View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE

provided by Open Repository and Information System (BORIS)

Capital Cities in Interurban Competition:

Local Autonomy, Urban Governance, and Locational Policy-Making

David Kaufmann

University of Bern, KPM Center for Public Management, Schanzeneckstrasse 1, 3001 Bern, , +41 (0)31 631 5996, [email protected]

Published in Urban Affairs Review, https://doi.org/10.1177/1078087418809939

Abstract

Capital cities are government cities that tend to lack a competitive political economy. Especially

secondary capital cities – defined as capitals that are not the primary economic centers of their

nation states – are pressured to increase their economic competitiveness in today’s globalized

interurban competition by formulating locational policies. This article compares the locational

policies agendas of Bern, Ottawa, The Hague, and Washington, D.C. The comparison reveals

that (1) secondary capital cities tend to formulate development-oriented locational policies

agendas, (2) local tax autonomy best explains the variance in locational policies agendas, and

(3) secondary capital cities possess urban governance arrangements where public actors

dominate and where developers are the only relevant private actors. The challenge for

secondary capital cities is to formulate locational policies that enable them to position

themselves as government cities, as well as business cities, while not solely relying on the

development of their physical infrastructure. Introduction

Economic globalization contests the political and symbolic centrality of capital cities. The ascendance of global cities, the rise of transnational institutions, and the increasing concentration of the knowledge economy in a few dominant metropolitan centers challenge the traditionally importance of capital cities (Friedmann 1986; Sassen 1991). Contemporary capitalism pressures capital cities to enter into globalized interurban competition like any other city. It is, however, uncertain whether and how cities can influence their economic destiny in an international market economy (Savitch and Kantor 2002). Secondary capital cities (SCCs), defined as capitals that are not the primary economic centers of their nation states, are especially challenged by these pressures because these cities lack a competitive political economy

(Kaufmann 2018).

The political economy of SCCs differs from political economies of other types of cities because

SCCs have more complicated government-market interactions, and they are subject to a greater influence from the national government on the local economy, the local labor market, and local land markets (Campbell 2000). The specific political economy of SCCs is produced by

“complex relationships between government, private-sector, and third-sector actors [that] form a distinctive economic system, which is spatially manifested through their interactions, which, in turn, produce information and knowledge” (Mayer et al. 2018, p. 4). As a consequence, the regional economy of SCCs possesses strong clusters of firms in highly regulated and knowledge-intensive sectors, it lacks strong industrial sectors and it is depend on public procurement (Kaufmann 2018; Mayer et al. 2018). And finally, capital cities are places that represent national identity, where a nation’s memory and symbols are staged and thus they have to maintain a modern and representative infrastructure (Cochrane 2006). The legacy as

‘government cities’ constitutes the unique competitiveness challenges for SCCs. Therefore,

SCCs enter globalized interurban competition with a political economy that is configured

1 differently than the political economies of global economic powerhouses, such as New York,

London, or Tokyo, or overachievers in contemporary capitalism, such as the Silicon Valley,

Amsterdam, or Singapore. It is within these settings that SCCs seek ways to position themselves in interurban competition, and they do this by formulating locational policies that aim to increase their economic competitiveness (Kaufmann 2018).

Nation states deliberately chose secondary cities as capitals in order to exert a balance between different regions or cities within a nation state with the idea that they should refrain from developing into economic powerhouses. In some instances, SCCs were chosen to avoid the concentration of economic and political powers and to serve as independent and alternative sites to traditional commercial centers (Gottmann 1977; Mayer et al. 2016; Slack and

Chattopadhyay 2009). In other cases, formerly colonized nations sought to break with their colonial ties by building a new as a symbol of their independence (Moser 2010;

Rossmann 2017). SCCs can be found on every continent. Famous examples of SCCs exist in

Africa (e.g. Pretoria, Abuja), Asia (e.g. Jerusalem, Islamabad), Oceania (e.g. Wellington,

Canberra), Europe (e.g. , The Hague), North America (e.g. Washington, D.C., Ottawa) and South America (e.g. Brasilia, Sucre). National governments may choose to establish new capital cities from scratch or to relocate capital cities to secondary cities. Examples include the relocation of the Brazilian capital from Rio de Janeiro to Brasilia in 1960, the relocation of the

Nigerian capital from Lagos to Abuja in 1991, and the construction of the new Malaysian administrative capital of Putrajaya, which began in 1995. Relocating a capital city is a normal process in the political life of empires, kingdoms, and nations with regard to time and space: around 40 % of all nation states have discussed relocating their capital city (Rossmann 2017).

Given that the global system of capital cities is dynamic, it is likely that other SCCs will be established in the future and that these new SCCs will face the same competitiveness challenge that current SCCs do.

2 The political science and public administration literature perceive SCCs as government cities and it analyzes them in relation to the (federal) nation state (e.g. Harris 1995; Rowat 1968,

1973) or it focuses on how capital cities in federations are organized and financed (Slack and

Chattopadhyay 2009). This article perceives SCCs as economic actors that engage in globalized interurban competition and thus it uncouples SCCs, to a certain degree, from the analytical fixation on the nation-state.

In what follows, I draw on the literature on multilevel governance, local autonomy, urban politics, and locational policies in order to establish the theoretical framework for this article.

In individual case studies, I study variations in the locational policies agendas of four different

SCCs, namely Bern, Ottawa, The Hague, and Washington, D.C. The cross-case comparison finds that SCCs tend to formulate locational policies agendas that favor the physical development of their cities. It also reveals that local tax autonomy greatly influences the formulation of locational policies because it alters the opportunity structure through which local governments raise funds. I discuss the generalizability of these findings and I conclude by briefly recommending strategies that may counteract the negative implications of SCCs’ locational policies agendas.

A Multilevel Governance Framework for Studying Urban Policies

The multilevel governance (MLG) concept, adapted to the urban perspective, provides the theoretical framework behind this article (summarized in Table 1). Two dimensions of MLG serve as the explanatory factors to analyze the locational policies agendas in SCCs.

3 Table 1: Theoretical framework

Overarching Multilevel Governance framework

Explanatory factor 1 Explanatory factor 2 Phenomena to be explained:

Concepts Vertical dimension: Local dimension: Urban Locational policies agendas Local autonomy governance arrangements

Operationalization - Governing structure - Social production - Tax maximization of concepts - Local tax autonomy model - Development and public funds

The MLG concept theorizes the decision-making of multiple intervening actors that operate on multiple scales without a structuring authority (Hooghe and Marks 2003). Horak and Young

(2012), among others, adapt the MLG concept to the urban perspective. They propose two MLG dimensions: The vertical dimension analyzes the interaction between governments at multiple levels in policy-making, whereas the local dimension examines the involvement of non- governmental actors in the policy-making process (Young 2012, pp. 5–6). Consequently, Horak

(2012, p. 339) defines MLG as “a mode of policy making that involves complex interactions among multiple levels of government and social forces.”

Both dimensions are crucial for a comparative analysis of urban policy in general (e.g. Gurr and King 1987; Kantor and Savitch 2005; Sellers 2005), and these dimensions are especially relevant for the comparative study of locational policies in SCCs. The vertical dimension encompasses contextual elements, national variations and institutional differences (Kübler and

Paganao 2012). To capture the influence of higher-level governments is important because the different layers of government intersect much more profoundly in SCCs than in any other types of cites (Campbell 2000, p. 10). The local dimension is essential for understanding policy- making in economic policies, such as locational policies, because it accounts for the influence of private actors in urban governance arrangements (e.g. Stone 1989).

4 Phenomena to be explained: Locational Policies Agendas

Locational policies aim to enhance the competitiveness of a locality (Brenner 1999). They rely on the identification, development, and promotion of place-specific assets because these assets may allow places to escape from a fully competitive, and therefore level, global market

(Kaufmann and Arnold 2017; Kaufmann 2018). Cities possess varying local resources and operate under varying institutional and economic constraints. All of these factors shape urban economic policies (Savitch and Kantor 2002). Locational policies can take many forms.

Kaufmann and Arnold (2017) distinguish between six types of locational policies: (1) innovation policies, which facilitate knowledge flows between a region’s crucial actors, 2) image building policies, (3) business prerequisites strategies that encompass real estate, infrastructure, and tax policies, (4) strategies to attract firms, (5) the establishment of coordination structures for locational policies, and (6) strategies to tap into higher-tier governmental funds. Similarly, Jonas and Ward (2007) mention policies that foster start-ups, attract outside investments and encourage new urban governance arrangements. These kinds of locational policies have expanded substantially in their quantity and they also take new and varied forms (Young 2012, p. 18). Uyarra (2010, p. 132) emphasizes that locational policies appear in complex bundles, occupy multiple policy domains, and are often mutually dependent.

Given that city governments formulate locational policies based on local assets, capital cities may rely on their capital city status when devising locational policies (Kaufmann 2018; Mayer et al. 2016).

Vertical Dimension: Local Autonomy

The vertical dimension assesses the local autonomy of cities, which can be more or less be constrained by higher-tier governments (Goldsmith 1995; Gurr and King 1987; Sellers and

Lidström 2007). The local autonomy of capital cities tends to be more limited than the local

5 autonomy of other cities in the national urban system. James Madison provides the intellectual justification for such capital city specific local autonomy constraints in The Federalist Papers, no. 43, where he argues that the U.S. capital should be independent from state or commercial interests (Hamilton, Madison, and Jay 2005). Political science scholars emphasize that capital cities are torn between the conflicting priorities of serving the nation state as a whole and serving their local residents (Harris 1995; Rowat 1968, 1973). These conflicting priorities are known as the classic capital city conflict, the challenge of dual democracy, or simply as the

Rowat thesis (Harris 1995; Nagel 2013b). Following Page and Goldsmith (1987, 5–7), I examine SCCs’ local autonomy by focusing on their constitutional status and on their degree of financial and fiscal autonomy.1

The constitutional status of capital cities, also known as their governing structures, has been a prominent research object since the beginning of comparative capital city research. Rowat

(1968; 1973) compares seventeen federal capitals and distinguishes between three types of governing structures: (1) a capital city located in a special district, (2) a capital city as a city- state that is simultaneously a constitutive unit of its nation, and (3) a capital city located within a province, state or canton with no special status. This threefold distinction is prevalent in capital city research (Harris 1995; Slack and Chattopadhyay 2009). Each of these governing types assigns more or less local autonomy to capital cities. Capital cities as special districts lack the constitutional sovereignty that states/provinces enjoy, and thus the national government can exert considerable control over them. Capital cities as city-states have the power and responsibilities of both cities and states/provinces, and they tend to have more power and more local autonomy than other cities in the national urban system. A capital city in a state/province possesses the same legal status as other cities in the national urban system. The local autonomy of these types of capitals do not tend to be very restricted, however, they fall under the responsibility of their respective state/province (Slack and Chattopadhyay 2009).

6 Michael Goldsmith (1995, 2012) highlights the importance of the national tax systems under which local governments operate. The national tax system determines jurisdictions’ ability to raise funds (Goldsmith and Page 1987, p. 7). The proportion of all national tax revenue collected at the local level is a straightforward measurement of local tax autonomy (see OECD 2014).

Furthermore, high local autonomy means that local governments have a variety of tax instruments available, such as personal income tax, corporate income tax, and property tax on land and real estate. In a low local tax autonomy context, some of these tax instruments are the prerogative of higher-tier political entities. To compensate for the lack of local tax instruments available, higher-tier political entities transfer a substantial amount of public money to finance local budgets (Goldsmith 2012, p. 137). Local governments are more likely to behave competitive in their formulation of locational policies when they operate in a high local tax autonomy setting (Kaufmann and Sager 2018).

SCCs must endure capital city-specific local tax autonomy constraints. For example,

Washington, D.C., as the , does not enjoy the same tax rights as U.S. states.

Furthermore, tax exemptions on property belonging to the national government, as well as on property belonging to foreign governments (such as embassies or consulates), restrict the local tax base of capital cities. The national government may compensate for these restrictions to the property tax base with payments-in-lieu-of-taxes (Slack and Chattopadhyay 2009).

Local Dimension: Urban Governance Arrangements

The local dimension integrates a key aspect of the urban politics literature: the interplay between local public and local private actors in governing the city. The two seminal studies in urban politics that constitute the community power debate (Dahl 1961; Hunter 1953) suggest that local business actors substantially influence urban politics. Three decades after the community power debate, the growth machine theory (Logan and Molotch 1987; Molotch

7 1976) affirms the power of land and property owners, together with other growth-oriented actors, such as such as investment firms, developers, construction firms, local utility companies, local media, small, and self-employed businesses, as well as universities and cultural institutions. A commitment to economic growth based on tangible benefits unites these diverse actors (Harding 1995, p. 42). The growth machine theory criticizes that the exchange-value of property and land trumps its use-value. The urban regime analysis (Stone 1989, 1993), in a nutshell, argues that popular control (votes) and investments in local development projects

(money) are the two decisive resources that create the ‘capacity to act’ in an urban arena. This

‘capacity to act’ is the foundation of Stone’s ‘social-production model’, which proposes a more diffuse form of power: the facilitative ‘power to’ rather than the absolutist ‘power over’ (Stone

1989, p. 229). The ‘social production model’ emphasizes that decision-making in local economic development does not follow a formal line of authority. A wide array of private actors participates in decision-making processes because they provide essential investments. Business actors are strategic actors who look beyond specific local economic development projects and seek to influence the general locational policies agenda (Swyngedouw, Moulaert, and

Rodriguez 2002).

Given the difficulties of the urban regime analysis to travel through time and space (e.g. Pierre

2014), I draw on the ‘social production model’ as the crucial analytical element for examining

‘urban governance arrangements’. Stone (2015) acknowledges that socio-economic restructuring has altered the urban political arena and he argues that: (1) there is less urgency to conduct big development projects, such as expressways or business city centers, (2) corporations are not as place-bound as they were before, and (3) diverse non-governmental organizations are now important urban political actors. All in all, the post-industrial city does not seem to be a breeding ground for a stable governing coalition with a cohesive and ambitious policy agenda. Thus, I analyze the interactions of public and private actors in the formulation of locational policies through the perspective of urban governance arrangements. As I 8 demonstrate in the case studies, urban governance arrangements are distinctive in SCCs because public actors occupy a central role in these arrangements due to the lack of an industrial history that may have otherwise produced powerful business actors.

Research Design

This article employs a comparative case study design that includes four SCCs in OECD countries, namely Bern, Ottawa, The Hague, and Washington, D.C. The research design juxtaposes a cross-case analysis with a within-case analysis that together allow for reliable causal inferences (Collier, Brady, and Seawright 2010, p. 10). The case selection is based on variance in the explanatory factors. The four cases are a theory-driven sample since they vary in the proposed explanatory factors but share many similarities in contextual variables (see

Table 2). Focusing on SCCs in Europe and North America enables me to control for some of the economic and political context. Furthermore, the exclusion of the other six cases from the population of SCCs in OECD countries2 can be justified due to their lack of comparability and due to practical reasons. Berlin, Jerusalem, and Rome fit the economic definition of SCCs, but they are the primary historical, symbolic, and cultural cities of their nations. I exclude Ankara because of its rather idiosyncratic political and cultural setting. I primarily exclude and Wellington, despite their good fit in the category of SCCs, for practical reasons, as I would have required considerable resources to be able to conduct field research in Oceania.

9 Table 2: Summary of selected cases

Type of factor Factor Bern Ottawa The Hague Washington, D.C. Type of capital Secondary Secondary Secondary Secondary Controlled factor city capital city capital city capital city capital city Type of country Western Western Western Western Controlled factor OECD OECD OECD country OECD country country country Context factor Inhabitants 131,554 957,148 514,861 672,228 Context factor State type Federal state Federal state Decentralized Federal state unitary state Local autonomy - Governing City in a state City in a City in a state Federal structures (i.e. canton) state (i.e. (i.e. province) District Explanatory factor 1 province)

- Local tax High Rather low Low High autonomy Urban Government Government- Corporatist Business- governance dominated developer arrangement developer- Explanatory factor 2 arrangement arrangement arrangement government arrangement Locational Tax Development Development Tax Phenomena policies agenda maximization and public and public maximization to be explained funds funds and development

This article relies on 91 semi-structured, in-person interviews with 103 relevant decision makers in the four SCCs (see Table 3). I carefully selected interview partners to ensure sufficient variety within the cases and consistency between them. The interviews took place during three-month field studies in all four SCCs between summer 2014 and summer 2015.

There is an anonymized list of interview partners in the Appendix (see Table A1). To enhance confidence in the observations, I triangulate reactive data (interviews) with non-reactive data

(such as secondary literature, reports, databases, strategic papers, and city budgets).

10 Table 3: Summary of interviews

Bern Ottawa The Hague Washington, Total Type of Interviewee D.C. - Public official (local, second-tier and 6 5 9 8 28 national government) - Economic development agent 3 6 4 4 17 - Regional coordination agent - Business actor - Private interest group 7 6 5 8 26 representative - Expert 3 4 6 7 20 - Academic Total 19 21 24 27 91

I present all four case studies in the same order: first, I briefly outline the reasoning behind the selection of each city as the capital, next I describe the local autonomy and the urban governance arrangement, and then I explain how these two explanatory factors influence locational policies agendas. The analytical weight of this article rests on the cross-case comparison in the discussion section.

Bern

The city of Bern was chosen as the capital of Switzerland in 1848 for pragmatic reasons. At that time, Lucerne, a conservative catholic stronghold, was still skeptical of the new Swiss

Confederation, and Zurich was already too economically powerful (Kübler 2009; Stadler 1971).

Furthermore, the choice of the city of Bern as the capital city was an inclusionary gesture at this time of nation state building due to its central geographic location and its proximity to the

French speaking parts of Switzerland (Stadler 1971, p. 582).

Local Autonomy

Swiss municipalities enjoy high local autonomy. They have residual powers, i.e. they can legislate in areas where superior bodies have not legislated (Kübler 2009, p. 245). Legally, the

11 capital city is treated like any other Swiss municipality and thus, there are no capital city specific constraints. In the Swiss political system, cantons are the most powerful political entities with regard to policy formulation and implementation (Sager, Ingold and Balthasar 2017).

Local tax autonomy is also high in Switzerland. Local governments are able to levy personal income taxes, corporate income taxes, and property taxes. They also have the power to set their own tax rates. Municipalities raise 15.16 % of all Swiss taxes (OECD 2014). Taxes levied on personal income are by far the highest source of revenue for the city of Bern (see Table 4).

Other than a lump sum that the federal level provides for cultural activities, the city of Bern does not receive any compensation from the Swiss Confederation. However, it receives about

15 % of its revenue from financial transfers from the canton.

12 Table 4: Local revenue composition of the city of Bern

Budgetary items Swiss Franc (CHF) Percentage (%) in Millions Property tax 39.77 2.63 Personal income tax 642.48 42.47

Corporate income tax 150.06 9.92

Other taxes 61.22 4.05 User fees 200.70 13.27

Patents and concessions 1.65 0.11

Assets 154.10 10.19 Cantonal governmental transfers 167.60 11.08

Cantonal fiscal equalization 63.25 4.18 scheme Miscellaneous 31.84 2.10

Total 1,512.69 100 Sources: Federal Finance Administration (2016), data from 2014. Notes: Sales and gross receipt taxes are the prerogatives of the federal level. The lump sum of one million CHF annually provided for cultural activities is not recorded in the data of the Federal Finance Administration and is thus not displayed in this table.

Urban Governance Arrangement

Public actors dominate Bern’s urban governance arrangement. While there are local private interest groups that share a common interest in the economic advancement of the city of Bern, these groups are only loosely connected and are not very influential. In a book about the international activities of European cities, Van der Heiden (2010, p. 44) states: “The few international activities of the City of Bern are clearly in the hands of the city administration.

Private actors and the public are wholly excluded from Bern’s few international activities”.

Additionally, a comparative study of large-scale urban construction projects in Swiss cities finds that the Bernese local government holds the key position, whereas private actors only enter the scene during the realization of these projects (Lambelet 2017). This powerful role held by the local government also applies to locational policies. For example, an influential business

13 representative assesses the interactions between public and private actors as much more dynamic in Zurich than in Bern (Interview 2). Other business representatives blame the political dominance of the social democratic and the green parties, which they say hinders the ability for business representatives to contribute their ideas (Interviews: 5 & 7). Furthermore, profound direct democratic institutions are a special feature of Bernese city politics that limits business influence. Bernese citizens are automatically called to the ballot box when a projected public expenditure is expected to exceed seven million Swiss Francs or if a law would modify the local land use or local housing policy. Additionally, citizens must approve the city budget and tax rate annually (Kaufmann et al. 2016).

Locational Policies Agenda

The city of Bern pursues a tax maximization locational policies agenda. It focuses on being attractive for residents through the formulation of locational policies that seek to enhance its residents’ quality of life. These locational strategies include maintaining green spaces, preserving the old town, establishing schools for expatriate children, and supporting cultural activities (Interviews: 3, 6 & 18). These efforts aim to attract wealthy taxpayers to the city of

Bern in order to increase the personal income tax base that currently comprises 42 % of the local revenue. The city’s locational policies do not focus on acquiring firms because it is the canton of Bern that holds the discretionary power to offer tax incentives to firms (Interview 6), and because corporate income taxes only comprise 10 % of local revenue. In general, the city of Bern does not formulate many economic-oriented locational policies. Instead, it concentrates on quality of life issues, and it positions itself as the political center of Switzerland by arguing that a strong capital city is in the interest of the whole nation state.

14 Ottawa

Ottawa was a farmer and lumber town prior to being named as the capital of the Province of

Canada in 1857. Queen Victoria made the final decision to choose Ottawa as the capital

(Andrew 2013, pp. 86–87). Egglestone (1961, p. 102) argues that Ottawa was the only place that the majority of the existing Canadian cities considered to be an acceptable choice as the capital. With the establishment of the Canadian Confederation in 1867, Ottawa became the federal capital (Tassonyi 2009, p. 57).

Local Autonomy

The Canadian Constitution does not recognize municipalities. Its only reference to municipalities is as ‘creatures of the provinces’. The city of Ottawa operates under the statutory framework of the province of Ontario. The National Capital Commission (NCC) exerts direct control over the planning, zoning and building of federal land and therefore constrains the local autonomy of Ottawa compared to other Canadian municipalities. “This means that neither the provincial nor the local authority has any rights of taxation, legislation, or regulation over such property, except what the national authority chooses to give it” (Taylor 2011, p. 28). The NCC is the single largest property owner in Ottawa, with direct control over approximately 10 % of all land in Ottawa, including some very prominent areas in Downtown (Champagne 2011, p.

46; Interviews: 52, 54 & 58).

Canadian local governments raise 9.69 % of all tax revenue in Canada. Three tax revenue categories exist for municipalities in Ontario: property taxes, user charges, and transfers from other governmental levels (mostly from the provincial government) (Siegel 2009, pp. 50–51).

Governmental money transfers consist of four categories: (1) conditional grants, (2) unconditional grants, (3) payments-in-lieu-of-taxes (PILTs), and (4) revenue sharing. The

PILTs that Ottawa receives are remarkable from a comparative perspective on the financing of

15 capital cities because not many other capital cities receive such generous PILTs (Slack and

Chattopadhyay 2009).

Table 5 summarizes the revenue breakdown of the city of Ottawa. Property taxes are extremely important as they comprise 47 % of the city’s revenue. User fees account for another 24 % of revenue. The city of Ottawa raises 75 % of its budget independently. Government grants (19

%) and payments-in-lieu-of-taxes (6 %) add up to 25 % of the revenue that comes from higher- tier governments.

Table 5: Local revenue composition of the city of Ottawa

Budgetary items Canadian Percentage (%) Dollars (CAD) in Millions Property tax 1,455.26 47.08

Fees and services 735.78 23.80

Federal transfers 499.81 16.17 Provincial transfers 79.56 2.57

Payments in lieu of 191.88 6.21 taxes Miscellaneous 128.98 4.17

Total 3,091.27 100 Source: City of Ottawa (2016), data from 2015.

Urban Governance Arrangement

Public actors and developers dominate the urban governance arrangement in Ottawa. Horak

(2012, p. 356) argues that large firms, property developers, and chambers of commerce are important for governance arrangements in Canadian cities. According to the interview partners, chambers of commerce and large firms do not exercise much influence in Ottawa. Since the crash of Ottawa’s pivotal high-tech sector in the early 2000s, Ottawa no longer houses a strong industry and thus, the chambers of commerce lack influence and money (Interview 49). An expert explains the consequences:

16

Here in Ottawa, no urban regime exists, except for the developers. (…) Local developers in Ottawa are very important in running the city. There are about 50 influential developers that have something to say. They do not want to be organized because than they would be recognized as political players. It is a diffuse form of power. (Interview 58)

Another expert is similarly trenchant in describing the role of the developers in Ottawa:

“Developers are the only people that have an influence on city hall. It is not the chamber of commerce or other organized business interests” (Interview 48). Developers are important because they are able to form ad-hoc coalitions when pushing for certain issues (Interview 45) and “they get things done” (Interview 61).

Locational Policies Agenda

Ottawa’s locational policies agenda seeks to increase the value of its property tax base and to attract funds from higher-tier governments. In terms of the former, the city hall plays an especially active role in Ottawa’s Downtown because of the high prices in this area. Property taxes comprise 47 % of the local revenue. As a consequence, the city hall seeks to ensure low commercial vacancy rates by cooperating with side locators, offering tax incentives for renovating Downtown real estate, and prioritizing permissions for Downtown real estate renovations in a fast-track procedure (Interviews: 44, 46 & 55). The strong role developers’ play in the urban governance arrangement fuels this development-oriented strategy. Developers are able to advance certain development projects in a quick and non-bureaucratic manner

(Interviews: 45 & 61). Higher-tier public funds account for a quarter of local revenue. There are ample opportunities to request public funds because many higher-tier governmental funds compensate the low tax autonomy of Canadian local governments.

The Hague

In the Middle Ages, The Hague served as a neutral meeting place, a site for negotiations, and a venue for arbitration for the powerful Dutch city-states (van Krieken and McKay 2005, p. 3).

17 Its historic role made Prince Maurice, in 1585, to place the Dutch political and judicial organizations there. However, Amsterdam is the official capital city of the Netherlands because during the French occupation of the Netherlands (1806-1813), Napoleon Bonaparte and his brother, King Louis, preferred to settle in Amsterdam. After the withdrawal of Napoleon in

1813, Dutch decision makers returned the to The Hague but left Amsterdam with capital city status.

Local Autonomy

The Netherlands is a decentralized unitary state with a strong central government. Its provinces are the least powerful level of the Dutch political system. Since the 1980s, the policy responsibilities of the municipalities have been extended (Andeweg and Irwin 2014, pp. 212-

214). Dutch municipalities deliver public services in many policy areas, such as social assistance, public housing, education, and cultural activities. Central government funds largely finance these services. The Hague does not face additional constraints due to its capital city function and the Dutch political system does not offer compensation payments to its capital city.

Dutch municipalities have low local tax autonomy. The local level only raises 3.6 % of all

Dutch taxes (OECD 2014). Thus, Dutch local governments rely heavily on central government funds. Local governments have three main sources of income: (1) local taxes (mainly on property) and local user fees, (2) unconditional government grants, and (3) conditional government grants (Dersken and Schaap 2010). This low local tax autonomy manifests itself in

The Hague’s budget (see Table 6). Local taxes comprise 4 % of the budget. Property taxes constitute 3.2 % of the budget, and other taxes (such as dog or tourist taxes) comprise another

1 % of the budget. Consequently, unconditional government grants (about 45 % of the budget)

18 and conditional government grants (about 18 % of the budget) are important for sustaining the budget of The Hague.

Table 6: Local revenue composition of the city of The Hague

Budgetary Items Euro (EUR) Percentage (%) in Millions

Property tax 80.50 3.23

Other local taxes 24.70 0.99

Unconditional government grants 1,129.60 45.31

Conditional government grants 455.80 18.28

Other income (user fees, interests, 802.60 32.19 dividends, and leases)

Total 2,493.20 100

Source: City of The Hague (2014, 242–44). Outlook data for 2015.

Urban Governance Arrangement

The Hague’s urban governance arrangement be described as corporatist. This means that private interest groups and the government have a relationship that is based on exchange and cooperation rather than on competition. In Dutch policy-making, employer organizations, labor unions, and governmental entities cooperate to address issues in a consensus-based, non- institutionalized, and non-confrontational way (Andeweg and Irwin 2014). The local level reproduces this corporatist tradition. In The Hague, the economic agenda is discussed in institutionalized meetings in the so-called Administrative Consultations for Economic Affairs

(Bestuurlijk Overleg Economische Zaken), which consists of members of labor unions, employer organizations, and the city (Interviews: 34 & 35).

Locational Policies Agenda

The Hague aims to attract higher-tier governmental funds and focuses on the development of real estate and infrastructure. Vertical money transfers comprise 64 % of The Hague’s local

19 revenue and attracting economic development funds is thus of special importance to its locational policies agenda. For example, the Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs’ top sector program provides funding for The Hague’s cluster organization in cyber security sector, called

The Hague Security Delta (Interviews: 25 & 41). Given the importance of these funds, the city of The Hague employs specialists entrusted with the task of tapping into various public funding opportunities (Interviews: 40 & 42). As a second priority, The Hague focuses on the development of modern real estate projects because property tax is the only important locally raised tax. For example, The Hague invests a great deal into its Central Business District

(Interview 42). Local government officials explain that “all Dutch municipalities largely focus on developing its physical infrastructure (…) It can be explained with the locally raised real estate taxes” (Interview 25). An expert mentions, in a somewhat sarcastic manner, that real estate development “is all that local governments do in the Netherlands” (Interview 32).

Washington D.C.

The establishment of a new U.S. capital city along the Potomac River was an intentional move to insulate the federal government from the influence of states and commercial centers (Ghandi et al. 2009, p. 271). D.C. is a planned city founded in 1791 and initiated as the U.S. capital in

1800. The U.S. Constitution does not specify the location of the District. Gilliland (2013) argues that the decision to move the U.S. capital to its current location was a compromise between

Northern states, who succeeded in having their war debts nationalized, and Southern states, who extracted the capital from the influence of Pennsylvanian Northerners.3 It was President George

Washington who finally decided on the exact location of the proposed District, and he chose an area close to his own home in Mount Vernon, Virginia (Gilliland 2013, p. 35).

20 Local Autonomy

The governing structure of Washington D.C. is described as Home Rule under Congressional supervision (Nagel 2013a). A non-voting member in the U.S. House of Representatives is the only representative of District residents. Congress can influence the District’s policy-making by either blocking spending on particular budgetary items or by directly vetoing D.C. laws

(Nagel 2013a, pp. 64–65). Congress has used this power extensively (Fauntroy 2003; Nagel

2013a, p. 71). Interview partners consider congressional oversight to be highly controversial, especially with regard to D.C.’s current policy initiatives, such as legalizing abortion and the consumption of marihuana, establishing a needle exchange program, and tightening fire arms regulations (Interviews: 75, 79, 81, 84 & 88). Congress has made use of its “authority over locally generated funds as a means to enact its own legislative provision through so-called

‘social riders’ (…). These ‘social riders’ specifically impact District policy, however, they actually reflect broader political debates” (Ghandi et al. 2009, p. 279). The federal administration can further intervene in local matters via The National Capital Planning

Commission (NCPC), which represents interests over federal land and buildings.

D.C. bears the responsibility of a state, as well as that of a county, a city, and a school district

(Ghandi et al. 2009, p. 265). In comparison to states, the Home Rule Act of 1973 diminishes

D.C.’s personal income tax base by prohibiting it from levying the so-called Commuter Tax on the income of non-residents that work in the District. Non-residents earn two thirds of income in the District (Ghandi et al. 2009, pp. 279–280), which would have accounted for an additional

US$ 2.26 billion in tax revenue in 2005 (Yilmaz 2009). Furthermore, the tax on currently tax- exempt properties would have accounted for an additional tax revenue of about US$ 540 million in 2005 (Yilmaz 2009). The District does not receive payments-in-lieu-of-taxes for most of its federal and foreign properties (Ghandi et al. 2009, p. 280). Overall, D.C.’s constrained tax

21 autonomy creates a structural income deficit, which is seen as a reason for its historically high taxes (Interviews: 69 & 89; O’Cleireacain 1997, pp. 6–10).

Table 7 shows D.C.’s revenue composition. The 28 % of federal governmental transfers stems from the fact that the district has the same responsibilities as different levels of government, such as state, county, city, and school district. This percentage would be significantly higher if the US$ 1.3 billion annual compensation payment would be reflected in the budget (Nagel

2013a, p. 65). Taxes raise 44 % of the budget. Property tax, sales and gross receipt tax, and personal income tax account for more or less the same percentage of revenue.

Table 7: Local revenue composition in the city of Washington D.C.

Budgetary item United States Percentage (%) Dollars (US$) in Millions Federal governmental transfers 3,982 28.26

Property tax 1,970 13.98

Sales and gross receipt tax 1,511 10.72

Individual income tax 1,641 11.64

Corporate income tax 453 3.21

Other taxes 605 4.30

Charges, utility revenue and 3,931 27.89 miscellaneous revenue

Total 14,093 100 Source: United States Census Bureau, (2015): State and Local Government Finance, data from 2013.

Urban Governance Arrangement

Public officials, business actors, leaders of non-profit organizations, and developers all engage in an intense, non-institutionalized discussion of locational policies. Business communities in the District are well organized and business organizations have access to local public leaders via their own networks and not via institutionalized access channels (Interviews: 71, 77, 90). In the case of big infrastructure projects (e.g. the renovation of Union Station or the construction of the Convention center), business organizations activate their networks to accelerate these 22 development projects and to ensure their funding (Interview 69). Different business organizations in the District meet each other informally and sporadically in order to find common ground and to share their priorities (Interview 87). Most of these business organizations also hire lobbyists that represent their interests. Thus, business interests in D.C. are well heard despite their lack of institutional access to public leaders (Interview 75).

Interview partners do not describe the urban governance arrangement as a typical urban regime

(Interviews: 75, 77, 88 & 90). The absence of a strong industry in D.C. makes developers very influential in District politics (Interviews: 69, 80 & 82). Thus, an expert calls the urban governance arrangement “rather a growth machine type than an urban regime. It applies more, because D.C. has no industries, but it has land to develop” (Interview 88).

Locational Policies Agenda

D.C. follows a tax maximization and a development-oriented locational policies agenda. The development of neighborhoods and large infrastructure projects aim to lure wealthy tax payers into the District in order to increase the personal income tax base (Interviews: 73, 84 & 86;

Hyra and Prince 2016; Sturtevant 2013). The District government increasingly focuses on so- called place-based development that aims to transform neighborhoods into areas that have a high quality of life by incentivizing the establishment of small retail businesses and cultural institutions, as well as improving schools, and lowering crime rates. An economic development agent explains:

Our major success was to invest in place. We invested in neighborhoods, transportation infrastructure, retail opportunities, schools, and libraries to make D.C. more attractive for talent. (…) To invest in place is our key narrative that we are telling. D.C. is viewed as a talent attractor. D.C. did a great job and now we have to be careful how we avoid the bad symptoms of gentrifications such as unaffordability of housing and real estate. (Interview 73).

However, most of the District’s current economic development strategy focuses on real estate development (Interview 84). The District’s 5 Year Economic Development Strategy, which

23 aims to generate 100,000 additional jobs, exemplifies this focus since the strategy expects that more than half of the jobs (55,000) will be created in the real estate and construction sectors

(The District of Columbia 2012, p. 12). The district transfers brown fields and underused facilities to developers (Interview 91). The interplay between the D.C. administration and developers enables this development-oriented locational policies agenda (Interviews: 80, 86 &

88).

Furthermore, D.C. asks for federal compensation payments due to its capital city specific constraints. Since the Home Rule Act of 1973, which implicitly acknowledges the unique fiscal role of the District, the D.C. administration has sought to increase federal compensation payments (Ghandi et al. 2009, p. 274). For example, the Revitalization Act of 1997 increased federal payments from around US$ 660 million to US$ 1.3 billion annually. Since the turn of the millennium, D.C. has lobbied for US$ one billion in federal dollars to help fund the modernization of its outdated infrastructure (Interviews: 79, 81, 88 & 90). In these negotiations with the federal level, D.C. decision makers explicitly refer to its capital city status. A local lobbyist explains:

We launched the discussions for the new infrastructure deal because the Obama administration came into power. We thought the Clinton administration gave us the Revitalization Act, the Bush administration gave us some land that we could develop and so we can also give the Obama administration a choice to improve the District. The commuter tax was always the elephant in the room over the years because every state can do that and because it is a lot of money given the number of commuters. We thought we are probably not getting the commuter tax, but we can negotiate a compensation for it. (Interview 81)

Comparing and explaining locational policies agendas

The cross-case comparison reveals that governing structures of capital cities, local tax autonomy, and urban governance arrangements are relevant for explaining locational policies agendas. However, the effects of these explanatory factors on locational policies vary in terms of their strength and magnitude (see Table 8).

24 Table 8: Summary of case studies

Case Locational Policies Agendas Explanatory Factors Bern - Increasing personal income tax base by - High local tax autonomy investing in quality of life Ottawa - Increasing property tax base by supporting - Low local tax autonomy and developers development projects - Attracting higher-tier governmental funds - Low local tax autonomy - Asking for compensation payments - Capital city specific local autonomy constraints The Hague - Attracting higher-tier governmental funds - Low local tax autonomy - Increasing the property tax base by - Low local tax autonomy supporting development projects Washington - Increasing tax bases by place-based - High local tax autonomy and developers D.C. neighborhood development and large-scale development projects - Asking for compensation payments - Capital city specific local autonomy constraints

Governing Structures of Capital Cities

The governing structures of capital cities can explain whether or not SCCs request compensation payments. In the context of SCCs, compensation payments are seen as locational policies because they are important for financing capital cities and these payments are subject to intense negotiations between local governments and relevant national organizations

(Kaufmann 2018). Of the four SCCs analyzed, Ottawa and D.C. ask for compensation payments. In both North American capitals, local autonomy is constrained by an agency that represents interests over federal land. In D.C., local autonomy constraints are more profound, to the extreme that the Congress has de facto oversight over local policy-making. In neither of the two European SCCs does a national land-use agency exist, nor is there a mechanism for an actor from the federal level to intervene in local policy-making.

The comparison suggests that a city’s status prior to its selection as capital is important for explaining its capital city specific constraints. Both European SCCs exercised important

25 functions within their national urban systems at the time they were chosen as capitals. For this reason, it seems unlikely that Bern or The Hague would have accepted local autonomy cutbacks brought along by capital city status. In contrast, the two North American capitals were built from scratch, or were primarily developed to serve as the capital. Thus, it is important to differentiate between purpose-built capitals and purposely-selected capitals when studying the local autonomy of SCCs. This distinction enriches the existing threefold categorization proposed by Rowat (1973) (see second section of the article).

Local Tax Autonomy

The priorities of locational policies agendas (in Table 8) are mirrored in the revenue categories of the local budgets (see Table 9). The importance of the individual revenue categories can be explained by local tax autonomy. Local governments exhibit a strong functional orientation towards increasing their most important revenue sources via the formulation of locational policies. In Bern, personal income tax comprises 42 % of local revenue, which explains its strong focus on increasing the city’s quality of life in order to attract wealthy residents. In

Ottawa, property tax comprises 47 % of local revenue, thereby explaining its focus on development projects and its efforts to maintain real estate values. In The Hague, governmental transfers account for 64 % of local revenue. This explains The Hague’s activities that attract governmental economic development funds. D.C. pursues a mix of locational policy instruments, which its rather diversified budget mirrors.

26 Table 9: Local revenue comparison of the four SCCs

Budgetary items Bern (%) Ottawa (%) The Hague (%) Washington, D.C. (%) Property tax 2.63 47.08 3.23 13.98 Personal income tax 42.47 - - 11.64 Corporate income tax 9.92 - - 3.21 Other taxes 4.05 0.00 0.99 15.02 Governmental transfers 15.26 18.74 63.59 28.26 Payments in lieu of taxes - 6.21 - - User fees, assets, and 25.67 27.97 32.19 27.89 miscellaneous revenue Total 100 100 100 100

Sources are listed in the case studies

All in all, local tax autonomy is a game changer for locational policies agendas. Differences in local tax autonomy lead to different opportunity structures for how local governments can raise funds. These different opportunity structures yield two ideal types of locational policies agendas. One is that low local tax autonomy encourages a development and public funds locational policies agenda, which is found in Ottawa and The Hague. In these cases, local governments prioritize infrastructure and real estate development in order to boost the property tax base, which is the major independently-raised source of local revenue. Higher-tier government entities compensate for this low local tax autonomy by offering various public funds. In contrast, high local tax autonomy leads to a tax maximization locational policies agenda. The focus of these kinds of agendas is to maximize the revenue from the multiple tax instruments at hand. This ideal type of locational policies agendas, found in Bern and D.C., aims to reap the benefit of its locational policies activities in the form of various tax revenues.

Since personal income tax is the most important revenue category for municipalities in the

Swiss tax system, Bern seeks to boost its personal income tax base. Similarly, the importance of the property tax and the personal income tax for D.C. leads to a focus on place-based development and infrastructure development.

27 Urban Governance Arrangements

The cross-case comparison reveals the important role that local governments and developers play in the urban governance arrangements of SCCs. The central role of local governments somewhat contrasts with the assumptions of the ‘social production model’ At the time of

Stone’s study of Atlanta (1946-1988), business elites provided crucial resources, such as money, land, and technical expertise, whereas the local government provided political legitimacy. With the exception of D.C., local governments are the central players in urban governance arrangements in these four SCCs, and business elites are largely missing. While in

Bern public actors exploit this position in order to exercise a dominant role, city administrations in The Hague and Ottawa operate in an integrative and coordinative manner and ensure interaction with local private actors. In general, business actors in SCCs are unable to provide the variety of resources described in the urban regime theory (Lambelet 2017; Stone 1989;

1993). In their essence, SCCs are government cities that lack an industrial tradition. In such a context, a resource-rich, and thus powerful, business elite was not able to develop. Although knowledge-intensive and highly regulated economic sectors are important for the economy of

SCCs, such ‘ed and med’ firms and organizations do not engage in city politics as a collective force (Stone 2015, p. 111). Local governments are able to occupy such a central position because business actors are largely absent. Therefore, local governments are in a position to lead these urban governance arrangements.

Only in the two North American SCCs do powerful business actors exist, namely developers.

In the two European SCCs, developers do not have the same leverage over local politics. The locational policies agenda of The Hague also focuses on land and real estate development; however, developers do not facilitate these activities. This begs the question: Why are developers important in North American cities but not in European ones?

28 First, business elites and local public actors are generally more entangled in North American contexts than in Continental Europe (e.g. DiGaetano and Klemanski 1999; Pierre 2005, 2014).

In the European context, private actors’ institutionalized access to urban politics keep them in check to a certain degree. As the case of The Hague exemplifies: developers were important in the construction of the Central Business District, but they do not influence locational policy formulation because it is the competence of the institutionalized Administrative Consultations for Economic Affairs. Second, cities were at the forefront of territorial expansion as centers of trade and commerce in the North American settler countries (Judd and Swanstrom 2015, pp. 3–

4). In these cases, developers satisfied the demand for urban development. Third, property taxation is more important in former British Empire countries when compared to other OECD countries (Brülhart, Bucovetsky, and Schmidheiny 2015, pp. 1138–1139). This importance of property taxation, in combination with the strong role of developers, seem to explain the development-oriented locational policies agenda in the two North American capitals. Thus, national tax systems seem to influence urban governance arrangements.

Conclusion

This article combines classic urban politics theories of local autonomy and urban governance under the framework of multilevel governance in order to analyze the variety of locational policies that secondary capital cities (SCCs) formulate. SCCs are government cities that are pressured to enter globalized interurban competition without possessing a competitive political economy. The article compares locational policies agendas of four SCCs, namely Bern, Ottawa,

The Hague, and Washington D.C. The cross-case comparison reveals that SCCs are prone to pursue a development-oriented locational policies agenda and that three factors can explain the locational policy agendas in SCCs.

First, local autonomy restrictions, such as nation state oversight over land or city budgets, are more common in purpose-built capitals (such as Ottawa and Washington, D.C.) than in

29 purposely-selected capitals (such as Bern and The Hague). These capital city specific local autonomy constraints allow purpose-built capitals to request compensation payments. This distinction between purpose-built capitals and purposely-selected capitals also seems to be relevant when studying other SCCs. For example, in purpose-built Brasilia, national government funds compensate for tax-exempt property. In addition, the Brazilian capital receives about 7 % of its annual budget from national government subsidies that are meant to compensate for capital city burdens (Wolman et al. 2007, p. 16). Pretoria, on the other hand, was purposely selected as the host of the South African administration. Pretoria does not have to cope with any local autonomy constraints, and it does not demand capital city specific compensation payments (Steytler 2009).

Second, local tax autonomy is a real game changer for locational policies agendas. Decision makers in all four cities share the rationale of wanting to be competitive in globalized interurban competition, i.e. a neoliberal rationale (Weaver 2018), and they feel pressured by economic globalization. Locational policies are formulated as a reaction to these capitalistic pressures.

The actual locational policies devised in the different SCCs vary, and this is mainly due to the national tax system. Low local tax autonomy leads to a locational policies agenda that prioritizes infrastructure and real estate development in order to boost the property tax base and that is dependent on higher-tier governmental grants. High local tax autonomy leads to a locational policies agenda that focuses on the maximization of tax revenue from the multiple tax instruments at hand. Thus, national tax systems are highly relevant when studying comparative urban economic policy because cities must raise funds to sustain and expand their budget. This article buttresses the importance of institutions for explaining policy variations in comparative urban economic development research (see for example Kaufmann 2018; Peterson

1981; Savitch and Kantor 2002; Weaver 2016).

30 Third, local governments are central actors in SCCs’ urban governance arrangements. SCCs are government cities that lack an industrial history. In the two North American SCCs, local governments and developers join together in urban governance arrangements. The two North

American capital cities possess a growth-machine type of urban governance (Logan and

Molotch 1987; Molotch 1976). Such a growth machine was able to thrive in a specific context, i.e. SCCs’ absence of an industrial tradition, the development-orientation of North American cities, and the primacy of the property tax. Developers seem to fill the vacuum resulting from the absence of private actors. Thus, urban governance arrangements in SCCs are distinctive, but they may also be found in other cities where private actors are not very influential. The urban politics literature discusses similar regime descriptions, such as the government-led pro- growth regime (DiGaetano and Klemanski 1999) and the local-statist regime (Imbroscio 1998).

Government-led arrangements may become more important in future because the growing ‘ed and med’ sectors do not seem to be very interested in engaging in city politics as a collective force (Stone 2015).

This article reveals that locational policy agendas in SCCs do not seem to be qualitatively different from other cities with regard to their adherence to the rationale of being competitive and with regard to the importance of tax systems for the configuration of their locational policies. What I found to be rather specific about locational policy agendas in SCCs is that they heavily rely on the physical development of their city. For sure, physical development is a locational policy priority in many cities worldwide, but this reliance on physical development is very intense in SCCs because of capital city specific tax constraints and path-dependent urban power structures in which developers assume a powerful role. Thus, the specific political economy of SCCs triggers this development orientation of locational policy agendas in SCCs.

This also seems to be true for other SCCs. For example, Canberra focuses on developing its infrastructure and justifies this locational policies agenda with its capital city status: “[G]iven the ACT’s [Australian Capital Territory] lack of manufacturing and resources such as mining 31 and agriculture revenues, planning efficiency and land development are more economically significant in the ACT than in any other Australian jurisdiction” (ACT Government 2008, p.

4). This development focus fuels gentrification and segregation tendencies, as demonstrated in two recent books about Washington, D.C. (Hyra and Prince 2016; Hyra 2017) and in an edited volume about European capital cities (Tammaru et al. 2015).

Given the specific political economy of SCCs, the reliance on physical development can not just be altered by a realignment of locational policy priorities. However, it is possible to derive several strategies from the case studies that could help to minimize the reliance on physical development. First, nation states may better support their capital cities by providing them with more financial resources or by easing some of their capital city specific local autonomy constraints. This would acknowledge the special situation of SCCs and alleviate some pressures caused by interurban competition. Second, local governments in SCCs may invest in economic sectors where capital cities have a competitive advantage. These include highly-regulated and knowledge-intensive sectors, such as medical technology, cyber security, or sustainable energy

(Mayer et al. 2016, 2018). This would allow SCCs to raise funds beyond physical development.

Third, the case of Bern shows that direct democratic instruments provide city residents with an institutional veto to object large-scale development projects. This may induce local policy makers to find alternative locational policy strategies and to be more sensitive about residential interests. Finally, and most radically, place-based development, as in the case of Washington,

D.C., could be accompanied by place-based ownership models of corporations, houses, or land

(Imbroscio, Williamson and Alperovitz 2003; Imbrosciso 2013). This would more securely anchor investments in the city and it may provide a mechanism through which to counter gentrification.

32 Notes

1. Page and Goldsmith (1987, 5–7) recommend a fourfold classification of local autonomy

for use in comparative studies. In addition to the constitutional status and the degree of

financial and fiscal autonomy, they propose an analysis of the different kinds and ranges

of services and functions that local governments must perform and the discretion local

governments possess in determining how they want to perform these service and

functions.

2. There are ten SCCs in the 34 OECD countries: Canberra, Australia; Ottawa, Canada;

Berlin, ; Jerusalem, Israel; Rome, Italy, The Hague, The Netherlands;

Wellington, New Zealand; Bern, Switzerland; Ankara, Turkey; Washington, D.C.,

United States.

3. See Gilligan (2013, 34-35) for a discussion of other explanations of why the new capital

city was established on the Potomac River.

33 Bibliograhpy

ACT Government. 2008. “Submission to the Joint Standing Comittee on the National Capital

and External Territories: Inquiriy into the Role of National Capital Authority.”

https://www.aph.gov.au/Parliamentary_Business/Committees/House_of_Representati

ves_Committees?url=ncet/natcapauth/subs/sub069.pdf (accessed September 10, 2018)

Andeweg, Rudy, and Galen Irwin. 2014. Governance and Politics of the Netherlands.

Palgrave Macmillan.

Andrew, Caroline. 2013. “The Case of Ottawa.” In The Problem of the Capital City: New

Research on Federal Capitals and Their Territory, edited by Klaus-Jürgen Nagel, 83–

102. Generaltat de Catalunya, Institut d’Estudis Autonomics.

Brenner Neil. 1999. “Globalisation as reterritorialisation: The re-scaling of urban governance

in the European Union.” Urban Studies 36(3): 431–451.

Brülhart, Marius, Sam Bucovetsky, and Kurt Schmidheiny. 2015. “Taxes in Cities.” In

Handbook of Regional and Urban Economies, edited by Gilles Duranton, Vernon J.

Henderson, and William C. Strange, 1123–1196. Elsevier.

Champagne, Eric. 2011. “Transportation Failure in the Federal Capital Region.” In The

Unimagined Canadian Capital: Challenges for the Federal Capital Region, edited by

Rupak Chattopadhyay and Gilles Paquet, 43–52. Ottawa: Invenire Books.

City of Ottawa. 2016. Budget 2016. http://ottawa.ca/en/city-hall/budget-and-taxes/budget-

2016 (accessed September 10, 2018)

City of The Hague. 2014. Programmabegroting 2015-2018.

Cochrane, Allan. (2006). “Making up meanings in a capital city power, memory and

monuments in Berlin.” European Urban and Regional Studies, 13(1), 5–24.

Collier, David, Henry E Brady, and Jason Seawright. 2010. “Introduction to the Second

Edition: A Sea Change in Political Methodology.” In Rethinking Social Inquiry:

34 Diverse Tools, Shared Standards, edited by Henry E Brady and David Collier, 1–10.

Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.

Dahl, Robert Alan. 1961. Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City. New

Haven.

Dersken, Johan Wim, and Linze Schaap. 2010. Lokaal Bestuur. Dordrecht: Convoy Uitgevers

B.V..

DiGaetano, Alan, and John Klemanski. 1999. Power and City Governance: Comparative

Perspectives on Urban Development. University of Minnesota Press.

Eggleston, Wilfrid. 1961. The Queen’s Choice: A Story of Canada’s Capital, Ottawa. Ottawa:

Queen’s Printer.

Fauntroy, Michael. 2003. Home Rule or House Rule? Congress and the Erosion of Local

Governance in the District of Columbia. Lanham, MD: University Press of America.

Federal Finance Administration. 2016. “Einnahmen–2014: Städte Und Kantonshauptorte.”

https://www.efv.admin.ch/efv/de/home/themen/finanzstatistik/berichterstattung.html

(accessed September 10, 2018)

Friedmann, John. 1986. “The World City Hypothesis” Development and Change 17(1): 69–

83.

Ghandi, Natwar, Yesim Yilmaz, Robert Zahradnik, and Marcy Edwards. 2009. “Washington,

District of Columbia, United States of America.” In Finance and Governance of

Capital Cities in Federal Systems, edited by Enid Slack and Rupak Chattopadhyay,

263–91. Montreal and Kingston, ON: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

Gilliland, Anthony. 2013. “Choosing the Federal Capital: A Comparative Study of the United

States, Canada and Australiaia.” In The Problem of the Capital City: New Research on

Federal Capitals and Their Territory, edited by Klaus-Jürgen Nagel, 25–60.

Generaltat de Catalunya, Institut d’Estudis Autonomics.

35 Goldsmith, Michael. 1995. “Autonomy and City Limits.” In Theories of Urban Politics,

edited by David Judge, Gerry Stoker, and Harold Wolman, 228–252. London: Sage

Publications.

Goldsmith, Michael. 2012. “Cities in Intergovernmental Systems.” In The Oxford Handbook

of Urban Politics, edited by Karen Mossberger, Susan E Clarke, and Peter John, 133–

151. Oxford University Press.

Goldsmith, Michael, and Edward Page. 1987. Central and Local Government Relations: A

Comparative Analysis of West European Unitary States. London: Sage Publications.

Gottmann, J. 1977. “The Role of Capital Cities.” Ekistics: The Problem and Science of

Human Settlements 44(264): 240–43.

Gurr, Ted Robert, and Desmond King. 1987. The State and the City. University of Chicago

Press.

Hamilton, Alexander, James Madison, and John Jay. 2005. The Federalist. Hackett

Publishing.

Harris, Charles Wesley. 1995. Congress and the Governance of the Nation’s Capital: The

Conflict of Federal and Local Interests. Georgetown University Press.

Hazelton Jr, George C. 1914. The National Capitol: Its Architecture, Art, and History. New

York: JF Taylor & Company.

Hooghe, and Gary Marks. 2003. “Unraveling the Central State, but How? Types of Multi-

Level Governance.” American Political Science Review 97 (2): 233–243.

Horak, Martin. 2012. “Conclusion: Understanding Multilevel Governance in Canada’s

Cities.” In Sites of Governance: Multilevel Governance and Policy Making in

Canada’s Big Cities, edited by Martin Horak and Robert Young, 339–370. Montreal

and Kingston, ON: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

36 Horak, Martin, and Robert Young, eds. 2012. Sites of Governance: Multilevel Governance

and Policy Making in Canada’s Big Cities. Montreal and Kingston, ON: McGill-

Queen’s University Press.

Hunter, Floyd. 1953. Community Power Structure: A Study of Decision Makers. Chapel Hill:

The University of North Carolina Press.

Hyra, Derek. 2017. Race, Class, and Politics in the Cappuccino City. University of Chicago

Press.

Hyra, Derek, and Sabiyha Prince, eds. 2016. Capital Dilemma: Growth and Inequality in

Washington, DC. New York and Oxon: Routledge.

Imbroscio, David. 1998. “Reformulating Urban Regime Theory: The Division of Labor

between State and Market Reconsidered.” Journal of Urban Affairs 20 (3): 233–248.

Imbroscio, David. 2013. “From redistribution to ownership: Toward an alternative urban

policy for America’s cities.” Urban Affairs Review 49 (6) (2013): 787–820.

Imbroscio, David, Thad Williamson, and Gar Alperovitz. 2003. “Local Policy Responses to

Globalization: Place-Based Ownership Models of Economic Enterprise.” Policy

Studies Journal 31 (1): 31–52.

Jonas, Andrew, and Kevin Ward. 2007. “Introduction to a Debate on City-Regions: New

Geographies of Governance, Democracy and Social Reproduction.” International

Journal of Urban and Regional Research 31 (1): 169–178.

Judd, Dennis R., and Todd Swanstrom. 2015. City Politics. Routledge.

Kantor, Paul, and Hank Savitch. 2005. “How to study comparative urban development

politics: A research note.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 29

(1): 135–151.

Kaufmann, David. 2018. Varieties of Capital Cities: The Competitiveness Challenge for

Secondary Capital Cities. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

37 Kaufmann, David, Martin Warland, Heike Mayer, and Fritz Sager. 2016. “Bern’s Positioning

Strategies: Escaping the Fate of a Secondary Capital City?” Cities 53: 120–129.

Kaufmann, David and Tobias Arnold. 2017. “Strategies of Cities in Globalized Interurban

Competition: The Locational Policies Framework.” Urban Studies. Early Online.

Kaufmann, David and Fritz Sager. 2018. “How to organize secondary capital city regions:

Institutional drivers of locational policy coordination.” Governance. Early Online.

Krieken, Peter van, and David McKay. 2005. “Introduction.” In The Hague: Legal Capital of

the World, edited by Peter van Krieken and David McKay, 3 – 28. The Hague: T-M-C

Asser Press.

Kübler, Daniel. 2009. “Bern, Switzerland.” In Finance and Governance of Capital Cities in

Federal Systems, edited by Enid Slack and Rupak Chattopadhyay, 238–62. Montreal

and Kingston, ON: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

Kübler, Daniel, and Michael A Pagano. 2012. “Urban Politics as Multilevel Analysis.” The

Oxford Handbook of Urban Politics, edited by Karen Mossberger, Susan E. Clarke,

and Peter John, 114 – 129. Oxford University Press.

Lambelet, Sébastien. 2017. “Filling the Resource Gap of Urban Regime Analysis to Make it

Travel in Time and Space.” Urban Affairs Review. Early Online.

Logan, John, and Harvey Molotch. 1987. Urban Fortunes: The Political Economy of Place.

University of California Press.

Mayer, Heike, Fritz Sager, David Kaufmann and Martin Warland. 2016. “Capital city

dynamics: Linking regional innovation systems, locational policies and policy

regimes”, Cities 51: 11–20.

Mayer, Heike, Fritz Sager, David Kaufmann and Martin Warland. 2018. The Political

Economy of Capital Cities. London: Routledge.

Molotch, Harvey. 1976. “The City as a Growth Machine: Toward a Political Economy of

Place.” American Journal of Sociology, 309–332.

38 Moser, Sarah. 2010. “Putrajaya: Malaysia’s New Federal Administrative Capital.” Cities 27

(4): 285–297.

Nagel, Klaus-Jürgen. 2013a. “Representation for the Taxed? Projects to End the Asymmetry

of Washington DC and Why (Most of Them) Have Failed.” In The Problem of the

Capital City: New Research on Federal Capitals and Their Territory, edited by Klaus-

Jürgen Nagel, 61–82. Generaltat de Catalunya, Institut d’Estudis Autonomics.

Nagel, Klaus-Jürgen. 2013b. The Problem of the Capital City: New Research on Federal

Capitals and Their Territory. Generaltat de Catalunya, Institut d’Estudis Autonomics.

O’Cleireacain, Carol. 1997. The Orphaned Capital: Adopting the Right Revenues for the

District of Columbia. Brookings Institution Press.

OECD. 2014. OECD Fiscal Decentralization Database. Organisation for Economic

Cooperation and Development (OECD). http://www.oecd.org/tax/federalism/fiscal-

decentralisation-database.htm (accessed September 10, 2018)

Peterson, Paul. 1981. City Limits. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Pierre, Jon. 2005. “Comparative Urban Governance Uncovering Complex Causalities.” Urban

Affairs Review 40 (4): 446–462.

Pierre, Jon. 2014. “Can Urban Regimes Travel in Time and Space? Urban Regime Theory,

Urban Governance Theory, and Comparative Urban Politics.” Urban Affairs Review.

Rossman, Vadim. 2017. Capital Cities: Varieties and Patterns of Development and

Relocation. Abingdon and New York: Routledge.

Rowat, Donald C. 1968. “The Problems of Governing Federal Capitals.” Canadian Journal of

Political Science 1 (3): 345–356.

Rowat, Donald Cameron. 1973. The Government of Federal Capitals. Toronto: University of

Toronto Press.

Sager Fritz, Karin Ingold und Andreas Balthasar. 2017. Policy-Analyse in der Schweiz.

Besonderheiten, Theorien, Beispiele. Zürich: NZZ Libro.

39 Sassen, Saskia. 1991. The Global City: New York, London, Tokyo. Princeton: Princeton

University Press.

Savitch, Hank, and Paul Kantor. 2002. Cities in the International Marketplace: The Political

Economy of Urban Development in North America and Western Europe. Princeton:

Princeton University Press.

Sellers, Jefferey. 2005. “Re-placing the nation: An agenda for comparative urban politics.”

Urban Affairs Review 40 (4): 419–445.

Sellers, Jefferey, and Anders Lidström. 2007. “Decentralization, Local Government, and the

Welfare State.” Governance 20 (4): 609–632.

Siegel, David. 2009. “Ontario.” In Foundations of Governance: Municipal Government in

Canada’s Provinces, edited by Andrew Sancton and Robert Young, 20–69. University

of Toronto Press.

Slack, Enid, and Rupak Chattopadhyay. 2009. Finance and Governance of Capital Cities in

Federal Systems. Montreal and Kingston, ON: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

Stadler, Peter. 1971. “Die Haupstadtfrage in Der Schweiz: 1798-1848.” Schweizerische

Zeitschrift Für Geschichte 21: 526–582.

Steytler, Nico. 2009. “Cape Town and Pretoria, South Africa” In Finance and Governance of

Capital Cities in Federal Systems, edited by Enid Slack and Rupak Chattopadhyay,

198–220. Montreal and Kingston, ON: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

Stone, Clarence. 1989. Regime Politics: Governing Atlanta, 1946-1988. University Press of

Kansas Lawrence, KS.

Stone, Clarence. 1993. “Urban Regimes and the Capacity to Govern: A Political Economy

Approach.” Journal of Urban Affairs 15 (1): 1–28.

Stone, Clarence. 2015. “Reflections on Regime Politics: From Governing Coalition to Urban

Political Order.” Urban Affairs Review 51 (1): 101–137.

40 Sturtevant, Lisa. 2013. “The New Distric of Columbia: What Population Growth and

Democraphic Change Mean for the City.” Journal of Urban Affairs, 1–26.

Swyngedouw, Erik, Frank Moulaert, and Arantxa Rodriguez. 2002. “Neoliberal Urbanization

in Europe: Large–Scale Urban Development Projects and the New Urban Policy.” In

Spaces of Neoliberalism. Urban Restructuring in North America and Eastern Europe.,

edited by Neil Brenner, 195–229. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Tammaru, Tiit, Maarten van Ham, Szymon Marcińczak, and Sako Musterd, eds. 2015. Socio-

Economic Segregation in European Capital Cities: East Meets West. Routledge.

Tassonyi, Almos. 2009. “Ottawa, Canada.” In Finance and Governance of Capital Cities in

Federal Systems, edited by Enid Slack and Rupak Chattopadhyay, 55–78. Montreal

and Kingston, ON: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

Taylor, John. 2011. “The Crippling Influence of the National Authority.” In The Unimagined

Canadian Capital: Challenges for the Federal Capital Region, edited by Rupak

Chattopadhyay and Gilles Paquet, 27–34. Ottawa: Invenire Books.

The District of Columbia. 2012. The Five–year Economic Development Strategy Ofor the

District of Columbia.

United States Census Bureau. 2015. “2013 State and Local Government Finances.”

http://www.census.gov/govs/local/ (accessed September 10, 2018)

Uyarra, Elvira. 2010. “What is evolutionary about ‘regional systems of innovation’?

Implications for regional policy.” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 20 (1): 115–

137. van der Heiden, Nico. 2010. Urban Foreign Policy and Domestic Dilemmas: Insights from

Swiss and EU City-Regions. European Consortium for Political Research Press.

Weaver, Timothy. 2016. Blazing the Neoliberal Trail: Urban Political Development in the

United States and the United Kingdom. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania

Press.

41 Weaver, Timothy. 2018. “By Design or by Default: Varieties of Neoliberal Urban

Development.” Urban Affairs Review 54(2): 234–66.

Wolman, Harold, Jan Chadwick, Anna Karruz, Julia Friedman, and Garry Young. 2007.

“Capital Cities and Their National Governments: Washington, D.C. in Comparative

Perspective.” George Washington University, Institute of Public Policy, Working

Paper No. 30.

Young, Robert. 2012. “Introduction: Multilevel Governance and Its Central Research

Questions in Canadian Cities.” In Sites of Governance: Multilevel Governance and

Policy Making in Canada’s Big Cities, edited by Martin Horak and Robert Young, 3–

25. Montreal and Kingston, ON: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

Author biography

David Kaufmann is a postdoctoral researcher at the KPM Center for Public Management,

University of Bern, Switzerland. He is specialized in policy studies with a focus on urban policies and migration policies. A more in-depth study of secondary capital cities is published in the book Varieties of Capital Cities: The Competitiveness Challenge for Secondary Capital

Cities (Edward Elgar Publishing, 2018).

42 Appendix

Table A1: Anonymized list of interview partners

Interview City Role Relevant affiliation(s) number Private actor/Interest 1 Bern Partner and lawyer group representative Private actor/Interest Swiss bank 2 Bern group representative Swiss Post 3 Bern Public official City of Bern National politician 4 Bern Public official Mayor of a Swiss city Private actor/Interest Local firm 5 Bern group representative National politician Economic development 6 Bern Canton of Bern agent International firm Private actor/Interest Employer Association canton of Bern 7 Bern group representative Chamber of Commerce of the canton of Bern 8 Bern Expert University of Bern, Private actor/Interest Swiss Venture Club 9 Bern group representative Venture capitalist 10 Bern Public official Canton of Bern 11 Bern Public official Municipality of Köniz Bern Public official Federal Office for Spatial Development 12 Bern Public official Federal Office for Spatial Development Private actor/Interest National Politician 13 Bern group representative Ex-member, City Council of Bern Economic development Economic Area of Bern (Bern 14 Bern agent Wirtschaftsraum) Private actor/Interest 15 Bern Local firm group representative 16 Bern Expert Journalist and author Economic development 17 Bern Capital Region Switzerland agent Mayor of a Swiss City 18 Bern Public official National politician 19 Bern Expert Consultant 20 The Hague Public official City of The Hague Private actor/Interest 21 The Hague Entrepreneur group representative 22 The Hague Expert Leiden University Economic development 23 The Hague The Hague Security Delta agent Private actor/Interest 24 The Hague International firm group representative The Hague Public official City of The Hague 25 The Hague Public official City of The Hague 26 The Hague Expert The Hague University of Applied Sciences 27 The Hague Public official City of The Hague Private actor/Interest The Hague Lawyer and partner group representative 28 Private actor/Interest Lawyer and partner The Hague group representative Erasmus University Rotterdam 29 The Hague Public official Dutch Ministry of Foreign Affairs

43 Economic development 30 The Hague West-Holland Foreign Investment Agency agent Economic development 31 The Hague InnovationQuarter agent 32 The Hague Expert Delft University of Technology 33 The Hague Public official City of The Hague 34 The Hague Expert Consultant Private actor/Interest Chamber of Commerce of Southwest 35 The Hague group representative Holland 36 The Hague Expert Centre for Innovation, Leiden University 37 The Hague Public official Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs 38 The Hague Public official Province South Holland Private actor/Interest 39 The Hague NGO group representative 40 The Hague Public official City of The Hague The Hague Expert Consultant 41 The Hague Expert Consultant The Hague Public official City of The Hague 42 The Hague Public official City of The Hague Economic development Metropolitan Region Rotterdam The The Hague agent Hague 43 Economic development Metropolitan Region Rotterdam The The Hague agent Hague 44 Ottawa Public official City of Ottawa Ottawa Private actor/Interest 45 Developer group representative 46 Ottawa Expert University of Ottawa 47 Ottawa Expert Forum of Federations 48 Ottawa Expert Ministry of Foreign Affairs Ottawa Economic development Ottawa Centre for Research and 49 agent Innovation Ottawa Private actor/Interest 50 Ottawa Chamber of Commerce group representative Ottawa Economic development 51 Ontario Centres of Excellence agent 52 Ottawa Public official National Capital Commission 53 Ottawa Public official Ottawa 2017 Bureau 54 Ottawa Public official National Capital Commission Ottawa Economic development 55 Invest Ottawa agent 56 Ottawa Public official FedDev Ontario Ottawa Private actor/Interest 57 Gatineau Chamber of Commerce group representative 58 Ottawa Expert University of Ottawa Ottawa Private actor/Interest Alcatel-Lucent 59 group representative Invest Ottawa Ottawa Economic development Information and Communications 60 agent Technology Council Ottawa Private actor/Interest 61 Kanata North Business Association group representative Ottawa Economic development Développement économique – CLD agent Gatineau 62 Ottawa Economic development Ville de Gatineau agent Ottawa Economic development 63 Invest Ottawa agent Ottawa Private actor/Interest Startup Grind Ottawa 64 group representative Entrepreneur 65 Washington D.C. Public official Department of Homeland Security

44 Economic development Metropolitan Washington Council of 66 Washington D.C. agent Governments Economic development 67 Washington D.C. Rockville Economic Development agent Private actor/Interest Developer 68 Washington D.C. group representative 2030 Business group Private actor/Interest 69 Washington D.C. Federal City Council group representative Private actor/Interest 70 Washington D.C. Northern Virginia Technology Council group representative 71 Washington D.C. Expert George Mason University Economic development Alexandria Economic Development Washington D.C. agent Partnership, Inc. 72 Economic development Alexandria Economic Development Washington D.C. agent Partnership, Inc. 73 Washington D.C. Public official District of Columbia, Office of Planning Washington D.C. Public official National Capital Planning Commission 74 Washington D.C. Public official National Capital Planning Commission Private actor/Interest 75 Washington D.C. D.C. Fiscal Policy Institute group representative Private actor/Interest 76 Washington D.C. Venture capitalist group representative 77 Washington D.C. Public official Washington D.C. Mayor's Office Economic development Washington D.C. Arlington Economic Development agent 78 Economic development Washington D.C. Arlington Economic Development agent 79 Washington D.C. Expert Brookings Institutions 80 Washington D.C. Expert Woodrow Wilson International Center 81 Washington D.C. Expert D.C. Appleseed Center for Law & Justice 82 Washington D.C. Expert George Washington University 83 Washington D.C. Expert Virginia Tech U.S. Office of Community Planning and 84 Washington D.C. Public official Development Private actor/Interest 85 Washington D.C. Lawyer and Partner group representative Private actor/Interest Downtown D.C. Business Improvement 86 Washington D.C. group representative District Private actor/Interest 87 Washington D.C. Greater Washington Board of Trade group representative Washington D.C. Expert George Washington University 88 Washington D.C. Expert George Washington University District of Columbia Government, Office 89 Washington D.C. Public official of Revenue Analysis

90 Washington D.C. Public official Washington D.C. Mayor's Office

91 Washington, D.C. Public official Congressional staffer

45