Unanticipated Changes in Aggregate Supply Page 1 of 3

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Unanticipated Changes in Aggregate Supply Page 1 of 3 Monetary and Fiscal Policy Recessions and Booms Unanticipated Changes in Aggregate Supply Page 1 of 3 We’ve described bad deflation as a period of falling prices that coincides with falling output; that is, during a period of recession, prices often drop, particularly when the recession is driven by a reduction in demand. When the action starts on the supply side, however, you can get an odd alternative, which is that falling prices are actually occurring during the period of increased output. That is the best of both worlds; a lower price level and a higher standard of living. On the one hand, you can also get the worst of both worlds; that is, rising prices during a period of high unemployment. When the supply side is the main actor in the story, we wind up with prices and output moving in opposite directions. Let’s see how this works. Consider now a change in the environment that shifts the short-run aggregate supply curve. The short-run aggregate supply curve shifts independently of long run supply when there’s a change in something that influences the prices that businesses have to charge for their goods and services. That would result, if for example, there was a supply shock like an increase in the price of some important resource input like oil or if wages were suddenly increased because of activity on the part of unions. If wages go up or if supply shocks occur, then the short-run aggregate supply curve moves independently of the green curve because businesses then have to pass these higher costs onto their customers in the form of higher prices for the output. So, for instance, if there is a supply shock, say during the early 1970’s when war in the Middle East increased the price of oil substantially, it showed up in the model on this form. The short-run supply curve shifted upward meaning that businesses were now going to be charging higher prices than before for the same outputs. So here we now wind up with a new short- run aggregate supply curve. What’s going to happen is the economy adjusts in the short run. At the original price level now we have excess demand for goods; that is, on the red curve businesses, households, foreigners and the government still want to buy the same quantity of goods and services. However on the supply side, because of the rising cost of doing business, businesses want to produce less. The result of this excess demand for goods is going to be a rise in prices and rise in prices then are going to have an effect on both sides of the market. As the price level rises on the demand side, the aggregate demand, the quantity of goods and services that people want to buy is going to be shrinking. First of all, because of the wealth effect. Consumers now feel less wealthy because higher prices shrink the purchasing power of their mutual funds and savings accounts and nominal wealth. Businesses want to spend less because the increased demand for money that accompanies rising prices bids up the interest rate and as the interest rate rises, businesses find it less profitable to invest in factories and equipment. And finally, foreigners are going to be buying less because our prices in the U.S. are rising relative to prices abroad. On the supply side of the economy, we’re going to find that the quantity of goods supplied increases, because as the price level rises three things happen. First, the price of output rising relative to the price of wages, and when that happens then, businesses see a temporary profit opportunity and expand their output. The second thing is because of sticky prices not all of the businesses in the economy are able to get their prices up with the general price level and they experience a short term surge in demand for their products which are relatively under-priced. And finally there’s confusion. Businesses don’t know yet whether these rising prices represent increased demand for their particular products or whether it’s just general economy-wide inflation so they take advantage of what they think may be a business opportunity by increasing their output in the short run. The end result is with the supply shock we wind up with the following change. Output in equilibrium falls below its full employment level at the same time as the price level increases from the original level of P0 to a new higher level of P1. Well, look, there you have it; stagflation. Rising prices at the same time as a recession is occurring because output is falling below full employment. Unemployment coexists with rising prices. You can only get that outcome whenever the story is driven by a change on the supply side. Supply shocks create stagflation. Now the question is what could the government do, what could the Fed do to mitigate the impact of this change in the environment. Well, the problem is two fold. We’ve got rising prices; that is, inflation which has its own costs and we’ve got unemployment which has its own costs. It turns out that anything the government does is going to improve one of these problems by making the other one worse. Let’s see how this might work. Government spending and taxes, that is, fiscal policy, could be used to try to offset the effect of this supply shock. If the government wanted to try to take pressure off of prices, it could reduce government spending or raise taxes and shift the aggregate demand curve inwards. If the aggregate demand curve is shifted inwards, then what happens is the price level is going to fall back to its original level in the short run equilibrium. However getting this aggregate demand curve down here is going to mean that output falls even further, the recession deepens. So the government Monetary and Fiscal Policy Recessions and Booms Unanticipated Changes in Aggregate Supply Page 2 of 3 can take the pressure off the prices, but only at the expense of reducing output further and increasing unemployment. On the other hand if the government wants to get unemployment down to its original level or increase output back to full employment, it could spend more money or cut taxes to stimulate demand. In that case what happens is the economy returns to full employment. On the other hand the price level is going to wind up going higher in equilibrium. So, you see we’re stuck here with the tradeoff, the typical tradeoff that the Phillips Curve describes. You can either fight inflation or you can fight unemployment; but you can’t do both simultaneously. This is the tradeoff that these supply shocks create for the economy. So let’s suppose that the government is particularly concerned about unemployment. If it is, then what’s going to happen is this. The government is going to spend more money pushing the aggregate demand curve from its original level of AB0 out to AB1. In this case, the increased demand for goods and services means that more output is required at any price level to satisfy demand. What that does then is in the short run pushes prices up even higher and as these prices rise, businesses are willing to produce more output and some of the demand from consumers and businesses is choked off even further till we get to the new equilibrium. But because the situation began with a supply shock, we wind up with a higher price level. If the government wants to close this unemployment gap and bring us back to full employment, the cost is going to be higher prices. And prices noticed wind up going up by exactly the amount that businesses were trying to raise originally in response to the supply shock. So prices wind up going up by the full amount of what it was that fed into the economy originally and created the problem. What could the Fed do? Well, the Fed could reduce the money supply and fight the inflation by shifting the aggregate demand curve inward. If the Fed reduced the money supply, then the aggregate demand curve would shift back here as interest rates rose and businesses cut back their spending. That would push the price level back to its original level, but it would deepen the recession. Alternatively, the Fed could increase the money supply and lower interest rates and stimulate the economy pushing the aggregate demand curve to this level. Prices are going to go up further, but at least we don’t have to suffer the recession. That’s the way things work whenever the story is driven on the supply side. Let’s consider one more possibility and that’s the case where the green curve actually shifts. If the green curve shifts, then the full employment level of output is going to increase in equilibrium. So we’re going to move from an original long-run aggregate supply curve, 0, to a new one and we’ll call this long run aggregate supply curve 1. What would cause this to happen? What causes a long-run aggregate supply curve to increase? What causes the economy to be able to produce more goods and services than before without having to worry about inflation? Well, the things that could do that would be an improvement in technology or immigration, which increases the labor supply to the economy. Also capital accumulation, building more factories increases the amount of output that we can produce before inflation becomes a risk.
Recommended publications
  • Dangers of Deflation Douglas H
    ERD POLICY BRIEF SERIES Economics and Research Department Number 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks Pilipinas F. Quising Asian Development Bank http://www.adb.org Asian Development Bank P.O. Box 789 0980 Manila Philippines 2002 by Asian Development Bank December 2002 ISSN 1655-5260 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Asian Development Bank. The ERD Policy Brief Series is based on papers or notes prepared by ADB staff and their resource persons. The series is designed to provide concise nontechnical accounts of policy issues of topical interest to ADB management, Board of Directors, and staff. Though prepared primarily for internal readership within the ADB, the series may be accessed by interested external readers. Feedback is welcome via e-mail ([email protected]). ERD POLICY BRIEF NO. 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks and Pilipinas F. Quising December 2002 ecently, there has been growing concern about deflation in some Rcountries and the possibility of deflation at the global level. Aggregate demand, output, and employment could stagnate or decline, particularly where debt levels are already high. Standard economic policy stimuli could become less effective, while few policymakers have experience in preventing or halting deflation with alternative means. Causes and Consequences of Deflation Deflation refers to a fall in prices, leading to a negative change in the price index over a sustained period. The fall in prices can result from improvements in productivity, advances in technology, changes in the policy environment (e.g., deregulation), a drop in prices of major inputs (e.g., oil), excess capacity, or weak demand.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 19 the Theory of Effective Demand
    Chapter 19 The theory of effective demand In essence, the “Keynesian revolution” was a shift of emphasis from one type of short-run equilibrium to another type as providing the appropriate theory for actual unemployment situations. Edmund Malinvaud (1977), p. 29. In this and the following chapters the focus is shifted from long-run macro- economics to short-run macroeconomics. The long-run models concentrated on factors of importance for the economic evolution over a time horizon of at least 10-15 years. With such a horizon the supply side (think of capital accumulation, population growth, and technological progress) is the primary determinant of cumulative changes in output and consumption the trend. Mainstream macro- economists see the demand side and monetary factors as of key importance for the fluctuations of output and employment about the trend. In a long-run perspective these fluctuations are of only secondary quantitative importance. The preceding chapters have chieflyignored them. But within shorter horizons, fluctuations are the focal point and this brings the demand-side, monetary factors, market imper- fections, nominal rigidities, and expectation errors to the fore. The present and subsequent chapters deal with the role of these short- and medium-run factors for the failure of the laissez-faire market economy to ensure full employment and for the possibilities of active macro policies as a means to improve outcomes. This chapter introduces building blocks of Keynesian theory of the short run. By “Keynesian theory”we mean a macroeconomic framework that (a) aims at un- derstanding “what determines the actual employment of the available resources”,1 including understanding why mass unemployment arises from time to time, and (b) in this endeavor ascribes a primary role to aggregate demand.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Answers FE312 Fall 2010 Rahman 1) Suppose the Fed
    Problem Set 7 – Some Answers FE312 Fall 2010 Rahman 1) Suppose the Fed reduces the money supply by 5 percent. a) What happens to the aggregate demand curve? If the Fed reduces the money supply, the aggregate demand curve shifts down. This result is based on the quantity equation MV = PY, which tells us that a decrease in money M leads to a proportionate decrease in nominal output PY (assuming of course that velocity V is fixed). For any given price level P, the level of output Y is lower, and for any given Y, P is lower. b) What happens to the level of output and the price level in the short run and in the long run? In the short run, we assume that the price level is fixed and that the aggregate supply curve is flat. In the short run, output falls but the price level doesn’t change. In the long-run, prices are flexible, and as prices fall over time, the economy returns to full employment. If we assume that velocity is constant, we can quantify the effect of the 5% reduction in the money supply. Recall from Chapter 4 that we can express the quantity equation in terms of percent changes: ΔM/M + ΔV/V = ΔP/P + ΔY/Y We know that in the short run, the price level is fixed. This implies that the percentage change in prices is zero and thus ΔM/M = ΔY/Y. Thus in the short run a 5 percent reduction in the money supply leads to a 5 percent reduction in output.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflationary Expectations and the Costs of Disinflation: a Case for Costless Disinflation in Turkey?
    Inflationary Expectations and the Costs of Disinflation: A Case for Costless Disinflation in Turkey? $0,,993 -44 : Abstract: This paper explores the output costs of a credible disinflationary program in Turkey. It is shown that a necessary condition for a costless disinflationary path is that the weight attached to future inflation in the formation of inflationary expectations exceeds 50 percent. Using quarterly data from 1980 - 2000, the estimate of the weight attached to future inflation is found to be consistent with a costless disinflation path. The paper also uses structural Vector Autoregressions (VAR) to explore the implications of stabilizing aggregate demand. The results of the structural VAR corroborate minimum output losses associated with disinflation. 1. INTRODUCTION Inflationary expectations and aggregate demand pressure are two important variables that influence inflation. It is recognized that reducing inflation through contractionary demand policies can involve significant reductions in output and employment relative to potential output. The empirical macroeconomics literature is replete with estimates of the so- called “sacrifice ratio,” the percentage cumulative loss of output due to a 1 percent reduction in inflation. It is well known that inflationary expectations play a significant role in any disinflation program. If inflationary expectations are adaptive (backward-looking), wage contracts would be set accordingly. If inflation drops unexpectedly, real wages rise increasing employment costs for employers. Employers would then cut back employment and production disrupting economic activity. If expectations are formed rationally (forward- 1 2 looking), any momentum in inflation must be due to the underlying macroeconomic policies. Sargent (1982) contends that the seeming inflation- output trade-off disappears when one adopts the rational expectations framework.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Bank Objectives and Aggregate Disturbances
    Central Bank Objectives and Aggregate Disturbances by 1 Chandranath Amarasekara Abstract The amendment to the Monetary Law Act in 2002 defines “economic and price stability” as one of Central Bank of Sri Lanka’s core objectives. Using a standard aggregate demand – aggregate supply model with varying policy preferences this paper discusses the achievability of “economic and price stability” when the economy is faced with aggregate demand disturbances and aggregate supply disturbances. As demand disturbances move both output and prices in the same direction, monetary policy can counter the shock thus achieving output and price stability simultaneously. However, supply disturbances move output and prices in opposite directions, and the central bank may not be able to maintain both output and price stability. In such circumstances, extreme policy aimed purely at price stability aggravates the effect of the supply disturbance on the real economy. This confirms that, while price stability must remain the focus of a modern central bank, the stability of the real economy cannot be totally ignored in monetary policymaking. Keywords: central banking, monetary policy, supply disturbances, demand disturbances JEL classification: E10, E52, E58, E61 Introduction I have often been intrigued by the amendment to the Monetary Law Act in 2002 which defined “economic and price stability” as one of CBSL’s key objectives particularly because it somewhat differs from the perception that a central bank must aim at maintaining nothing but price stability. The objective of “economic and price stability” has been further clarified in Wijewardena (2007), citing the then Governor A.S.Jayawardena: “if you have only price stability, then you would fall into the trap of attempting to stabilize a price index which is not what is meant by price stability, in the context of a central bank.
    [Show full text]
  • A Classical View of the Business Cycle
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A CLASSICAL VIEW OF THE BUSINESS CYCLE Michael T. Belongia Peter N. Ireland Working Paper 26056 http://www.nber.org/papers/w26056 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2019 We are especially grateful to David Laidler for his encouragement during the development of this paper and to John Taylor, Kenneth West, two referees, and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta for helpful comments on previous drafts. All errors that remain are our own. Neither of us received any external support for, or has any financial interest that relates to, the research described in this paper. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2019 by Michael T. Belongia and Peter N. Ireland. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. A Classical View of the Business Cycle Michael T. Belongia and Peter N. Ireland NBER Working Paper No. 26056 July 2019 JEL No. B12,E31,E32,E41,E43,E52 ABSTRACT In the 1920s, Irving Fisher extended his previous work on the Quantity Theory to describe, through an early version of the Phillips Curve, how changes in the money stock could be associated with cyclical movements in output, employment, and inflation.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 33: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Principles of Economics, 8Th Edition N
    Chapter 33: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Principles of Economics, 8th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1 1. Introduction a. We now turn to a short term view of fluctuations in the economy. b. This is the chapter that made this book controversial as Mankiw tends to ignore the Keynesian framework contained in most Principles textbooks. c. I personally find that to be a substantial improvement over those earlier books. d. Here we use the aggregate demand-aggregate supply model to explain short term economic fluctuations around the long term trend of the economy. e. On average over the past 50 years, the production of the US economy as measured by real GDP has grown by about 3 percent per year. i. While this has to be adjusted for population growth, one has to wonder why people tend to view their economic position so negatively. ii. Recession is a period of declining real incomes and rising unemployment. P. 702. iii. A depression is a severe recession. P. 702. 2. Three Key Facts about Economic Fluctuations a. Fact 1: Economic fluctuations are irregular and unpredictable i. They are called the business cycle, which can be misleading. ii. Figure 1: A Look at Short-run Economic Fluctuations. P. 703. iii. Every time that you hear depressing economic news–and they are reported often, remember Figure 1(a). iv. The last 25 years has observed steady real growth with only minor reversals. b. Fact 2: Most macroeconomic quantities fluctuate together c. Fact 3: As output falls, unemployment rises 3. Explaining Short Run Economic Fluctuations a.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effects on the Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply During the Great Economic Depression
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by UGD Academic Repository The Effects on the Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply during the Great Economic Depression ISSN 1857-9973 338.124.4:[338.23:336.74(100) Stevan Gaber 1, Vasilka Gaber-Naumoska 2, Aleksandar Naumoski3 1Goce Delcev University, Faculty of Economics, Krste Misirkov St., 10-A, Stip, Republic of Macedonia, e-mail: [email protected] 2Public Revenue Office, Bul. Kuzman Josifovski-Pitu No.1, Skopje 1000, Republic of Macedonia, e-mail: [email protected]; 3 Ss. Cyril and Methodius University in Skopje, Faculty of Economics, Bul. Goce Delcev 9V, Skopje 1000, Republic of Macedonia, e-mail: [email protected] Abstract The Great Depression of 1929 created significant consequences for the US economy and world economy that are detected through serious changes in output and prices. It contributed to put greater emphasis on aggregate demand and aggregate supply. Many economists agreed that in addition to monetary factors major impact on the crisis had also non-monetary factors. Numerous studies have indicated that even the gold standard played an important role in reducing output and the price level. This paper attempts to highlight key segments, such as the wrong monetary policy, the gold standard, neglected banking problems, political pressure aimed at relaxing the monetary policy as areas that have made mistakes when looking a way out of the crisis. The critics of such thesis believed that the tighter monetary policy was not strong enough to cause so far-reaching consequences and expressed serious doubts that the reduced money supply is the real cause of the collapse of the national product and price levels.
    [Show full text]
  • Robert J. Barro Harvard University Department of Economics Littauer Center Cambridge, MA 02138 Keynesian Models
    NEER WORKING PAPER SERIES NEW CLASSICALS AND KEYNESIANS, OR THE GOOD GUYS AND THE BAD GUYS - RobertJ.Barro WorkingPaper No. 2982 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 May, 1989 Prepared for presentation at the 125th anniversary meeting of the Swiss Economic Association, April 1989. This paper is part of NBER's research program in Economic Fluctuations. Any opinions expressed are thoseof the author not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER WorkingPaper #2982 May1989 NEWC1ASSICALS AND KEYNESIANS, OR THEGOOD GUYS AND THE BAD GUYS ABSTRACT Old-style Keynesian models relied on sticky prices or wages to explain unemployment and to argue for demand-side macroeconomic policies. This approach relied increasingly on a Phillips-curve view of the world, and therefore lost considerable prestige with the events of the 1970s. The new classical macroeconomics began at about that time, and focused initially on the apparent real effects of monetary disturbances. Despite initial successes, this analysis ultimately was unsatisfactory as an explanation for an important role of money in business fluctuations. Nevertheless, the approach achieved important methodological advances, such as rational expectations and new methods of policy evaluation. Subsequent research by new classicals has deemphasized monetary shocks, and focused instead on real business cycle models and theories of endogenous economic growth. These areas appear promising at this time. Another development is the so-called new Keynesian economics, which includes long-term contracts, menu costs, efficiency wages and insider-outsider theories, and macroeconomic models with imperfect competition. Although some of these ideas may prove helpful as elements in real business cycle models, my main conclusion is that the new Keynesian economics has not been successful in rehabilitating the Keynesian approach.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses
    Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses Craig K. Elwell Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy August 30, 2010 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov R40512 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses Summary Despite the severity of the recent financial crisis and recession, the U.S. economy has so far avoided falling into a deflationary spiral. Since mid-2009, the economy has been on a path of economic recovery. However, the pace of economic growth during the recovery has been relatively slow, and major economic weaknesses persist. In this economic environment, the risk of deflation remains significant and could delay sustained economic recovery. Deflation is a persistent decline in the overall level of prices. It is not unusual for prices to fall in a particular sector because of rising productivity, falling costs, or weak demand relative to the wider economy. In contrast, deflation occurs when price declines are so widespread and sustained that they cause a broad-based price index, such as the Consumer Price Index (CPI), to decline for several quarters. Such a continuous decline in the price level is more troublesome, because in a weak or contracting economy it can lead to a damaging self-reinforcing downward spiral of prices and economic activity. However, there are also examples of relatively benign deflations when economic activity expanded despite a falling price level. For instance, from 1880 through 1896, the U.S. price level fell about 30%, but this coincided with a period of strong economic growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Summary of IS-LM and AS-AD
    Summary of IS-LM and AS-AD Karl Whelan September 19, 2014 The Goods Market • This is in equilibrium when the demand for goods equals the supply of goods. • Higher real interest rates mean there is less demand for spending. – Consumers choose to save instead of spend. – Businesses discouraged from borrowing for investment. • So higher real interest rates mean the goods market equilibrium (demand = supply) occurs at a lower level of supply, i.e. lower GDP> The IS Curve Shifts in the IS Curve • Anything that leads to higher demand for spending that is NOT real interest rates will shift the IS curve to the right. This includes – Improvements in consumer\business sentiment. – Higher government spending. – Lower taxes. – Good news about the future of the economy. • The opposite type of developments (e.g. lower consumer sentiment) will shift the IS curve to the left. A Fall in Consumer Confidence The Money Market: Demand • You have to keep all of your assets in one of two forms – Money, which bears no interest but can be used for transactions. – Bonds, which pay an interest rate of r. • Three factors determine the demand for money – GDP: More GDP means you need more money for transactions. – Prices: Doubling prices means you need double the money for transactions – Interest Rates: Higher interest rates means less demand for money and more demand for bonds. An Equation for Money Demand An equation to describe this would look like this: Where Money Supply • This is set by the central bank. • In reality, the central bank only controls the monetary base (currency and reserves at the central bank).
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 12 the Phillips Curve
    Lecture 12 The Phillips Curve Principles of Macroeconomics KOF, ETH Zurich, Prof. Dr. Jan-Egbert Sturm Fall Term 2008 General Information 23.9. Introduction Ch. 1,2 30.9. National Accounting Ch. 10, 11 7.10. Production and Growth Ch. 12 14.10. Saving and Investment Ch. 13 21.10. Unemployment Ch. 15 28.10. The Monetary System Ch. 16, 17 4.11. International Trade (incl. Basic Concepts of Ch. 3, 7, 9 Supply/Demand/Welfare) 11.11. Open Economy Macro Ch. 18 18.11. Open Economy Macro Ch. 19 25.11. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Ch. 20 2.12. Monetary and Fiscal Policy Ch. 21 9.12. Phillips Curve Ch. 22 16.12. Overview / Q&A Q&A Session next week (december 16) • Please send your questions to • [email protected] • Questions received before Friday, december 12, 23:59 will be discussed during the Q&A session Remember: Natural Rate of Unemployment • The natural rate of unemployment is unemployment that does not go away on its own even in the long run • There are two reasons why there is a positive natural rate of unemployment: 1. job search (frictional unemployment) 2. wage rigidity (structural unemployment) • Minimum-wage laws • Unions • Efficiency wages Remember: The Classical Dichotomy • The quantity equation: M × V = P × Y • relates the quantity of money (M) to the nominal value of output (P×Y) • The quantity equation shows that an increase in money must be reflected in one of three other variables: • The price level must rise, • the quantity of output must rise, or • the velocity of money must fall • The velocity of money is considered to be (relatively) fixed • The classical dichotomy • Real economic variables do not change with changes in the money • Hence, changes in the money supply only affect the price level Remember: A Contraction in Aggregate Demand 2.
    [Show full text]