The Relevance for Developing Counfries of Recent Developments in Macroeconomic Theory

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Relevance for Developing Counfries of Recent Developments in Macroeconomic Theory THE WORLD BANK Discussion Paper Public Disclosure Authorized DEVELOPMENT POLICY ISSUES SERIES Report No. JERS5 The Relevance for Developing Counfries Public Disclosure Authorized of Recent Developments in Macroeconomic Theory W. Max Corden Public Disclosure Authorized June 1986 Office of the Vice President Economics and Research Public Disclosure Authorized The views presented here are those of the author, and they should not be interpreted as reflecting those of the World Bank. THE RELEVANCE FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES OF RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN MACROECONOMIC THEORY by W. Max Corden June 1986 The author is Professor of Economics, Australian National University. An earlier version of this paper was prepared, at the suggestion of Carlos Diaz-Alejandro, as background for a proposed World Bank project on macroeconomic policy in developing countries. I am indebted to valuable comments from John Cuddington and Mohsin Khan. for the views expressed herein The World Bank does not accept responsibility be attributed to the World which are those of the author(s) and should not findings, interpretations, and Bank or to its affiliated organizations. The by the Bank; they do not conclusions are the results of research supported Bank. The designations employed, necessarily represent official policy of the in this document are solely the presentation of material, and any maps used imply the expression of any for the convenience of the reader and do not Bank or its affiliates concerning opinion whatsoever on the part of the World city, area, or of its authorities, the legal status of any country, territory, or national affiliation. or concerning the delimitations of its boundaries, Abstract This paper reviews recent developments in macroeconomic theory and considers their relevance for the study of developing countries. Particular emphasis is given to the rational expectations revolution. It is asked whether government policies can be regarded as systematic, and it is suggested that the expectations on which governments' own decisions are based need to be studied. Also discussed are the neo-Ricardian theorem, the implications of real wage rigidity and of supply side models with sectoral income effects, and recent models involving large group interaction. Table of Contents Page No. I. Introduction .......................................... 1 II. Keynesian Economics and Rational Expectations ......... 2 A. Market-Clearing Approach .................. 2 B. Explaining Nominal Rigidities ................... 3 C. Policy Surprises and Rational Expectations ........ 4 III. Are There Keynesian Effects in LDCs?............... 6 IV. The Rational Expectations Revolution .............. 10 V. Systematic and Benign Government Policies? 12 A. Are Government Policies Systematic? ....... 1 2 B. Benign, Optimizing Government and the Political Economy Issue ..... 13 C. The Crucial Macroeconomic Issues for LDCs........ 15 VI. The Rational Expectations of Government ............ 16 VII. The Neo-Ricardian Theorem and LDCs ..................... 17 VIII. Nonmarket Clearing Models.................... 20 IX. Real Wage Rigidity .............................. 21 A. Explaining Real Wage Rigidity ............... 21 B. Raising Employment with Real Wage Rigidity..... 22 C. Real Wage Rigidity and LDCs ................ 23 X. Supply Side Models and Sectoral Income Effects........ 24 XI. Large Group Interaction and Game Theory ...... 26 XII. Conclusion ............ ......... ...... 28 The Relevance for Developing Countries of Recent Developments in Macroeconomic Theory W. Max Corden I. Introduction This paper reviews the recent literature of macroeconomic theory in developed countries (called DCs here). To a great extent this is an American literature, though I shall also refer to some approaches more popular in Europe. The paper considers the relevance of various discussions and models for developing countries (LDCs). Much of the paper is concerned with the "irational expectations revolution" and its possible relevance for studying macroeconomic policies in LDCs. It is impossible to specify some standard DC model, or perhaps some textbook written for DCs, and then relate it to a standard LDC model, or to a particular LDC, hence clearly bringing out differences between the models or bringing out the way in which the DC model (or the textbook) needs adjusting to suit the particular LDC. The reasons for this are (a) that DC macroeconomic theory since the destruction of the Keynesian consensus is not sufficiently consolidated, and (b) the great diversity of the characteristics and experiences of the LDCs. Every idea that can be found in the recent DC literature can be shown to have some relevance for some LDC somewhere, and the DC literature is so extensive that one could never successfully claim that an issue important for any LDC has been completely neglected in the DC literature. For this reason every generalization made below must be thoroughly qualified. -2- II. Keynesian Economics and Rational Expectations The central message of Keynesian economics is that demand management through monetary and fiscal policies can successfully stabilize output and employment, and possibly raise the average level of employment over a longer period. The recent DC theoretical literature seeks to explain to what extent Keynesian nominal demand policies can work when some allowance is made for rational behavior. This literature can really be regarded as having three parts. In the first part it is assumed that market-clearing wages and prices are continuously established, and the question is then asked whether Keynesian effects can still be generated through policy surprises. The second part seeks to explain the existence of nominal rigidities, especially wage rigidities. The third part - which is the most interesting and relevant for the present discussion - is concerned with the role of policy surprises and the scope for policy activism, given some rigidities. A. Market-Clearing Approach Suppose that there were instantaneous market clearing; any increase in nominal demand in a, particular market would thus lead to a rise in the relevant price. Surprise shocks in nominal demand - e.g., an increase in the money supply - would still have real effects if their implications were initially misunderstood. This is an "incomplete information" problem. 1/ For example, if a nominal demand expansion leads to a rise in prices and nominal wages, without necessarily any change in real wages, but it is misunderstood 1/ This market-clearing approach is set out systematically in Barro (1984, Chapter 18), and originated with Lucas, Barro, and Sargent and Wallace (see footnote 3 below). -3- as either a rise in real wages (so as to lead to greater labor supply) or as representing a rise in real profitability (so as to lead to an expansion by firms and thereby greater labor demand), then nominal demand policies would have real effects, This type of story (the Lucas supply function) has been given much prominence in the DC theoretical literature. The argument of the rational expectations theorists is that it is not possible to surprise private agents consistently. If the government is following some kind of policy rule, that rule will be discovered in due course. On average, nominal demand changes will thus come to be expected, and then they will not be misunderstood when they happen. There is an objection to this approach. It seems implausible that firms or workers misunderstand a general expansion or contraction of demand when these actually happen. They may not understand why they happen, and may have failed to anticipate them, but with complete and instantaneous price and wage flexibility it is not really necessary to anticipate events. If one believes that prices and wages are very flexible in response to market conditions one should, therefore, not expect nominal demand policies to generate real output and employment changes, even when the policies are expected. The whole discussion only becomes interesting once some rigidities in prices and wages, or at least significant lags in their adjustment to changing conditions, are introduced. B. Explaining Nominal Rigidities An extensive literature seeks to explain nominal rigidities, especially wage rigidity, as part of an efficient maximizing process. It is -4- notable that nominal wages are (more or less) rigid downwards, and also somewhat sluggish upwards, even in a country like the United States where trade unions are relatively weak. There are explanations both in terms of explicit and implicit contracts. Explicit contracts with unions tend to be longer term in the United States than in-other DCs, so that there has been a particular emphasis on such contracts. One explanation is in terms of negotiation costs, including the costs and delays involved in the process of organizing collectively agreed upon positions (the "logic of collective action"). Another explanation rests on the willingness of employers to accept the risks for their profits of demand fluctuations, employees being risk- averse and unable to insure adequately against income fluctuations. There is an implicit contract literature, which cannot be summarized here (see Azariadis and Stiglitz, 1983). Most explanations for wage rigidities seem to be explanations of real rather than nominal rigidities, and only the difficulties of indexation (which, surely, are not so great) can explain why rigidities that are intended to be real turn out to be nominal. If there is learning, then the experience of inflation
Recommended publications
  • How the Rational Expectations Revolution Has Enriched
    How the Rational Expectations Revolution Has Changed Macroeconomic Policy Research by John B. Taylor STANFORD UNIVERSITY Revised Draft: February 29, 2000 Written versions of lecture presented at the 12th World Congress of the International Economic Association, Buenos Aires, Argentina, August 24, 1999. I am grateful to Jacques Dreze for helpful comments on an earlier draft. The rational expectations hypothesis is by far the most common expectations assumption used in macroeconomic research today. This hypothesis, which simply states that people's expectations are the same as the forecasts of the model being used to describe those people, was first put forth and used in models of competitive product markets by John Muth in the 1960s. But it was not until the early 1970s that Robert Lucas (1972, 1976) incorporated the rational expectations assumption into macroeconomics and showed how to make it operational mathematically. The “rational expectations revolution” is now as old as the Keynesian revolution was when Robert Lucas first brought rational expectations to macroeconomics. This rational expectations revolution has led to many different schools of macroeconomic research. The new classical economics school, the real business cycle school, the new Keynesian economics school, the new political macroeconomics school, and more recently the new neoclassical synthesis (Goodfriend and King (1997)) can all be traced to the introduction of rational expectations into macroeconomics in the early 1970s (see the discussion by Snowden and Vane (1999), pp. 30-50). In this lecture, which is part of the theme on "The Current State of Macroeconomics" at the 12th World Congress of the International Economic Association, I address a question that I am frequently asked by students and by "non-macroeconomist" colleagues, and that I suspect may be on many people's minds.
    [Show full text]
  • Das Maynard Keynes Problem: Rethinking Rationality
    Das Maynard Keynes Problem: Rethinking Rationality Ailian Gan Abstract As with Adam Smith in Das Adam Smith Problem, critics have observed that, across the large body of work produced in John Maynard Keynes’s lifetime, Keynes displays a shifting or even inconsistent view of rationality. In the Treatise on Probability, Keynes argues that economic actors use all available information to make rational decisions. In The General Theory, however, Keynes argues that people are irrational and are highly susceptible to psychological forces. This paper seeks to reconcile both views by arguing that, if one allows economic actors to display a range of rationality, Keynes’s work is wholly consistent. I. Introduction For any great intellectual who produces an enormous body of work, tracing his philosophical foundations and precise intentions is a valuable but daunting task. For Adam Smith, critics were intrigued by the transformations and inconsistencies in arguments of his two most prominent works. In The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Smith was an advocate of sympathy for our fellow human being. In The Wealth of Nations, however, he became a strong advocate of self-interest, arguing that it was the primary motive behind economic behavior and the driving force of the economy. This selfless/selfish mismatch has led many economists following in Smith’s footsteps to question which stance he truly intended and whether the two can be reconciled. Either reading of his intentions can lead to vastly different interpretations of his theories and his legacy. Such was the nature of das Adam Smith problem. For John Maynard Keynes, interpreters of his work face a similar problem.
    [Show full text]
  • The Alleged Necessity of Microfoundations*
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by Erasmus University Digital Repository MAARTEN C. W. JANSSEN Erasmus University Rotterdam Rotterdam, The Netherlands The Alleged Necessity of Microfoundations* It is often said that models in the microfoundations literature derive macroeconomic results from the theory of individual behavior only. This paper examines two of the assumptions that are usually made in these models: market clearing and rational expectations. In the context of simple models it is shown that only in some special cases these assumptions can be derived from the fundamental notion that individ- uals behave rationally. Thus, the usual rationale for the microfoundations literature is challenged. The paper concludes with a more modest rationale for the "necessity" of microfoundations. 1. Introduction Macroeconomics is in need of a microeconomic foundation. Nowadays, this is a widely accepted doctrine in the economics profession. Most economists take the necessity for a microeconomic foundation for granted. If arguments in favor of the necessity for microfoundations are cited, they often are of the following reduc- tionist form. Society consists of individuals who are the only sub- jects that make economic decisions. So, in order to explain what is going on in the economy as a whole--for example, unemployment, inflation, business cycles--we have to understand the individual de- cisions from which a particular situation originates. I think that this "'reductionist credo" itself is largely correct. However, if it is used as an argument in favor of the necessity for microeconomic foun- dations it is presupposed either that microeconomics is only con- cerned with individual behavior or that all microeconomic propo- sitions can be derived from statements concerning individual decision *This paper was written while I was visiting Duke University.
    [Show full text]
  • Unemployment Did Not Rise During the Great Depression—Rather, People Took Long Vacations
    Working Paper No. 652 The Dismal State of Macroeconomics and the Opportunity for a New Beginning by L. Randall Wray Levy Economics Institute of Bard College March 2011 The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2011 All rights reserved ABSTRACT The Queen of England famously asked her economic advisers why none of them had seen “it” (the global financial crisis) coming. Obviously, the answer is complex, but it must include reference to the evolution of macroeconomic theory over the postwar period— from the “Age of Keynes,” through the Friedmanian era and the return of Neoclassical economics in a particularly extreme form, and, finally, on to the New Monetary Consensus, with a new version of fine-tuning. The story cannot leave out the parallel developments in finance theory—with its efficient markets hypothesis—and in approaches to regulation and supervision of financial institutions. This paper critically examines these developments and returns to the earlier Keynesian tradition to see what was left out of postwar macro.
    [Show full text]
  • Microfoundations
    TI 2006-041/1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper Microfoundations Maarten Janssen Department of Economics, Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam, and Tinbergen Institute. Tinbergen Institute The Tinbergen Institute is the institute for economic research of the Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam, Universiteit van Amsterdam, and Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam. Tinbergen Institute Amsterdam Roetersstraat 31 1018 WB Amsterdam The Netherlands Tel.: +31(0)20 551 3500 Fax: +31(0)20 551 3555 Tinbergen Institute Rotterdam Burg. Oudlaan 50 3062 PA Rotterdam The Netherlands Tel.: +31(0)10 408 8900 Fax: +31(0)10 408 9031 Please send questions and/or remarks of non- scientific nature to [email protected]. Most TI discussion papers can be downloaded at http://www.tinbergen.nl. MICROFOUNDATIONS Maarten C.W. Janssen1 Erasmus University Rotterdam and Tinbergen Institute Abstract. This paper gives an overview and evaluates the literature on Microfoundations. Key Words: Representative Agents, New Keynesian Economics, and New Classical Economics JEL code: B22, D40, E00 1 Correspondence Address: Erasmus University Rotterdam and Tinbergen Institute, Postbus 1738, 3000 DR Rotterdam, The Netherlands, e-mail: [email protected]. This paper is prepared as an entry for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (3rd edition) that is currently being prepared. I thank the editors, Steven Durlauf and David Easley, for comments on an earlier version. 1 The quest to understand microfoundations is an effort to understand aggregate economic phenomena in terms of the behavior of
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Expectations in the Choice of Monetary Policy
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS INTHE CHOICE OF MONETARY POLICY John B. Taylor Working Paper No 1044 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge MA 02138 December 1982 Prepared for a Conference on Monetary Policy Issues for the 1980's sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, at Jackson Hole. Wyoming, August 9-10, 1982 The research reported here was supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation at Princeton University and at the National Bureau of Economic Research and was partly completed at the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. I am grateful to Alan Blinder, David Bradford, Phillip Cagan, Roman Frydman, Robert Gordon, Brian Horrigan, Frederic Mishkin and Joseph Stiglitz for helpful discussions. The research reported here is part of the NBER's research program in Economic Fluctuations. Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Paper #1044 December 1982 The Role of Expectations in The Choice of Monetary POlicy Abstract This paper reviews and contrasts different views about the role of expectations in policy research and practice. Recently, two widely dif- ferent views seem to have dominated the analysis of policy questions. One view, which is referred to as the "new classical macroeconomic" view, is that expectations overwhelm the influence of monetary policy. The other view, which is referred to as the "Keynesian" macroeconomic view, is that expectations are unimportant because people do not adjust to expectations of policy change. The paper argues that both these views are misleading.
    [Show full text]
  • Rational Expectations, Business Cycles, and Government Behavior
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Rational Expectations and Economic Policy Volume Author/Editor: Stanley Fischer, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-25134-9 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/fisc80-1 Publication Date: 1980 Chapter Title: Rational Expectations, Business Cycles, and Government Behavior Chapter Author: Herschel I. Grossman Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c6259 Chapter pages in book: (p. 5 - 22) 1 Rational Expectations, Business Cycles, and Government Behavior Herschel I. Grossman Government and Business Cycles Irregular fluctuations in economic activity, as measured by aggregate production and employment, are a persistent characteristic of market economies. What is the relation between these business cycles and the government’s monetary and fiscal policies, by which we mean its regu- lation of the quantity of money and its total spending and taxation? From an historical perspective, have governmental monetary and fiscal actions exacerbated or mitigated business cycles? With regard to prospects for the future, what are the possibilities for prescribing monetary and fiscal policies that can improve the cyclical performance of the economy? A decade or so ago, the belief was widespread that economists knew the answers to questions such as these, or at least knew how to find the answers. This belief is now severely shaken. The previous optimism derived mainly from the reasonably satisfactory completion of the re- search program associated with the Keynesian revolution. This pro- gram involved the resolution of long-standing theoretical and empirical This paper provides an introduction to the subject of the conference on ra- tional expectations and economic policy and a selective summary.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Has Deflation Continued Under Extraordinary Monetary Expansion?
    PDPRIETI Policy Discussion Paper Series 19-P-028 Why has Deflation Continued under Extraordinary Monetary Expansion? KOBAYASHI, Keiichiro RIETI The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry https://www.rieti.go.jp/en/ RIETI Policy Discussion Paper Series 19-P-028 October 2019 Why has deflation continued under extraordinary monetary expansion?1 Kobayashi, Keiichiro The Tokyo Foundation for Policy Research, RIETI, Keio University, CIGS Abstract We propose a theoretical argument for a new rational expectations equilibrium hypothesis in the intergenerational economy, where each generation is intergenerationally altruistic and rational. The intergenerationally-rational expectations equilibrium implies that deflation can continue under an extreme increase in money supply. Keywords: Deflationary equilibrium, transversality condition, zero nominal interest rate policy. JEL classification: E31, E50, The RIETI Policy Discussion Papers Series was created as part of RIETI research and aims to contribute to policy discussions in a timely fashion. The views expressed in these papers are solely those of the author(s), and neither represent those of the organization(s) to which the author(s) belong(s) nor the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry. 1I thank Makoto Yano and seminar participants at Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI) for encouraging and useful comments. All remaining errors are mine. This study is conducted as a part of the Project “Microeconomics, Macroeconomics, and Political Philosophy toward Economic Growth” undertaken at RIETI. 1 1. Transversality condition and the velocity of money Observing the monetary policy in Japan for the last three decades, we have a question whether the velocity of money may be endogenous and responsive to the policy changes.
    [Show full text]
  • For a Modest and Heterodox Mainstream Economics
    FOR A MODEST AND HETERODOX MAINSTREAM ECONOMICS Luiz Carlos Bresser-Pereira Paper presented to the Coimbra Conference 2010 “The Revival of Political Economy – Prospects for a Sustainable Provision”, sponsored by the Faculty of Economics of Coimbra University, October 21-23 2010. Suddenly, in the aftermath of the 2008 global financial crisis, the king turned naked. Or we all realized that he was naked. Neoclassical economics was dominant since the late 1970s, but proved unable to explain and predict the behavior of economic systems. Mainstream economics, based on the homo economicus and on the rational expectations assumptions, concluded from them that markets were efficient and self-regulated. They were not. It also concluded that the existing market failures were eventually minor and did not questioned the logic of that revealed truth. It would be enough to guarantee markets, to protect property rights and contracts, to defend competition, and to keep public finances balanced, that the rest – financial and price stability, fast growth, and fair income distribution would in place. But this was also false. Although hypothetical- deductive economic models may show that income is distributed according to the marginal productivity of factors, non-regulated markets were never just or even fair; although market competition was supposed to automatically cause fast growth, historical experiences of catching up were always combined with active state action; although inflation was supposed to be under control provided that budget deficit and the supply of money were under control, these two implicit correlations were not confirmed by regression analyses; although deregulated financial markets were supposed to guarantee financial stability, the enormous increase of asset bubbles and financial crises, or, in Kindleberg’s wording, the recurrence of euphoria, manias and panics after the collapse of the Bretton Woods agreement, proved that this was just not true.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomic Analysis Without the Rational Expectations Hypothesis∗
    Macroeconomic Analysis without the Rational Expectations Hypothesis∗ Michael Woodford Columbia University August 16, 2013 Abstract This paper reviews a variety of alternative approaches to the specification of the expectations of economic decisionmakers in dynamic models, and reconsid- ers familiar results in the theory of monetary and fiscal policy when one allows for departures from the hypothesis of rational expectations. The various ap- proaches are all illustrated in the context of a common model, a log-linearized New Keynesian model in which both households and firms solve infinite-horizon decision problems; under the hypothesis of rational expectations, the model re- duces to the standard \3-equation model" used in studies such as Clarida et al. (1999). The alternative approaches considered include rationalizable equi- librium dynamics (Guesnerie, 2008); restricted perceptions equilibria (Branch, 2004); decreasing-gain and constant-gain variants of least-squares learning dy- namics (Evans and Honkapohja, 2001); rational belief equilibria (Kurz, 2012); and near-rational expectations equilibria (Woodford, 2010). Issues treated in- clude Ricardian equivalence; the determinacy of equilibrium under alternative interest-rate rules; non-fundamental sources of aggregate instability; the trade- off between inflation stabilization and output-gap stabilization; and the possi- bility of a “deflation trap." ∗Prepared for Annual Review of Economics, volume 5. I would like to thank Klaus Adam, Ben Hebert, Mordecai Kurz, David Laibson, and Bruce Preston for helpful discussions, Savitar Sundaresan for research assistance, and the Institute for New Economic Thinking and the Taussig Visiting Professorship, Harvard University, for supporting this research. A crucial methodological question in macroeconomic analysis is the way in which the expectations of decisionmakers about future conditions should be modeled.
    [Show full text]
  • Goodbye, Homo Economicus1 Anatole Kaletsky [The Times, UK]
    real-world economics review, issue no. 50 Goodbye, homo economicus1 Anatole Kaletsky [The Times, UK] Was Adam Smith an economist? Was Keynes, Ricardo or Schumpeter? By the standards of today’s academic economists, the answer is no. Smith, Ricardo and Keynes produced no mathematical models. Their work lacked the “analytical rigour” and precise deductive logic demanded by modern economics. And none of them ever produced an econometric forecast (although Keynes and Schumpeter were able mathematicians). If any of these giants of economics applied for a university job today, they would be rejected. As for their written work, it would not have a chance of acceptance in the Economic Journal or American Economic Review. The editors, if they felt charitable, might advise Smith and Keynes to try a journal of history or sociology. If you think I exaggerate, ask yourself what role academic economists have played in the present crisis. Granted, a few mainstream economists with practical backgrounds—like Paul Krugman and Larry Summers in the US—have been helpful explaining the crisis to the public and shaping some of the response. But in general how many academic economists have had something useful to say about the greatest upheaval in 70 years? The truth is even worse than this rhetorical question suggests: not only have economists, as a profession, failed to guide the world out of the crisis, they were also primarily responsible for leading us into it. By “economists” in this context I do not mean the talking heads and commentators (myself included) employed by the media and financial institutions to explain the credit crunch or the collapse of house prices or the rise of unemployment or the movements of currencies and stock markets—usually well after the event.
    [Show full text]
  • Expectations, Deflation Traps and Macroeconomic Policy
    11 Expectations, Deflation Traps and Macroeconomic Policy1 George W. Evans and Seppo Honkapohja 1 Introduction Following the introduction of inflation targeting and related monetary strate- gies, target inflation rates seem to have fallen to relatively low levels, about two to three percent in many countries. This implies that large adverse shocks might push the economy into periods of deflation. This was clearly a major concern in the US during the 2001 recession. The experiences of 2008 and 2009, as well as the earlier experience of Japan since the 1990s, have underscored these concerns and created a situation in which the monetary policy response is constrained by the zero lower bound on nominal inter- est rates, a phenomenon sometimes called a ‘liquidity trap.’ Furthermore, in a liquidity trap there is the potential for the economy to get stuck in a deflationary situation with declining or persistently low levels of output. The theoretical plausibility of the economy becoming trapped in a defla- tionary state, and the macroeconomic policies that might be able to avoid or extricate the economy from a liquidity trap, have been examined pre- dominantly from the rational expectations (RE) perspective. One central feature of this literature emphasizes the role of commitment. For exam- ple, Krugman (1998) and Eggertsson and Woodford (2003) argue that if the economy encounters a liquidity trap, monetary policy should commit to be- ing expansionary for a considerable period of time, by keeping interest rates near zero even after the economy has emerged from deflation. Another is- sue concerns the possibility of permanent deflation. Under RE this hinges on the precise form of fiscal policy in the deflationary steady state and on whether this is consistent with the household’s transversality condition.
    [Show full text]