NGDP Targeting and the Great Recession

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

NGDP Targeting and the Great Recession The Real Problem Was Nominal: The Great Recession and Nominal GDP Targeting Scott Sumner, Bentley University and the Mercatus Center Part I: Think outside the box “Tell me,” the great twentieth-century philosopher Ludwig Wittgenstein once asked a friend, “why do people always say it was natural for man to assume that the sun went around the Earth rather than that the Earth was rotating?” His friend replied, “Well, obviously because it just looks as though the Sun is going around the Earth.” Wittgenstein responded, “Well, what would it have looked like if it had looked as though the Earth was rotating?” The consensus view “The worst financial crisis in the history of the United States and many other countries started in 1929. The Great Depression followed. The second-worst struck in the fall of 2008 and the Great Recession followed.” (Robert Hall, JEP, 2010.) Real GDP: 2007-2010, (monthly estimates from Macroeconomics Advisors) Nominal GDP: 2007-2010 Friedman on low interest rates “Low interest rates are generally a sign that money has been tight, as in Japan; high interest rates, that money has been easy. After the U.S. experience during the Great Depression, and after inflation and rising interest rates in the 1970s and disinflation and falling interest rates in the 1980s, I thought the fallacy of identifying tight money with high interest rates and easy money with low interest rates was dead. Apparently, old fallacies never die.” (WSJ, Dec. 1997) Mishkin’s key lessons for monetary policy 1. It is dangerous always to associate the easing or the tightening of monetary policy with a fall or a rise in short-term nominal interest rates. 2. Other asset prices besides those on short-term debt instruments contain important information about the stance of monetary policy because they are important elements in various monetary policy transmission mechanisms. 3. Monetary policy can be highly effective in reviving a weak economy even if short term rates are already near zero. Real interest rates on Treasury bonds with a roughly 5 year maturity; July to Nov. 2008 Commodity prices in 2008 The value of the dollar in late 2008 Other Asset Markets Stock prices crashed in late 2008 Commercial real estate prices started falling sharply about the same time as NGDP, and long after the subprime bubble Residential real estate prices in the heartland (Texas, etc.) had been stable during the 2006-08 subprime crash, and started falling in late 2008 along with NGDP TIPS spreads (i.e. inflation expectations) fell sharply. Bernanke on monetary indicators The imperfect reliability of money growth as an indicator of monetary policy is unfortunate, because we don’t really have anything satisfactory to replace it. As emphasized by Friedman . nominal interest rates are not good indicators of the stance of policy . The real short-term interest rate . is also imperfect . Ultimately, it appears, one can check to see if an economy has a stable monetary background only by looking at macroeconomic indicators such as nominal GDP growth and inflation. If you insist on using interest rates The housing crash was mostly over before the unemployment rate began rising sharply. Jan. 2006: starts = 2,303,000, completions = 2,058,000, average = 2,180,000, U-rate = 4.7% April 2008: starts = 1,008,000, completions =1,014,000, average = 1,011,000, U-rate = 5.0% October 2009: starts = 527,000, completions = 745,000, average = 636,000. U-rate = 10.0% Two examples of fiscal austerity: The US NGDP (red line) and the Eurozone NGDP (blue line) Slow Eurozone NGDP growth depresses bond yields The “musical chairs model” Why NGDP growth is important Nominal wage contracts. Nominal hourly wage growth is very “sticky”. When NGDP slows unexpectedly, businesses don’t earn enough revenue to pay workers at existing wage rates Unemployment rises. Nominal debt contracts. Nominal GDP is the total income available to people, businesses and governments to repay nominal debts. Less NGDP Financial stress. Imaginary conversation Wittgenstein: Tell me, why do people always say it’s natural to assume the Great Recession was caused by the financial crisis of 2008? Friend: Well, obviously because it looks as though the Great Recession was caused by the financial crisis of 2008. Wittgenstein: Well, what would it have looked like if it had been caused by Fed and ECB policy errors, which allowed nominal GDP to fall at the sharpest rate since 1938, especially during a time when banks were already stressed by the subprime fiasco, and when the resources for repaying nominal debts come from nominal income? Nominal GDP targeting Can the central bank target NGDP? Advantages over inflation targeting Advantages of level targeting Target the forecast Use market forecasts Market Monetarism: Taking Pre- 2008 macro seriously Low rates don’t mean easy money (Friedman, Mishkin, Bernanke) Monetary policy highly effective at zero bound. (Friedman, Mishkin, Bernanke) Fiscal policy not an effective stabilization tool, even at zero bound. (Krugman) Level targeting is more effective at the zero rate bound. (Eggertsson, Woodford) Central banks should target the forecast (Lars Svensson) Expectations are rational, asset markets are efficient. (Lucas, Woodford, Fama, etc.) NGDPLT (arguably the least important aspect of market monetarism) Share of Treasury debt held by the Fed Apparent monetary ease is often a symptom of monetary tightness On any given day, a lower fed funds target is more expansionary. (Keynesian view) Over any extended period of time, however, lower rates reflect more bearish forecasts. (NeoFisherian perspective) What do current eurozone and Japanese i-rate forecasts imply about NGDP growth in those two regions? Don’t “do more”, do different. Level shifts vs. growth rate shifts In January 2015, the Swiss simultaneously cut IOR from negative 0.25% to negative 0.75%, and appreciated the franc by more than 10%. Both level and growth rate shifts were contractionary. In most cases, level and growth rate shifts move in opposite directions. (Dornbusch overshooting) Needed: Level and growth rate shifts that are both expansionary. I.e., Japan could suddenly depreciate the yen by 20%, and then fix to the dollar. The policy would be expansionary, despite raising Japanese interest rates. What’s wrong with inflation targeting? NGDP better reflects the “welfare costs of inflation” (especially excess taxation of capital income, and sticky wages) National income targeting is easier for the public to understand. Ask Bernanke about his attempt to explain to the public (in 2010) why the Fed was trying to raise their cost of living during a recession. NGDP targeting better stabilizes labor and debt markets. Why level targeting? Policy is more credible, in terms of growth rates. (Contrast an inflation and PL target that each undershoot by ½% each year.) Creates stabilizing expectations. Inflation expectations rise during periods of undershooting, such as 2009, which reduces longer term real interest rates. Most importantly, that makes the recession itself milder (in NK models). How to make NGDPLT operational One could create a Taylor Rule-type reaction function, with an NGDP level targeting objective Would not be dramatically different from actual Taylor Rule. Alternative -- “target the forecast”: 1. Use internal central bank forecast (Svensson) 2. Target market forecasts, using discretion or NGDP futures markets. (Market monetarists) NGDP futures targeting Target external NGDP futures market. Problems: circularity problem, lack of liquidity. Internalize NGDP futures market---Fed buys and sells unlimited quantities of NGDP futures at price equal to policy goal. Transactions lead to automatic adjustments in the monetary base. Multiple contingent NGDP futures auctions for various possible instrument settings. Transactions occur only at instrument setting where long and short positions roughly balance. Central banks reluctant to give up all discretion 1. What if unanticipated shock made “automatic” setting inappropriate? 2. Risk premium in NGDP futures prices. 3. Risk of futures market manipulation. Constrained discretion Set an NGDP level target along a 4% growth path. Renew the target each year, based on previous year endpoint, but not outside 3% to 5% growth range. Fed promises to take a “short” position on any NGDP futures contracts at 5% growth, and a long position on any 3% NGDP growth contracts. Fed makes a profit if actual NGDP ends up inside the range, and still avoids losses if Fed bets are “balanced” when NGDP is outside the range. If it works, gradually narrow the “guardrails”. Making the world safe for classical economics Goal is to keep NGDP expectations growing at a slow but steady rate. In this world there is no paradox of thrift or toil. No argument for mercantilism. No argument for fiscal stimulus. No argument for bailing out companies to “save jobs”. Standard classical assumptions about opportunity cost would once again hold true. Paul Krugman in 1999 “What continues to amaze me is this: Japan's current strategy of massive, unsustainable deficit spending in the hopes that this will somehow generate a self-sustained recovery is currently regarded as the orthodox, sensible thing to do - even though it can be justified only by exotic stories about multiple equilibria, the sort of thing you would imagine only a professor could believe. Meanwhile further steps on monetary policy - the sort of thing you would advocate if you believed in a more conventional, boring model, one in which the problem is simply a question of the savings-investment balance - are rejected as dangerously radical and unbecoming of a dignified economy. Will somebody please explain this to me?” .
Recommended publications
  • Campaign for Liberty — with All Due Respect Mr. President
    Campaign For Liberty — With all due respect Mr. President http://www.campaignforliberty.com/blog.php?view=9636 "There is no disagreement that we need action by our government, a recovery plan that will help to jumpstart the economy." — PRESIDENT-ELECT BARACK OBAMA, JANUARY 9 , 2009 With all due respect Mr. President, that is not true. Notwithstanding reports that all economists are now Keynesians and that we all support a big increase in the burden of government, we do not believe that more government spending is a way to improve economic performance. More government spending by Hoover and Roosevelt did not pull the United States economy out of the Great Depression in the 1930s. More government spending did not solve Japan's "lost decade" in the 1990s. As such, it is a triumph of hope over experience to believe that more government spending will help the U.S. today. To improve the economy, policy makers should focus on reforms that remove impediments to work, saving, investment and production. Lower tax rates and a reduction in the burden of government are the best ways of using fiscal policy to boost growth. Burton Abrams, Univ. of Delaware Marek Kolar, Delta College Douglas Adie, Ohio University Roger Koppl, Fairleigh Dickinson University Ryan Amacher, Univ. of Texas at Arlington Kishore Kulkarni, Metropolitan State College J.J. Arias, Georgia College & State University of Denver Howard Baetjer, Jr., Towson University Deepak Lal, UCLA Stacie Beck, Univ. of Delaware George Langelett, South Dakota State Don Bellante, Univ. of South Florida University James Bennett, George Mason University James Larriviere, Spring Hill College Bruce Benson, Florida State University Robert Lawson, Auburn University Sanjai Bhagat, Univ.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Political Economy of Monetary Rules
    SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE! “The Independent Review does not accept “The Independent Review is pronouncements of government officials nor the excellent.” conventional wisdom at face value.” —GARY BECKER, Noble Laureate —JOHN R. MACARTHUR, Publisher, Harper’s in Economic Sciences Subscribe to The Independent Review and receive a free book of your choice* such as the 25th Anniversary Edition of Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government, by Founding Editor Robert Higgs. This quarterly journal, guided by co-editors Christopher J. Coyne, and Michael C. Munger, and Robert M. Whaples offers leading-edge insights on today’s most critical issues in economics, healthcare, education, law, history, political science, philosophy, and sociology. Thought-provoking and educational, The Independent Review is blazing the way toward informed debate! Student? Educator? Journalist? Business or civic leader? Engaged citizen? This journal is for YOU! *Order today for more FREE book options Perfect for students or anyone on the go! The Independent Review is available on mobile devices or tablets: iOS devices, Amazon Kindle Fire, or Android through Magzter. INDEPENDENT INSTITUTE, 100 SWAN WAY, OAKLAND, CA 94621 • 800-927-8733 • [email protected] PROMO CODE IRA1703 Some Political Economy of Monetary Rules F ALEXANDER WILLIAM SALTER n this paper, I evaluate the efficacy of various rules for monetary policy from the perspective of political economy. I present several rules that are popular in I current debates over monetary policy as well as some that are more radical and hence less frequently discussed. I also discuss whether a given rule may have helped to contain the negative effects of the recent financial crisis.
    [Show full text]
  • A Conversation with Dr. Scott Sumner, June 3, 2015 Participants Summary
    A conversation with Dr. Scott Sumner, June 3, 2015 Participants • Dr. Scott Sumner – Director, Program on Monetary Policy, the Mercatus Center at George Mason University (Mercatus) • Alexander Berger – Research Analyst, Open Philanthropy Project • Karl Smith – Consultant, Open Philanthropy Project Note: These notes were compiled by the Open Philanthropy Project and give an overview of the major points made by Dr. Scott Sumner. Summary The Open Philanthropy Project spoke with Dr. Sumner of Mercatus as part of its investigation into the economic and policy advocacy landscape around nominal gross domestic product (NGDP) targeting. Conversation topics included support for NGDP targeting from economists, past obstacles to implementing NGDP targeting, the value of prediction markets, and Dr. Sumner’s role at Mercatus. NGDP targeting Support for nominal GDP targeting Dr. Sumner believes that the Federal Reserve (Fed) is likely to adopt a particular monetary policy if there is consensus among economists about its effectiveness. There is now significant support for NGDP targeting from well-known economists on both the left and the right, including: • Christina Romer (University of California, Berkeley) • James Bullard (President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis) • In recent remarks, Larry Summers (Harvard University) seemed to view NGDP targeting positively, though he did not explicitly endorse it • Mark Carney suggested that NGDP targeting should be considered as an option, just before he began serving as Governor of the Bank of England Dr. Sumner sees interest in NGDP targeting increasing steadily. The UK may be the country most likely to adopt NGDP targeting in the near future. Past obstacles to aDopting NGDP targeting Widely used New Keynesian economic models do not include NGDP as a variable, which makes it harder for many economists to see NGDP targeting as optimal.
    [Show full text]
  • Scott Sumner
    FEATURE A NEW VIEW OF THE GREAT RECESSION Scott B. Sumner argues US monetary policy has been too tight, not too easy ive years on, economists still don’t agree the ambiguity. Here’s Milton Friedman in 1998 on the causes of the financial crisis of expressing dismay that economists were confusing 2007–08. Nor do they agree on the easy and tight money in Japan: correct policy response to the subsequent Frecession. But one issue on which there is almost Low interest rates are generally a sign that universal agreement is that the financial crisis money has been tight, as in Japan; high caused the Great Recession. interest rates, that money has been easy … In this essay, I suggest that the conventional After the U.S. experience during the Great view is wrong, and that the financial crisis did not Depression, and after inflation and rising cause the recession—tight money did. This new interest rates in the 1970s and disinflation view must overcome two difficult hurdles. Most and falling interest rates in the 1980s, people think it is obvious that the financial crisis I thought the fallacy of identifying tight caused the recession, and many are incredulous money with high interest rates and easy when they hear the claim that monetary policy money with low interest rates was dead. has been contractionary in recent years. The first Apparently, old fallacies never die.1 part of the essay will explain why the conventional view is wrong; monetary policy has indeed been Many pundits claim that the Bank of Japan quite contractionary in the United States, Europe (BoJ) tried an easy money policy in the 1990s and and Japan (but not in Australia.) The second part early 2000s because nominal interest rates were will explain how people have reversed causation, low and the monetary base was growing rapidly.
    [Show full text]
  • The Case for NGDP Targeting Lessons from the Great Recession
    The Case for NGDP Targeting Lessons from the Great Recession Scott Sumner 23 Great Smith Street ADAM SMITH London SW1P 3BL INSTITUTE www.adamsmith.org www.adamsmith.org The Case for NGDP Targeting Lessons from the Great Recession Scott Sumner Scott Sumner has taught economics at Bentley University for the past 27 years. He earned a BA in economics at the University of Wisconsin and a PhD at the University of Chicago. His research has been in the field of monetary economics, particularly the role of the gold standard in the Great Depression. © Adam Smith Research Trust 2011 Published in the UK by ASI (Research) Limited Some rights reserved. Copyright remains with the copyright holder, but users may download, save and distribute this work in any format provided that: (1) the Adam Smith Institute is cited; (2) the URL www.adamsmith.org <http://www.adamsmith.org> is published together with a prominent copy of this notice; (3) the text is used in full without amendments (extracts may be used for criticism or review); (4) the work is not resold; and (5) a link to any online use is sent to [email protected]. The views expressed in this publication are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the publisher. They have been selected for their independence and intellectual vigour, and are presented as a contribution to public debate. ISBN 1 902737 73 3 Printed in England by Grosvenor Group (Print Services) Limited, London Contents Executive Summary 5 Introduction 5 1 The advantages of NGDP targeting 6 over inflation targeting 2 NGDP targeting and the crash of 2008 9 3 Level targeting and forecast targeting 16 Executive summary The recent economic crisis has exposed important flaws with inflation targeting, particularly the form practiced by real world central banks.
    [Show full text]
  • The Fisher Relation in the Great Depression and the Great Recession
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Laidler, David Working Paper The Fisher Relation in the Great Depression and the Great Recession EPRI Working Paper, No. 2013-2 Provided in Cooperation with: Economic Policy Research Institute (EPRI), Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario Suggested Citation: Laidler, David (2013) : The Fisher Relation in the Great Depression and the Great Recession, EPRI Working Paper, No. 2013-2, The University of Western Ontario, Economic Policy Research Institute (EPRI), London (Ontario) This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/70277 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen
    [Show full text]
  • LESSONS from QUANTITATIVE EASING in the UNITED STATES: a GUIDE for AUSTRALIAN POLICYMAKERS Stephen Kirchner June 2019 Table of Contents
    LESSONS FROM QUANTITATIVE EASING IN THE UNITED STATES: A GUIDE FOR AUSTRALIAN POLICYMAKERS Stephen Kirchner June 2019 Table of contents The United States Studies Centre at the University of Sydney is a university-based research centre, dedicated Executive summary 01 to the rigorous analysis of American foreign policy, Introduction 02 economics, politics and culture. The Centre is a national resource, that builds Australia’s awareness of the dynamics The US experience with quantitative 03 shaping America — and critically — their implications for easing: What did the Fed do? Australia. The Centre’s Trade and Investment Program examines What effect did quantitative easing 06 trends, challenges and opportunities in the trade and have in the United States? investment relationship between Australia and the United States. It places the Australia-US economic relationship in What did the Fed get wrong? 10 the broader context of Australia’s relations with the rest of Lessons for Australia the world and promotes public policy recommendations Myths about quantitative easing 11 conducive to the growth and integration of the Australian, US and world economies. Conclusion 14 United States Studies Centre Endnotes 15 Institute Building (H03) The University of Sydney NSW 2006 About the author 17 Australia Phone: +61 2 9351 7249 Email: [email protected] Twitter: @ussc Website: ussc.edu.au This report may be cited as: Stephen Kirchner, “Lessons from quantitative easing in the United States: A guide for Australian policymakers,” United States Studies Centre at the University of Sydney, June 2019. Research conclusions are derived independently and authors represent their own view, not those of the United States Studies Centre.
    [Show full text]
  • A Comparative Institutional Analysis of Free Banking and Central Bank NGDP Targeting
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by Southern Methodist University The Journal of Private Enterprise 29(1), 2013, 25–39 A Comparative Institutional Analysis of Free Banking and Central Bank NGDP Targeting Ryan H. Murphy* Suffolk University Abstract This paper argues that the choice between free banking and central bank NGDP targeting is a difficult to answer empirical question, contrary to the position of those on either side of the debate. Public choice concerns, the lack of the signals of profit and loss, and optimal determination of currency areas are points against any form of central banking. However, free banking may be suboptimal relative to central bank NGDP targeting for three reasons explored here. Until more data become available, it is impossible to gauge the relative importance of one set of these tradeoffs against the other. JEL Codes: E24, E42, D70 Keywords: Free banking; NGDP targeting; Public choice; Comparative institutional analysis I. Introduction As the Great Recession continued, some of the most ardent supporters of the free market began entertaining the possibility that “demand-side” problems were causing persistent unemployment. Although the right-wing press has criticized the untraditional behavior of central banks, monetary policy actually appeared tight by the standard set forth by one of the most eminent and stringent inflation hawks of the 20th century, F.A. Hayek. This standard requires constant total overall spending in the economy (Hayek, 1931; White, 1999). This implies that M*V should be kept at a constant level for money to remain “neutral.” Following the equation of exchange, this is in effect the same as a Nominal Gross Domestic Product (NGDP) target of 0%.
    [Show full text]
  • Reflections on Allan Meltzer's Contributions to Monetary Economics and Public Policy
    REFLECTIONS ON ALLAN MELTZER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO MONETARY ECONOMICS AND PUBLIC POLICY January 4, 2018 Kimpton Hotel Palomar Philadelphia Sponsored by the Institute for Humane Studies & the Mercatus Center at George Mason University elcome to the Policy Research Seminar on Reflection’s on Allan Meltzer’s WContributions to Monetary Economics and Public Policy, sponsored by the Institute for Humane Studies (IHS) and the Mercatus Center at George Mason University. You have been invited to this event because we hold your work in high esteem for both its scholarly contributions and for its practical application to our understanding of a free society. We encourage you to join in what promises to be an active and lively conversation, and to draw from your own research and experiences throughout the discussion. One of the primary goals for this program is to help facilitate scholarly collaboration among the faculty, graduate students, policy experts, and IHS and Mercatus Center staff members in attendance. I hope you see this as a valuable opportunity to get to know dozens of like-minded scholars with similar research interests. We are hosting several world-class speakers who can share their experience and advice on how to flourish, as they have, in the world of monetary economics and public policy. We have found that some of the best conversations from our seminars occur spontaneously in the hallways and during meals and receptions, so please be present for scheduled events. Thank you again for joining us. We look forward to meeting each of you individually over the course of the seminar, and we hope you benefit as much from this seminar as we benefit from having you in attendance.
    [Show full text]
  • CURRICULUM VITAE Manuel M. F. Martins
    CURRICULUM VITAE Manuel M. F. Martins PERSONAL INFORMATION Name: Manuel António da Mota Freitas Martins Birth date: 29 November 1964 Nationality: Portuguese Address: Faculdade de Economia, Universidade do Porto Office nº 514 Rua Dr. Roberto Frias 4200 464 Porto Portugal Tel: 351 22 557 1100 (ext. 518); Fax: 351 2 550 5050 E-mail: [email protected] EDUCATION 2003 PhD in Economics Faculdade de Economia, Universidade do Porto Thesis: "Macroeconomic Trade-offs and Monetary Policy in the Euro Area". Supervision: Prof. Dr. Álvaro Aguiar. 1996 Masters in Economics Faculdade de Economia, Universidade do Porto Grade point average: 16/20. Thesis: "Moeda e Preços em Portugal 1932-1990 - Uma Investigação com Métodos de Séries Temporais." Supervision: Prof. Dr. Fernando Teixeira dos Santos. 1987 Licenciatura in Economics Faculdade de Economia, Universidade do Porto Grade point average: 14/20. PROFESSIONAL EXPERIENCE 1987-present Faculdade de Economia, Universidade do Porto 2003-present Assistant Professor 1996-2003 Senior Lecturer 1991-1996: Invited Senior Lecturer 1987-1991: Teaching Assistant Courses taught: Introductory Economics (E101) Macroeconomics (E201), Macroeconomics I (LEC201), Macroeconomics (1E201) Applied Economic Studies (E523) Economic Policy (E512, LEC417) International Monetary Economics (E713) 1 Macroeconomics I (EC709/DE802; ECON702; 3E102) Macroeconometrics (EC756/DE830; ECON708; 3E107) Researcher at the Macroeconomics and Forecasting Research Centre CEMPRE - Centro de Estudos Macroeconómicos e Previsão 1991-1994 I. E. S. F., Porto (Instituto de Estudos Superiores Financeiros e Fiscais) Teaching Assistant Courses taught: Macroeconomics 1987-1998 Associação Industrial Portuense Economist at the Research Department: Business Cycles and Economic Policy analysis MAIN SCIENTIFIC AREAS OF INTEREST Macroeconomics, Business Cycles, Monetary theory and policy, Time Series Methods.
    [Show full text]
  • Great Expectations and the End of the Depression
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Great Expectations and the End of the Depression Gauti B. Eggertsson Staff Report no. 234 December 2005 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in the paper are those of the author and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author. Great Expectations and the End of the Depression Gauti B. Eggertsson Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 234 December 2005 JEL classification: E52, E63 Abstract This paper argues that the U.S. economy’s recovery from the Great Depression was driven by a shift in expectations brought about by the policy actions of President Franklin Delano Roosevelt. On the monetary policy side, Roosevelt abolished the gold standard and—even more important—announced the policy objective of inflating the price level to pre-depression levels. On the fiscal policy side, Roosevelt expanded real and deficit spending. Together, these actions made his policy objective credible; they violated prevailing policy dogmas and introduced a policy regime change such as that described in work by Sargent and by Temin and Wigmore. The economic consequences of Roosevelt’s policies are evaluated in a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with sticky prices and rational expectations. Key words: deflation, Great Depression, regime change, zero interest rates Eggertsson: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (e-mail: [email protected]).
    [Show full text]
  • Volume 22 | No. 4 | Winter 2019
    THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS VOLUME 22 | No. 4 | WINTER 2019 WWW.QJAE.ORG ARTICLES An Overlooked Scenario of “Reswitching” in the Austrian Structure of Production .........509 Er’el Granot The Macroeconomic Models of the Austrian School: A History and Comparative Analysis ...533 Renaud Fillieule Rothbard on the Economics of Slavery ........................................................................................565 Mark Thornton The Wealth Effect and the Law of Demand: A Comment on Karl-Friedrich Israel ..............579 Joseph T. Salerno A Note on Some Recent Misinterpretations of the Cantillon Effect ........................................596 Arkadiusz Sieroń The Relevance of Bitcoin to the Regression Theorem: A Reply to Luther .............................603 George Pickering Book Review: Narrative Economics: How Stories Go Viral and Drive Major Economic Events By Robert J. Shiller ...........................................................................................................................620 Brendan Brown Book Review: Indebted: How Families Make College Work at Any Cost By Caitlin Zaloom ............................................................................................................................627 Jeffrey Degner Book Review: The Bitcoin Standard: The Decentralized Alternative to Central Banking By Saifedean Ammous ....................................................................................................................634 Kristoffer M. Hansen Book Review: Beyond Brexit:
    [Show full text]