to ‘constraining dissensus’ and the Federal Republic of Germany’, although on the side of national constituencies (Hooghe MacDougall considered 5-7% a more realistic and Marks, 2009). No common identity, no figure in the beginning (as it is known, the EU demos, no electoral room for a political union, let budget today only amounts to ca. 1% of aggregate alone a Transfer Union: this is the prevailing line GDP). The Report proposed aCommunity Unem- of the reasoning. But can we confidently say that ployment Fund to cushion temporary setbacks, domestic public opinions share this unsolidaristic a budget equalization scheme for weak member ethos? states up to 65% of the average fiscal capacity, and A survey we recently conducted has provided a ‘conjunctural convergence facility’ to counteract surprisingly hopeful results (Ferrera and Pelle- cyclical crises (MacDougall, 1977, pp. 12–13). It gata, 2017). We asked 9326 respondents in six was through this sequence of initiatives that the countries (France, Germany, Italy, Poland, Spain, ‘social dimension’ of integration made its silent, Sweden) to investigate their disposition to support but tangible appearance within the EU symbolic a solidarization of Europe. First, we tested what and institutional framework and that the value of kind of symbolic image citizens associate to the solidarity – in particular inter-territorial solidarity EU. Four different metaphors were proposed – came to be a part and parcel of the European by the survey: 1) the EU as the ‘common home’ ‘ethos’. of all European citizens; 2) the EU as an ‘apart- Contrast this early sensitivity with the current ment building’ in which national peoples, with predicament. The transition towards a ‘Union of legitimate diversities, live next to each other; 3) a national adjustments’ is a dramatic change of para- ‘playground’ (a commons) that facilitates mutually digm in both descriptive and prescriptive terms. beneficial economic exchanges; 4) a ‘sinking ship’ The new outlook assumes that the EMU frame- from which Member States should escape as fast work - as currently configured - is essentially well as they can – the Eurosceptic view. The preferred designed and that structural adjustment is funda- image turned out to be the apartment building mentally a matter of homework and rule compli- (30.1%), followed by the playground (26.0%), the ance. The derogatory connotation attributed to the common home (23.8%) and, finally, the sinking idea of a Transfer Union in Brussels and in various ship (20.3%). Northern capitals testifies to this anti-solidaristic The survey also asked more concrete questions drift of the EU value framework, especially for about possible EU policies inspired by pan-Eu- the Eurozone. The ‘myth of the beggar’, the idea ropean solidarity norms. Almost all respondents that solidarity would prevent market pressure and (89.1%) agreed that the EU should ensure that no remove incentives to reform has rapidly prompted citizen remain without means of subsistence. In a de-solidarizing and harshly conflictual polariza- addition, more than three respondents out of four tion between ‘deserving’ richer and ‘undeserving’ were in favour of a specific EU funded scheme to poorer Member States, saints and sinners, indus- fight poverty. trious ants and indolent grasshoppers. One may object that people may be in favour of solidarity, but they are not really willing to pay for it. Yet, 77% of respondents were in favour of an

RE-SOLIDARIZING EUROPE AND DEFUSING THE CRISIS 265 Maurizio Ferrera increase of the EU budget to support jobless people of political authority: almost a deliberate recipe during a crisis. In particular, the fact that more for undermining the conditions of polity mainte- than two thirds of Germans are ready to support nance. a partial mutualisation of the risk of unemploy- ment is remarkable, considering the reluctance of Conclusion the German government when it comes to mutua- lisation policies. In addition, more than three out In conclusion, the inability to govern the unstable of four respondents in the six countries were in new reality of Europe’s irreducible and irrever- favour of increasing the EU budget to foster social sible integration is alarming. While a polari- investment policies (75.9%). By contrast, ‘only’ zing political rhetoric divides Europe’s quibbling 56% supported the introduction of Eurobonds, a politicians, there still is a surprising amount of percentage that drops to 37.3% if one considers consensus that could be activated by responsible only Germany. Yet, even these numbers mean that leaders. potentially one every three Germans is supportive In the run-up to the German elections of 2017, of Eurobonds, a fact which sharply contrasts with Angela Merkel and Wolfgang Schäuble repea- the absence of political parties in Germany cham- tedly stated that in EU politics ‘this is no time for pioning this proposal. visions’. We disagree. As famously argued by Max It must also be noted that the results of our survey Weber, world images and visions can sometimes have been robustly confirmed by other recent operate as switchmen, channelling historical investigations (e.g. Gerhards et al., 2017). On developments towards new directions. But ideas this basis, it can be suggested that voter resis- need political ‘carriers’. Today we see some promi- tance and electoral constraints cannot explain that sing ideas with potential popular support, but no process of de-solidarization of the EU which we available carrier. In this post crisis but still turbu- have described above previous section. Quite to lent phase, the long-term sustainability of the EU the contrary, a ‘silent majority’ seems to potenti- cannot be taken for granted. ally available for supporting a strategy of realign- ment between the deep togetherness created by the EMU, on the one hand, and the institutional and symbolic architecture of the EU, on the other. The absence of such strategy represents a clear failure of European political elites. An elective (i.e. choice based) partnership such as the EU, based on forward looking objectives, can turn onto fully fledged “familiy of nations” to the extent that their leaders engage in some fraternal nudging. The exercise of ‘socioemotional leadership’, capable of developing a collective fraternal idioculture has become difficult in a world increasingly based on fluid social relationships, self-seeking behaviours and rational-legal authority (Brint, 2001). But the EMU elite has made long steps in the oppo- site direction, emphasising difference and apart- ness between national communities and their governments, denigrating, also symbolically, any mechanism of mutual support, promoting a histo- rically unprecedented rule-based formalization

RE-SOLIDARIZING EUROPE AND DEFUSING THE CRISIS 266 Maurizio Ferrera References Hutter, S., Grande, E. and Kriesi, H. (2016) Poli- ticising Europe: Integration and Mass Politics Bauböck R. (2017) Citizenship and Collective Iden- (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). tities as Political Sources of Solidarity in the Kriesi, H., Grande, E., Dolezal, M., Helbling, D. European Union, in Banting K. and Kymlicka M., Höglinger, P. D., Hutter, P. S. and Wüest, P. W. (eds.) The Strains of Commitment: The Polit- B. (2012) Political Conflict in Western Europe ical Sources of Solidarity in Diverse Societies, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). (New York: Oxford University Press) 80-106. MacDougall, D. (1977) Report of the Study Group Bellamy, R. (2013) ‘An Ever Closer Union Among on the Role of Public Finance in European Integ- the Peoples of Europe’: Republican Intergov- ration (Brussels: Commission of the European ernmentalism and Demoicratic Representation Communities). within the EU’. Journal of European Integra- tion, Vol. 35, No. 5, pp. 499–516. Nicolaïdis, K. (2013) ‘European Demoicracy and Its Crisis’. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Brint, S. (2001) Gemeinschaft Revisited: A Critique Studies, Vol. 51, No. 2, pp. 351–369. and Reconstruction of the Community Concept. Sociological theory, Vol. 19, No. 1, pp. 1–23. Wuthnow, R. (1989) Meaning and Moral Order: Explorations in Cultural Analysis (Berkeley: Chalmers, D., Jachtenfuchs, M. and Joerges, University of California Press). C. (2016) The End of the Eurocrats’ Dream: Adjusting to European Diversity (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Cheneval, F. and Nicolaidis, K. (2017) ‘The Social Construction of Demoicracy in the European Union’. European Journal of Political Theory, Vol. 16, No. 2, pp. 235–260. Ferrera, M and Pellegata, A. (2017) Can Economic and Social Europe Be Reconciled? Citizen Views on Integration and Solidarity, REScEU Working Paper, www.resceu.eu, last access 01/09/2018 Gerhards, J., Lengfeld, H., Ignácz, Z. S., Kley, F. K. and Priem, M. (2018) ‘How Strong Is European Solidarity’. BSSE Working Paper, No. 37. Harré, R. (1987) ‘Grammar, Psychology and Moral Rights’. In Chapman, M. and Dixon, R.A. (eds) Meaning and the growth of understanding: Wittgenstein’s significance for developmental psychology (Berlin; Heidelberg: Springer), pp. 219–230. Hooghe, L. and Marks, G. (2009) ‘A Postf unc- tionalist Theory of European Integration: From Permissive Consensus to Constraining Dissensus’. British Journal of Political Science, Vol. 39, No. 1, pp. 1–23.

RE-SOLIDARIZING EUROPE AND DEFUSING THE CRISIS 267 Maurizio Ferrera SUMMARISING COMMENTS CONCLUDING REMARKS: the political responses to it. Indeed, many schol- ECONOMIC CULTURES arly analyses of the Eurozone see precisely the North-South diversity as the key source of the AND THE POLITICS OF systemic weakness of the monetary union (Hall, INTERDEPENDENCE 2014; Johnston and Reagan, 2016). At the same time, however, both Germany and Italy are coun- Visnja Vukov tries with important internal diversity, be it the Universitat Pompeu Fabra diversity of religious denominations and their associated economic ideas, as apparent in the Introduction Protestant and Catholic traditions in Germany, or the diversity in social capital and economic Integrating diverse economies and societies under capacities, as apparent in Italy, which itself unites the umbrella of ever wider set of common rules differentially competitive North and South under has been a persistent challenge for European inte- the same political and economic institutions. The gration, from the launching of the Single Market, contributions to this volume are based primarily through the creation of the monetary union, on the discussions of Germany and Italy, but also and the subsequent Eastern enlargement. The tackle broader questions of European integra- Eurozone crisis, in particular, has brought the tion and thus offer numerous important insights problem of North-South imbalances firmly onto for scholarship and practice of politics in Europe. the EU agenda, raising further questions about While it would be impossible to elaborate on all the economic, but also institutional and cultural, of them in detail, the goal of these concluding divergence as a source of inherent tensions in inte- remarks is to point to some of the most important gration. The crisis has also fuelled political chal- ways in which this volume advances our current lenges, with the rise of the Eurosceptic parties in understanding of the economic and political chal- many Member States rendering “united in diver- lenges in Europe and opens promising avenues sity” an ever more elusive and contentious goal. for further research. The paper will be organised What are the main aspects of this diversity that around four main themes that emerge from the matter for the ongoing crisis and how has the contributions: the role of diversity in the inter- crisis affected different economic institutions pretations of the crisis, the notion of interdepend- and cultures in Europe? What are the prospects ence, the importance of economic cultures, and for political responses that would contribute to the politics of crisis responses. enhancing mutual benefits from diversity across Europe, rather than leading to disintegration? Diversity and the crisis

The study of Germany and Italy as the prin- The causes of the Eurozone crisis have been widely cipal focus of this volume offers a great oppor- debated in the academic and policy discussions, tunity for exploring these questions. On the one with positions ranging from placing the blame hand, Germany and Italy are paradigmatic cases on the fiscal profligacy of the Southern coun- of Northern export-oriented growth model and tries and their weaker governance structures, to co-ordinated market economy versus the Southern the incompleteness of the European Monetary demand-led model and mixed market economy Union with a single currency but multiple states. (Hall and Soskice, 2001; Molina and Rhodes, In comparative politics and political economy, the 2007, Baccaro and Pontusson, 2016). Compara- view that has gained the most attention has been tive analysis of these two countries can thus show informed by the Varieties of Capitalism (VoC) how domestic institutions and economic cultures approach (Hall and Soskice, 2001), and, more mediate their vulnerability to the crisis as well as

CONCLUDING REMARKS: ECONOMIC CULTURES AND THE POLITICS OF INTERDEPENDENCE 269 Visnja Vukov recently, the Growth Models perspective (Baccaro spread image of the lack of competitiveness, high and Pontusson, 2016). For the VoC, in particular, labour costs and excessive public and/or private one important systemic weakness of the Euro- debt as the problems in the Eurozone South, zone stems from the diversity of socio-economic Italy was pushed into crisis primarily due to the models and institutions governing markets in the reactions of the financial markets and sudden North and in the South (Hall, 2014; Johnston and capital outflows motivated by fears of contagion, Reagan, 2016). One of the key aspects of this diver- rather than by domestic fundamentals (Jones, sity is usually seen in the wage-bargaining institu- 2018). Thus, instead of focusing predominantly tions, with co-ordinated bargaining in the North on domestic socio-economic models leading to yielding higher export competitiveness vis-à-vis imbalances in the Eurozone, it might be more the lack of such co-ordination in the European fruitful to examine the implications of financial South (Höpner and Lutter, 2017, Hancke, 2013, market integration and the importance of capital Iversen and Soskice, 2013). account movements. In addition, as Kohl and While institutional diversity certainly represents Spielau argue, wage-bargaining institutions are an important aspect of understanding the chal- not the only domestic institutions that matter, as lenges of monetary integration, the contribu- Europe is also marked by the diversity of housing tions to this volume nevertheless revise this styl- regimes which itself might tilt the economy and ised account in several ways. To begin with, the capital inflows towards non-tradeable sectors, standard image of wage co-ordination between the such as construction, rather than export-oriented public and private sector is challenged by Di Carlo ones (Kohl and Spielau, this volume). Academics (Chapter 3 in this volume). In contrast with the but also policy-makers hence need to look beyond predominant views, his analysis shows that wage the focus on competitiveness and especially labour restraint in the German public sector does not costs as the drivers of imbalances, and, instead, result from effective inter-sectoral co-ordination pay more attention to the financial market inte- or the dominance of the social block concerned gration, capital movements and the institutions with export competitiveness. Rather, it stems which govern non-tradeable sectors in order to primarily from the particular structure of the address the systemic weaknesses of the Eurozone. German federal state. Similarly, public sector wage inflation in Italy has more to do with its role as Interdependence socio-economic stabiliser and with the dynamics A further challenge for comparative analysis of political party coalitions in Italy, than with the stems from the fact that the Eurozone crisis inability of the government or the export-oriented made it very clear that European economies sector to tame the demands of the sheltered public have become deeply interdependent so that the sector employees (Di Carlo, Chapter 3 in this German responses to the crisis cannot be under- volume. Given that public sector wages are a key stood without taking into account Italian political element of the overall labour cost differentials in and economic dynamics and vice versa. Including the Eurozone, this analysis provides an important the premise of interdependence presents a host corrective of the VoC based approaches. of conceptual and methodological challenges for Another pertinent question is whether labour comparative analysis, from the adequate choice of costs and the concomitant loss of competitiveness the unit of analysis to the selection of a research actually represent the most important drivers of strategy that could reflect causal processes in the imbalances and crisis in the Eurozone. Erik Jones’ world in which “no polity can realistically connect analysis of the Italian case (Jones, 2018) clearly cause and effect through its own institutions and shows that many of the usual narratives about the policies without regard for the actions of others” crisis do not apply to Italy. Contrary to the wide-

CONCLUDING REMARKS: ECONOMIC CULTURES AND THE POLITICS OF INTERDEPENDENCE 270 Visnja Vukov (Schmitter, 2009: 18). For comparative political zone that set the EU on the path of irreducible and economy, taking interdependence seriously would irreversible integration (Ferrera and Burelli, this also mean departing from the prevailing meth- volume). Yet, as important as the Eurozone and its odological nationalism and understanding socio- North-South integration is, one might add that the economic models, such as the German and Italian dynamics of European political economy cannot models, as part of a common and complex system, be fully grasped without taking into account the rather than as self-contained comparative units of simultaneous increase of West-East interdepend- analysis. ence. 1997, the year of the birth of the Stability Many contributions in this volume already take and Growth Pact, is, at the same time, the year in a step precisely in that direction. Ferrera and which the EU officially decided to start accession Burelli (this volume) make a strong argument negotiations with countries of the former socialist for conceiving of the EU as a complex system, bloc. Besides the creation of the Eurozone, the which is both irreducible and irreversible. Simi- late 1990s were thus also the period in which East larly, German export success partly appears as a European countries became increasingly inte- result of the crisis, rather than preceding it, and grated in the European market and opened their is also associated with the concomitant return of economies towards foreign direct investment – an capital from the periphery to the core, rather than openness often helped by various aspects of the merely resulting from superior German institu- EU enlargement strategy (Bohle and Greskovits, tions (Manow, this volume). The extent of North- 2012, Vukov, forthcoming). South interdependence is particularly relevant This East-West integration has many important in the illuminating comparison of Germany and implications, both for the North and the South of Japan, where Japan’s experience figures as a useful the Eurozone. As Manow shows, the re-location of counterfactual as to what would have happened German business to the East helped to keep wages had Germany not been part of the Euro and the under control (Manow, this volume). Furthermore, EU. As Estevez-Abe (this volume) shows, Germa- it also increased the productivity of the German ny’s capacity to become an exporting powerhouse economy through the re-organisation of cross- was crucially shaped by its participation in the border production chains. The four Visegrád 4 Eurozone. The latter provided additional quasi- countries, taken together as a region, is the largest domestic markets and prevented the German German trading partner, thanks, primarily, to currency from appreciation, while membership in transnational production chains. After the USA, the EU protected it from bilateral trade negotia- they are also the largest supplier of components for tions with the US – all the advantages that Japan German exports (Poplawski, 2016). The borders was not able to enjoy. An important point is thus of competitive German industry are thus far from that Modell Deutschland functions as well it does coinciding with the borders of German socio- precisely because the other countries in the Euro- economic institutions.Similarly, the first channel zone are not the same as Germany and because through which the Italian financial system turned Germany managed to benefit from integration far out to be vulnerable in the 2008 financial crisis was more than other, in particular peripheral, coun- through its exposure via subsidiaries in Eastern tries (Ferrera and Offe, 2018). Europe (Pagoulatos and Quaglia, 2013). The map With Germany and Italy as the focus of this of interdependence among core and peripheral volume, many contributions naturally focus countries in Europe cannot thus be confined to primarily on the interdependence of European the North-South monetary integration. Rather, it North and South, which was particularly strength- is part of a more complex picture in which North- ened after the creation of the Euro. For Ferrera South coincides and overlaps with the East-West and Burelli, it is precisely the creation of the Euro- interdependence, and in which monetary union

CONCLUDING REMARKS: ECONOMIC CULTURES AND THE POLITICS OF INTERDEPENDENCE 271 Visnja Vukov represents only one among several forms of core- istic spirit” and promoting corporatist institutions periphery integration, each with their own devel- shaped some of the key elements of the economic opmental challenges (Bruszt and Vukov, 2018). order in post-War Italy (Hien, this volume). In Taking interdependence seriously is thus crucial addition to cross-national differences in policy for better theorising about the causes and conse- ideas about crisis responses (Bruno, this volume), quences of the crisis. But it is also necessary for the concept of economic cultures suggests that we normative reasons – understanding interdepend- should explore the ways in which these ideas stem ence can lead to different attributions of respon- from broader norms, traditions, historical experi- sibility for the crisis and is thus one of the key ences and historically-shaped forms of meaning- aspects of considerations of justice in the Eurozone making (Hien, this volume). The politics of Euro- (Morgan, this issue). Furthermore, the awareness pean integration thus also implies integration of of interdependence is also a fundamental ingre- such diverse economic cultures and the key ques- dient of solidarity (Sangiovanni, 2018). Social tion is how to govern this diversity in a way that sciences thus have an important role to play in would foster co-operation (Joerges, this volume) providing the foundations for such an awareness rather than cultural conflict. and in contributing to public debates with insights The notion of culture usually implies sort of a that would go beyond methodological nation- long-durée perspective – if institutions are sticky, alism. traditions and values are usually seen as even stickier and more difficult to change as they Economic Cultures emerge from deep layers of historical experi- ence. Moreover, culture is often assumed to mean An important innovative aspect of this volume is national culture, nation seen as the most stable its focus on the ways in which economic cultures, and durable cultural community, tied by language, traditions and predominant ideas shape economic common history, and, in some cases, religion. Yet, integration in Europe. That markets are embedded the contributions to this volume challenge both of in broader social relations and norms is a well- these assumptions. The story of economic culture known premise of which in post-War Germany is very much the story of has more recently received increased attention, cultural change, with multiple shifts and mutual especially with the revival of the work of Karl adjustments between Protestantism and Catholi- Polanyi. Notwithstanding this, not much has cism (Hien, this volume). Similarly, Blome (this been done to date to tease out what exactly this volume) brings a fascinating account of changing means for the organisation of markets in Europe family values and gender norms in Germany, and, in particular, for their integration. Hien though not in Italy. Further research would thus (this volume) tackles precisely this question with need to explore what prompts such cultural his analysis of the impact of different religious change and under what conditions it is more or traditions on post-War economic institutions less likely to happen. Moreover, the papers also and responses to the crisis in Germany and Italy. challenge the view of monolithic national cultures. The Protestant roots of ordoliberalism with its Germany managed to successfully combine emphasis on individual self-reliance were instru- economic ideas and institutions stemming from mental in the German approach to the economic both Protestantism and Catholicism, while Italy crisis of the 1930s and have also been the back- also seems far from a nationally unique economic bone behind the conditionality that German culture, as noted already by Putnam (1993) and leaders required from Southern countries after as apparent in the different implications of corpo- the Eurozone crisis. On the other hand, Catholic ratism in the North and South of Italy (Hien, this social doctrine condemning the “evil individual- volume). The diversity of economic institutions is

CONCLUDING REMARKS: ECONOMIC CULTURES AND THE POLITICS OF INTERDEPENDENCE 272 Visnja Vukov also paralleled by the diversity in political choices the famous motto of European integration thus which again demonstrate a clear divide between may not be simply about creating conditions for the Italian North and South (Kriesi, this volume). harmonious co-existence of diverse and stable An important question is thus what enables more blocs. Instead, it should be thought of as the search or less sustainable configurations of economic for the modes of channelling change (Joerges, this and cultural diversity, and whether Europe could volume) in mutually beneficial, rather than mutu- possibly learn something from the experiences of ally destructive, ways. its internally diverse Member States. The concept of economic cultures, as elaborated Politics of interdependence in this volume, builds upon the Varieties of Capi- How to attain such governance is, of course, a talism (VoC) literature but seeks to complement political question par excellence and the one that it by showing how socio-economic institutions can hardly be answered in a single volume. As emerge out of historically specific practices and Ferrera and Burelli (this volume) argue, the EU how they are also embedded in economic ideas, has evolved into a complex system, but one which traditions and exercises of “meaning-making”. lacks adequate instruments to address the risks While the contributors here recognise various of integration and to govern the interdependen- amendments and criticism of the VoC, one line cies among its Member States. The contributions of criticism which I believe is particularly relevant here point to numerous deficiencies of Euro- for the study of Europe is the one developed by pean governance and several ways in which it has Crouch (2005). In his book, Capitalist Diversity become particularly problematical in the after- and Change, Colin Crouch takes issue with the VoC math of the Eurozone crisis. Historically, Euro- argument of institutional complementarity and pean integration has been based upon integration consistency as the roads to viable and/or competi- through law, which has always had its limitations, tive capitalist models. Rather than celebrating neat visible primarily in the de-politicisation of deci- institutional homogeneity, Crouch argues that it is sion-making. After the crisis, however, the EU has institutional heterogeneity that facilitates innova- witnessed the shift towards integration through tion, by presenting actors with alternative strate- crisis, which made it simultaneously less demo- gies when existing paths seem blocked, and by cratic and less legitimate (Scicluna, this volume). making it possible for them to make new combi- Furthermore, Mangold (this volume) argues nations among elements of diverse institutional that the European Commission has increasingly configurations (Crouch, 2005). Perhaps, the same turned from being an “honest broker” towards could be thought of culture: one might even posit becoming a political actor, while not being that it was precisely the cultural diversity and the directly politically accountable to the electorate. possibility of productive cultural re-combina- The problem of accountability is also emphasised tions between Protestant and Catholic thought by Ferrera and Burelli (this volume), who submit that contributed to the relative success of German that the structure of authority in the EU suffers post-War model, either in its more corporatist or from two important shortcomings: it continues to in its more liberal version. The key issue for Europe treat the Member States as self-determined units thus remains the question of the forms of govern- rather than taking the complex interdependence ance that could bring about new institutional and among them into account, and its governance is cultural re-combinations, and that could foster based largely upon non-majoritarian institutions the appearance of ‘institutional entrepreneurs’ which function through technocratic surveillance, (Crouch, 2005), capable of using the elements of discipline and sanctioning. While the EU can diversity for creating institutional innovations certainly be seen as a possible means to resolve and fostering new paths. “United in diversity”,

CONCLUDING REMARKS: ECONOMIC CULTURES AND THE POLITICS OF INTERDEPENDENCE 273 Visnja Vukov the emerging democratic deficit of nation-states capital, which, to date, national political élites which are increasingly limited in their policy seem neither ready nor willing to take up. options because of globalisation and growing What could be done to foster the emergence interdependence (Joerges, this volume; Inner- of political actors who would tap into this soli- arity, 2018), it has failed to supplant this deficit daristic capital? A useful starting-point here is with new democratic procedures and forms of Sangiovanni’s analysis (2018) of the concept of governing interdependence at the supranational solidarity as being constituted by two parts: recog- level. Such authority structure has also helped nition of mutual dependence, and the joint action fuel the rise of populism with citizens increasingly that follows in its wake. While the importance of turning against the EU, which they perceive as interdependence has already been mentioned, his undermining territorial sovereignty and lacking discussion also suggests that one of the key distin- democratic representation (Ferrera and Burelli, guishing features of joint action based upon soli- this volume; see, also, Kriesi, this volume). darity as opposed, for example, to love, is that we What are the prospects for changing this kind of are disposed to share the fate of our fellow man dysfunctional authority structure? The papers in only in ways that are related to the shared goals of this volume offer a mixed picture. On the one hand, our joint action. the findings show important differences among “When we act in solidarity with one the German and Italian élites in in how they view another, we take into account only our the crisis and possible European-level solutions relation as defined by the ground of our (Puntscher Riekmann and Wydra, this volume; solidarity, and hence disregard what else Bruno, this volume; Quaglia, this volume), as well might divide us. What matters is that we as their mutual distrust (Pellegata, this volume), on are workers, not that you are a farmer and the other. Nevertheless, survey results also show I am a factory worker; what matters is that that the majority of citizens in Italy as well as in we are fellow nationals, not that I am a poet Germany tend to attribute the blame for the crisis and you are a banker’ (Sangiovanni, 2018). to the banks, rather than the excessive spending of [italics in original] the Southern Eurozone members (Pellegata, this volume). In other words, the narrative of Southern From this point, it seems that one of the key prob- responsibility which is predominant in the overall lems with Europe and its current political insti- discourse and élite representations of crisis in tutions is precisely that they fail to foster visions Germany (Ferrera and Offe, 2018) seems to be and political projects that would enable the crea- endorsed by only one third of the German popu- tion of trasnsnational relations of solidarity which lation. Similarly, the surveys carried out within the emphasise aspects of identity other than the RESCUE project show that the majority of Euro- national one. Solidarity among Europeans where peans across the Member States are in favour of it would matter that they are both workers, rather an increase of the EU budget to support jobless than a German worker and a Romanian worker; or people during a crisis and display a solidaristic that they are both feminists, rather than a Swedish ethos when thinking about Europe (Ferrera and feminist and an Italian feminist, is not actively Burelli, this volume). Thus, it seems that, at least forged in any of the European electoral arenas, at the level of citizens, there might be more space precisely because such arenas remain organised for trans-European solidarity and more scope for around national electoral institutions. policies that would go beyond the zero-sum game In addition to national democracies and national than is commonly assumed. As Ferrera and Burelli forms of representation, governing interdepend- argue, it would, however, require responsible élites ence in Europe might thus also require transna- who were capable of exploiting this solidaristic tional forms of political representation in which

CONCLUDING REMARKS: ECONOMIC CULTURES AND THE POLITICS OF INTERDEPENDENCE 274 Visnja Vukov at least some political élites would have stakes precisely in creating new coalitions and forging new solidarities which transcend national bound- aries. While this is not an easy task, the alterna- tive that is currently in place is leaving all conten- tious EU-level issues to the outcomes of national elections and having them debated primarily through the prism of national interest. As we can see in a number of European countries, not least Germany and Italy, such a prism primarily strengthens various strands of nationalism which, in its extreme versions, may also take the form of attacking the basic tenets of liberal democracy. Matching economic integration with the creation of political institutions that could foster polity- building based upon the notion of interdepend- ence, mutual trust and solidarity remains a chal- lenge that Europe will need to resolve if it wants to ensure not only the path of integration, but also democracy itself.

CONCLUDING REMARKS: ECONOMIC CULTURES AND THE POLITICS OF INTERDEPENDENCE 275 Visnja Vukov References edu/~iversen/PDFfiles/Iversen&Soskice_ euro2015.pdf. Baccaro, L., and J. Pontusson (2016), “Rethinking Johnston, A., and A. Regan (2016), “European Comparative Political Economy: The Growth Monetary Integration and the Incompatibility Model Perspective”, Politics & Society 44 (2): of National Varieties of Capitalism”, Journal of 175-207. Common Market Studies, 54 (2): 1-19, 318-336. Bohle, D., and B. Greskovits (2012), Capitalist Diver- Jones, E. (2018), “Italy and the Completion of the sity on Europe’s Periphery. Ithaca NY: Cornell Euro Area”, European Policy Analysis 2018:1. University Press. SIEPS Swedish Institute for European Policy Bruszt, L., and V. Vukov (2018). “Governing market Studies. integration and development - lessons from Molina, O., and M. Rhodes (2007), “The Political Europe’s Eastern and Southern peripheries: Economy of Adjustment in Mixed Market Econ- Introduction to the Special Issue”. Studies in omies: A Study of Spain and Italy”, in: B. Hancké, Comparative International Development 52(2): M. Thatcher and M. Rhodes (eds), Beyond Vari- 153-168. eties of Capitalism: Conflict, Contradictions and Crouch, C. (2005). Capitalist Diversity and Change. Complementarities in the European Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 223-52. Ferrera, M., and C. Offe (2018), ‘Order in the Euro- Pagoulatos, G., and L. Quaglia (2013), “Turning zone: Maurizio Ferrera and Claus Offe in Conver- the Crisis on its Head: Sovereign Debt Crisis as sation’ VerfBlog, 2018/7/13, available at: https:// Banking Crisis in Italy and Greece”, in: I. Hardie verfassungsblog.de/order-in-the-eurozone- and D. Howarth (eds), Market-Based Banking maurizio-ferrera-and-claus-offe-in-conversa- and the International Financial Crisis. Oxford: tion, DOI: https://doi.org/10.17176/20180713- Oxford University Press, 179-200. 104316-0. Popławski, Konrad (2016), “The Role of Central Hall, P.A., and D. Soskice (2001), Varieties of Capi- Europe in the German Economy. The Political talism: The Institutional Foundations of Compara- Consequences.” OSW Report June 2016. tive Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Putnam, R. (1993), Making Democracy Work: Civic Hall, Peter A. (2014), “Varieties of Capitalism and Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton NJ: Princ- the Euro Crisis”, West European Politics 37 (6): eton University Press. 1223-1243. Sangiovanni, A. (2018), “Solidarity.” Unpublished Hancke, B. (2013), Unions, Central Banks and EMU: manuscript. Paper presented at the conference Labour Market Institutions and Monetary Inte- “Responses of European Economic Cultures to gration in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Europe’s Crisis Politics: The Example of German- Press. Italian Discrepancies”, Villa Vigoni, 25-27 June Höpner, M., and M. Lutter (2017), “The Diversity of 2018. Wage Regimes: Why the Eurozone is too Hetero- Schmitter, P. (2009), “The nature and future of geneous for the Euro”, European Political Science comparative politics” European Journal of Polit- Review, pp. 1-26. ical Research 1 (1): 33-61. Innerarity, D. (2018), Democracy in Europe: A Polit- Vukov, V. (forthcoming), “Europeanizing develop- ical Philosophy of the EU, London: Palgrave ment: EU integration and developmental state Macmillan. capacities in Eastern Europe”, in: M. Matlak, F. Iversen T., and Soskice D. (2013), “A Structural- Schimmelfennig and T. Wozniakowski (eds.), institutional Explanation of the Eurozone Crisis.” “Europeanization Revisited”, EUI – RSCAS Unpublished manuscript. Cambridge MA: Working Paper Series, European University Harvard University, Department of Government, Institute (EUI), Robert Schuman Centre of available at: http://www.people.fas.harvard. Advanced Studies (RSCAS), Florence.

CONCLUDING REMARKS: ECONOMIC CULTURES AND THE POLITICS OF INTERDEPENDENCE 276 Visnja Vukov TWO ANNEXES ORDER IN THE EUROZONE: done by the ECB. At the same time, the extremely MAURIZIO FERRERA low interest rate, also determined by the ECB, benefits the winners by making their public debt AND CLAUS OFFE IN easier to service. For instance, experts speak of CONVERSATION 294 billion Euros, a figute that comes close to an annual Federal budget, that the German public Maurizio Ferrera, Claus Offe debt burden has been made lighter since 2007 through low interest rates. Another way in which the Euro benefits winner countries is that it works MF: You have recently written a lot about Europe as an export subsidy due to its uniform external and the increasing North-South divides within the exchange rate. Absent the Euro, the new Deutsch- Eurozone. You are also one of the few influential mark would dramatically appreciate its exchange German intellectuals who openly criticizes German rate with the outside world and German export governments and their orientations on EMU. Do industries would largely collapse as a conse- you see a nexus between the EMU’s dysfunctiona- quence. No wonder that winners such as, most lities and the social and political crisis, especially in of all, Germany indulge in their obsessions with Southern Europe? automatic rules and austerity. Yet the German CO: Yes, I certainly do. The monetary regime of government does not show any inclination to the Euro under which 19 very diverse national share this windfall profit with those whose plight economies within the EU now live and operate is has indirectly given rise to it. This all looks like plainly dysfunctional. It does not serve its alleged what the Hungarian-born historian Karl Polanyi, and promised purpose of convergence but does referring to the “veritable abyss of human degra- the exact opposite. It is economically and politi- dation” that occurred under early capitalism, has cally divisive: Some participants win, others lose called a “satanic mill”. One feature that makes the and the gap becomes wider. mill particularly „satanic“ is the fact that nobody, The Euro ties the hands of the losers, roughly the neither losers nor winners, can rationally (and Mediterranean region of the EU. They can no actually does in earnest) opt for leaving the Euro. longer adjust to challenges of competitiveness by Unilateral exit from the EMU is, in spite of some devaluing their national currency because there demagoguery to the contrary, a plain non-starter is none any more. If they need to adjust, they due to the huge damages exiteers would have to must do so „internally“, i. e. by depressing wages, cope with as a consequence. Unless there is a way pensions, and state (in particular welfare) expen- to reform and to some fair compensation of losers, ditures, all of which is detrimental to growth, we remain trapped in the „mill“. Yet the longer it employment, and the prospects of reducing public operates and inflicts damages on losers and grants debt through a fiscal dividend resulting from profits to winners, the harder it becomes politi- growth. Today, Italian GDP per capita is still 8 per cally to embark on a serious path of reform that cent below of what it was in 2008. Yet that does opens a credible prospect of convergence. Such not seem to be enough to boost Italian unit costs reform, together with winners funding large scale of labor, the key determinant of competitiveness border-crossing investments programs, remains in international trade. The living conditions of the only collectively rational way out. But for char- ordinary people have been severely depressed, ting such path time may be running out. giving rise to discontent, resentment and angry MF: This logic was partly there from the beginning if often misdirected protest. Loser economies are of EMU. Don’t you think that some institutional no longer allowed, under the EMU regime, to reforms introduced in the early 2010s – such as the set their targeted rate of inflation because that is Fiscal Compact, the strengthening of supranational

ORDER IN THE EUROZONE: MAURIZIO FERRERA AND CLAUS OFFE IN CONVERSATION 278 Maurizio Ferrera and Claus Offe controls and conditionality, the adoption of demo- mies of the Eurozone; they are even dictated by its cratic “monsters” such as reverse qualified majority long term and well-considered interest in making rule for macro-economic and fiscal decisions – have the EMU a robust and inclusive monetary regime. severely aggravated EMU’s dysfunctionality? MF: As the largest Member State and as the CO: Absolutely. The new tools of enforcing „disci- economic powerhouse of Europe, one would expect pline“, austerity and control are widely recog- Germany to somehow serve as a benign hegemon, nized to be counterproductive in their effects. But capable of reconciling her own national interests they are the only tools the EU, driven by a cons- with the interests of others and especially with the tant and no doubt realistic fear of the disasters long term economic and political sustainability of the „markets“ may inflict upon its stability, has at the EU its disposal and which are within the reach of the CO: During the long crisis Germany has in fact intergovernmental making of treaties between largely abdicated its responsibility in and for EU member states. They confirm the image of Europe. The German government’s obsession „Brussels“ as an illegitimate foreign power impo- with rules, austerity and conditionality has been sing rules without being itself subject to demo- the main driving force behind the growing diver- cratic accountability. We now have a rich evidence gence of EMU economies and the devastating in Europe of the electoral outcomes to which this social shocks which has hit Southern member economic and monetary regime gives rise. The states. Germany has tried to push through her EU lacks the requisite state capacity to deal with own economic and social model, based on flawed the partly disastrous consequences caused by the assumptions that we might call a „flower pot operation of its monetary system. If the EU were a theory”. Such theory is the favorite mode of thin- federal state, and a democratic federal state at that, king of winners. Their message: the rules that it would have at its disposal the governing capacity have worked so advantageous in „our“ case are to tax and to redistribute its resources across state the same that would work to the benefit of „you“ borders and compensate losers for at least parts of as well – if only you could overcome yourself to their systematically generated losses. In its present follow „our“ rules which you are most welcome, in institutional shape, it is still far from having the fact required, to adopt and follow. Flowers in sepa- authority to do so. rate flower pots develop similarly if you use the MF: The obvious question is then: cui prodest? Who same seeds, the same fertilizers etc. What is wrong are, let us name then, the EMU winners? And do with this comfortable mode of thinking is that it you think there was a deliberate power strategy? ignores and denies systemic interdependence. CO: As I said, Germany has been the main benefi- However, there is a powerful intellectual antidote. ciary of the institutional architecture and measures It is captured in a sentence by authors Mathijs and that were put in place since 2008. That fact need Blyth, often quoted in the scholarly literature on not be due to what you call a „deliberate power the EU. It reads: „The Eurozone as a whole cannot strategy“ or conspiracy of sorts. Power, as poli- become more like Germany. Germany could only tical scientist Karl Deutsch has famously pointed be like Germany because the other countries were out, is the ability to afford not to learn. In that not.“ Germany is like Germany, we might add, sense German power consists in the unwilling- because of its reaping of unreciprocated advan- ness of German political elites (as well as, it must tages from the system of EU member states and be added, major parts of ill-informed non-elites) their interdependencies – the opposite of separate to promote and adopt reforms needed to remedy flower pots. the worst institutional pathologies of the EMU. Such reforms are not only affordable for one of the biggest and currently one of the wealthiest econo-

ORDER IN THE EUROZONE: MAURIZIO FERRERA AND CLAUS OFFE IN CONVERSATION 279 Maurizio Ferrera and Claus Offe MF: In the flower pot theory a key role is played by poor sociology. In a complex system such as EMU rules and decision making procedures. The motto is it still possible to determine with any politically of German and Northern elites during the crisis has relevant precision those effects which can be traced been pacta sunt servanda. That is fair enough. But back to domestic policy decisions and therefore Roman law foresaw an additional clausola rebus implicate national “responsibility”? Moreover, it is sic stantibus: treaty obligations can remain unful- in the nature of all social interaction that we are not filled due to a compelling change in circumstances. rewarded for all positive effects we cause for others, Only the jus cogens based on basic principles was nor are we bound to compensate others for all the peremptory, with no possibility of derogation….Can negative externalities we cause for them. Of course I we say that such rather obvious distinctions have am not denying that there are numerous policy areas been forgotten during the crisis – or possibly even in in which domestic decision still make the difference the original design of EMU? and therefore do implicate national responsibility. CO: This question takes us into the difficult field And we know that some governments even cheated where we must explore the relation between rules Brussels when the crisis erupted. But don’t you think and decisions. Rules of social and political life are that the rhetoric of “saints” and “sinners” espoused not in any sense „given“; they are man-made and by German leaders (including social, media and have been adopted at some point by decision. Follo- intellectual elites) has grown beyond limits of epis- wing rules as a matter of routine can be a highly temic, moral and political acceptability? efficient way to avoid the need to make decisions. CO: I couldn’t agree more. Again, the questions But social agents can also decide to break rules takes us into the field of legal philosophy. To what rather than comply with them, and sometime there extent can actors alone be held responsible for the are even good and justifiable reasons for doing so, misfortune they suffer or the gains they achieve? e. g. when the rebus sic stantibus proviso does Again, winners tend to ascribe their profit to their not apply. For instance, the rules may be biased own talents and efforts, while losers like to frame and favor one of the conflicting parties to which themselves as victims of adverse circumstances. they apply. Nota bene: uniform rules do not create Winners depict losers as having failed to obey a level playing field. Absent such reasons, there the commands of prudence and moral consis- are reasons to enforce rules. But efforts at enfor- tency, while losers look at winners as having bene- cement can fail, or it can involve the violation of fitted from sheer luck or the uncompensated help other rules. It all boils down to the issue of how we of others. These conflicting narratives must be judge the quality of those respective reasons. This checked case by case for their relative merits, and conflict may be resolved by bending or tempora- care must be taken that the narratives of winners rily suspending rules in order to avoid having to do not prevail over other narratives and frames, break them, or by reforming them. Insisting on as they often tend to do in the multilingual and rules being valid once and forever can be an atti- hence fragmented public sphere of the EU. tude that is driven by self-interest of those whom The German framing of the problem of the EMU the rules favor rather than an attitude inspired by and the EU is often described and criticized as sincere respect for the rules. As we easily recog- an obsession with „order“. In fact, the economic nize, each of these ramifications play a role in the policy doctrine of „ordo liberalism“ that was cano- day-to-day discourse and conflicts over European nized by committed protestant professors and poli- integration and Eurozone politics. ticians in the early post-war period of the Federal MF: Another shibboleth of neoliberal doctrine Republic is inspired by the deep intuition that a is that we cannot separate control and liability: stable and robust social order is best built when whoever decides to do something must be solely rules are irreversibly put in place and decisions held responsible for its consequences. This is simply and discretionary interventions – be it by corpo-

ORDER IN THE EUROZONE: MAURIZIO FERRERA AND CLAUS OFFE IN CONVERSATION 280 Maurizio Ferrera and Claus Offe rate actors or political authorities – are banned or kept to a minimum. This doctrine has always reminded me of a story told by Bertolt Brecht in his collection of anecdotal sketches called Flücht- lingsgespräche (conversations of refugees [from Nazi Germany in the 1930s]). One is a physics professor, the other a metal worker. The latter concludes their conversation on the nature of order by musing: „We might put it this way. Where nothing is in its right place, there is disorder. Yet order is where in the right place there is nothing.“ The professor agrees: „Order is a phenomenon of something missing.“ Just to illustrate: As reported in a recent comment in the Financial Times (May 6, 2018), one paragon of fiscal probity and auste- rity, namely Nicolae Ceausescu, the Romanian dictator, boasted a budget surplus of 9 billion dollar in 1989. By the end of that year, his regime had suddenly collapsed and he was no longer among the living.

ORDER IN THE EUROZONE: MAURIZIO FERRERA AND CLAUS OFFE IN CONVERSATION 281 Maurizio Ferrera and Claus Offe GERMANY IS QUIETLY Two pertain to the sphere of macroeconomic REBALANCING ITS ECONOMY policy proper, i.e. wage and fiscal policy. One has to do with an empirical manifestation of macro- – BUT THIS WILL NOT FIX economic policy in the German balance of trade, 278 THE EUROZONE’S FLAWS i.e. persistent current account surpluses. The last criticism is centred on the growth model itself Donato Di Carlo279 and considers the implications of the German Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies, export Weltmeister for the European Economic Cologne and Monetary Union (EMU), as well as global imbalances). In what follows I focus solely on the Ever since the financial and sovereign debt crisis, EUROpean perspective and leave the issue of the political and economic implications of Germa- global imbalances to others. ny’s unbalanced economy have lured the attention of academics, policy institutions, the public and Germany’s ‘unbalanced’ politicians across Europe and beyond. Frequent are economy and the EMU the pleas made to the German political establish- ment to rebalance its export-oriented economic German policy makers, the argument goes, should model, increase fiscal expenditures and thus rein rein in the country’s trade surplus and allow for in the world’s largest current account surplus. The symmetric adjustments in the EMU. Germany issue has become so controversial that one reads is accused of engineering economic growth at economic commentators venturing into pictur- home by free-riding on other European coun- esque appraisals, comparing today’s Germany to tries’ aggregate demand. Some even go as far as to Nicolae Ceausescu’s Romania. argue that Germany is “artificially” and “purpose- But what is Germany being criticised for? In fully” repressing domestic household consump- essence, the controversy revolves around macro- tion, government spending and private invest- economic policy making and what the German ments to sustain a mercantilist model. Germany growth model implies for the rest of the world. allegedly refuses to correct trade imbalances and – There are four constitutive elements in this debate. given fixed exchange rates – grows at the expense of other EMU participants, which have to go 278 This piece has originally appeared, in the form of a blog through painful internal devaluations and fiscal post, on the LSE Europp Blog on 14/9/2018, available at: http:// austerity. What is thus being asked of Germany is blogs.lse.ac.uk/europpblog/2018/09/14/germany-is-quietly- rebalancing-its-economy-but-this-will-not-fix-the-eurozones- to reduce its budget and trade surpluses to provide flaws/, and on Social Europe on 20/9/2018, available at: https:// a more symmetric adjustment mechanism to the www.socialeurope.eu/germany-is-quietly-rebalancing-its-eco- single currency via the expansion of its domestic nomy-but-this-will-not-fix-the-eurozones-flaws. demand for EMU exports. The version presented here has been slightly modified with re- spect to the original blog post in order to incorporate critiques In the eyes of the critics, Germany’s increased and suggestions. imports are thus supposed to work as a func- 279 I am grateful to Benjamin Braun, Sebastian Diessner, tional equivalence for the lack of supranational Martin Höpner, Fritz Scharpf and Jachim Truger with whom I had the chance to discuss these issues to refine my thinking. adjustment mechanisms in the monetary union. All mistakes are my sole responsibility. In other words, Germany should act as a fixer of I am especially thankful to Dr. Paul Steinhardt who has written last resort in the Eurozone and, to fulfil this role, a thoughful critique to my original piece. This has helped me substantially to refine my thinking and correct initial mistakes domestic macroeconomic policy should follow I had committed. His critique has appeared as a blog post suit. Since participating in the EMU entails a loss (in German) on the Makroskop blog on 28/9/2018, available of sovereignty over exchange rate and monetary at: https://makroskop.eu/2018/09/wissenschaftliche-sensa- policies, both criticism and policy advice focus on tion-deutschlands-stilles-rebalancing-wurde-entdeckt. wage and fiscal policy.

GERMANY IS QUIETLY REBALANCING ITS ECONOMY – BUT THIS WILL NOT FIX THE EUROZONE’S FLAWS 282 Donato Di Carlo Let’s start with the criticism. People concerned What has Germany done since the crisis and what with wage policy argue that Germany has under- can it possibly do, given the institutional setting? gone a substantial internal devaluation of its unit In general terms, the criticism on such a high labour costs (ULCs): wages have fallen behind the current account surplus is certainly valid. Yet, economy’s productivity rates in both the private what the critiques have in common is that they and public sector, thus yielding a cost and price rarely ask what Germany has done since 2010 to competitiveness premium to the German export address these issues. It thus seems appropriate to secto rbest captured by its remarkable ULC-based ask whether the trends of wage restraint and fi scal Real Exchange Rate (REER) depreciation. Th ose austerity, visible before 2008, have been reversed in who point at fi scal policy stress the German the post-crisis era or whether Germany continues budget surplus, bemoaning the lack of government to “beg her neighbours”. spending. Defl ationary wage policies (decreasing real wages) are said to deter household consump- Figure 1: Unit labour costs: total economy (1999 tion at home and imports from abroad. An austere and 2010=100) fi scal policy contains the govern- ment’s fi nal consumption and contributes to keeping imports artifi cially low. At any rate, the combination of a restrictive wage and fi scal stance represses total domestic demand (public and private), leads to relatively low infl ation, REER competitive- ness and trade surpluses – which prevent the possibility for other EMU participants of adjusting via an export-led recovery. Now the policy advice: what should Germany ULCs in post-crisis Germany (fi gure 1) have do? Policy remedies follow consistently from the increased steadily. Since 2010, the trend of internal critiques. ULCs in Germany should rise faster depreciation so much pronounced during 1999- than its competitors’ so as to experience an appre- 2008 has been reversed and Germany has under- ciation of its REER and hence a loss of the compet- gone a substantial REER appreciation (fi gure itiveness (unfairly) acquired before 2008. Addi- 2) vis-à-vis its EMU peers, forced into a path of tionally, the German government should spend internal devaluation. Th e REER competitiveness more money. Th e eff ects of this policy mix would gained in the pre-crisis period has not been fully set in motion two complementary mechanisms reabsorbed yet. Still, the trend has clearly reversed. for adjustment. On the one hand, the wage and price infl ation deriving from higher wage rates and an expansionary fi scal stance will decrease (ULCs- and CPI-based) REER competitiveness and help rebalance the current account – allowing other EMU countries to “breathe”. On the other, increased households’ purchasing power (due to higher real wages) and government consumption will increase domestic demand and imports from abroad.

GERMANY IS QUIETLY REBALANCING ITS ECONOMY – BUT THIS WILL NOT FIX THE EUROZONE’S FLAWS 283 Donato Di Carlo Figure 2: Real Exchange Rates in Germany and (approx. 45% of total expenditures)- it would be the EMU (1999 and 2010=100) pointless to expect substantial wage increases in the TV-L contract without a fi scal federalism reform that attrib- utes more money to subnational governments. Even more funda- mental is that it is unclear why one should expect the fi nance minister of a German State to respond to Eurozone impera- tives, while being accountable to their local constituency. Th e only instrument the German government could use to inter- vene in wage-setting is to legis- Surely, criticising Germany for its own sake may late for an increase of the minimum wage above lead to one always ask “how much is enough”. infl ation. Th is has already been agreed and the Th is would perhaps be a fair question given the government is about to ratify an above-infl ation remarkable pattern of wage restraint observable increase of 4%. before the crisis. But a constructive and – real- Figure 3: Real Compensation per Employee, istic - critique should go beyond a mere numer- defl ator is HCPI (1999-2019) ical macroeconomic argument and include institutional struc- tures in order to elaborate on the feasibility of an extraordinary internal appreciation, given the German wage setting systems. Tarifautonomie allows for no government interference in private sector wage negotia- tions and, frankly, it sounds quite absurd to expect the German government to ask the social partners to price themselves out of the market in order to purposefully lose competi- Even assuming that it would be structurally tiveness vis-à-vis its EMU peers. possible to raise German price infl ation far above Regarding public sector wage setting, aft erthe the EMU average via wage push infl ation, this is reforms of the mid-2000s it is now the fi nance minis- likely to create more damage than relief. Given ters of the Länder who are in charge of negotiating Germany’s size in the EMU, it will rather put enor- wage increases for the public employees they are in mous political pressures on the soon-to-be new charge with, i.e. the majority. Given that the Länder governor of the ECB to tighten monetary policy. lack the possibility to manipulate their marginal Th e eff ect for the EMU would be the opposite of tax revenues - and that personnel pay is the most the desired symmetric adjustment: countries in burdensome item in State administrations’ books the periphery would be pushed into even direr straits.

GERMANY IS QUIETLY REBALANCING ITS ECONOMY – BUT THIS WILL NOT FIX THE EUROZONE’S FLAWS 284 Donato Di Carlo What about the German fi nance ministers, are Calculations based on AMECO data also confi rm a they really so stingy? In terms of real government reversal of the trend: a moderate but steady expan- expenditures (net of interest payments), Germany sion of Governments’ expenditures. In the decade has since the crisis spent considerably more than before the crisis (1999-2008), total expenditures most other OECD countries, even more than the in Germany (excluding interests) have increased increase in spending in the United States – oft en at an average annual rate of 1.9% (4.2% in the EU praised for its post-crisis Keynesian stance. – 4.2% in the EMU). Aft er the crisis spending has Figure 4: Real total expenditure excluding increased at an annual average of 3%, while it has interest of general government (2008=100) collapsed to 1.9% in the EU and 1.7% in the EMU. Th e same trend can be observed with regard to Government’s gross capital formation. During the pre-crisis era, annual average growth of invest- ment spending in Germany was 1.9% while it has increased at an annual pace of 3.4% during the period 2010-2018, while in the EU as a whole, in the post-crisis period it has been fallen to 0.6% (from 5.5%) and even negative in the EMU, -0.1% (from 4.7%). Figure 5: Governments’ total expenditures (excluding interests) and gross fi xed capital formation (1999-2018) Since gross fi xed capital formation of general government does not consider the eff ect of capital

Th e fact is that focusing on the budget surplus may be misleading since, in a buoyant economy, it is relatively faster growth of reve- nues that drives the calculation up. It is thus perfectly possible to continue expanding invest- ment spending at a moderate yet steady pace, while still remaining in a territory of surplus. It is certainly true that the public- investments/GDP ratio remains below the Eurozone average and that there are depreciation, a better measure to look at addi- innumerable fi elds in which Germany could (and tional investment activity on tangible and intan- should) invest more (e.g., in physical and digital gible assets is net fi xed capital formation (gross infrastructure). I certainly agree with this plea. fi xed capital formation – depreciation). Figure But one should also notice that, according to BMF 6 shows the impressive decline in public fi xed data, since 2005 public investment spending in capital formation in Germany since 1991. Before Germany has been increasing at an average annual the crisis, two periods are striking: 1993-1997 and growth rate of 3.8%, i.e., at a faster pace than both 2000-2005. total expenditure and nominal GDP.

GERMANY IS QUIETLY REBALANCING ITS ECONOMY – BUT THIS WILL NOT FIX THE EUROZONE’S FLAWS 285 Donato Di Carlo Th ere are three ways in which this fall in public From a more historical perspective it becomes investment can be interpreted: (1) to read these hard, in my view, to claim that Germany purpose- shift s as the result of a conscious mercantilist fully (and in bad faith!) neglected public invest- strategy aimed at compressing domestic demand ments. Germany could not spend more in the and price infl ation to maintain export-competi- early 2000s because it had already fi scal problems tiveness at the expenses of trading partners; (2) to due to high unemployment and low growth, hence read them as the fetishism for balanced budgets weak revenues and high social expenditures for at all costs; (3) as lack of administrative capacity automatic stabilisers. My interpretation is rather to plan and implement investments. I would argue that this was a contingent strategy and that now that there is a fourth, more historical, interpreta- that times are good again, the trend of public tion. investment (as well as of domestic demand) will On July 17th 1992, the Bundesbank raised interest gradually increase, as it has already gone back to rates to unprecedented levels in German post-war the levels of the mid-1990s and is now line with history (even higher than the June 1973 peak). the trend of public spending expansion in France. Th is engineered an economic slowdown whose It makes much more sense, instead, to argue that eff ects would be felt for fi ft een years. Th eBundes- the countries which are desperately in need of bank’s policy had the precise purpose of punishing public and private investments are those asym- the expansionary fi scal stance of the Kohl govern- metrically hit by the crisis – it is suffi cient to look ment (meant to pay for reunifi cation) and the wage at Italy in fi gure 6. setters’ loss of discipline (both the private sector IG Figure 6: net fi xed capital formation at current Metall and the public sector ÖTV) which ensued prices: general government (1991-2019) from the infl ationary post-reunifi cation period (in the 1991 and 1992 wage rounds). In this contin- gency, throughout the 1990s, the Kohl govern- ment decided to slash public investment, to reduce the size of the unifi ed public sector and to force public sector wage restraint in order to rein in the budget defi cit and comply with the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) by the fi scal year 1997. Ironi- cally enough, it was Mr. Th eo Waigel who wanted the SGP which then haunted Germany until 2006. During the early 2000s, Germany (a then sick man) had hard disputes with the Economic Commis- sioner Pedro Solbes (in the Prodi Commission) to comply with the 3% fi scal rule which it repeat- edly broke, unpunished. In a scenario in which the Commission barks at your back, the easiest way for a government to bring the budget defi cit down Surely enough, one can ask how much is enough. in the short term is to cut/freeze public sector But, again, considering that approximately 2/3 wages (and benefi ts) and slash public investment – of fi scal spending in Germany takes place at the this is, in fact, what also the countries of the EMU decentralized level, we should ask ourselves why periphery did aft er 2010/2011. Th is is surely not should local administrators respond to Eurozone a smart long-term strategy, but it does the job, if imperatives while being accountable to their local that is the political objective to be achieved in the constituencies? short term, given the rules of the game at a specifi c point in time.

GERMANY IS QUIETLY REBALANCING ITS ECONOMY – BUT THIS WILL NOT FIX THE EUROZONE’S FLAWS 286 Donato Di Carlo German Federal and local administrators would started in 2008, is almost completed, i.e. lower be better off investing in the future of their citi- imports from Southern Europe are not the whole zens, especially given the cheap funding possi- story here. Secondly, the collapse of demand in bilities Germany enjoys today. This is an obvious the South could(and should!) have been avoided statement with which it is easy to agree. But, real- regardless of the German current account surplus: istically speaking, I don’t see why one shouldn’t it is due to the lack of stabilization mechanisms also be open to the possibility that, more simply, at the supranational level and, especially, to bad the timing may be wrong to ask Germany for a policy choices. Teutonic New Deal: it is perfectly conceivable, in So, where does the German current account fact, to imagine German local administrators to surplus come from? Neither from the EU Single currently maintain a preference for a moderate Market, nor from the Euro Area. (yet steady) expansion of investment rather than a massive fiscal stimulus. Ever since summer 2008, Germany’s trade surplus with EMU partners has disappeared and the In other words, there seems to exist an inconsist- current account surplus has been driven solely ency in the very pre-conditions for the implemen- by extra-EMU trade. In this sense, Germany tation of Keynesian economic policies in a system quietly exited the euro in 2008 to then assail inter- of multilevel governance: i.e., a clear mismatch national markets in 2011. OECD statistics show between the possibility – and the incentives – for that the driving markets behind export growth German fiscal authorities to implement Keynesi- in Germany have been the US, the UK and the anism at home (in Germany) with the hope to People’s Republic of China - all of them outside engineer Keynesianism abroad (in the EMU). This the EMU. is because of the asymmetric effects of an incom- plete EMU. After all, to be completely honest: It is exactly this that makes Donald Trump and didn’t Keynes also say that hoarding money in his colleagues very angry. Global imbalances and good times is functional to governments’ counter- the German extra-EMU current account surplus cyclical spending in hard ones? do constitute a serious political and economic issue in advanced capitalism, not least because What about Germany’s current account surplus the surplus makes Germany (and hence the whole vis-à-vis its European partners in the single EMU) fragile vis-à-vis exogenous shocks beyond market? Ever since the crisis, German exports of her control. But in this essay - it is good to repeat goods to the EU have decreased substantially rela- - I leave this issue out of the analysis and only deal tive to its imports. The intra-EU export/imports with the EUROpean perspective. ratio has been going down significantly. In fact, the core countries of the EMU, together with the Here again, it will be argued that the closing of the Visegrád Group, show a higher exports/imports intra-EMU surplus is due to the fall in imports ratio than Germany. from the Periphery. Again, I would subscribe to this objection if it weren’t for the fact that It will be argued, perhaps correctly, that the bulk reasoning in this way constitutes a genetic fallacy: of this decrease is due to fiscal austerity and wage the fact that since 2010 the German intra-EMU restraint in the periphery of the EMU. I am not surplus has disappeared because of austerity and in principle against this objection, but I would internal devaluations in the periphery does not like to ask the reader to consider two qualifica- make the intra-EMU rebalancing less true. tions. First, figure 6 shows that when the ratio for Southern European countries starts going up after the beginning of austerity measures in 2010, the German adjustment in the single market, which

GERMANY IS QUIETLY REBALANCING ITS ECONOMY – BUT THIS WILL NOT FIX THE EUROZONE’S FLAWS 287 Donato Di Carlo Figure 7: Intra-EU exports divided by intra-EU not via internal devaluations!). Will, on the other imports (2002-16) hand, asking Germany to slow down its extra- EMU export engine benefi t the EMU? I think it is hard to tell. Possibly, it is instead likely to reduce German imports from its EU trade partners even further. Figure 9: Top-three partners of each member state in intra-EU exports of goods (2016)

Figure 8: German trade balances with the Euro Area and Extra-Euro Area partners (1999-2018)

Is economic growth in Germany driven by exports, i.e. net trade (exports minus imports)? Or, in other words, does Germany “steal” growth from abroad? When decomposing GDP growth (Figure 10) in the aft ermath of the crisis, we ascertain that export-led growth is an historical parenthesis rather than a structural feature of the German economy. GDP growth was strongly driven by net exports during 2001-2007. In the aft ermath of the crisis, given increased real wages and government expenditures, GDP growth has been driven mostly by household consumption, public and private As far as the single market is concerned, Germany investment. Yes, the export share in total GDP is virtually the largest importer for all its members. remains high in relative terms, but data suggests Germany, thanks to its size and industrial sector at that net exports have not been the main drivers the core of the EMU, already provides a very wide of GDP growth in post-crisis Germany: the trend market for EMU exports. Th is will not come as a has been reversed. surprise to many, but it is simply taken to show that there will be limits to the extent that Germany can realistically expand its imports from its EMU peers – especially until these upgrade their productive structures (with smart investments –

GERMANY IS QUIETLY REBALANCING ITS ECONOMY – BUT THIS WILL NOT FIX THE EUROZONE’S FLAWS 288 Donato Di Carlo Figure 10: Contributions of different compo- itself. I would argue that, contrary to what is nents of aggregate demand to change of GDP usually claimed, there are indications to main- (1996-2019) tain that the pre-crisis trend is being reversed and that Germany has made some important steps towards a “quiet” rebalancing. This is good news and should be kept in mind if we aspire to having constructive politics in the EU. But does this mean that Germany, and the EMU, are safe and sound? No, not at all. As for Germany’s extra-EMU current account surplus, there is probably only one person real- istically capable of tackling the issue. This person sits in Washington and we should expect him to sooner or later deal with it. It is likely to be nasty and the EMU should be ready when the next exog- enous shock will arrive. An incomplete EMU remains fragile and requires upkeep. German politicians are not immaculate in this story and, if they want others to stop teaching CONCLUSIONS them how to run their fiscal and wage policies, they should stop opposing projects to fine-tune Before moving to the conclusions I shall make the EMU and venture into a serious reform plan clear what this essay does not argue, in order to that envisages blühende Landschaften for EUROpe avoid any misunderstanding. I am not arguing that as a whole and not for Germany alone. Whether the German current account and fiscal surpluses they like it or not, they belong to a common are good and desirable. Most importantly, I am not project now. arguing that what documented here is enough for There seems to be one priority around which Germany and the EMU to cheer up, as well as I accusers and defendants should come together am not arguing that German wages should not rise before the next shock arrives: to avoid asymmetric further or that German authorities shouldn’t invest macroeconomic adjustments based solely on the in the future of their citizens. My aim was to play compression of wages and public investment. Two a bit the devils’ advocate and ask two questions institutional changes could serve the purpose. which seem to be forgotten in this very contro- Broadly speaking, a pan-European unemploy- versial debate: what has Germany done since 2010 ment benefit scheme based on national (or better to address its unbalanced growth? And, from a regional) PPPs would work as an automatic stabi- realistic and constructive perspective, what could liser to support household consumption when Germany do given its institutional setting (i.e. countries most in need are forced to switch them off in wage setting structures and fiscal constitution)? their budgets. Secondly, one could imagine an ECB In so doing, I have attempted to go beyond a pure that supports a European Growth Bond by the Euro- macroeconomic reasoning based on accounting pean Investment Bank in the context of a proper identities and tried to push the reader into European Investment Plan. Unfortunately, the reflecting upon historical contingencies and the importance of both these reforms for the stabilisa- institutional constraints on a strategy of Teutonic tion of the EMU has been eclipsed by the attempts Keynesianism that shall rescue the Euro from to create a Capital Markets Union to engineer a financial fix to the structural flaws of the EMU.

GERMANY IS QUIETLY REBALANCING ITS ECONOMY – BUT THIS WILL NOT FIX THE EUROZONE’S FLAWS 289 Donato Di Carlo A complete monetary union is likely to relieve inconsistency problem. It is a short circuit which, to these conflicts and bring benefits also to the be solved, requires today an irrational politician in Germans. I may be wrong, but I do not seem to Germany to drive a process of institutional change remember anyone in my life that has ever argued which tomorrow will benefit also Germany and that Lombardy should undergo an internal appre- the People of Europe. ciation vis-à-vis Sicily (or vice versa). We do not A big obstacle to a constructive debate remains, even seem to discuss publicly whether Sicily runs alas, the fact that German authorities have never a current account deficit or a surplus (although bothered to acknowledge the issue of German regional finance is indeed a hot topic, I agree). To responsibilities in the first place. This is regret- those who argue that an EMU with pan-European table and does not pay justice to the need to play automatic stabilizers will turn into a permanent cooperatively in a monetary union. Yet, it is also structure of uni-directional fiscal transfers to the time for critics (me included) to face the fact that, South, one should remind two points. while being necessary, an acknowledgment of the First, Germany is a big country with relatively problem of Germany’s unbalanced growth will not deprived areas as much as Italy is a big country be sufficient to trigger the supposed spectacular with relatively rich and prosperous areas. Shifting German expansion that shall cure the sorrows of the political discourse around fiscal transfers to the young Euro. In my view, it is a mistake to insist the regional dimension (NUTS 1 and 2) would that Keynesianism in Germany will fix the Euro- probably help to avoid poisonous nationalist zone’s problems: Germany should not and cannot discourses and would enable us to see how all be the fixer of last resort for the single currency. countries would stand to benefit from a system Supranational adjustment mechanisms are needed of supranational automatic stabilisers calibrate on for the stabilisation of the Eurozone in hard times- a regional basis - even the “Wessi” Germans and even if I am aware that this is easier said than done. the Northern Italians, the “non terroni”. Secondly, But we should start from somewhere. had the EMU had a system of supranational auto- matic stabilisers in place since 1999, the Germans - or better parts of Germany - would have been net receivers for approximately half of the EMU’s existence. The simple intuition here is that insur- ance systems exist exactly because we live in an uncertain world and cannot foresee exogenous shocks. Indeed, if we could, we wouldn’t let them occur – I guess just like in that Tom Cruise movie, Minority Report. Given its high current account surplus, Germany is, today more than ever, a very fragile country in a world in which free trade and liberal values cannot be taken for granted anymore. Since German authorities are now under the impres- sion of being immortal, they think that a pan- European insurance system is not in Germany’s long-term interest. I wonder what the answer would have been, had one asked them about the merits of a pan-European unemployment bene- fits scheme in 2001/2004. This is, basically, a time

GERMANY IS QUIETLY REBALANCING ITS ECONOMY – BUT THIS WILL NOT FIX THE EUROZONE’S FLAWS 290 Donato Di Carlo QM-05-18-106-EN-N

doi:10.2870/83554 ISBN:978-92-9084-711-3