Inflation and Deflation Lyle M

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Inflation and Deflation Lyle M South Dakota State University Open PRAIRIE: Open Public Research Access Institutional Repository and Information Exchange SDSU Extension Circulars SDSU Extension 5-1952 Inflation and Deflation Lyle M. Bender Follow this and additional works at: http://openprairie.sdstate.edu/extension_circ Part of the Agriculture Commons Recommended Citation Bender, Lyle M., "Inflation and Deflation" (1952). SDSU Extension Circulars. 560. http://openprairie.sdstate.edu/extension_circ/560 This Circular is brought to you for free and open access by the SDSU Extension at Open PRAIRIE: Open Public Research Access Institutional Repository and Information Exchange. It has been accepted for inclusion in SDSU Extension Circulars by an authorized administrator of Open PRAIRIE: Open Public Research Access Institutional Repository and Information Exchange. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 'XTENSION CIRCULAR 482 MAY 1952 el M F L A T I 0 ,4,J, . DEFLATION STABILITY ~- /NFI..ATION Pr/ces AGRICULTURAL EXTENSION SERVICE SOUTH DAKOTA STATE CO LL EGE, BROOKINGS U. S. D E P A R T M E N T O F A G R I C U LT U · R E •i I • What Is It? Inflation and deflation are words of many different mean- ings. They refer to the changes in general price levels. Inflation refers generally to a situation where most prices are rising. On the other hand, deflation refers to a situation in which most prices are falling. In between these two extremes is an "ideal" situation called "stability." In our form of economy fluctuations in general price levels are normal. Inflation may be more carefully defined as a situation where the number of dollars spent increases faster than the goods and services produced. In this case, prices will rise. The opposite situation, deflation, is·defined as a situation where the amount of goods and services produced increases fast- er than the number of dollars spent for them. In this case, prices will fall. The in-between situation, called stability may .be defined as a situation where the dollars spent equal the goods and services pro- duced. This is a condition of more or less stable prices. Agricultural Extension Service Published under Acts of Congress May 8 and June 30, 1914 by the Agricultural Extension Service of South Dakota State College, George I. Gilbertson, director, and the United States Department of Agriculture, cooperating. •• f) INFLATION and DEFLATION LYLE M. BENDER* Causes of Inflation and Deflation There are many causes of inflation and bor are fully employed. It increases incomes deflation. Six different causes are described. without creating immediate consumer Changes in Money or Credit Supply: On gqods to offset higher incomes. It is infla- the money and credit side of our economy tiona,ry in the short run and deflationary in changes in its supply in relation to demand the long run. for goods and services may bring about in- Inventory Building: An inflationary pres- flationary or deflationary conditions. On sure may come from the attempts of manu- the inflationary side whenever there is an facturers, wholesalers, retailers and con- expected shortage of goods there is usually sumers to increase inventories. This in- a scramble for them. This requires financ- crease means that manufacturers bid against ing, usually through an increase in the each other for raw materials; wholesalers money or credit supply. An increase in the against each other for manufactured goods; money or credit supply may come from retailers against each other for retail goods; many sources such as, government deficit and you and I against each other for that spending, increase in bank loans and an in- sugar, those tires, etc. crease in consumer credit. The other side of the picture, deflationary When bank credit is allowed to expand, pressures, come when we stay at home, eat either through borrowing by individuals, off the pantry shelves, and work hard to pay business or by government the money avail- off our short term debts or replenish our able to be spent is increased. It means more savings. dollars available in relation to the supply of Spending from Savings: People's atti- goods. tudes about savings may also be an impor- Supply of Goods and Services: One of the tant factor contributing to inflation or defla- greatest inflationary pressures in a defense tion. Early in the Korean war people fig- economy comes from the decline in the pro- ured that goods might be scarce and high in duction of consumer's goods, such as refrig- price in the future. Those with savings used erators, cars, clothing and the like. The them to buy goods. Such action increased amount of inflationary pressure varies with the money supply relative to available goods the amount of goods going into military in the market. Early in 1951 the opposite production. situation took place. Savings were in- A deflationary condition arises when creased, thus the effective money supply total consumer's goods production increases was smaller than the increasing supply of as a result of new plant expansion and or a goods for sale and this action is contribut- reduction in the amount of goods going to ing to deflation. the military. Cost-Price Spiral: The cost-price spiral is Investment Expansion: A strong destab- an important cause of inflation. It is most ilizing factor in our economy is capital in- important when the economy is near or at vestment such as new plants and equip- full employment or under the strain of war ment. It puts pressure on raw materials and or defense production. Under such condi- labor at time~ when existing plants and la- tions a shortage of goods causes prices to rise. Labor is fully employed or there may •Extension Farm Management Specialist be shortages. With this set up, organized , 4 South Dakota Extension Circular 482 labor can use their power to push wages up labor and plants are fully employed, indus- A and prices usually rise with them. Often, try may tend to push up prices faster than under these conditions, wage rates tend to costs and plant productivity. This new in- increase faster than labor productivity. come or purchasing power makes further Also, when goods are in short supply and price increases possible. · Effects of Inflation and Deflation Not all price rises are bad. Neither are all Effects on Debtors and Creditors: Infla- price declines bad. Gently rising prices en- tion tends to favor people who owe debts. courage increasing productivity. Gently Deflation, on the other hand, tends to favor lowering of prices tend to encourage more those who receive payments for debts. consumption of goods produced by industry · Farmers' and others who are in debt ga~n and agriculture. Probably what concerns us from inflation as the price rises making the most is the rapid rise in prices when our debt easier to pay. economy is operating at a full plant capacity Effect on Profit Receivers and Fixed In- and full employment level. Three effects are come Groups: In periods of inflation people described. on fixed incomes stand to lose a great deal. Effects on Output of Goods and Employ- This group includes all those on salaries, ment: The effects of inflation on production and people who receive money incomes in of goods are mixed depending on the the form of pensions, interest on bonds and amount of inflation and its rapidity. A mild saving deposits, annuities, and rents that are inflation increases employment and produc- fixed by long term contracts. These folks tion. Rapid inflation distorts employment suffer because any type of money payment and production. received such as life insurance benefits, loan repayments or bond redemption means Inflation may offset workers' productiv- much less in terms of goods and services it ity and willingness to work if consumption will buy. In periods of deflation these goods are very scarce and if inflation de- groups tend to gain relative to other groups. stroys the value of savings. During periods of inflation people who In deflation the growing unemployment receive profit such as businesses and farmers of labor and capital causes the total of the gain from rising prices. During the infla- community's well-being to be less. Almost tion prices rise faster than costs. However everyone loses in a bad deflation or de- when deflation takes place the gains by pression. these groups are narrowed and may be lost. M~thods of Controlling Inflation We can now deal with some of the major system to work "freely" at all times. T he proposals for controlling inflation. Since price system is the basic mechanism which deflation is the other side of inflation, the allocates resources and guides production proposals for controlling deflation would and consumption. usually be the oppo~ites that _are proposed By following this procedure we would for controlling inflation. eliminate all administrative costs and the The major suggested proposals for con- inconvenience of other schemes, and would trolling inflation can be classed into three insure the continued operation of a "free" groups as follows: market. It would tend to encourage people "Do Nothing" Policy on fixed income to shift quicker to defense This policy is one of allowing the price jobs to maintain their standard of living. Inflation and Deflation 5 On the other hand, if prices were permit- rate may slow down investment when ma- ted to move freely through the inflationary terials and labor are short. It would also cycle there would be many inequities creat- tend to encourage some people to save ed between different income groups. When more. we reach the condition of full plant use and 4. Margin Controls: The ability to con- employment, rapid inflation would take trol margins in stock and commodity mar- place as a result of wage-price battles.
Recommended publications
  • Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions by Irving Fisher
    THE DEBT-DEFLATION THEORY OF GREAT DEPRESSIONS BY IRVING FISHER INTRODUCTORY IN Booms and Depressions, I have developed, theoretically and sta- tistically, what may be called a debt-deflation theory of great depres- sions. In the preface, I stated that the results "seem largely new," I spoke thus cautiously because of my unfamiliarity with the vast literature on the subject. Since the book was published its special con- clusions have been widely accepted and, so far as I know, no one has yet found them anticipated by previous writers, though several, in- cluding myself, have zealously sought to find such anticipations. Two of the best-read authorities in this field assure me that those conclu- sions are, in the words of one of them, "both new and important." Partly to specify what some of these special conclusions are which are believed to be new and partly to fit them into the conclusions of other students in this field, I am offering this paper as embodying, in brief, my present "creed" on the whole subject of so-called "cycle theory." My "creed" consists of 49 "articles" some of which are old and some new. I say "creed" because, for brevity, it is purposely ex- pressed dogmatically and without proof. But it is not a creed in the sense that my faith in it does not rest on evidence and that I am not ready to modify it on presentation of new evidence. On the contrary, it is quite tentative. It may serve as a challenge to others and as raw material to help them work out a better product.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation and the Business Cycle
    Inflation and the business cycle Michael McMahon Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 1 / 68 To Cover • Discuss the costs of inflation; • Investigate the relationship between money and inflation; • Introduce the Romer framework; • Discuss hyperinflations. • Shocks and the business cycle; • Monetary policy responses to business cycles. • Explain what the monetary transmission mechanism is; • Examine the link between inflation and GDP. Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 2 / 68 The Next Few Lectures Term structure, asset prices Exchange and capital rate market conditions Import prices Bank rate Net external demand CPI inflation Bank lending Monetary rates and credit Policy Asset purchase/ Corporate DGI conditions Framework sales demand loans Macro prudential Household policy demand deposits Inflation expectations Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 3 / 68 Inflation Definition Inflation is a sustained general rise in the price level in the economy. In reality we measure it using concepts such as: • Consumer Price Indices (CPI); • Producer Price Indices (PPI); • Deflators (GDP deflator, Consumption Expenditure Deflator) Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 4 / 68 Inflation: The Costs If all prices are rising at same rate, including wages and asset prices, what is the problem? • Information: Makes it harder to detect relative price changes and so hinders efficient operation of market; • Uncertainty: High inflation countries have very volatile inflation; • High inflation undermines role of money and encourages barter; • Growth - if inflation increases by 10%, reduce long term growth by 0.2% but only for countries with inflation higher than 15% (Barro); • Shoe leather costs/menu costs; • Interaction with tax system; • Because of fixed nominal contracts arbitrarily redistributes wealth; • Nominal contracts break down and long-term contracts avoided.
    [Show full text]
  • Dangers of Deflation Douglas H
    ERD POLICY BRIEF SERIES Economics and Research Department Number 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks Pilipinas F. Quising Asian Development Bank http://www.adb.org Asian Development Bank P.O. Box 789 0980 Manila Philippines 2002 by Asian Development Bank December 2002 ISSN 1655-5260 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Asian Development Bank. The ERD Policy Brief Series is based on papers or notes prepared by ADB staff and their resource persons. The series is designed to provide concise nontechnical accounts of policy issues of topical interest to ADB management, Board of Directors, and staff. Though prepared primarily for internal readership within the ADB, the series may be accessed by interested external readers. Feedback is welcome via e-mail ([email protected]). ERD POLICY BRIEF NO. 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks and Pilipinas F. Quising December 2002 ecently, there has been growing concern about deflation in some Rcountries and the possibility of deflation at the global level. Aggregate demand, output, and employment could stagnate or decline, particularly where debt levels are already high. Standard economic policy stimuli could become less effective, while few policymakers have experience in preventing or halting deflation with alternative means. Causes and Consequences of Deflation Deflation refers to a fall in prices, leading to a negative change in the price index over a sustained period. The fall in prices can result from improvements in productivity, advances in technology, changes in the policy environment (e.g., deregulation), a drop in prices of major inputs (e.g., oil), excess capacity, or weak demand.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: a Business Perspective
    Deflation: a business perspective Prepared by the Corporate Economists Advisory Group Introduction Early in 2003, ICC's Corporate Economists Advisory Group discussed the risk of deflation in some of the world's major economies, and possible consequences for business. The fear was that historically low levels of inflation and faltering economic growth could lead to deflation - a persistent decline in the general level of prices - which in turn could trigger economic depression, with widespread company and bank failures, a collapse in world trade, mass unemployment and years of shrinking economic activity. While the risk of deflation is now remote in most countries - given the increasingly unambiguous signs of global economic recovery - its potential costs are very high and would directly affect companies. This issues paper was developed to help companies better understand the phenomenon of deflation, and to give them practical guidance on possible measures to take if and when the threat of deflation turns into reality on a future occasion. What is deflation? Deflation is defined as a sustained fall in an aggregate measure of prices (such as the consumer price index). By this definition, changes in prices in one economic sector or falling prices over short periods (e.g., one or two quarters) do not qualify as deflation. Dec lining prices can be driven by an increase in supply due to technological innovation and rapid productivity gains. These supply-induced shocks are usually not problematic and can even be accompanied by robust growth, as experienced by China. A fall in prices led by a drop in demand - due to a severe economic cycle, tight economic policies or a demand-side shock - or by persistent excess capacity can be much more harmful, and is more likely to lead to persistent deflation.
    [Show full text]
  • The Evolution of Inflation and Unemployment: Explaining the Roaring Nineties
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Karanassou, Marika; Sala, Héctor; Snower, Dennis J. Working Paper The evolution of inflation and unemployment: Explaining the roaring nineties IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2900 Provided in Cooperation with: IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Suggested Citation: Karanassou, Marika; Sala, Héctor; Snower, Dennis J. (2007) : The evolution of inflation and unemployment: Explaining the roaring nineties, IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2900, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/4105 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu IZA DP No. 2900 The Evolution of Inflation and Unemployment: Explaining the Roaring Nineties Marika Karanassou Hector Sala Dennis J.
    [Show full text]
  • How Real Is the Threat of Deflation to the Banking Industry?
    An Update on Emerging Issues in Banking How Real is the Threat of Deflation to the Banking Industry? February 27, 2003 Overview The recession that began in March 2001 has had a generally benign effect on the banking industry, which remains highly profitable and well capitalized. The current financial strength of the industry is an important buffer against the effects of economic shocks. Nevertheless, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) routinely considers a number of economic scenarios that could develop over the next several quarters to evaluate factors that could result in the erosion in the financial health of individual banks or the industry. One such scenario that could present a major challenge to the banking industry involves deflation. This paper outlines the current debate over deflation, focusing on its potential effect on the banking industry. What is Deflation and How Does It Affect the Economy? Deflation refers to a decline in the general price level, usually caused by a sharp decline in money or credit supply or a severe contraction in the economy.1 Although sometimes used interchangeably, deflation differs from disinflation -- a falling rate of inflation. Although there have been sector-specific downward price adjustments, the U.S. economy has not experienced an outright decline in the aggregate price level since World War II, except for a brief and mild deflation in 1949.2 However, the inflation rate in the U.S. has fallen steadily since the early 1980s. In order to fully understand the effect of deflation on economic output, it is important to differentiate the concept of a "real" value from a "nominal" value.
    [Show full text]
  • An Assessment of Modern Monetary Theory
    An assessment of modern monetary theory M. Kasongo Kashama * Introduction Modern monetary theory (MMT) is a so-called heterodox economic school of thought which argues that elected governments should raise funds by issuing money to the maximum extent to implement the policies they deem necessary. While the foundations of MMT were laid in the early 1990s (Mosler, 1993), its tenets have been increasingly echoed in the public arena in recent years. The surge in interest was first reflected by high-profile British and American progressive policy-makers, for whom MMT has provided a rationale for their calls for Green New Deals and other large public spending programmes. In doing so, they have been backed up by new research work and publications from non-mainstream economists in the wake of Mosler’s work (see, for example, Tymoigne et al. (2013), Kelton (2017) or Mitchell et al. (2019)). As the COVID-19 crisis has been hitting the global economy since early this year, the most straightforward application of MMT’s macroeconomic policy agenda – that is, money- financed fiscal expansion or helicopter money – has returned to the forefront on a wider scale. Some consider not only that it is “time for helicopters” (Jourdan, 2020) but also that this global crisis must become a trigger to build on MMT precepts, not least in the euro area context (Bofinger, 2020). The MMT resurgence has been accompanied by lively political discussions and a heated economic debate, bringing fierce criticism from top economists including P. Krugman, G. Mankiw, K. Rogoff or L. Summers. This short article aims at clarifying what is at stake from a macroeconomic stabilisation perspective when considering MMT implementation in advanced economies, paying particular attention to the euro area.
    [Show full text]
  • Harvard Kennedy School Mossavar-Rahmani Center for Business and Government Study Group, February 28, 2019
    1 Harvard Kennedy School Mossavar-Rahmani Center for Business and Government Study Group, February 28, 2019 MMT (Modern Monetary Theory): What Is It and Can It Help? Paul Sheard, M-RCBG Senior Fellow, Harvard Kennedy School ([email protected]) What Is It? MMT is an approach to understanding/analyzing monetary and fiscal operations, and their economic and economic policy implications, that focuses on the fact that governments create money when they run a budget deficit (so they do not have to borrow in order to spend and cannot “run out” of money) and that pays close attention to the balance sheet mechanics of monetary and fiscal operations. Can It Help? Yes, because at a time in which the developed world appears to be “running out” of conventional monetary and fiscal policy ammunition, MMT casts a more optimistic and less constraining light on the ability of governments to stimulate aggregate demand and prevent deflation. Adopting an MMT lens, rather than being blinkered by the current conceptual and institutional orthodoxy, provides a much easier segue into the coordination of monetary and fiscal policy responses that will be needed in the next major economic downturn. Some context and background: - The current macroeconomic policy framework is based on a clear distinction between monetary and fiscal policy and assigns the primary role for “macroeconomic stabilization” (full employment and price stability and latterly usually financial stability) to an independent, technocratic central bank, which uses a “flexible inflation-targeting” framework. - Ten years after the Global Financial Crisis and Great Recession, major central banks are far from having been able to re-stock their monetary policy “ammunition,” government debt levels are high, and there is much hand- wringing about central banks being “the only game in town” and concern about how, from this starting point, central banks and fiscal authorities will be able to cope with another serious downturn.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation Or Disinflation?
    Focus No. 3 – 22 january 2009 Defl ation or disinfl ation? The rapid fall in infl ation in a context of a fi nancial crisis and a very sharp economic slowdown raises the spectre of defl ation, a situation where the decline in prices is associated with a prolonged and severe economic crisis. However, not all declines in prices are synonymous with defl ation; the distinction must be made between a defl ationary situation and the much more positive disinfl ationary situation. The aim of this Focus is to clarify these two concepts and to show that current dynamics in France and the euro area are characteristic of a disinfl ationary trend, resulting in particular from a temporary correction of certain prices, particularly energy prices. J Defl ation: defi nition and mechanisms Defi nitions Inflation means a sustained increase in the general price level in an economy. It is not an instantaneous shock, limited 1 to the prices of certain goods. It is a persistent and general process. Inflation is fuelled by expectations: when workers and companies expect prices to rise, they adjust upwards their prices and wages accordingly. Conversely, deflation means a sustained decrease in the general price level in an economy. If only certain prices fall, this is not deflation. For example, the price of laptop computers or hi-fi equipment may decrease due to technological progress, but this is not deflation. Disinflation means a reduction in the rate of inflation or a temporary decrease in the general price level in an economy. For example, if inflation falls from 3% per year to 1% per year, this is disinflation.
    [Show full text]
  • A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory
    2021 A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory Steven Globerman fraserinstitute.org Contents Executive Summary / i 1. Introducing Modern Monetary Theory / 1 2. Implementing MMT / 4 3. Has Canada Adopted MMT? / 10 4. Proposed Economic and Social Justifications for MMT / 17 5. MMT and Inflation / 23 Concluding Comments / 27 References / 29 About the author / 33 Acknowledgments / 33 Publishing information / 34 Supporting the Fraser Institute / 35 Purpose, funding, and independence / 35 About the Fraser Institute / 36 Editorial Advisory Board / 37 fraserinstitute.org fraserinstitute.org Executive Summary Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) is a policy model for funding govern- ment spending. While MMT is not new, it has recently received wide- spread attention, particularly as government spending has increased dramatically in response to the ongoing COVID-19 crisis and concerns grow about how to pay for this increased spending. The essential message of MMT is that there is no financial constraint on government spending as long as a country is a sovereign issuer of cur- rency and does not tie the value of its currency to another currency. Both Canada and the US are examples of countries that are sovereign issuers of currency. In principle, being a sovereign issuer of currency endows the government with the ability to borrow money from the country’s cen- tral bank. The central bank can effectively credit the government’s bank account at the central bank for an unlimited amount of money without either charging the government interest or, indeed, demanding repayment of the government bonds the central bank has acquired. In 2020, the cen- tral banks in both Canada and the US bought a disproportionately large share of government bonds compared to previous years, which has led some observers to argue that the governments of Canada and the United States are practicing MMT.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: a Marxist Critique
    Class, Race and Corporate Power Volume 7 Issue 1 Article 1 2019 Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Michael Roberts [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Roberts, Michael (2019) "Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique," Class, Race and Corporate Power: Vol. 7 : Iss. 1 , Article 1. DOI: 10.25148/CRCP.7.1.008316 Available at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower/vol7/iss1/1 This work is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Arts, Sciences & Education at FIU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Class, Race and Corporate Power by an authorized administrator of FIU Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Abstract Compiled from a series of blog posts which can be found at "The Next Recession." Modern monetary theory (MMT) has become flavor of the time among many leftist economic views in recent years. MMT has some traction in the left as it appears to offer theoretical support for policies of fiscal spending funded yb central bank money and running up budget deficits and public debt without earf of crises – and thus backing policies of government spending on infrastructure projects, job creation and industry in direct contrast to neoliberal mainstream policies of austerity and minimal government intervention. Here I will offer my view on the worth of MMT and its policy implications for the labor movement. First, I’ll try and give broad outline to bring out the similarities and difference with Marx’s monetary theory.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: Who Let the Air Out? February 2011
    ® Economic Information Newsletter Liber8 Brought to You by the Research Library of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Deflation: Who Let the Air Out? February 2011 “Inflation that is ‘too low’ can be problematic, as the Japanese experience has shown.” —James Bullard, President and CEO, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, August 19, 2010 The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), the Federal Reserve’s policy-setting committee, took further steps in early November 2010 to attempt to alleviate economic strains from a high unemployment rate and falling inflation rates. 1 While it is clear that a high unemployment rate and rapidly increasing prices (inflation) are undesirable for economies, it is less obvious why decreasing prices (deflation) can also restrain economic growth. At its November meeting, the FOMC discussed the potential of further slow growth in prices (disinflation). That month, the price level, as measured by the Consumer Price Index (CPI) , was 1 percent higher than it was the previous November. 2 However, less than a year earlier, in December 2009, the year-to-year change was 2.8 percent. While both rates are positive and indicate inflation, the downward trend indicates disinflation. Economists worry about disinfla - tion when the inflation rate is extremely low because it can potentially lead to deflation, a phenomenon that may be difficult for central bankers to combat and can have various negative implications on an economy. While the idea of lower prices may sound attractive, deflation is a real concern for several reasons. Deflation dis - cour ages spending and investment because consumers, expecting prices to fall further, delay purchases, preferring instead to save and wait for even lower prices.
    [Show full text]