Renewable Incentives: Approaching Maturity 4Th Edition

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Load more

Renewable Incentives: Approaching Maturity 4th Edition Introduction 1 Australia 10 s Belgium 12 Czech Republic 14 t France 16 Germany 18 n Italy 20 Japan 22 Korea 24 e Morocco 26 t The Netherlands 28 Poland 30 Romania 32 n Slovakia 34 Spain 36 o Thailand 38 Turkey 40 United Arab Emirates 42 c United Kingdom 44 Ukraine 46 Renewable Incentives Guide 1 June 2014-4th edition Renewable Incentives Guide: 4th edition Introduction The last few years have seen a turbulent Growth in Global Renewables Investment time for the renewable energy sector. 2013 300 figures show that global investment in renewables fell significantly in both 2012 ) and 2013. Continuing global economic n o 200 i l l i problems and uncertainty over renewable b $ policy frameworks in key countries take a S U significant share of the blame. In particular, ( 100 retroactive reductions in incentives in a number of European countries (in the solar 0 sector) have caused investors to be 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 extremely cautious about the stability of financial support mechanisms. Figures extracted from Global Trends in Renewable Energy Investment 2014 – Frankfurt School – UNEP Centre / Bloomberg New Energy Finance Interestingly, part of the reason for the declining value of investment in 2012/13 has been the reduction in technology costs, Global Renewable Electricity Capacity and Projection especially in solar and wind markets. This reduction in costs has helped deployment 3000 of renewables to continue rising despite recent falling value of investment, and 2000 deployment is projected to grow strongly at ) W least up to 2020. In 2012, total renewable G ( electricity generation capacity hit 1579 GW, 1000 and the International Energy Agency expects renewable electricity production to be 60% of the increase in power generation 0 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 across the OECD between 2012 and 2018 (see tables inset). Figures extracted from IAE's Medium-Term Renewable Energy Market Reports 2012 and 2013 Is renewable generation becoming cost- targets will be achieved across the EU, Europe will affect national policy on effective without subsidies? In some although around half the Member States renewables, particularly in light of cases, e.g. Turkey and New Zealand, need to make increased efforts. geo -political conflict in Eastern Europe, onshore wind can compete effectively in and the desirability of reducing reliance on However, while the Commission seeks the wholesale electricity markets. However, uncertain fuel supplies. Already the UK increased carbon reductions and in the main, renewable generation capacity Government has sought to push the EU renewable targets in its new 2030 climate still needs financial subsidies to ensure to expand shale gas development to package, a number of Member States are continued growth in capacity. How does improve EU energy security. resisting binding renewables targets as this fit with achieving targets? they look to other potential medium-term This Guide, now expanded to In Europe, there are some encouraging ways of reducing emissions. These 19 countries across the world, gives a signs of progress on meeting 2020 climate include possibly using shale gas as an description of the key renewable incentive change targets. The European interim measure to take over from coal schemes in these countries, focussing Commission (the Commission) expects the capacity. It remains to be seen how the principally on electricity generation. Over 20% carbon reduction and renewables potential for a shale gas bonanza in the years, a number of different types of © Clifford Chance 2 Renewable Incentives Guide subsidy mechanism have developed. Recently, Feed-in Tariff (FIT) / Feed-in Common types of renewable incentive mechanism for Premium (FIP) schemes and, to a lesser electricity generation degree, Green Certificate-type schemes Green Certificates (or Quota obligation mechanisms) have become the pre-dominant support Green Certificate schemes operate by awarding qualifying renewable energy mechanisms. For example, REN generators with certificates equivalent to the amount of renewable energy 21 i notes that five FIT schemes alone generated. Some newer renewable energy technologies may receive a larger were adopted in Africa and the Middle number of certificates than long-established technologies, to reflect the difference in East in 2012. These are joined by a wide deployment costs. Electricity suppliers are placed under an obligation to source a range of other ways of encouraging the certain proportion of their electricity from renewables and they evidence satisfaction growth of renewable energy, including tax of their obligation by presenting Green Certificates to the regulator, which are advantages, levies and grid connection bought from renewable generators. Penalties are payable if suppliers do not meet advantages (see box inset) . their obligation. Incentive schemes each have Feed-in Tariffs (FIT) / Feed-in Premiums (FIP) advantages and disadvantages in terms FIT schemes are more numerous than Green Certificate schemes as they are of encouraging production of new easier to administer and generally provide renewable energy generators with greater capacity, ensuring flexibility faced with certainty of income. FIT schemes pay a sum of money or tariff to generators on rising or falling costs, achieving top of their electricity sales. The sum paid is often a variable amount to “top up” renewables targets, providing certainty the sales income to an agreed level. This provides a high level of price guarantee to for investors, and their impacts on the generator. electricity markets. Experience of such FIPs are a more developed form of FIT scheme, which have been adopted by a schemes in Europe has led to one of the number of countries. They often involve payment of a fixed amount, irrespective of most significant recent developments: a the electricity sales price received by the generator, but they can be variable new push by the European Commission payments which respond in some degree to fluctuations in market pricing. They to regulate the forms of financial support result in generators being still exposed to electricity market prices. for renewable electricity generation on offer in Member States. Other types of subsidy / incentive measure A wide variety of policies and support measures exist, including: Intervention by the EU Commission n Carbon pricing and taxes on fossil fuels n Tax exemptions and deductions for energy saving investments The Commission has recently taken a more interventionist approach to n Priority rights to connect renewables to the grid renewable subsidies. It has looked not n Tax-efficient loan finance for renewable investment only at whether support should be n Guaranteed purchasers through “Supplier of last resort” mechanisms provided, but also at the forms of support n Exemptions from licensing requirements or discounts in fees on offer. This responds to a number of concerns. In particular, the Commission is worried that Member States are not continuing; see recent proposals in to become more integrated over the next considering suitable alternatives (such as Romania. The renewables sector now few years. Conflict can exist not only over expanding inter-connection capacity) has significant market share and there is the level of aid that can be given to before introducing support schemes. greater recognition that incentive renewable generators but also over the Also, the lack of flexibility of schemes to schemes can have an impact on grids extent to which domestic industries can deal with changing market conditions and and system stability. They can also be protected by the rises in prices that falling costs of technology has led to the impact on competition, not only between this will cause. renewable and traditional generators, but controversial retroactive changes made to The Commission’s new intervention has also between Member States, given a a number of support schemes in recent broadly taken two forms: years. These retroactive changes are still European electricity market which is set i Renewable Energy Policy Network for the 21st Century, in their Renewables 2013 Global Status Report © Clifford Chance Renewable Incentives Guide 3 n adoption in principle of new updated opened up to energy generation Guidelines on environmental and anywhere in the EU. What is State Aid? energy aid published in April 2014 Under EU law, state aid potentially (the New Guidelines); and The Commission’s arises whenever state resources are general direction used to provide assistance and that n publication of a Communication with The Commission recognises that the assistance gives some organisations accompanying working document various forms of support mechanism have an advantage over other setting out best practice on renewable different advantages and impacts. In organisations. It will be State aid if the subsidies (Best Practice Guidance). particular, FITs / FIPs tend to protect aid is liable to distort competition in a producers better from revenue risk but do relevant market and would be The New Guidelines will be of great not provide the efficiency benefits of sufficient to affect trade between interest to developers as they set out the exposure to market pricing. Green Member States. The advantage may, parameters for when the Commission will Certificate mechanisms, on the other for example, be a grant, loan or tax consider new subsidy mechanisms as hand, introduce market exposure but can, break or the
Recommended publications
  • Implications of Tradable Green Certificates for the UK

    Implications of Tradable Green Certificates for the UK

    The Implications of Tradable Green Certificates for the UK ETSU Project Number : TGC (K/BD/00218) Contractor: SPRU Authors : Catherine Mitchell, Teresa Anderson March 2000 ii Executive Summary A Green Certificate (GC) is used to represent the ‘greenness ’ of a unit of renewable electricity. This allows the unit to be divided into two parts: the physical electricity and its associated greenness. If the two parts are regarded as distinct, they can then be traded in two separate markets: the conventional physical electricity market and the market for greenness. Within a situation where there is an imposed demand (ie an obligation) GCs serve two purposes: • they act as an accounting system to verify whether the obligation has been met • they facilitate trade which allows the obligation to be filled either by buying physical electricity with GCs or by GCs alone in the alternative tradable green certificate market (at which point they become TGCs) The UK could establish a national TGC market where only UK-generated TGCs were valid or the UK could become part of a wider trans-national market (for example, made up of EU countries) where TGCs from all EU countries are valid. A national TGC system would be easier to establish than a trans-national system. This is because a TGC has to be both accredited and standardised so that TGCs are a defined product. Within a UK national system, there is the prospect of four uses for GCs: • combined GCs & kWh used to qualify for the Climate Change Levy (CCL) exemption for large business users, but not eligible against the RE obligation (not agreed as yet by Customs and Excise or DETR); • combined GCs & kWh used to obtain the CCL rebate for small business users, (also eligible against the RE obligation); • GCs traded separately or combined with kWh which can be used against the RE obligation; • GCs traded separately or combined with kWh which are used within voluntary green power supply, which cannot be used against the RE obligation.
  • A Policymaker's Guide to Feed-In Tariff Policy Design DE-AC36-08-GO28308

    A Policymaker's Guide to Feed-In Tariff Policy Design DE-AC36-08-GO28308

    A Policymaker’s Guide to Feed-in Tariff Policy Design Toby D. Couture E3 Analytics Karlynn Cory Claire Kreycik National Renewable Energy Laboratory Emily Williams U.S. Department of State Technical Report NREL/TP-6A2-44849 July 2010 NREL is a national laboratory of the U.S. Department of Energy, Office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy, operated by the Alliance for Sustainable Energy, LLC. On the Cover Feed-in tari ff (FIT) policies can apply to several renewable energy technologies and their applications including (top to bottom) solar photovoltaics (PV) on commercial buildings (Art Institute of Chicago – Chicago, Illinois); on-site wind energy (Great Lakes Science Center – Cleveland, Ohio); rooftop PV on residences (Glastonbury, Connecticut); solar power tower (Solar One –Barstow, California); and dry-steam geothermal plant (The Geysers – Calistoga, California). Cover Photo Credits – (background) Oberlin College, Ohio - PIX#10861 and (top to bottom) PIX#13789, PIX#14827, PIX#15679, PIX#00036, PIX#01045. Acknowledgments This work was funded by the U.S. Department of Energy’s (DOE) Solar Energy Technologies Program. The authors want to thank participating DOE staff – Charles Hemmeline and Jennifer DeCesaro – for providing useful insights and overall direction to this project. The authors are also grateful for the guidance and helpful input of the project manager, Robert Margolis of the National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL). We would also like to thank David Kline (NREL), Professor Volkmar Lauber of the University of Salzburg (Austria), and Wilson Rickerson from Meister Consultants Group for their detailed and thoughtful comments on early drafts of the report, and for providing their valuable insights and expertise.
  • Taxes and Incentives for Renewable Energy

    Taxes and Incentives for Renewable Energy

    Taxes and incentives for renewable energy KPMG International kpmg.com/energytax Taxes and Incentives for Renewable Energy is designed to help energy companies, investors and other entities stay current with government policies and programs that support renewable energy from wind, solar, biomass, geothermal and hydropower. Compiled by KPMG’s Global Energy & Natural Resources tax practice, the 2015 edition provides updates on renewable energy promotion policies for 31 countries. It also includes information on adoption trends for renewables, the growing prominence of emerging markets, new solar and wind initiatives, and key investments in renewable energy around the world. Lars Behrendt Tax Partner, KPMG in Germany © 2015 KPMG International Cooperative (“KPMG International”). KPMG International provides no client services and is a Swiss entity with which the independent member firms of the KPMG network are affiliated. Contents Introduction 2 2015 industry trends 4 Global investment in renewable energy production 6 Renewable energy promotion policies by country 10 Argentina 12 Australia 13 Austria 15 Belgium 16 Brazil 17 Canada 19 China 22 Costa Rica 25 France 27 Germany 30 Greece 34 India 38 Ireland 40 Italy 42 Japan 44 Mexico 45 The Netherlands 47 New Zealand 48 Norway 49 Peru 51 Philippines 52 Poland 56 Romania 59 South Africa 61 South Korea 63 Spain 65 Sweden 67 Turkey 68 United Kingdom 69 United States 73 Uruguay 75 Top Five Countries 2014 77 Appendix A: REN21 2014 Renewable Global Status Report 78 © 2015 KPMG International Cooperative (“KPMG International”). KPMG International provides no client services and is a Swiss entity with which the independent member firms of the KPMG network are affiliated.
  • Green Certificate Trading

    Green Certificate Trading

    Journal of Energy in Southern Africa 22(1): 42–54 DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.17159/2413-3051/2011/v22i1a3201 Green certificate trading Kerri Brick Environmental Policy Research Unit, University of Cape Town Martine Visser School of Economics, University of Cape Town Abstract on Climate Change (UNFCCC), which was opened Policies to promote renewable electricity are for signature in 1992. ‘The primary objective of the increasingly seen as a way to reduce the negative UNFCCC is to achieve stabilisation of the concen- environmental impacts associated with electricity trations of GHG in the atmosphere at a level that consumption and meet growing electricity demand. would prevent dangerous anthropogenic interfer- This paper reviews the international experience ence with the climate system’ (UNFCCC, 1992). As with one such policy, namely, renewable energy cer- South Africa ratified the UNFCCC in 1997, the tificates, and considers important design aspects of country is entitled to apply for financial assistance a national green certificate system. Within a South from the Global Environmental Facility for climate African context, a green certificate system would change related activities. provide a mechanism with which to verify compli- The Kyoto Protocol,1 a legal instrument under ance with any future renewable energy obligations, the framework of the Convention, sets binding tar- and would encourage renewable electricity genera- gets under which industrialised (Annex I) countries tion in the current monopoly environment. In terms must reduce greenhouse gas emissions by an aver- of a national green certificate framework, interna- age of five percent against 1990 levels over the peri- tional experience has shown that renewable energy od 2008-2012 (UNFCCC, 1997).
  • Energy Attributes Certificates: a Novel Mechanism to Support Energy Transition in Lebanon

    Energy Attributes Certificates: a Novel Mechanism to Support Energy Transition in Lebanon

    AMERICAN UNIVERSITY OF BEIRUT ENERGY ATTRIBUTES CERTIFICATES: A NOVEL MECHANISM TO SUPPORT ENERGY TRANSITION IN LEBANON by NOURA NABIL LAYSSI STOUHI A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Sciences to the Department of Mechanical Engineering of the Maroun Semaan Faculty of Engineering and Architecture at the American University of Beirut Beirut, Lebanon June 2020 AMERICAN UNIVERSITY OF BEIRUT ENERGY ATTRIBUTES CERTIFICATES: A NOVEL MECHANISM TO SUPPORT ENERGY TRANSITION IN LEBANON by NOURA NABIL LAYSSI STOUHI Approved by: Dr. Nesreene Ghaddar, Professor Maroon Semaan Faculty of Engineering and Architecture Advisor Dr. Hassan Harajli, Lecturer Department of Environmental Health Co-Advisor Dr. Karim Makdisi, Associate Professor Department of Political Studies and Public Administration Member of Committee Dr. Ibrahim Alameddine, Assistant Professor Department of Civil and Environmental Engineering Member of Committee Date of thesis/dissertation defense: [June 18, 2020] AMERICAN UNIVERSITY OF BEIRUT THESIS, DISSERTATION, PROJECT RELEASE FORM Student Name: Layssi Stouhi _________________Noura _________________________ Last First Middle I authorize the American University of Beirut to: (a) reproduce hard or electronic copies of my thesis, dissertation, or project; (b) include such copies in the archives and digital repositories of the University; and (c) make freely available such copies to third parties for research or educational purposes. I authorize the American University of Beirut, to: (a) reproduce hard or electronic copies of it; (b) include such copies in the archives and digital repositories of the University; and (c) make freely available such copies to third parties for research or educational purposes after : One ---- year from the date of submission of my thesis, dissertation, or project.
  • CLIMATE CHANGE – Impact on Energy Regulation and Infrastructure

    CLIMATE CHANGE – Impact on Energy Regulation and Infrastructure

    Background paper for the 7th US-EU Energy Regulators Round Table, Session IV: Climate change Mrs. Yvonne Fredriksson, Director General Energy Markets Inspectorate, Sweden CLIMATE CHANGE – Impact on energy regulation and infrastructure Introduction The present paper presents some of the challenges to infrastructure and raises some of the problems for energy regulators resulting from measures aimed at meeting political environmental targets. The paper discusses possible solutions, with examples from the European Union (EU) but which could also be applicable to the US. The impact on the regulator and on network investment can vary depending on the type of promotion system for renewables chosen by countries - market-based or state aid-based. The areas discussed are: • The role of the regulator in meeting environmental goals • The need to promote reserve generation • Promotion of renewables from a market perspective • The impact of renewables on energy regulation and on network investment The role of the regulator for meeting environmental goals The national energy regulator must set its goals and develop its activities, while also complying with the environmental goals the government/politicians have set up, including e.g. quantitative targets regarding energy efficiency, and establishing rules which are instrumental to promoting the generation of power from renewable sources. In general terms, the role of the energy regulator in helping to meet environmental goals is primarily to contribute to efficient energy markets, which means: • ensuring the reliability and quality of energy supply • promoting energy efficiency • safeguarding consumer interests 1 • guaranteeing access to the infrastructure (networks) for all suppliers (and even giving priority to renewable energy producers) At European level, the EU Directives – based on political priorities - constitute the legal framework within which the national authorities must ensure that citizens and industries are getting fair, competitive energy prices, through efficient energy markets.
  • Are Green Jobs Real Jobs? the Case of Italy

    Are Green Jobs Real Jobs? the Case of Italy

    Are Green Jobs Real Jobs? The Case of Italy Istituto Bruno Leoni May 2010 Luciano Lavecchia Carlo Stagnaro 2 — Luciano Lavecchia – Carlo Stagnaro Luciano Lavecchia (Palermo 1985) is Fellow of Istituto Bruno Leoni. ([email protected]) Carlo Stagnaro is Director, Research and Studies at Istituto Bruno Leoni ([email protected]) IBL is grateful to GAS INTENSIVE Soc. Consortile a r.l.- Milano - for its support to this study Are Green Jobs Real Jobs? The Case of Italy — 3 1. INTRODUCTION 1.1. European policies The European Union has committed itself to increase the share of renewable energy up to 20% of the final consumption by 2020, from 9.2% in 2006 (EC 2009). The same political wave is mounting in several other countries, most notably the United States. The feeling that renew- able energy sources (RES) should cover a higher share of energy production relies on two ma- jor arguments: (a) it is assumed that reliance on fossil fuels should be reduced, both for the sake of energy security and for climate-related reasons; and (b) investing in RES will spur economic growth and, in the post-recession world, will enhance economic recovery. The goal of this paper is to deal with (b). As to (a), we will just raise two issues. The questions are the following: • Assuming that we should reduce greenhouse gases (GHGs) emissions by a given amount (as to Europe, GHGs should be reduced by 20% below 1990 levels by 2020), is it correct to define a specific target for RES? • How does this interact with the existing policies? Even these questions shall not be answered in this paper.
  • Incentivising Renewables: a European Analysis Incentivising Renewables: a European Analysis 1

    Incentivising Renewables: a European Analysis Incentivising Renewables: a European Analysis 1

    Incentivising Renewables: A European Analysis Incentivising Renewables: A European Analysis 1 s Belgium 9 t Czech Republic 11 France 13 n Germany 15 Italy 17 e t The Netherlands 19 Poland 21 n Romania 23 Spain 25 o The United Kingdom 27 c Global Renewables Group 28 Incentivising Renewables: A European Analysis New renewable generation capacity is set to increase dramatically across the EU due to commitments to produce 20% of our energy requirements from renewable sources by 2020. Whilst many Member States are taking different approaches to incentivising the deployment of renewables, common themes and barriers can be seen. This guide, drawing on expertise from across our European offices, analyses those themes and barriers and provides a brief overview of the specific mechanisms employed in Belgium, the Czech Republic, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Poland, Romania, Spain and the UK. Although increases in renewable energy generation capacity are already being 2009 Renewable Generation Capacity seen (see inset box “ 2009 Renewable In 2009, renewable energy sources accounted for 62% of new electricity Generation Capacity ”), it is clear that for generation capacity installed in the EU, comprising 17GW out of a total 27.5GW. many European countries, creating This is up from 57% in 2008, suggesting that the 2009 Renewables Directive 1 and significant additional renewable generating the financial incentives offered for renewables deployment are beginning to have capacity will be a major challenge an effect. requiring a step-change in policy, commercial and industrial capability and Wind power represented the largest of all energy sources at 37.1% in 2009, ahead of financing ingenuity.
  • Understanding the Guarantees of Origin and Their Impacts on the Electricity Value Chain

    Understanding the Guarantees of Origin and Their Impacts on the Electricity Value Chain

    Norwegian School of Economics Bergen, Spring 2019 Understanding the Guarantees of Origin and their impacts on the electricity value chain A comparative case study of Norway and Germany Margaux Snoeck Supervisors: Mette H. Bjørndal, Endre Bjørndal Master thesis Major Energy, Natural Resources and the Environment MSc Economics and Business Administration NORWEGIAN SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS This thesis was written as a part of the Master of Science in Economics and Business Administration at NHH. Please note that neither the institution nor the examiners are responsible − through the approval of this thesis − for the theories and methods used, or results and conclusions drawn in this work. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to express my gratitude to my two supervisors, Mette H. Bjørndal and Endre Bjørndal of the Norwegian School of Economics for their useful comments, remarks and engagement throughout the writing process of this Master’s Thesis. I would also like to thank all the people that accepted to take part in the interviews or answered my many questions by e-mail. A particular thank you goes to: Antti Kuronen (Grexel), Christian Herforth (Umweltbundesamt), Dennis Herweg (RWE), Ivar M. Clausen (Statnett), Marine Mouilleron (Becour), Nikolai T. Iversen and David P. Zwick (ECOHZ), Paul T. Ørstavik (Kinect Energy Group), Phil Moody (AIB), Preben K. Olsen (BKK), Roland Kok (Innogy) as well as others who wished to remain anonymous. My thanks to all the close friends I made here in Norway for their encouragement and sharing this experience with me. Finally, I would like to give a warm thank you to my parents and my sister for their unwavering support from the beginning until the end of this Master’s Thesis, despite the challenges due to the geographical distance between where I was working and they were living.
  • Are Tradable Green Certificates a Cost-Efficient Policy Driving Technical Change Or a Rent-Generating Machine?

    Are Tradable Green Certificates a Cost-Efficient Policy Driving Technical Change Or a Rent-Generating Machine?

    Linköping University Post Print Are tradable green certificates a cost-efficient policy driving technical change or a rent- generating machine? Lessons from Sweden 2003-2008 Anna Bergek and Staffan Jacobsson N.B.: When citing this work, cite the original article. Original Publication: Anna Bergek and Staffan Jacobsson, Are tradable green certificates a cost-efficient policy driving technical change or a rent-generating machine? Lessons from Sweden 2003-2008, 2010, ENERGY POLICY, (38), 3, 1255-1271. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2009.11.001 Copyright: Elsevier Science B.V., Amsterdam. http://www.elsevier.com/ Postprint available at: Linköping University Electronic Press http://urn.kb.se/resolve?urn=urn:nbn:se:liu:diva-54262 Are Tradable Green Certificates a cost-efficient policy driving technical change or a rent-generating machine? Lessons from Sweden 2003-2008 The paper was originally submitted to Energy Policy 2009-06-05. This is an amended version of the revision submitted 2009-11-02. Abstract In the European policy debate, tradable green certificates (TGC) have been suggested to be a superior regulatory framework for promoting the diffusion of renewable electricity technologies. The purpose of this paper is to assess the performance of the Swedish TGC system, contributing to the European debate on the suitability of different types of frameworks. The expectations of the TGC system were that it would: a) be effective in terms of increasing the supply of “green” electricity; b) do this in a cost effective manner (from both a social and a consumer perspective); c) generate an equitable distribution of costs and benefits and d) drive technical change.