Wealth and Income Distribution: New Theories Needed for a New Era | VOX, CEPR’S Policy Portal
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
The Econometric Society European Region Aide Mémoire
The Econometric Society European Region Aide M´emoire March 22, 2021 1 European Standing Committee 2 1.1 Responsibilities . .2 1.2 Membership . .2 1.3 Procedures . .4 2 Econometric Society European Meeting (ESEM) 5 2.1 Timing and Format . .5 2.2 Invited Sessions . .6 2.3 Contributed Sessions . .7 2.4 Other Events . .8 3 European Winter Meeting (EWMES) 9 3.1 Scope of the Meeting . .9 3.2 Timing and Format . 10 3.3 Selection Process . 10 4 Appendices 11 4.1 Appendix A: Members of the Standing Committee . 11 4.2 Appendix B: Winter Meetings (since 2014) and Regional Consultants (2009-2013) . 27 4.3 Appendix C: ESEM Locations . 37 4.4 Appendix D: Programme Chairs ESEM & EEA . 38 4.5 Appendix E: Invited Speakers ESEM . 39 4.6 Appendix F: Winners of the ESEM Awards . 43 4.7 Appendix G: Countries in the Region Europe and Other Areas ........... 44 This Aide M´emoire contains a detailed description of the organisation and procedures of the Econometric Society within the European Region. It complements the Rules and Procedures of the Econometric Society. It is maintained and regularly updated by the Secretary of the European Standing Committee in accordance with the policies and decisions of the Committee. The Econometric Society { European Region { Aide Memoire´ 1 European Standing Committee 1.1 Responsibilities 1. The European Standing Committee is responsible for the organisation of the activities of the Econometric Society within the Region Europe and Other Areas.1 It should undertake the consideration of any activities in the Region that promote interaction among those interested in the objectives of the Society, as they are stated in its Constitution. -
KALDOR's WAR J.E. King*
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 1441-5429 DISCUSSION PAPER 25/07 KALDOR’S WAR * J.E. King * Department of Economics and Finance, La Trobe University, Victoria 3086, Australia Email: [email protected] © 2007 J.E. King All rights reserved. No part of this paper may be reproduced in any form, or stored in a retrieval system, without the prior written permission of the author. Introduction In the 1930s the young Nicholas Kaldor (1908-1986) established himself as one of the world’s leading economic theorists (King 2007). As with so many lives, Kaldor’s was turned around by the Second World War. This was not the result of enemy action. Although his family in Hungary suffered grievously at the hands of the Nazis, Nicky himself was not called to arms. While he had become a British citizen in 1934, and made enquiries about joining the Civil Service as an economic advisor, he was told that his Hungarian origins would disqualify him from anything other than menial duties in Whitehall. He therefore decided to stay in academia, and relocated to Cambridge with his remaining LSE colleagues in September 1939, when the Ministry of Works took over the School’s Aldwych site in central London .1 Now based at Peterhouse, Kaldor was able to deepen old friendships and develop new ones. A ‘war circus’ of economists began to operate, named by analogy with the ‘Cambridge circus’ of young theorists who had interrogated Keynes in 1930- 1 after the publication of the Treatise on Money and helped to focus his mind on the revolutionary breakthrough of the General Theory (Moggridge 1995, pp. -
Nicholas Kaldor
PROFILES OF WORLD ECONOMISTS 26 NICHOLAS KALDOR NICHOLAS KALDOR – ONE OF THE FIRST CRITICS OF MONETARISM doc. Ing. Ján Iša, DrSc. Known in economic circles as one of the thought in several fields, but it was his work founders of Post-Keynesianism, Nicholas on the theory of distribution and economic Kaldor (1908–1986) ranks among the worl- growth that stirred the greatest reaction. d's foremost economists of the second half Less well-known, however, is Kaldor's con- of the 20th century. Kaldor contributed to tribution to monetary theory, which has long the development of modern economic been standing quietly in the background. Nicholas Kaldor was born in Budapest on 12 May 1908. rous Third World countries, as well as an advisor to central His father was a lawyer and his mother came from wealthy banks and to the United Nations Economic Commission for business family. Although his father had wanted him to Latin America. Most significant, however, was his role as an study law, Kaldor opted for economics. He began his studi- advisor to Labour finance ministers from 1964 to 1968 and es at the University of Berlin in 1925 and then after two 1974 to 1976. After completing his two-year mission in years moved to the London School of Economics (LSE), Geneva in 1949, Kaldor began to work at Cambridge Uni- from which he graduated in 1930. He remained at the LSE versity and became, as John Maynard Keynes had been, a as lecturer until 1947, during which time his colleagues inc- fellow of King's College, Cambridge. -
Economics Annual Review 2018-2019
ECONOMICS REVIEW 2018/19 CELEBRATING FIRST EXCELLENCE AT YEAR LSE ECONOMICS CHALLENGE Faculty Interviews ALUMNI NEW PANEL APPOINTMENTS & VISITORS RESEARCH CENTRE BRIEFINGS 1 CONTENTS 2 OUR STUDENTS 3 OUR FACULTY 4 RESEARCH UPDATES 5 OUR ALUMNI 2 WELCOME TO THE 2018/19 EDITION OF THE ECONOMICS ANNUAL REVIEW This has been my first year as Head of the outstanding contributions to macroeconomics and Department of Economics and I am proud finance) and received a BA Global Professorship, will and honoured to be at the helm of such a be a Professor of Economics. John will be a School distinguished department. The Department Professor and Ronald Coase Chair in Economics. remains world-leading in education and research, Our research prowess was particularly visible in the May 2019 issue of the Quarterly Journal of Economics, and many efforts are underway to make further one of the top journals in the profession: the first four improvements. papers out of ten in that issue are co-authored by current colleagues in the Department and two more by We continue to attract an extremely talented pool of our former PhD students Dave Donaldson and Rocco students from a large number of applicants to all our Macchiavello. Rocco is now in the LSE Department programmes and to place our students in the most of Management, as is Noam Yuchtman, who published sought-after jobs. This year, our newly-minted PhD another paper in the same issue. This highlights how student Clare Balboni made us particularly proud by the strength of economics is growing throughout LSE, landing a job as Assistant Professor at MIT, one of the reinforcing our links to other departments as a result. -
Field Experiments in Development Economics1 Esther Duflo Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Field Experiments in Development Economics1 Esther Duflo Massachusetts Institute of Technology (Department of Economics and Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab) BREAD, CEPR, NBER January 2006 Prepared for the World Congress of the Econometric Society Abstract There is a long tradition in development economics of collecting original data to test specific hypotheses. Over the last 10 years, this tradition has merged with an expertise in setting up randomized field experiments, resulting in an increasingly large number of studies where an original experiment has been set up to test economic theories and hypotheses. This paper extracts some substantive and methodological lessons from such studies in three domains: incentives, social learning, and time-inconsistent preferences. The paper argues that we need both to continue testing existing theories and to start thinking of how the theories may be adapted to make sense of the field experiment results, many of which are starting to challenge them. This new framework could then guide a new round of experiments. 1 I would like to thank Richard Blundell, Joshua Angrist, Orazio Attanasio, Abhijit Banerjee, Tim Besley, Michael Kremer, Sendhil Mullainathan and Rohini Pande for comments on this paper and/or having been instrumental in shaping my views on these issues. I thank Neel Mukherjee and Kudzai Takavarasha for carefully reading and editing a previous draft. 1 There is a long tradition in development economics of collecting original data in order to test a specific economic hypothesis or to study a particular setting or institution. This is perhaps due to a conjunction of the lack of readily available high-quality, large-scale data sets commonly available in industrialized countries and the low cost of data collection in developing countries, though development economists also like to think that it has something to do with the mindset of many of them. -
Welfare Goal in Antitrust Journals.Sagepub.Com/Home/Abx
The Antitrust Bulletin 1-39 ª The Author(s) 2018 The Unsound Theory Behind Article reuse guidelines: sagepub.com/journals-permissions the Consumer (and Total) DOI: 10.1177/0003603X18807802 Welfare Goal in Antitrust journals.sagepub.com/home/abx Mark Glick* Abstract This is the first installment of a two-part commentary on the New Brandeis School (the “New Brandeisians”) in Antitrust. In this first part, I examine why the New Brandeisians are correct to reject the consumer welfare standard. Instead of arguing, as the New Brandeisians do, that the consumer welfare standard leads to unacceptable outcomes, I argue that the consumer or total welfare standard was theoretically flawed and unrigorous from the start. My basic argument is that antitrust law addresses the impact of business strategies in markets where there are winners and losers. For example, in the classical exclusionary monopolist case, the monopolist’s conduct is enjoined to increase competition in the affected market or markets. As a result of the intervention, consumers benefit, but the monopolist is worse off. One hundred years of analysis by the welfare economists themselves shows that in such situations “welfare” or “consumer welfare” cannot be used as a reliable guide to assess the results of antitrust policy. Pareto Optimality does not apply in these situations because there are losers. Absent an ability to divine “cardinal utility” from obser- vations of market behavior, other approaches such as consumer surplus, and compensating and equivalent variation cannot be coherently extended from the individual level to markets. The Kaldor-Hicks compensation principle that is in standard use in law and economics was created to address problems of interpersonal comparisons of utility and the existence of winners and losers. -
Capitalism and Society
Capitalism and Society Volume 3, Issue 3 2008 Article 2 The Many Contributions of Edmund Phelps: American Economic Association Luncheon Speech Honoring the 2006 Nobel Laureate in Economics James J. Heckman∗ ∗University of Chicago; Geary Institute, University College Dublin; and the American Bar Foundation Copyright c 2008 The Berkeley Electronic Press. All rights reserved. Heckman: The Many Contributions of Edmund Phelps The following speech was given at the American Economic Association Annual Meetings, New Orleans, January 5, 2008. This draft was revised August 14, 2008. This research was supported by the American Bar Foundation and the Geary Institute, University College Dublin. Throughout his career, Ned Phelps has made fundamental contributions to growth theory, macroeconomics, public finance and social welfare theory that deserved the high recognition accorded by the Nobel Prize committee in October, 2006. He is one of the most original thinkers in economics. The citation issued when Phelps was made a Distinguished Fellow of the American Economic Association still speaks for the community of economists today: The collection of papers from a conference that he organized, Microeconomic Foundations, pushed questions about theoretical foundations to the front of the research agenda and changed forever our notion of what constitutes an acceptable macroeconomic theory... Throughout his career Phelps has been willing to step outside of the existing analytical framework and rethink the basic issues... He continues to push theorists and policy makers to rethink their analysis of expectations, inflation, and unemployment and to set a high standard for what it means to be an economic theorist. (American Economic Association 2001) Phelps’s output of original concepts, models and theorems has been vast. -
Anticipations of the Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen Mechanism1
Anticipations of the Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen Mechanism1 André Roncaglia de Carvalho2 ABSTRACT This paper aims to contribute to the literature on the intellectual history of the economics discipline in Brazil and its place within the network of international transmission of economic ideas, by delving into the history of the Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen mechanism, namely: the behavior of periodically-adjusted fixed nominal wages under persistent inflationary conditions (the sawtooth wages model). Ranging from the immediate post-War years to the end of the 1960s, our narrative reveals that prior to Nicholas Kaldor’s statement of the sawtooth model of real wages, other contributions sprung from various traditions. To this effect, we underline the discoursive appraisal by Celso Furtado (1954) and the early neoclassical model by Bent Hansen (1951), only to fit both of them in a broader historical context of the economics discipline, whereby the emergence of formal mathematical methods allows for the connection between this debate and the Operations Research Program in the North-American universities in the early 1950s. Keywords: chronic inflation, sawtooth model, formal mechanic models, Celso Furtado Operations Research Program RESUMO Este artigo busca contribuir com a literatura de história da ciência econômica no Brazil e seu lugar na rede internacional de transmissão das ideias econônomicas, por meio de uma análise da história do mecanismo Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen, qual seja: o comportamento de rendas nominais fixas com reajustamento periódico sob inflação -
Three Revolutions in Macroeconomics: Their Nature and Influence
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Laidler, David Working Paper Three revolutions in macroeconomics: Their nature and influence EPRI Working Paper, No. 2013-4 Provided in Cooperation with: Economic Policy Research Institute (EPRI), Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario Suggested Citation: Laidler, David (2013) : Three revolutions in macroeconomics: Their nature and influence, EPRI Working Paper, No. 2013-4, The University of Western Ontario, Economic Policy Research Institute (EPRI), London (Ontario) This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/123484 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen -
Plurality in Teaching Macroeconomics
Munich Personal RePEc Archive Plurality in Teaching Macroeconomics Azad, Rohit The New School for Social Research, Columbia University, Jawaharlal Nehru University 1 October 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/80056/ MPRA Paper No. 80056, posted 08 Jul 2017 14:35 UTC Plurality in Teaching Macroeconomics Rohit Azad 1 Introduction In the aftermath of the Great Depression, there was turmoil in the field of Macroeconomics, which resulted in the Keynesian ‘revolution’. However, the current Great Recession, the worst crisis that capitalism has faced since then, has failed, at least so far, to generate an upheaval in the teaching and practice of Macroeconomics. This seems bizarre as if nothing has happened and the economists are just going about doing business as usual. Without going into the politics of why this is so, let me just focus on how Macroeconomics ought to be taught to students at the intermediate level, which gives them an overall perspective on the subject1. I must note that this article has been inspired by an editorial published in EPW [2013]. Macroeconomics as a subject proper came into existence with the writ- ings of John Maynard Keynes2. There were debates during his time about how to characterise a capitalist economy, most of these are still a part of the discussion among economists. Keynes [1936, 1937] argued that capitalism is a fundamentally unstable system so the state needs to intervene to control this instability. Keynes [1936] has been interpreted in different, often contradictory, ways. In today’s context, they can be broadly classified in two categories: Post Keynesian and New Keynesian. -
Consumption Smoothing in Island Economies: Can Public Insurance
University of Pennsylvania Economics Department November 1999 Consumption Smoothing in Island Economies: Can Public Insurance Reduce Welfare? Orazio Attanasio University College, London Jos´e-V´ıctorR´ıos-Rull University of Pennsylvania, CEPR and NBER ABSTRACT In this paper we study the effects of certain types of public compulsory insurance arrangements for aggregate shocks on private allocations in environments with limited commitment. We show that this type of insurance can improve the wellbeing of private situations, but it can also deteriorate it. We also describe how different characteristics of the environment affect the role of public insurance. Using data on the Mexican PROGRESA program, we document the impact that some government programs have in crowding out private transfers. Keywords: Consumption Smoothing, Public Insurance, Incomplete Contracts. JEL E60, H30, D83. ¤ R´ıos-Rullthanks the National Science Foundation for Grant SBR-9309514 and the University of Pennsylvania Research Foundation for their support. Thanks to Fabrizio Perri for his comments and for his help with the code and to Tim Besley, Ethan Ligon and Robert Holzmann. Finally, we would like to thank Jos´eG´omezde Le´onand Patricia Muniz of PROGRESA for permission to use the data and Ana Santiago and Graciela Teruel for answering several questions about the data. Correspondence to Jos´e-V´ıctorR´ıos-Rull,Department of Economics, 3718 Locust Walk, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, 19104, USA. Phone 1-215-898-7767, Fax 1-215-573-4217, email [email protected]. 1 Introduction In a recent meeting between a World Bank official and a finance minister from a developing country in which the provision of an income support scheme or safety net was being dis- cussed the minister opposed strongly such scheme. -
Walking a Tightrope: the Neoclassical Synthesis in Action
Walking a tightrope: the neoclassical synthesis in action Michaël Assous1 Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, Phare Muriel Dal Pont Legrand Université Cote d’Azur, CNRS GREDEG Sonia Manseri Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, Phare Preliminary draft Abstract: The neoclassical synthesis which emerged in the late 1950s is associated to a specific understanding of the connection between short-run Keynesian and long-run neoclassical analyses. In the early 1960s, when economists from both Cambridges tried to revisit the conditions likely to guarantee the stability of long-run paths, this view was challenged. Then, issues related to the determinants of income distribution and expectations were raised. Our goal in this article is to discuss the significance of these findings and see how they challenged the whole neoclassical synthesis. Using original archives material from Duke and Cambridge (UK) Universities, the paper pays mostly attention to arguments raised by Frank Hahn, Nicholas Kaldor, Paul Samuelson, Armatya Sen and Robert Solow. 1 Contact : [email protected]. 1 Introduction In 1955, Samuelson introduced the notion of neoclassical synthesis in the third edition of his Economics. With the works of Robert Solow, James Meade, Trevor Swan and James Tobin, the synthesis started designating the outcome of a process by which short-run Keynesian and long-run neoclassical analyses were made compatible. In a nutshell, as long as the economy was supposed to be managed on a Keynesian-basis in the short-run, the neoclassical growth model was seen as the more appropriate tool to analyze and sustain full-employment growth. In addition, with the publication of Solow 1957 paper, the neoclassical synthesis meant a particular way to empirically deal with the long-run impact of technical progress.