The Medieval Theories of the Just Price: Romanists, Canonists, and Theologians in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries Author(S): John W

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Medieval Theories of the Just Price: Romanists, Canonists, and Theologians in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries Author(S): John W The Medieval Theories of the Just Price: Romanists, Canonists, and Theologians in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries Author(s): John W. Baldwin Source: Transactions of the American Philosophical Society, New Series, Vol. 49, No. 4 (1959), pp. 1-92 Published by: American Philosophical Society Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1005819 Accessed: 18-04-2018 18:45 UTC REFERENCES Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1005819?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://about.jstor.org/terms American Philosophical Society is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Transactions of the American Philosophical Society This content downloaded from 128.196.130.121 on Wed, 18 Apr 2018 18:45:35 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms TRANSACTIONS OF THE AMERICAN PHILOSOPHICAL SOCIETY HELD AT PHILADELPHIA FOR PROMOTING USEFUL KNOWLEDGE NEW SERIES-VOLUME 49, PART 4 1959 THE MEDIEVAL THEORIES OF THE JUST PRICE Romanists, Canonists, and Theologians in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries JOHN W. BALDWIN Department of History, University of Michigan THE AMERICAN PHILOSOPHICAL SOCIETY INDEPENDENCE SQUARE PHILADELPHIA 6 JULY, 1959 This content downloaded from 128.196.130.121 on Wed, 18 Apr 2018 18:45:35 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms J. M. J. MARGARITAE PRETIOSAE D. D. D. Copyright ? 1959 by The American Philosophical Society Library of Congress Catalog Card No. 59- 13420 This content downloaded from 128.196.130.121 on Wed, 18 Apr 2018 18:45:35 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms PREFACE We are like "puny dwarfs perched on the shoulders made more fruitful and pleasant through the kindness of giants. We see more and farther than our and assistance of Mlle d'Alverny and Mme Rambaud- predecessors, not because we have keener vision or Buhot of the Bibliotheque Nationale. greater height, but because we are lifted up and borne The major research for this study was made possible aloft on their gigantic stature." This metaphor of through the Fulbright program effectively administered Bernard of Chartres preserved by John of Salisbury by the Commission Franco-Americaine d'Pgchanges was a commonplace in the twelfth century, yet to a Universitaires. Later opportunity to verify manuscript present-day beginner in medieval studies it remains sources in France was provided by a grant from the strikingly appropriate. My reliance on the works of Faculty Research Fund of the Horace H. Rackham others is apparent from the footnotes and bibliography, School of Graduate Studies, the University of Michigan. but here it is also appropriate to acknowledge my many Finally, I am indebted to the American Philosophical personal obligations. Society for undertaking the publication. In America I benefited from the interest and help Because of the high cost of printing foreign languages of four distinguished medievalists who consented to in this country I have felt it wise to limit the amount read the manuscript in entirety and to offer criticism of Latin texts in the footnotes to a minimum. There- from their particular fields of interest. If I have fore, the Latin quotations derived from printed editions, fallen into error, it is only because I have not heeded both early and recent, have been eliminated with two their warnings. Professor Stephan Kuttner of the occasional exceptions: first, texts of which precise Catholic University of America advised me on matters grammatical phrasings were essential to my analysis, of medieval Roman and Canon law, a field in which and second, texts derived from early printed editions his authority can hardly be surpassed. Professor Fred- virtually impossible to obtain anywhere in this country. eric C. Lane of the Johns Hopkins University and Latin quotations excerpted from unedited manuscripts, Professor Raymond de Roover of Boston College con- however, have been printed in full. These last quo- tributed from their extensive knowledge of medieval tations do not attempt to provide critical editions of the economic practice. To Professor Sidney Painter of passages because of the great number of treatises in- the Johns Hopkins University I owe my introduction volved. Of some treatises I have had access to only to and formation in medieval studies, and I wish to one manuscript. Of others I have consulted all of the express my special gratitude for his constant aid and manuscripts available in Paris, and constructed a text counsel throughout this project. based on the two best ones. In these references the In Paris I profited from the friendly advice of M. Gabriel LeBras, Professor at the Faculte de Droit; two manuscripts have been cited, but the actual passage Abbe Louis Guizard, Professor at the Institut Catho- printed represents the combined reading that makes the lique; Msgr. Charles Lefebvre, now of the Sacra best sense. A full list of the manuscripts employed Romana Rota; M. Pierre Legendre, now Professor at in this study may be found in the bibliography. the Faculte de Droit, Universite de Lille; and Mr. J. W. B. Clemens Heller of the Centre de Recherches His- Ann Arbor, Michigan toriques. Especially were my labors in the manuscripts 31 October, 1958 3 This content downloaded from 128.196.130.121 on Wed, 18 Apr 2018 18:45:35 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms ABBREVIATIONS AND EXAMPLES OF CITATIONS C.-Code of Justinian. M.G.H.-Monumenta Germaniae historica, edidit So- Source: Corpus iuris civilis, Vol. II, P. Krueger, ed. cietas aperiendis fontibus rerum Germanicarum medii Berlin, Weidmann, 1914. aevi. Example: C. 4, 44, 10-Liber 4, Titulus 44, Lex 10. Nov.-Novellae of Justinian. (pr.-principium and par.-paragraph). Source: Corpus iuris civilis, Vol. III, W. Kroll, ed., Causa-Causa in Pars secunda of Gratian's Decretum. Berlin, Weidmann, 1912. Source: Corpus iuris canonici, Vol. I, A. Friedberg, Example: Nov. 120, c. 9-Novella 120, Capitulum 9. ed., Leipzig, 1879. (pr.-principium and par.-paragraph). Example: Causa XIV, q. 3, c. 4, Usura-Pars Paris Bibl. Nat. Lat.-Manuscript from Paris. secunda, Causa 14, Questio 3, Canon 4, Incipit Bibliotheque Nationale, Fonds Latin. Usura. Paris Mazar.-Manuscript from Paris, Bibliotheque Comp.-Compilatio antiqua. Mazarine. Source: Quinque compilationes antiquae, A. Fried- P.G.-Patrologiae . series Graeca, 166v. J. P. berg, ed., Leipzig, 1882. Migne, ed., Paris, 1857-1866. Example: Comp. I: III, 15, c. 4, Quum dilecti- P.L.-Patrologiae . series Latina, 221v. J. P. Compilatio antiqua I, Liber 3, Titulus 15, Canon Migne, ed., Paris, 1844-1865. 4, Incipit Quum dilecti. Thomas, Sum. theo.-Thomas Aquinas, Summa theo- C.Th.-Theodosian Code. logica. Source: Theodosiani libri XVI, 2 v. T. Mommsen Source: Opera omnia, 25v. Parma, 1852-1873, re- and P. Meyer, ed., Berlin, Weidmann, 1905. Example: C.Th. 3, 1, 1-Liber 3, Titulus 1, Lex 1. printed at New York, Musurgia, 1948-1950. Abbreviations: D.-Digest of Justinian. I, II-Pars prima-secundae. Source: Corpus iuris civilis, Vol. I, T. Mommsen II, II-Pars secunda-secundae. and P. Krueger, ed., Berlin, Weidmann, 1920. Example: D. 47, 11, 6-Liber 47, Titulus 11, Lex qu.-Quaestio. a.-Articulus. 6. (pr.-principium and par.-paragraph). obj.-Objectum. De poen.-De poenitentia of Quaestio III, Causa resp.-Respondeo. XXXIII of Pars secunda of Gratian's Decretum. ad-Argumentum ad objectum. Source: Corpus iuris canonici, Vol. I, A. Friedberg, Example: Thomas, Sum. theo. II, II, qu. 77, a. 1, ad ed., Leipzig, 1879. 1-Pars secunda-secundae, Quaestio 77, Articulus Example: De poen. V, c. 2, Qualitas-Distinctio 5, 1, Argumentum ad primum objectum. Canon 2, Incipit Qualitas. Di.-Distinctio in pars prima of Gratian's Decretum. X-Decretales of Gregory IX. Source: Corpus iuris canonici, Vol. II, A. Friedberg, Source: Corpus iuris canonici, Vol. I, A. Friedberg, ed., Leipzig, 1881. ed., Leipzig, 1879. Example: Di. XLVII, c. 2, Quoniamn-Pars prima, Example: X: V, 32, c. 1, Intelleximus-Liber 5, Titulus 32, Canon 1, Incipit Intelleximus. Distinctio 47, Canon 2, Incipit Quoniam. Inst.-Institutes of Justinian. An example of citation in the glosses and apparatus Source: Corpus iuris civilis, Vol. I, P. Krueger, ed., to legal material: Accursius, Glossa ordinaria to Berlin, Weidmann, 1920. elegerit: C. 4, 44, 2.-The gloss of Accursius to the Example: Inst. 3, 23-Liber 3, Titulus 23. (pr.- word elegerit in the Code of Justinian, Liber 4, principium and par.-paragraph). Titulus 44, Lex 2. 4 This content downloaded from 128.196.130.121 on Wed, 18 Apr 2018 18:45:35 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms THE MEDIEVAL THEORIES OF THE JUST PRICE Romanists, Canonists, and Theologians in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries JOHN W. BALDWIN CONTENTS PAGE PAGE Introduction ........................................... 5 5. The Theologians (Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries) .. 58 1. The Legacy of Antiquity ............................ 10 I. The Synthesis of Justice ........................ 58 I. Aristotle-A Theory of Exchange ................ 10 II. The Justification of the Merchant ................ 63 II. The Church Fathers-Misgivings about the Mer- III. The Problem of Fraud ........................... 67 chant ............................. 12 IV. The Doctrine of the Just Price according to the III. Ancient Roman Law-A Legal System of Sale .. 16 Theologians ................................... 68 A. The Doctrine before Thomas Aquinas ........ 68 2.
Recommended publications
  • The End of Economics, Or, Is
    THE END OF ECONOMICS, OR, IS UTILITARIANISM FINISHED? By John D. Mueller James Madison Program Fellow Fellow of The Lehrman Institute President, LBMC LLC Princeton University, 127 Corwin Hall, 15 April 2002 Summary. According to Lionel Robbins’ classic definition, “Economics is the science which studies human behavior as a relationship between ends and scarce means that have alternate uses.” Yet most modern economists assume that economic choice involves only the means and not to the ends of human action. The reason seems to be that most modern economists are ignorant of the history of their own discipline before Adam Smith or Jeremy Bentham. Leading economists like Gary Becker attempt to explain all human behavior, including love and hate, as a maximization of “utility.” But historically and logically, an adequate description of economic choice has always required both a ranking of persons as ends and a ranking of scarce goods as means. What is missing from modern economics is an adequate description of the ranking of persons as ends. This is reflected in the absence of a satisfactory microeconomic explanation (for example, within the household) as to how goods are distributed to their final users, and in an overemphasis at the political level on an “individualistic social welfare function,” by which policymakers are purported to add up the preferences of a society of selfish individuals and determine all distribution from the government downwards, as if the nation or the world were one large household. As this “hole” in economic theory is recognized, an army of “neo-scholastic” economists will find full employment for the first few decades of the 21st Century, busily rewriting the Utilitarian “economic approach to human behavior” that dominated the last three decades of the 20th Century.
    [Show full text]
  • Last of the Schoolmen Natural Law and Social Justice in Karl Marx
    chapter 8 Last of the Schoolmen Natural Law and Social Justice in Karl Marx George E. McCarthy In this essay, we will examine the influence of natural law theory on the early and later writings of Karl Marx in order to show the continuity between his nineteenth-century critical social theory and the classical and medieval tradi- tions. In his 1926 work, Religion and the Rise of Capitalism, Richard Tawney wrote in a relatively obscure and largely forgotten comment that Marx was the “last of the Schoolmen,”1 that is, last of the medieval natural law theorists fol- lowing in the footsteps from the twelfth to the fourteenth century of Pierre 1 Richard Tawney, Religion and the Rise of Capitalism (London: J. Murray, 1927). By character- izing Marx as the “last of the Schoolmen,” Tawney was referring to Thomas Aquinas’ labor theory of value and the continuity of traditions between Marx and neo-Aristotelian medieval Scholasticism. Tawney argued that Marx was the end of a long tradition of theorists that included the 13th-century theologian Thomas Aquinas, the 14th-century scholastic Henry of Langenstein, and the 16th-century Protestant reformer Martin Luther who made the point that the appropriate and “reasonable remuneration” of wages for a worker or merchant should be based on their labor and contribution to the common good. “The medieval theorist condemned as a sin precisely that effort to achieve a continuous and unlimited increase in material wealth which modern societies applaud as a quality, and the vices for which he reserved his most merciless denunciations were the more refined and subtle of the economic virtues” (pp.
    [Show full text]
  • Annotated Guide to Secondary Literature on Medieval
    THE UNIVERSITY OF VIRGINIA DEPARTMENT OF HISTORY HIEU 390 Constantin Fasolt Fall 1999 TU TH 11:00-12:15 POLITICS, SOCIETY, AND SOCIAL THOUGHT IN EUROPE I: 400-1300 A GUIDE TO READING This guide is designed to explain my choice of readings for this course and to lead you to further readings appropriate for you, depending on how much or how little you already know about European history in general and the history of European political thought in particular. It is divided into three parts. The first part deals with general works, background information, and introductory readings of various sorts. The second part is arranged, roughly speaking, according to the topics that will be addressed in the course. The third part is a reference section, in which I simply list the most important books and articles and offer a few comments on some of them. I wrote this guide mostly for beginners. I have therefore placed special emphasis on introductory works and have tried to limit myself to works in English. But where it seemed useful or necessary I have not hesitated to mention works written in other languages. I have also made a special effort to single out books and articles that have struck me as especially telling or informative, never mind how difficult or advanced they may be. I hope that this procedure will make it easy for you to start reading where it will be most profitable for you, and to keep reading for a long time to come once your interest has been awakened. Table of Contents Part one: General works __________________________________________________ 3 A.
    [Show full text]
  • The Mendicant Preachers and the Merchant's Soul
    MARK HANSSEN THE MENDICANT PREACHERS AND THE MERCHANT'S SOUL THE CIVILIZATION OF COMMERCE IN THE LATE- MIDDLE AGES AND RENAISSANCE ITALY (1275-1425) Tesis doctoral dirigida por PROF. DR. MIGUEL ALFONSO MARTÍNEZ-ECHEVARRÍA Y ORTEGA PROF. DR. ANTONIO MORENO ALMÁRCEGUI FACULTAD DE CIENCIAS ECONÓMICAS Y EMPRESARIALES PAMPLONA, 2014 Table of contents Prologue .......................................................................................................... 7 PART I: BACKGROUND Chapter 1: Introduction The Merchant in the Wilderness ............................. 27 1. Economic Autarky and Carolingian Political "Augustinianism" ........................ 27 2. The Commercial Revolution ................................................................................ 39 3. Eschatology and Civilization ............................................................................... 54 4. Plan of the Work .................................................................................................. 66 Chapter 2: Theology and Civilization ........................................................... 73 1. Theology and Humanism ..................................................................................... 73 2. Christianity and Classical Culture ...................................................................... 83 3. Justice, Commerce and Political Society............................................................. 95 PART II: SCHOLASTIC PHILOSOPHICAL-THEOLOGY, ETHICS AND POLITICAL PHILOSOPHY Introduction................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Christian History & Biography
    Issue 73: Thomas Aquinas: Greatest Medieval Theologian Thomas Aquinas: Did You Know? Interesting and unusual fact about Thomas Aquinas editors Trounced In a detail from Andrea di Bonaiuto's fourteenth-century fresco The Triumph of Saint Thomas Aquinas, heretics Averroes and Arius crouch beneath the enthroned Aquinas. Averroes (also called Ibn Rushd; 1126-1198) was a Muslim philosopher who, according to Aquinas, made a hash of Aristotle and led many medieval Christians astray. Arius (c. 250-c. 336) denied Christ's full divinity by positing that "there was [a time] when the son was not." Aquinas participated in no physical crusades against heresy, but he did believe that heretics "deserve not only to be separated from the Church by excommunication, but also to be severed from the world by death." Fancy meeting you here Aquinas and several of his enemies make appearances in James Joyce's daunting 1922 novel Ulysses. In chapter one, a character is asked for his views on Hamlet but replies, "I'm not equal to Thomas Aquinas and the fiftyfive reasons he has made to prop it up. Wait till I have a few pints in me first." Arius, Sabellius (the third heretic at Aquinas's feet in The Triumph), Averroes, and Moses Maimonides (see page 37) pop up as well. Heeding the call Franciscans in Assisi will soon enjoy a new feature in their habits: cell phone pockets. Some critics consider the innovation inappropriate, but Elisabetta Biancheri, who designed the habits, said, "It is simply a functional item of clothing. Even monks make phone calls." Biancheri is right about the phones, but she shouldn't call Franciscans "monks"—they're friars, and, as Thomas well knew, there is a difference (see page 23).
    [Show full text]
  • Book Review. Ex Nihilo Nihil
    Maurer School of Law: Indiana University Digital Repository @ Maurer Law Articles by Maurer Faculty Faculty Scholarship 1974 Book Review. Ex Nihilo Nihil Morris S. Arnold Indiana University School of Law - Bloomington Follow this and additional works at: https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/facpub Part of the Common Law Commons, European Law Commons, and the Legal History Commons Recommended Citation Arnold, Morris S., "Book Review. Ex Nihilo Nihil" (1974). Articles by Maurer Faculty. 1150. https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/facpub/1150 This Book Review is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Articles by Maurer Faculty by an authorized administrator of Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Book Reviews Ex Nihilo Nihil The Birth of the English Common Law. By R. C. Van Caenegem. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973. Pp. vii, 160. $8.50. Reviewed by Morris S. Arnoldt Royal justice was rarely invoked in England at the beginning of the twelfth century, but, as many medievalists have recently noted, during the course of the century it became generally available to litigants and was more or less commonly sought in lieu of feudal or seignorial jus- tice.' This remarkable and indisputable development is apparent from even a cursory comparison of the Leges Henrici Primi (circa 1115)2 with Glanvill's Tractatus de Legibus (circa 1188). 3 Yet the exact steps in this process, and more important, the theories of government that made the change possible, have been the subject of much debate.
    [Show full text]
  • Book Reviews
    Book Reviews Ex Nihilo Nihil The Birth of the English Common Law. By R. C. Van Caenegem. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973. Pp. vii, 160. $8.50. Reviewed by Morris S. Arnoldt Royal justice was rarely invoked in England at the beginning of the twelfth century, but, as many medievalists have recently noted, during the course of the century it became generally available to litigants and was more or less commonly sought in lieu of feudal or seignorial jus- tice.' This remarkable and indisputable development is apparent from even a cursory comparison of the Leges Henrici Primi (circa 1115)2 with Glanvill's Tractatus de Legibus (circa 1188). 3 Yet the exact steps in this process, and more important, the theories of government that made the change possible, have been the subject of much debate. The work of Professor Van Caenegem has been conspicuous in this debate, and his present book, as its author notes, is in the main an abridged recapitulation of the views expressed at much greater length in his Royal Writs in England from the Conquest to Glanvill.4 It is good to have those ideas in the more succinct and accessible form in which they are now presented.5 The gradual displacement of local courts by central royal justice was once seen in terms of a jurisdictional battle between a grasping and usurping central government and a local nobility less than willing to surrender judicial power. Magna Carta, clause 34-which prohibits + Assistant Professor of Law, Indiana University School of Law, Bloomington. 1. The primary contributions are H.
    [Show full text]
  • [Introduction] Toward an Anthropology of the Just Price: History, Ethnography, Critique
    [Introduction] Toward an anthropology of the just price: history, ethnography, critique Article (Accepted Version) Luetchford, Peter and Orlando, Giovanni (2019) [Introduction] Toward an anthropology of the just price: history, ethnography, critique. Research in Economic Anthropology, 39. pp. 1-25. ISSN 0190-1281 This version is available from Sussex Research Online: http://sro.sussex.ac.uk/id/eprint/78700/ This document is made available in accordance with publisher policies and may differ from the published version or from the version of record. If you wish to cite this item you are advised to consult the publisher’s version. Please see the URL above for details on accessing the published version. Copyright and reuse: Sussex Research Online is a digital repository of the research output of the University. Copyright and all moral rights to the version of the paper presented here belong to the individual author(s) and/or other copyright owners. To the extent reasonable and practicable, the material made available in SRO has been checked for eligibility before being made available. Copies of full text items generally can be reproduced, displayed or performed and given to third parties in any format or medium for personal research or study, educational, or not-for-profit purposes without prior permission or charge, provided that the authors, title and full bibliographic details are credited, a hyperlink and/or URL is given for the original metadata page and the content is not changed in any way. http://sro.sussex.ac.uk INTRODUCTION TOWARD AN ANTHROPOLOGY OF THE JUST PRICE: HISTORY, ETHNOGRAPHY, CRITIQUE Peter Luetchford and Giovanni Orlando Introduction Two elements of contemporary life, price and justice, are central to this Volume.
    [Show full text]
  • Ruskin and Political Economy
    Donald Winch Ruskin and Political Economy Since I was educated originally as an economist, and have spent a number of years writing the history of what Ruskin came to regard as ‘the most cretinous, speechless, paralysing plague that has yet touched the brains of mankind’, you will sense my discomfort in speaking about his relationship with political economy on this celebratory occasion, surrounded by a distinguished gathering of Ruskinians.1 What I have to say, however, depends as much on my longer second occupation as a practitioner of intellectual history as it does on my fading knowledge of economists’ ways of thinking. Intellectual history requires a measure of generosity towards past thinkers, even an enjoyment of their quiddities. But approaching Ruskin’s views on political economy without prejudice requires an effort. For example, I cannot recognise the author of the Wealth of Nations, still less the author of the Theory of Moral Sentiments, in Ruskin’s description of Adam Smith as that ‘half-bred and half-witted Scotchman’ who had taught the ‘deliberate blasphemy’ that ‘thou shalt hate the Lord thy God, damn His laws, and covet thy neighbour’s goods’.2 Nor can I recognise John Stuart Mill in the hypercritical remarks that pepper Ruskin’s writings and correspondence. Supposing it to be true that Mill genuinely was ‘a poor cretinous wretch’ whose opinions on political economy were as false as Ruskin believed them to be, I still cannot believe that Mill was literally ‘the root of nearly all immediate evil among us in England’? 3 No doubt some of these pronouncements can be excused as rhetoric – in a post-modern world most things can.
    [Show full text]
  • BEYOND COMMUTATIVE JUSTICE: CONTRACT LAW, JUSTICE, and JUST PRICES1* Más Allá De La Justicia Conmutativa: Derecho De Contratos, Justicia Y Precios Justos
    LATIN AMERICAN LEGAL STUDIES Volume 7 (2020), pp. 363 - 3 2090 BEYOND COMMUTATIVE JUSTICE: CONTRACT LAW, JUSTICE, AND JUST PRICES1* Más allá de la Justicia Conmutativa: Derecho de Contratos, Justicia y Precios Justos Joaquín Reyes Barros2** Abstract: In this paper I evaluate James Gordley’s account of the just price as the price that preserves commutative justice. After raising some objections to this approach, I suggest that focusing on the institu- tional nature of prices, rejecting the value monism implicit in the standard account of the just price and allowing for the possibility of a pluralist approach to price justification can contribute to moving just price theory forward. Keywords: Commutative Justice; Just Price; Equality in Exchange; Exchange Value; Institutional Facts Resumen: En este artículo evalúo la teoría del precio justo defendida por James Gordley, según la cual el precio justo es aquel precio que preserva la justicia conmutativa. Luego de oponer algunas objeciones a esta perspectiva, sugiero que enfocarse en la naturaleza institucional de los precios, rechazar el monismo valórico implícito en la versión estándar del precio justo y permitir la posibilidad de un enfoque pluralista a la justificación de los precios puede contribuir a avanzar la teoría del precio justo. Palabras clave: justicia conmutativa; precio justo; igualdad en el inter- cambio; valor de intercambio; hechos institucionales 1 * For helpful comments and suggestions on early versions of this paper, I am grate- ful to Amalia Amaya, Chloe Kennedy, Luís Duarte D’Almeida, Alice Krzanich, Ismael Martínez-Torres, Euan MacDonald, Cormac MacAmlaigh, Claudio Michelon, Lucas Miot- to-Lopes, Margaret O’Brien, Felipe Oliveira de Sousa, Diego Papayannis, Esteban Pereira Fredes, Alberto Pino Emhart, Alexander Vargas Tinoco, Antonia Walterman, Neil Walker, and two anonymous reviewers.
    [Show full text]
  • Is a Just Price Enough?
    Journal of Markets & Morality Volume 20, Number 2 (Fall 2017): 263–278 Copyright © 2017 Is a Just Price Michael Wittmer Professor of Systematic Theology Enough? Grand Rapids Theological Seminary A standard definition of a just price asserts that it is determined solely by “willing consent between buyer and seller.” This is a satisfactory prima facie definition, but its limitations are exposed in financial transactions that involve significant disparities in knowledge or power. Then it seems particularly important for a maximal definition of justice to incorporate the Golden Rule, so that a just price is “whatever amount is agreed upon by a willing buyer and a willing seller who do to the other as they would have done to them.” This article sharpens that defini- tion through dialogue with such seminal philosophers as Thomas Aquinas, Joseph Fletcher, and Nicholas Wolterstorff, and it concludes with heuristic observations to stimulate further discovery.1 Many readers of this journal may agree that a just price is whatever amount is settled upon by a willing buyer and a willing seller. As long as both parties willingly consent, the price is just, regardless of its numerical value. Perhaps the seller or buyer could have found better deals elsewhere. If so, they may later bemoan the foolishness of their transaction, but they cannot complain that they were treated unjustly. Their free choice to buy or sell means their unwise exchange was at least just, or fair, to both parties. This definition of a just price has many advantages. It is simple, straightforward, and easy to determine. We need not worry about the cost of production or utility to others.
    [Show full text]
  • Middle Ages: Rival Theological Theorisations of the International Order
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Kent Academic Repository IR theory and the ‘Modern’ Middle Ages: rival theological theorisations of the international order Adrian Pabst Introduction The thesis that the secular system of modern international relations has medieval, religious roots is not new. Various accounts have documented how the Protestant Reformation and its late medieval antecedents represented a ‘revolution in ideas’ that broke away from the hierarchical arrangement of fragmented feudal polities, which was apparently characteristic of the Middle Ages, to the egalitarian society of sovereign states, which is seemingly synonymous with modernity.1 Linked to this is the standard story in IR that views the Renaissance, the Reformation and the Discovery of the New World as a radical rupture, which replaced the ‘Dark Ages’ with a new era of enlightenment progress.2 Such a supercessionist structuring of historical narrative reinforces the secularist bias that has dominated the discipline since the late 1950s and 1960s. As a result of the secularism in IR theory, the role of religion in international affairs has not so much been neglected and overlooked as misrepresented and under-theorised.3 Specifically for the purposes of this essay, IR theory lacks an account of both the historical influence and the contemporary relevance of rival theological approaches in relation to the modern international order. Recent scholarship in political thought and in the history of ideas has highlighted some of the profound continuities between the medieval and the modern period.4 Building on these and other accounts, this essay explores the role of theological shifts and religious changes in the genesis of modern international relations.
    [Show full text]