The Taxation System in Zambia

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Taxation System in Zambia A report for the Jesuit Centre for Theological Reflection THE TAXATION SYSTEM IN ZAMBIA Technical Report Final Report January 2011 This study was prepared by Messrs Alfred Mwila, David Manley, Patrick Chileshe, Ezekiel Phiri and Kelvin Mpembamoto for the Jesuit Centre for Theological Reflection (JCTR). The Debt, Aid and Trade (DAT) Programme provided funding for the study. The views expressed in this study are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of any allied institutions. ! ! I [ The Taxation System in Zambia Final Report-January 2011 CONTENTS Glossary... .......... ...iv Summary of the report.................................. vi PART 1 INTRODUCTION AND BACKGROUND........................................... .1 1.1 Introduction............... 1 1.2 Factors that motivated the study.......................................... ...2 1.3 The hypothesis and objective of the study........ ............ 3 1.4 Structure of the study.................. 4 PART 2 OVERVIEW OF THE TAX SYSTEM................................................ 5 2.1 Introduction...... ....................... 6 2.2 Alternative sources of developmental funding.. ..... ....... 6 2.3 The tax system in Zambia.............. 13 2.4 The process of formulating tax policies.............................. 19 2.5 Recommendations......... ............ .23 PART 3 THE STRUCTURE AND PERFORMANCE OF THE TAX SYSTEM...... 25 3.1 Introduction................................. 25 3.2 Structure of taxes in Zambia.... ........ 25 3.3 The performance of the tax system.............................. .....30 3.4 Recommendations................ 43 PART 4 TAX INCENTIVES................................ 45 4.1 Introd uction...................... 45 4.2 Arguments in support of tax incentives................ .45 4.3 Arguments against tax incentives............ ................ ....46 4.4 Domestic tax incentives.. ................ 48 4.5 Trade tax incentives.... ........... 51 4.6 Estimated revenue foregone from trade tax incentives.......................52 4.7 Incentives and compensatory measures in the national budget.......... 52 4.8 Proposals to manage tax incentives ...................... .54 4.9 Recommendations................. 56 PART 5 TAXATION OF THE MINING SECTOR........... ............ 57 5.1 Introduction......... .................. 57 5.2 The performance of the mining sector ................ 58 5.3 The optimal structure of a mining tax system................... 58 5.4 A simple guide to mineral policy formation in Zambia......................... 59 ii The Taxation System in Zambia Fi nal Report-J anuary2011 5.5 Description of current and past regimes.... ................................ 60 5.6 The current regime in detail and alternative modifications........... ..... 61 5.7 Tax loopholes in mining taxation................... .....66 5.8 Reforming tax mining regimes.................... 66 5.9 Recommendations................................ 67 PART 6 INFORMAL SECTOR TAXATION............ .... ...... 68 6,1 Introduction.. .... .............................. 69 6.2 Definition of the informal sector and rationale for taxation............... .69 6.3 The structure and conduct of the informal sector...... .......... 71 6.4 The size of the informal sector.......... ......................... 73 6.5 The informal sector tax regime.................. ......76 6.6 The performance of informal sector taxes.................................... 77 6.7 Challenges of informal sector taxation..................................... ....81 6.8 Recommendations.............. ............ 83 PART 7 FEASIBILITY OF A FINANCIAL TRANSACTION TAX.................... .86 7.1 Introduction..... .............. .....86 7.2 Concept of FTT and how it reduces volatility...... .......... 86 7.3 FTT experiences in other countries ............................ 87 7.4 Impact of a FTT.. ...................... 88 7.5 Benefits of a FTT........... .................. 90 7.6 Technical feasibility of a FTT................... ...91 7.7 Feasibility of a transaction tax with direct remittance of revenues... 91 7.8 Recommendations...... ........................ 92 PART 8 CONCLUSION AND SUMMARY OF RECOMMENDATIONS.. ........... 94 8.1 Conclusion............ .............................. 94 8.2 Recommendations........ ........................ 95 REFERENCES.......... ................... 96 The Taxation System in Zambia Final Report-January 2011 GlossAry AfDF African Development Fund AIT Advance Income Taxes ASIP Agricultural Sector Investment Programme CES Carbon Emission Surtax CFDs Contracts for Differences CFTC Commodity Futures Trading Commission CIT corporate income tax COMESA Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa COMEX COMEX = NYMEX = New York Mercantile Exchange CSO Central Statistics Office CSPR Civil Society for Poverty Reduction CSR Corporate Social Responsibility DFID Department for International Development EITI Extractive Transparency Initiative FDI Foreign Direct Investment FTT Financial Transaction Tax GDP Gross Domestic Product GNI Gross National Income GRZ Government of the Republic of Zambia HDI Human Development Index HIPC Highly Indebted Poor Countries ICT Information Communication Technology IDA International Development Association IMF International Monetary Fund JCTR Jesuit Centre of Theological Reflection KCM Konkola Copper Mine LME London Metal Exchange MDGs Millennium Development Goals MDRI Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative METR Marginal Effective Tax Rate MoFNP Ministry of Finance and National Planning MTEF Medium Term Expenditure Framework NGO Non-Governmental Organizations ODA Official Development Assistance OECD Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development PAYE Pay as You Earn iv The Taxation System in Zambia Final Rep ort-January 2011 SACU Southern African Customs Union SADC Southern African Development Community SEI Self-employed Individuals TPRC Tax Policy Review Committee UK United Kingdom UNDP United Nations. Development Programme VAT Value Added Tax ZESCO Zambia Electricity Supply Corporation ZMK Zambian Kwacha ZRA Zambia Revenue Authority The Taxation System in Zambia Final Report-January 2011 SummAry oF tHe report Taxes world over are mainly levied in order to raise revenue to fund government developmental operations and assist to reduce disparity between the rich and the poor and reduce poverty. This study was undertaken on behalf of the Jesuit Centre of Theological Reflection (JCTR), which is a research, education, and advocacy organization that promotes study and action on issues linking faith and social justice in Zambia. The Debt, Aid and Trade (DAT) programme of JCTR commissioned the study to comprehend the taxation system in Zambia with the aim of forming knowledgeable and evidence based opinions on how it affects social justice1. The study uses qualitative and quantitative analysis based on data compiled from various sources. This study was motivated by the poor performance of the revenue system in the last decade. In particular, there has been an obvious decline in the share of tax revenue to Gross Domestic Product (GDP) while the performance of some tax types, such as domestic VAT and trade taxes, have also progressively declined. The performance of the mining sector taxes has equally not been impressive and there has been concern as to whether the sector is being taxed optimally. Another factor that motivated the study was the need to analyse the role of the informal sector in the tax system and how it can sustainably contribute to domestic revenue mobilization. This is because, up until now, the tax system has relied mostly on revenues from the formal sector while the informal sector remains largely untaxed. The last motivating factor was the need to explore how Zambia can raise extra revenue from its traditional exports, like copper, through a financial transaction tax. The premise of this study is that Zambia has the potential to raise more tax revenue and improve social justice by employing prudent policies and practices that improve tax revenue administration. The major objective of the study is to contribute to the existing body of knowledge on the tax system in Zambia by identifying the key challenges and possible success factors. The information generated by this study would be used by the JCTR as research, education, and advocacy tools to lobby relevant authorities on how the current tax system can be best utilized and reorganised in order to attain social justice. Social justice deals with matters of fair distribution of advantages, assets, and benefits among all members of a society. This can be attained through degree of economic equality through progressive taxation, income redistribution, or even property redistribution. The Taxation System in Zambia Final Report-January 2011 Study findings Part 2 Government funding sources and overview of the tax system Zambian taxes are broadly categorised into three groups as follows: income taxes, consumption taxes and trade taxes. These taxes make up the domestic revenue base for the country. These taxes contribute up to 70 percent to national budget. Other revenues that Government mobilises to supplement tax revenue comes from funding from external donors through budgetary support, Foreign Direct Investment (FDI), and debt provision. Apart from these revenue sources, there are other sources that are not fully exploited yet. These include, local government revenues and alternatives taxes, such as wealth taxes. However, these alternative sources of revenue have challenges that need to be addressed if
Recommended publications
  • Imports in GST Regime (Goods & Services Tax)
    Imports in GST Regime (Goods & Services Tax) Introduction Under the GST regime, Article 269A constitutionally mandates that supply of goods, or of services, or both in the course of import into the territory of India shall be deemed to be supply of goods, or of services, or both in the course of inter-State trade or commerce. So import of goods or services will be treated as deemed inter-State supplies and would be subject to Integrated tax. While IGST on import of services would be leviable under the IGST Act, the levy of the IGST on import of goods would be levied under the Customs Act, 1962 read with the Custom Tariff Act, 1975. The importer of services will have to pay tax on reverse charge basis. However, in respect of import of online information and database access or retrieval services (OIDAR) by unregistered, non-taxable recipients, the supplier located outside India shall be responsible for payment of taxes (IGST). Either the supplier will have to take registration or will have to appoint a person in India for payment of taxes. Supply of goods or services or both to a Special Economic Zone developer or a unit shall be treated as inter-State supply and shall be subject to levy of integrated tax. Directorate General of Taxpayer Services CENTRAL BOARD OF EXCISE & CUSTOMS www.cbec.gov.in Imports in GST Regime (Goods & Services Tax) Importer Exporter Code (IEC): As per DGFT’s Trade Notice No. 09 The taxes will be calculated as under: dated 12.06.2017, the PAN of an entity would be used as the Import Particulars Duty Export code (IEC).
    [Show full text]
  • Taxation in Islam
    Taxation in Islam The following article is based on the book Funds in the Khilafah State which is a translation of Al-Amwal fi Dowlat Al-Khilafah by Abdul-Qadeem Zalloom.1 Allah (swt) has revealed a comprehensive economic system that details all aspects of economic life including government revenues and taxation. In origin, the permanent sources of revenue for the Bait ul-Mal (State Treasury) should be sufficient to cover the obligatory expenditure of the Islamic State. These revenues that Shar’a (Islamic Law) has defined are: Fa’i, Jizya, Kharaj, Ushur, and income from Public properties. The financial burdens placed on modern states today are far higher than in previous times. When the Caliphate is re-established it will need to finance a huge re-development and industrial programme to reverse centuries of decline, and bring the Muslim world fully into the 21st century. Because of this, the Bait ul-Mal’s permanent sources of revenue may be insufficient to cover all the needs and interests the Caliphate is obliged to spend upon. In such a situation where the Bait ul-Mal’s revenues are insufficient to meet the Caliphate’s budgetary requirements, the Islamic obligation transfers from the Bait ul-Mal to the Muslims as a whole. This is because Allah (swt) has obliged the Muslims to spend on these needs and interests, and their failure to spend on them will lead to the harming of Muslims. Allah (swt) obliged the State and the Ummah to remove any harm from the Muslims. It was related on the authority of Abu Sa’id al-Khudri, (ra), that the Messenger of Allah (saw) said: “It is not allowed to do harm nor to allow being harmed.” [Ibn Majah, Al-Daraqutni] Therefore, Allah (swt) has obliged the State to collect money from the Muslims in order to cover its obligatory expenditure.
    [Show full text]
  • The Financial Secrecy Index: Shedding New Light on the Geography of Secrecy
    The Financial Secrecy Index: Shedding New Light on the Geography of Secrecy Alex Cobham, Petr Janský, and Markus Meinzer Abstract Both academic research and public policy debate around tax havens and offshore finance typically suffer from a lack of definitional consistency. Unsurprisingly then, there is little agreement about which jurisdictions ought to be considered as tax havens—or which policy measures would result in their not being so considered. In this article we explore and make operational an alternative concept, that of a secrecy jurisdiction and present the findings of the resulting Financial Secrecy Index (FSI). The FSI ranks countries and jurisdictions according to their contribution to opacity in global financial flows, revealing a quite different geography of financial secrecy from the image of small island tax havens that may still dominate popular perceptions and some of the literature on offshore finance. Some major (secrecy-supplying) economies now come into focus. Instead of a binary division between tax havens and others, the results show a secrecy spectrum, on which all jurisdictions can be situated, and that adjustment lfor the scale of business is necessary in order to compare impact propensity. This approach has the potential to support more precise and granular research findings and policy recommendations. JEL Codes: F36, F65 Working Paper 404 www.cgdev.org May 2015 The Financial Secrecy Index: Shedding New Light on the Geography of Secrecy Alex Cobham Tax Justice Network Petr Janský Institute of Economic Studies, Faculty of Social Sciences, Charles University in Prague Markus Meinzer Tax Justice Network A version of this paper is published in Economic Geography (July 2015).
    [Show full text]
  • 2021 Tax Rates, Schedules, and Contribution Limits
    2021 tax rates, schedules, and contribution limits Income tax Tax on capital gains and qualified dividends If taxable Income income But Of the Single Married/Filing jointly/Qualifying Widow(er) Tax rate is over not over The tax is amount over $0–$40,400 $0–$80,800 0% Married/Filing $0 $19,900 $0.00 + 10% $0 jointly and $19,900 $81,050 $1,990 + 12% $19,900 Over $40,400 but not Over $80,800 but not over qualifying over $445,850 $501,600 15% widow(er)s $81,050 $172,750 $9,328 + 22% $81,050 Over $445,850 Over $501,600 20% $172,750 $329,850 $29,502 + 24% $172,750 Additional 3.8% federal net investment income (NII) tax applies to individuals $329,850 $418,850 $67,206 + 32% $329,850 on the lesser of NII or modified AGI in excess of $200,000 (single) or $250,000 $418,850 $628,300 $95,686 + 35% $418,850 (married/filing jointly and qualifying widow(er)s). Also applies to any trust or $628,300 $168,993.50 + 37% $628,300 estate on the lesser of undistributed NII or AGI in excess of the dollar amount Single $0 $9,950 $0.00 + 10% $0 at which the estate/trust pays income taxes at the highest rate ($13,050). $9,950 $40,525 $995 + 12% $9,950 Kiddie tax* $40,525 $86,375 $4,664 + 22% $40,525 Child’s unearned income above $2,200 is generally subject to taxation at $86,375 $164,925 $14,751 + 24% $86,375 the parent’s marginal tax rate; unearned income above $1,100 but not $164,925 $209,425 $33,603 + 32% $164,925 more than $2,200 is taxed at the child’s tax rate.
    [Show full text]
  • How Do Federal Income Tax Rates Work? XXXX
    TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK Key Elements of the U.S. Tax System INDIVIDUAL INCOME TAX How do federal income tax rates work? XXXX Q. How do federal income tax rates work? A. The federal individual income tax has seven tax rates that rise with income. Each rate applies only to income in a specific range (tax bracket). CURRENT INCOME TAX RATES AND BRACKETS The federal individual income tax has seven tax rates ranging from 10 percent to 37 percent (table 1). The rates apply to taxable income—adjusted gross income minus either the standard deduction or allowable itemized deductions. Income up to the standard deduction (or itemized deductions) is thus taxed at a zero rate. Federal income tax rates are progressive: As taxable income increases, it is taxed at higher rates. Different tax rates are levied on income in different ranges (or brackets) depending on the taxpayer’s filing status. In TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK Key Elements of the U.S. Tax System INDIVIDUAL INCOME TAX How do federal income tax rates work? XXXX 2020 the top tax rate (37 percent) applies to taxable income over $518,400 for single filers and over $622,050 for married couples filing jointly. Additional tax schedules and rates apply to taxpayers who file as heads of household and to married individuals filing separate returns. A separate schedule of tax rates applies to capital gains and dividends. Tax brackets are adjusted annually for inflation. BASICS OF PROGRESSIVE INCOME TAXATION Each tax rate applies only to income in a specific tax bracket. Thus, if a taxpayer earns enough to reach a new bracket with a higher tax rate, his or her total income is not taxed at that rate, just the income in that bracket.
    [Show full text]
  • State Individual Income Tax Rates
    STATE INDIVIDUAL INCOME TAXES (Tax rates for tax year 2021 -- as of January 1, 2021) TAX RATE RANGE Number FEDERAL (in percents) of INCOME BRACKETS PERSONAL EXEMPTIONS STANDARD DEDUCTION INCOME TAX Low High Brackets Lowest Highest Single Married Dependents Single Married DEDUCTIBLE ALABAMA 2.0 - 5.0 3 500 (b) - 3,001 (b) 1,500 3,000 500 (e) 2,500 (y) 7,500 (y) Yes ALASKA No State Income Tax ARIZONA (a) 2.59 - 8.0 (aa) 4 27,272 (b) - 163,633 (b) -- -- 100 (c) 12,400 24,800 ARKANSAS (a) 2.0 - 5.9 (f) 3 4,000 - 79,300 29 (c) 58 (c) 29 (c) 2,200 4,400 CALIFORNIA (a) 1.0 12.3 (g) 9 8,932 (b) - 599,012 (b) 124 (c) 248 (c) 383 (c) 4,601 (a) 9,202 (a) COLORADO 4.55 1 -----Flat rate----- -- (d) -- (d) -- (d) 12,550 (d) 25,100 (d) CONNECTICUT 3.0 - 6.99 7 10,000 (b) - 500,000 (b) 15,000 (h) 24,000 (h) 0 -- (h) -- (h) DELAWARE 0.0 - 6.6 7 2,000 - 60,001 110 (c) 220 (c) 110 (c) 3,250 6,500 FLORIDA No State Income Tax GEORGIA 1.0 - 5.75 6 750 (i) - 7,001 (i) 2,700 7,400 3,000 4,600 6,000 HAWAII 1.4 - 11.0 12 2,400 (b) - 200,000 (b) 1,144 2,288 1,144 2,200 4,400 IDAHO (a) 1.125 - 6.925 7 1,568 (b) - 11,760 (b) -- (d) -- (d) -- (d) 12,550 (d) 25,100 (d) ILLINOIS (a) 4.95 1 -----Flat rate----- 2,325 4,650 2,325 -- -- INDIANA 3.23 1 -----Flat rate----- 1,000 2,000 2,500 (j) -- -- IOWA (a) 0.33 - 8.53 9 1,676 - 75,420 40 (c) 80 (c) 40 (c) 2,130 (a) 5,250 (a) Yes KANSAS 3.1 - 5.7 3 15,000 (b) - 30,000(b) 2,250 4,500 2,250 3,000 7,500 KENTUCKY 5.0 1 -----Flat rate----- -----------None----------- 2,690 2,690 LOUISIANA 2.0 - 6.0 3 12,500 (b) - 50,001(b) 4,500
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding Real Estate Taxes in Ohio
    Understanding Real Estate Taxes in Ohio Real Estate Tax calculation begins with appraised value. Appraised value is based on what the property would sell for at a given point in time. We use a mass appraisal process to acquire property data. Mass appraisal computer software calculates the probable sales price of each property; this is known as the Appraised Value. This Appraised Value is then compared to actual sales to determine accuracy and if any adjustments are needed. You do not pay Real Estate Taxes on the Appraised Value. You pay tax on the Assessed Value, which is 35% of the Appraised Value. The Assessed Value multiplied by the tax rate produces the tax due. For example, if your property has an Appraised Value of $100,000, the Assessed Value (or Taxable Value) is only $35,000. There are different types of Tax Levies. We will discuss three of them. Each Levy reacts differently to value changes. They are: Inside Levies (Unvoted) – each taxing district can have up to 10 mills of unvoted millage. This millage is unique in that it moves in direct correlation with your property value. For instance, if your value increases or decreases 5%, your taxes on the inside millage will increase or decrease 5%, respectively. Fixed Sum Levies –are approved by the voters to generate a specific amount of money. The two most popular Fixed Sum Levies are Emergency Levies, where a school district levies a tax to generate a specified amount of money each year; and a Bond Levy, where a taxing district passes a levy to meet the annual debt requirements related to a project.
    [Show full text]
  • Environmental Taxation and International Eco-Industries Joan Canton
    Environmental Taxation and International Eco-Industries Joan Canton NOTA DI LAVORO 26.2007 FEBRUARY 2007 ETA – Economic Theory and Applications Joan Canton, GREQAM, Université de la Méditerranée This paper can be downloaded without charge at: The Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Note di Lavoro Series Index: http://www.feem.it/Feem/Pub/Publications/WPapers/default.htm Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://ssrn.com/abstract=970278 The opinions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the position of Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Corso Magenta, 63, 20123 Milano (I), web site: www.feem.it, e-mail: [email protected] Environmental Taxation and International Eco-Industries Summary Environmental policies are discussed when two countries differ in their ability to abate pollution. Northern eco-industries (the industry supplying abatement activities) are more efficient than Southern ones. Segmented environmental markets and a Northern monopoly yield identical second-best taxes in both countries. When markets are global, Southern countries underestimate the market power of eco-industries. Introducing competition creates positive (resp. negative) rent-shifting distortions in South (resp. North). Cooperation could reduce Northern pollution but has ambiguous consequences in South. Keywords: Eco-Industry, Strategic Environmental Policy, Asymmetric Oligopolies JEL Classification: D62, H23, F12 I would like to thank Hubert Stahn, Antoine Soubeyran and Tanguy Van Ypersele for their very helpful comments. I am also grateful to participants of Journées Doctorales de l'ADRES 2006 and of the Third World Congress of environmental and resource economics, in Kyoto. Address for correspondence: Joan Canton GREQAM, Université de la Méditerranée Chateau Lafarge route des Milles 13290 Les Milles France Phone: +33 04 42 93 59 80 Fax: +33 04 42 93 09 68 E-mail: [email protected] 1 Introduction One cannot deny huge di®erences in the stringency of environmental policies around the world.
    [Show full text]
  • Zambia Fiscal Guide 2017/2018
    Zambia Fiscal Guide 2017/2018 Ta x KPMG.com Document Classification: KPMG Confidential Zambia Fiscal Guide 2017/2018 | 0 Income tax Basis of taxation Tax is levied on a source or deemed source basis. Residents are taxed on domestic-source income and certain types of foreign income. Non-residents are usually taxed on Zambian-sourced income and are subject to a range of withholding taxes (WHT) − some of which may be reduced under a double tax treaty negotiated with the country of residence of the recipient. Rates of tax Resident companies Corporation tax: Manufacturing and other 35% Manufacturing of organic and chemical fertilizers 15% Mining 30% Mining – profits earned from tolling 30% Hedging income 35% Export duty on copper & cobalt concentrates 10% Export duty of copper blisters 15% Export duty on all other unprocessed or semi-processed mineral ores 10% First K250 000 - 35% Telecommunication companies Above K250 000 - 40% Banks 35% Public benefit organisations 15% Farming and agro-processing 10% Export of non-traditional products 15% Withholding tax (WHT) Dividends from non-mining companies 15% Dividends from companies carrying on mining operations 0% Profits distribution by branches of foreign companies 15% Winning from gaming, lotteries and betting (final tax) 20% Debenture interest paid to Zambian investors in a property company listed on 0% the Lusaka Stock Exchange Interest for individuals (earned from banks or building societies, savings and 0% deposit accounts), (final tax) Interest on Treasury Bills for individuals (final tax)
    [Show full text]
  • The Relationship Between Tax Rates and Government Revenue
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: A General Equilibrium Model for Tax Policy Evaluation Volume Author/Editor: Charles L. Ballard, Don Fullerton, John B. Shoven, and John Whalley Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-03632-4 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/ball85-1 Publication Date: 1985 Chapter Title: The Relationship between Tax Rates and Government Revenue Chapter Author: Charles L. Ballard, Don Fullerton, John B. Shoven, John Whalley Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11222 Chapter pages in book: (p. 188 - 202) 10 The Relationship between Tax Rates and Government Revenue 10.1 Introduction Since 1974, when Arthur B. Laffer first drew his famous curve on a napkin in a Washington restaurant, there has been considerable public debate about the possibility of an inverse relationship between tax rates and government revenue. Pictured in figure 10.1, the Laffer curve plots total revenue against the tax rate and claims to show that two rates exist at which a given revenue can be collected. The tax rate of figure 10.1 generally refers to any particular tax instrument, while revenues gener- ally refer to total tax receipts. An increase in the payroll tax rate, for example, could affect not only its own revenue, but work effort and thus personal income tax revenues. The upward-sloping portion of the curve is called the "normal" range and the downward-sloping segment is the "prohibitive" range. No ra- tional government would knowingly operate on the latter range in the long run, because the same revenue could be obtained with a lower tax rate.
    [Show full text]
  • Taxes, Efficiency, and Redistribution: Discriminatory Taxation of Villages in Ottoman Palestine, Southern Syria and Transjordan in the Sixteenth Century Metin M
    University of Connecticut OpenCommons@UConn Economics Working Papers Department of Economics July 2004 Taxes, Efficiency, and Redistribution: Discriminatory Taxation of Villages in Ottoman Palestine, Southern Syria and Transjordan in the Sixteenth Century metin M. Cosgel University of Connecticut Follow this and additional works at: https://opencommons.uconn.edu/econ_wpapers Recommended Citation Cosgel, metin M., "Taxes, Efficiency, and Redistribution: Discriminatory Taxation of Villages in Ottoman Palestine, Southern Syria and Transjordan in the Sixteenth Century" (2004). Economics Working Papers. 200222. https://opencommons.uconn.edu/econ_wpapers/200222 Department of Economics Working Paper Series Taxes, Efficiency, and Redistribution: Discriminatory Taxation of Villages in Ottoman Palestine, Southern Syria and Transjor- dan in the Sixteenth Century Metin Cos¸gel University of Connecticut Working Paper 2002-22R October 2002, revised July 2004 341 Mansfield Road, Unit 1063 Storrs, CT 06269–1063 Phone: (860) 486–3022 Fax: (860) 486–4463 http://www.econ.uconn.edu/ Abstract Governments can tax productive activities with either uniform or discrimina- tory rates among taxpayers. Although discriminatory rates can cause productive inefficiency and require high cost of administration, they can be preferred because of their advantage in distributional flexibility. This paper studies the discrimina- tory taxation of production in the Fertile Crescent. Using information from the Ottoman tax registers, it examines the basis, distortionary effects, and distribu- tional consequences of discriminatory rates quantitatively. The results challenge widely held beliefs about the basis for discriminatory rates in this region and the Ottoman government’s motivation in adapting systems of taxation in newly con- quered lands. Keywords: taxes, efficiency, redistribution, discriminatory rates, Ottoman Empire, Palestine, Syria, Transjordan Forthcoming in Explorations in Economic History.
    [Show full text]
  • B. Personal Income Tax
    B. Personal Income Tax Natural persons (individuals) are liable to (personal) income tax which is subject to increase by a solidarity surcharge. If responsible for a business or trade, individuals are also subject to trade tax. Corporate taxpayers (in parti- cular AG, GmbH, KGaA) are subject to corporate income tax and trade tax. The corporate income tax basically refers to many provisions of the personal income tax as far as the calculation of the tax base is concerned. The perso- nal income tax rules could therefore be considered as a starting point for the corporate income tax system. I. Liability for Personal Income Tax 1. Taxable persons: residents and non-residents Liability to tax is set out in sec. 1 EStG (German Income Tax Act). Each natural person, as defined in sec. 1 BGB (German Civil Code), is subject to personal income tax if he is resident in Germany. Such an individual, or rather natural person, is also referred to as a “tax subject” (Steuersubjekt). Partnerships, e.g., general partnerships (OHG), limited partnerships (KG), etc., are liable neither to personal income tax nor to corporate income tax. Revenue earned by such partnerships is taxed at the level of the share- holders, i.e., the shareholders are subject to tax on partnership earnings. If a natural person maintains a domicile or habitual place of abode in Ger- many, he is fully liable to (income) tax (unbeschränkte Steuerpflicht) as set out in sec. 1 para. 1 EStG. The place of residence and the habitual place of abode are defined in sec. 8 AO and sec.
    [Show full text]