Green Certificate Trading

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Green Certificate Trading Journal of Energy in Southern Africa 22(1): 42–54 DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.17159/2413-3051/2011/v22i1a3201 Green certificate trading Kerri Brick Environmental Policy Research Unit, University of Cape Town Martine Visser School of Economics, University of Cape Town Abstract on Climate Change (UNFCCC), which was opened Policies to promote renewable electricity are for signature in 1992. ‘The primary objective of the increasingly seen as a way to reduce the negative UNFCCC is to achieve stabilisation of the concen- environmental impacts associated with electricity trations of GHG in the atmosphere at a level that consumption and meet growing electricity demand. would prevent dangerous anthropogenic interfer- This paper reviews the international experience ence with the climate system’ (UNFCCC, 1992). As with one such policy, namely, renewable energy cer- South Africa ratified the UNFCCC in 1997, the tificates, and considers important design aspects of country is entitled to apply for financial assistance a national green certificate system. Within a South from the Global Environmental Facility for climate African context, a green certificate system would change related activities. provide a mechanism with which to verify compli- The Kyoto Protocol,1 a legal instrument under ance with any future renewable energy obligations, the framework of the Convention, sets binding tar- and would encourage renewable electricity genera- gets under which industrialised (Annex I) countries tion in the current monopoly environment. In terms must reduce greenhouse gas emissions by an aver- of a national green certificate framework, interna- age of five percent against 1990 levels over the peri- tional experience has shown that renewable energy od 2008-2012 (UNFCCC, 1997). The Kyoto certificates must be both accredited and standard- Protocol is the first and only binding international ized, with enforcement of penalties for non-compli- agreement to set targets for the reduction of green- ance with renewable energy quotas. Above all, a house gas emissions (Fakir and Nicol, 2008). long-term and stable policy environment is crucial In March 2002, South Africa acceded to the for developing renewable energy markets. Protocol. While the Protocol does not commit non- Keywords: renewable energy; tradable renewable Annex I (developing) economies such as South energy certificates Africa to quantified emission reduction targets over the period 2008-2012, there is potential for emis- sion reduction through the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) which promotes emission reductions between non-Annex I countries and 1. Introduction: international and domestic Annex I countries. The CDM facilitates Annex I context investment in emission-reducing projects in non- Strong action is needed to reduce global green- Annex I economies. In this way, Annex I countries house gas (GHG) emissions and reverse the trend are able to obtain carbon credits to enable them to towards higher global temperatures (Stern Review, meet their emissions reduction targets. As such, the 2007). Given the threat to the climate from fossil CDM supports sustainable development with fuels, a focus on clean energy and energy efficiency respect to GHG emissions in developing countries is growing (DEAT, 2008). Increasing the share of while helping Annex I countries to comply with their renewable energy in terms of the national energy Kyoto Protocol commitments and reducing the mix is rising to the top of political agendas world- overall level of GHG emissions (DME, 2003; Fakir wide. and Nicol, 2008). The Intergovernmental Negotiating Committee South Africa is very dependent on fossil fuels as for a Framework Convention on Climate Change a primary energy source. Specifically, around 90 drafted the United Nations Framework Convention percent of energy is derived from low cost coal 42 Journal of Energy in Southern Africa • Vol 22 No 1 • February 2011 (DEAT, 2008) . Furthermore, 93 percent of electrici - environmental degradation, such as air pollution ty generation is based on coal (Winkler, 2005). and climate change. The ‘polluter pays ’ principle South Africa is ranked 19 th in terms of world emis - states that the party responsible for such pollution sions (based on absolute totals for six GHGs 2 in must pay for the negative environmental impacts 2000) contributing 1.1 percent of the global emis - caused. There is an internalisation of external costs sions total, and is ranked 13 th in terms of the carbon if the polluter pays adequately for any environmen - intensity of electricity production (CAIT, 2009). In tal damage caused. When external costs, such as air the 2003 White Paper on Renewable Energy, while pollution, are not internalised, the market mecha - recognizing South Africa’s dependence on fossil nism fails to secure an optimal allocation of fuels to meet energy requirements, the state resources. This is because the prices of goods with acknowledged the growing need for South Africa to large external costs are understated when these become a responsible ‘global neighbour ’, amid external costs are not internalised. As such, these mounting concerns about global climate change goods are over -consumed relative to the optimal (DME, 2003) . level of consumption for the wellbeing of society. In this context, the 2003 White Paper on The internalisation of external costs is therefore a Renewable Energy sets out government’s vision for necessary pre-condition for the optimal allocation promoting renewable energy in South Africa : of resources. When these externalities are inter - nalised, energy production technologies will be allo - Government’s long-term goal is the establish - cated by the market according to their social costs, ment of a renewable energy industry producing and the price of goods (electricity) will reflect their modern energy carriers that will offer in future true cost (Ragwitz et al ., 2006). years a sustainable, fully non-subsidised alterna - The European Commission has evaluated the tive to fossil fuels. The proportion of final ener - external costs of different energy systems. The gy consumption currently provided by renew - Commission’s ExternE project on external costs able energy has come about largely as a result of estimated that the cost of producing electricity from poverty (e.g. fuelwood and animal waste used coal or oil in the European Union would double for cooking and heating). To get started on a and the cost of producing electricity from gas would deliberate path towards this goal, the increase by 30 percent if external costs, in the form Government’s medium-term (10-year) target is: of damage to environment and health, were taken 10 000 GWh renewable energy contribution to into account (Ragwitz et al ., 2006). final energy consumption by 2013, to be pro - Renewable energy sources decrease pollution, duced mainly from biomass, wind, solar and contribute to the achievement of the Kyoto Protocol small-scale hydro… This is approximately 4% climate change mitigation goals, allow countries to (1667 MW) of the projected electricity demand improve security of energy supply by reducing fos - for 2013 (41539 MW) . (DME, 2003: ix) sil fuel dependency and provide numerous socioe - conomic opportunities such as investment, devel - This paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 briefly opment and job creation. Yet, despite these many outlines the policy instruments available for the pro - benefits, renewable energy competes with conven - motion of renewable energy sources, while section tional electricity on an unequal playing field amid a 3 discusses green certificate trading in more detail, failure to internalize the negative externalities asso - including the green certificate market in South ciated with conventional energy production. Public Africa at present . Section 4 describes the interna - support is thus needed to level the playing field and tional implementation of renewable energy support promote the market penetration of renewable ener - mechanisms. The lessons learnt from this experi - gy sources (Gonzalez, 2007) . ence in terms of design suggestions for the devel - In many countries, particularly in Europe, the opment of a South African TREC framework are main policy instrument used to support renewable detailed in Section 5. Also from international expe - electricity 3 deployment is the feed-in tariff. In this rience, Section 6 provides a comparison of a feed- system, a premium price is paid for all qualifying in tariff scheme and a quota obligation system com - renewable electricity delivered to the grid. Utilities bined with tradable green certificates. Finally, the are obliged to purchase this electricity at the set interaction between emission trading schemes and price – which is determined by the state. Given that renewable energy promotion systems are outlined the costs of generation differ across the spectrum of in Section 7 . renewable energy technologies, the feed-in tariff usually differs by technology and is provided for a 2. Policy instruments for the promotion of specified time period. The feed-in tariff may also renewable energy decrease over time in line with reductions in the While energy is critical to all aspects of South cost of renewable energy generation. Theoretically, Africa’s economic and social development, the way by setting the price but not the quantity of electrici - in which it is produced and used can contribute to ty produced, it is not known in advance how much Journal of Energy in Southern Africa • Vol 22 No 1 • February 2011
Recommended publications
  • Implications of Tradable Green Certificates for the UK
    The Implications of Tradable Green Certificates for the UK ETSU Project Number : TGC (K/BD/00218) Contractor: SPRU Authors : Catherine Mitchell, Teresa Anderson March 2000 ii Executive Summary A Green Certificate (GC) is used to represent the ‘greenness ’ of a unit of renewable electricity. This allows the unit to be divided into two parts: the physical electricity and its associated greenness. If the two parts are regarded as distinct, they can then be traded in two separate markets: the conventional physical electricity market and the market for greenness. Within a situation where there is an imposed demand (ie an obligation) GCs serve two purposes: • they act as an accounting system to verify whether the obligation has been met • they facilitate trade which allows the obligation to be filled either by buying physical electricity with GCs or by GCs alone in the alternative tradable green certificate market (at which point they become TGCs) The UK could establish a national TGC market where only UK-generated TGCs were valid or the UK could become part of a wider trans-national market (for example, made up of EU countries) where TGCs from all EU countries are valid. A national TGC system would be easier to establish than a trans-national system. This is because a TGC has to be both accredited and standardised so that TGCs are a defined product. Within a UK national system, there is the prospect of four uses for GCs: • combined GCs & kWh used to qualify for the Climate Change Levy (CCL) exemption for large business users, but not eligible against the RE obligation (not agreed as yet by Customs and Excise or DETR); • combined GCs & kWh used to obtain the CCL rebate for small business users, (also eligible against the RE obligation); • GCs traded separately or combined with kWh which can be used against the RE obligation; • GCs traded separately or combined with kWh which are used within voluntary green power supply, which cannot be used against the RE obligation.
    [Show full text]
  • A Policymaker's Guide to Feed-In Tariff Policy Design DE-AC36-08-GO28308
    A Policymaker’s Guide to Feed-in Tariff Policy Design Toby D. Couture E3 Analytics Karlynn Cory Claire Kreycik National Renewable Energy Laboratory Emily Williams U.S. Department of State Technical Report NREL/TP-6A2-44849 July 2010 NREL is a national laboratory of the U.S. Department of Energy, Office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy, operated by the Alliance for Sustainable Energy, LLC. On the Cover Feed-in tari ff (FIT) policies can apply to several renewable energy technologies and their applications including (top to bottom) solar photovoltaics (PV) on commercial buildings (Art Institute of Chicago – Chicago, Illinois); on-site wind energy (Great Lakes Science Center – Cleveland, Ohio); rooftop PV on residences (Glastonbury, Connecticut); solar power tower (Solar One –Barstow, California); and dry-steam geothermal plant (The Geysers – Calistoga, California). Cover Photo Credits – (background) Oberlin College, Ohio - PIX#10861 and (top to bottom) PIX#13789, PIX#14827, PIX#15679, PIX#00036, PIX#01045. Acknowledgments This work was funded by the U.S. Department of Energy’s (DOE) Solar Energy Technologies Program. The authors want to thank participating DOE staff – Charles Hemmeline and Jennifer DeCesaro – for providing useful insights and overall direction to this project. The authors are also grateful for the guidance and helpful input of the project manager, Robert Margolis of the National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL). We would also like to thank David Kline (NREL), Professor Volkmar Lauber of the University of Salzburg (Austria), and Wilson Rickerson from Meister Consultants Group for their detailed and thoughtful comments on early drafts of the report, and for providing their valuable insights and expertise.
    [Show full text]
  • Taxes and Incentives for Renewable Energy
    Taxes and incentives for renewable energy KPMG International kpmg.com/energytax Taxes and Incentives for Renewable Energy is designed to help energy companies, investors and other entities stay current with government policies and programs that support renewable energy from wind, solar, biomass, geothermal and hydropower. Compiled by KPMG’s Global Energy & Natural Resources tax practice, the 2015 edition provides updates on renewable energy promotion policies for 31 countries. It also includes information on adoption trends for renewables, the growing prominence of emerging markets, new solar and wind initiatives, and key investments in renewable energy around the world. Lars Behrendt Tax Partner, KPMG in Germany © 2015 KPMG International Cooperative (“KPMG International”). KPMG International provides no client services and is a Swiss entity with which the independent member firms of the KPMG network are affiliated. Contents Introduction 2 2015 industry trends 4 Global investment in renewable energy production 6 Renewable energy promotion policies by country 10 Argentina 12 Australia 13 Austria 15 Belgium 16 Brazil 17 Canada 19 China 22 Costa Rica 25 France 27 Germany 30 Greece 34 India 38 Ireland 40 Italy 42 Japan 44 Mexico 45 The Netherlands 47 New Zealand 48 Norway 49 Peru 51 Philippines 52 Poland 56 Romania 59 South Africa 61 South Korea 63 Spain 65 Sweden 67 Turkey 68 United Kingdom 69 United States 73 Uruguay 75 Top Five Countries 2014 77 Appendix A: REN21 2014 Renewable Global Status Report 78 © 2015 KPMG International Cooperative (“KPMG International”). KPMG International provides no client services and is a Swiss entity with which the independent member firms of the KPMG network are affiliated.
    [Show full text]
  • Energy Attributes Certificates: a Novel Mechanism to Support Energy Transition in Lebanon
    AMERICAN UNIVERSITY OF BEIRUT ENERGY ATTRIBUTES CERTIFICATES: A NOVEL MECHANISM TO SUPPORT ENERGY TRANSITION IN LEBANON by NOURA NABIL LAYSSI STOUHI A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Sciences to the Department of Mechanical Engineering of the Maroun Semaan Faculty of Engineering and Architecture at the American University of Beirut Beirut, Lebanon June 2020 AMERICAN UNIVERSITY OF BEIRUT ENERGY ATTRIBUTES CERTIFICATES: A NOVEL MECHANISM TO SUPPORT ENERGY TRANSITION IN LEBANON by NOURA NABIL LAYSSI STOUHI Approved by: Dr. Nesreene Ghaddar, Professor Maroon Semaan Faculty of Engineering and Architecture Advisor Dr. Hassan Harajli, Lecturer Department of Environmental Health Co-Advisor Dr. Karim Makdisi, Associate Professor Department of Political Studies and Public Administration Member of Committee Dr. Ibrahim Alameddine, Assistant Professor Department of Civil and Environmental Engineering Member of Committee Date of thesis/dissertation defense: [June 18, 2020] AMERICAN UNIVERSITY OF BEIRUT THESIS, DISSERTATION, PROJECT RELEASE FORM Student Name: Layssi Stouhi _________________Noura _________________________ Last First Middle I authorize the American University of Beirut to: (a) reproduce hard or electronic copies of my thesis, dissertation, or project; (b) include such copies in the archives and digital repositories of the University; and (c) make freely available such copies to third parties for research or educational purposes. I authorize the American University of Beirut, to: (a) reproduce hard or electronic copies of it; (b) include such copies in the archives and digital repositories of the University; and (c) make freely available such copies to third parties for research or educational purposes after : One ---- year from the date of submission of my thesis, dissertation, or project.
    [Show full text]
  • CLIMATE CHANGE – Impact on Energy Regulation and Infrastructure
    Background paper for the 7th US-EU Energy Regulators Round Table, Session IV: Climate change Mrs. Yvonne Fredriksson, Director General Energy Markets Inspectorate, Sweden CLIMATE CHANGE – Impact on energy regulation and infrastructure Introduction The present paper presents some of the challenges to infrastructure and raises some of the problems for energy regulators resulting from measures aimed at meeting political environmental targets. The paper discusses possible solutions, with examples from the European Union (EU) but which could also be applicable to the US. The impact on the regulator and on network investment can vary depending on the type of promotion system for renewables chosen by countries - market-based or state aid-based. The areas discussed are: • The role of the regulator in meeting environmental goals • The need to promote reserve generation • Promotion of renewables from a market perspective • The impact of renewables on energy regulation and on network investment The role of the regulator for meeting environmental goals The national energy regulator must set its goals and develop its activities, while also complying with the environmental goals the government/politicians have set up, including e.g. quantitative targets regarding energy efficiency, and establishing rules which are instrumental to promoting the generation of power from renewable sources. In general terms, the role of the energy regulator in helping to meet environmental goals is primarily to contribute to efficient energy markets, which means: • ensuring the reliability and quality of energy supply • promoting energy efficiency • safeguarding consumer interests 1 • guaranteeing access to the infrastructure (networks) for all suppliers (and even giving priority to renewable energy producers) At European level, the EU Directives – based on political priorities - constitute the legal framework within which the national authorities must ensure that citizens and industries are getting fair, competitive energy prices, through efficient energy markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Are Green Jobs Real Jobs? the Case of Italy
    Are Green Jobs Real Jobs? The Case of Italy Istituto Bruno Leoni May 2010 Luciano Lavecchia Carlo Stagnaro 2 — Luciano Lavecchia – Carlo Stagnaro Luciano Lavecchia (Palermo 1985) is Fellow of Istituto Bruno Leoni. ([email protected]) Carlo Stagnaro is Director, Research and Studies at Istituto Bruno Leoni ([email protected]) IBL is grateful to GAS INTENSIVE Soc. Consortile a r.l.- Milano - for its support to this study Are Green Jobs Real Jobs? The Case of Italy — 3 1. INTRODUCTION 1.1. European policies The European Union has committed itself to increase the share of renewable energy up to 20% of the final consumption by 2020, from 9.2% in 2006 (EC 2009). The same political wave is mounting in several other countries, most notably the United States. The feeling that renew- able energy sources (RES) should cover a higher share of energy production relies on two ma- jor arguments: (a) it is assumed that reliance on fossil fuels should be reduced, both for the sake of energy security and for climate-related reasons; and (b) investing in RES will spur economic growth and, in the post-recession world, will enhance economic recovery. The goal of this paper is to deal with (b). As to (a), we will just raise two issues. The questions are the following: • Assuming that we should reduce greenhouse gases (GHGs) emissions by a given amount (as to Europe, GHGs should be reduced by 20% below 1990 levels by 2020), is it correct to define a specific target for RES? • How does this interact with the existing policies? Even these questions shall not be answered in this paper.
    [Show full text]
  • Incentivising Renewables: a European Analysis Incentivising Renewables: a European Analysis 1
    Incentivising Renewables: A European Analysis Incentivising Renewables: A European Analysis 1 s Belgium 9 t Czech Republic 11 France 13 n Germany 15 Italy 17 e t The Netherlands 19 Poland 21 n Romania 23 Spain 25 o The United Kingdom 27 c Global Renewables Group 28 Incentivising Renewables: A European Analysis New renewable generation capacity is set to increase dramatically across the EU due to commitments to produce 20% of our energy requirements from renewable sources by 2020. Whilst many Member States are taking different approaches to incentivising the deployment of renewables, common themes and barriers can be seen. This guide, drawing on expertise from across our European offices, analyses those themes and barriers and provides a brief overview of the specific mechanisms employed in Belgium, the Czech Republic, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Poland, Romania, Spain and the UK. Although increases in renewable energy generation capacity are already being 2009 Renewable Generation Capacity seen (see inset box “ 2009 Renewable In 2009, renewable energy sources accounted for 62% of new electricity Generation Capacity ”), it is clear that for generation capacity installed in the EU, comprising 17GW out of a total 27.5GW. many European countries, creating This is up from 57% in 2008, suggesting that the 2009 Renewables Directive 1 and significant additional renewable generating the financial incentives offered for renewables deployment are beginning to have capacity will be a major challenge an effect. requiring a step-change in policy, commercial and industrial capability and Wind power represented the largest of all energy sources at 37.1% in 2009, ahead of financing ingenuity.
    [Show full text]
  • Renewable Incentives: Approaching Maturity 4Th Edition
    Renewable Incentives: Approaching Maturity 4th Edition Introduction 1 Australia 10 s Belgium 12 Czech Republic 14 t France 16 Germany 18 n Italy 20 Japan 22 Korea 24 e Morocco 26 t The Netherlands 28 Poland 30 Romania 32 n Slovakia 34 Spain 36 o Thailand 38 Turkey 40 United Arab Emirates 42 c United Kingdom 44 Ukraine 46 Renewable Incentives Guide 1 June 2014-4th edition Renewable Incentives Guide: 4th edition Introduction The last few years have seen a turbulent Growth in Global Renewables Investment time for the renewable energy sector. 2013 300 figures show that global investment in renewables fell significantly in both 2012 ) and 2013. Continuing global economic n o 200 i l l i problems and uncertainty over renewable b $ policy frameworks in key countries take a S U significant share of the blame. In particular, ( 100 retroactive reductions in incentives in a number of European countries (in the solar 0 sector) have caused investors to be 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 extremely cautious about the stability of financial support mechanisms. Figures extracted from Global Trends in Renewable Energy Investment 2014 – Frankfurt School – UNEP Centre / Bloomberg New Energy Finance Interestingly, part of the reason for the declining value of investment in 2012/13 has been the reduction in technology costs, Global Renewable Electricity Capacity and Projection especially in solar and wind markets. This reduction in costs has helped deployment 3000 of renewables to continue rising despite recent falling value of investment, and 2000 deployment is projected to grow strongly at ) W least up to 2020.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding the Guarantees of Origin and Their Impacts on the Electricity Value Chain
    Norwegian School of Economics Bergen, Spring 2019 Understanding the Guarantees of Origin and their impacts on the electricity value chain A comparative case study of Norway and Germany Margaux Snoeck Supervisors: Mette H. Bjørndal, Endre Bjørndal Master thesis Major Energy, Natural Resources and the Environment MSc Economics and Business Administration NORWEGIAN SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS This thesis was written as a part of the Master of Science in Economics and Business Administration at NHH. Please note that neither the institution nor the examiners are responsible − through the approval of this thesis − for the theories and methods used, or results and conclusions drawn in this work. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to express my gratitude to my two supervisors, Mette H. Bjørndal and Endre Bjørndal of the Norwegian School of Economics for their useful comments, remarks and engagement throughout the writing process of this Master’s Thesis. I would also like to thank all the people that accepted to take part in the interviews or answered my many questions by e-mail. A particular thank you goes to: Antti Kuronen (Grexel), Christian Herforth (Umweltbundesamt), Dennis Herweg (RWE), Ivar M. Clausen (Statnett), Marine Mouilleron (Becour), Nikolai T. Iversen and David P. Zwick (ECOHZ), Paul T. Ørstavik (Kinect Energy Group), Phil Moody (AIB), Preben K. Olsen (BKK), Roland Kok (Innogy) as well as others who wished to remain anonymous. My thanks to all the close friends I made here in Norway for their encouragement and sharing this experience with me. Finally, I would like to give a warm thank you to my parents and my sister for their unwavering support from the beginning until the end of this Master’s Thesis, despite the challenges due to the geographical distance between where I was working and they were living.
    [Show full text]
  • Are Tradable Green Certificates a Cost-Efficient Policy Driving Technical Change Or a Rent-Generating Machine?
    Linköping University Post Print Are tradable green certificates a cost-efficient policy driving technical change or a rent- generating machine? Lessons from Sweden 2003-2008 Anna Bergek and Staffan Jacobsson N.B.: When citing this work, cite the original article. Original Publication: Anna Bergek and Staffan Jacobsson, Are tradable green certificates a cost-efficient policy driving technical change or a rent-generating machine? Lessons from Sweden 2003-2008, 2010, ENERGY POLICY, (38), 3, 1255-1271. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2009.11.001 Copyright: Elsevier Science B.V., Amsterdam. http://www.elsevier.com/ Postprint available at: Linköping University Electronic Press http://urn.kb.se/resolve?urn=urn:nbn:se:liu:diva-54262 Are Tradable Green Certificates a cost-efficient policy driving technical change or a rent-generating machine? Lessons from Sweden 2003-2008 The paper was originally submitted to Energy Policy 2009-06-05. This is an amended version of the revision submitted 2009-11-02. Abstract In the European policy debate, tradable green certificates (TGC) have been suggested to be a superior regulatory framework for promoting the diffusion of renewable electricity technologies. The purpose of this paper is to assess the performance of the Swedish TGC system, contributing to the European debate on the suitability of different types of frameworks. The expectations of the TGC system were that it would: a) be effective in terms of increasing the supply of “green” electricity; b) do this in a cost effective manner (from both a social and a consumer perspective); c) generate an equitable distribution of costs and benefits and d) drive technical change.
    [Show full text]