Hedge Fund Monitor

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Hedge Fund Monitor CALLAN INSTITUTE Hedge Fund Monitor Second Quarter 2017 Bear Ahead? Beware of the ‘False Charge.’ FIDUCIARY PERSPECTIVES “Be Prepared” I wondered aloud whether the pot-clanging technique still —Boy Scout motto worked. It did not, he quickly countered; bears today were quite used to that behavior. Now you need to holler and throw rocks When I was a Boy Scout backpacking in the Sierras, I thought at them, he declared.1 I had timeless advice for dealing with black bears rummaging through campsites looking for an easy meal. The bears were Seeing me gob-smacked by his provocative advice, he crisply nimble climbers, and many had already figured out they could added an important disclosure, “But beware of the false snatch food that had been stored high in trees by ropes. charge.” Satisfied that he had dispensed sound advice with all the necessary disclosures, he left us to ponder the worst-case To manage this well-known risk of motivated bears, my troop scenarios implied in his warning. It seems today’s more condi- assigned shifts of scouts at night, rotating every hour, to watch tioned bear has learned how to check the resolve of its “coun- for marauding bears on the perimeter. To scare them off, the terparties.” More on this later. sentry clanged a pot or made some raucous noise. That simple but chaotic-sounding response seemed to work fine—the four- As we look at capital markets today, we must worry about footed opportunist, however hungry, usually got the hint and another kind of evolving bear that tests the courage of our con- strolled off in search of less noisy campsites with a hint of food victions. I am not referring to the traditional bear associated in the air. with steadily declining stock prices driven by a looming reces- sion or other deteriorating fundamentals, but rather one that Fast forward three decades. I recently returned to the Sierras, suddenly explodes on the scene with, er, barely the slightest sharing a similar backpacking experience with my son. We provocation. After a quick purge of market confidence, prices came upon what appeared to be an experienced backpacker. recover speedily and fears subside. Given how fast information Unshaven with layers of trail dust, he seemed qualified to dis- travels, these flash crashes are predictably unnerving, particu- pense advice about risks in the wilderness, including bears. larly for the casual observer or inexperienced investor. 1 For more tips on bear safety, see www.fs.fed.us/visit/know-before-you-go/bears. Knowledge. Experience. Integrity. 1 FIDUCIARY PERSPECTIVES (Continued) This Fiduciary Perspectives reviews recent historical examples of these sudden market dislocations that proved to be “false LTCM Crisis – September 1998 charges.” A cursory look at each event’s contributing factors A giant hedge fund’s normally unrelated trades became can help to illustrate what defines a temporary crash versus a related. LTCM’s collapse spooked markets but also bolstered more self-sustaining, systemic move like those that followed the credibility behind the ‘Greenspan Put,’ the view among the Dot-Com Bubble in the late ‘90s and the Global Financial traders that the Federal Reserve and other central bankers Crisis in the mid-2000s. Given this distinction, risk-seeking would act to stem market downturns. behaviors leave some investors more exposed than others to a sudden bear market rout and rebound. Aware of these behav- iors, investors can be better prepared to protect their own capi- One often-cited “correction” that did not translate into a full tal and position themselves for a safer investment experience. bear market surrounded the plight of Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) in 1998. Prior to its demise, this $4 bil- “Forewarned, forearmed.” lion hedge fund boasted a well-diversified portfolio loaded —Ancient Roman Proverb with a wide array of profitable but normally unrelated trades (e.g., yield curve arbitrage, emerging market debt, credit arbi- Respect Wildlife trage). Comforted by its diversification, LTCM applied a signifi- Although capital markets are much more efficient than in years cant degree of leverage (more than 25x its equity capital) to past, they are also potentially less stable in the short run. generate attractive risk-adjusted returns. However, as events Sudden crashes are the manifestation of this instability, and around the world took their toll on investor confidence (e.g., a they can affect broad markets, niche markets, or risk factors series of emerging market currency devaluations in Thailand within a market. Then, almost as soon as these markets crash, and Russia), the S&P 500 fell 15.4% in July and August 1998. prices find their footing and jump back to their former levels, In this nervous setting, the previously accretive leverage com- leaving witnesses to wonder what just happened. bined with unexpected illiquidity to create a toxic mix for LTCM in September. Under the supervision of a Federal Reserve Ill-fated investors can suffer permanent damage for one of two worried that the fund’s collapse would lead to broader losses reasons. First, investors lose their resolve and sell risk assets throughout the financial markets, LTCM’s creditors assumed to be in safe harbors until the risk becomes better understood, control of the portfolio. but the market rebounds too quickly for them to get reinvested. Second, counterparties to investors, such as financing agents The process illustrated how LTCM’s trading partners could or underlying equity investors, yank their capital when margin step away from their bids as they witnessed the equity capital calls are unanswered. Since catalysts of such flash crashes of an overly confident risk taker being consumed by widening may be tied to deep-seated fears, the sudden ferocity can spreads. However, once the losses affecting LTCM—as well prompt any nervous participant to run for cash, Treasury as Russia and other related trades—were realized and dissi- bonds, or other havens. pated, the market regained its footing and marched to higher highs by the end of 1998. That correction of 1998 proved to be History has a variety of market meltdowns that occurred sud- only a brief setback for other long-term investors of risk capital. denly, leading to massive losses for the least prepared, or most Based on that experience of “temporary” systemic risk being over-confident, investors. Then markets quickly recovered reversed, in part by the Fed as a buyer of last resort, the nar- without seemingly any lasting damage to those able to stay rative behind the “Greenspan Put” gained wider acceptance. invested or move more nimbly. Consider these three examples: That is, market speculators were emboldened to buy future 2 FIDUCIARY PERSPECTIVES (Continued) market dips during brief spasms when systemic risk bared its or even positive, depending on whether they were able to add to teeth, confident that central bankers would step in at moments their positions that had become even more attractively priced. of peril. Flash Crash – May 6, 2010 Quant Crash – August 2007 A meltdown in the Dow Jones Industrial Average over a matter Some quantitative strategies imploded under pressure from of minutes showed how fragile markets are, even with steps external events. Highly leveraged firms were exposed to by regulators to control market behavior. painful losses; those more defensively positioned were able to ride out the storm and emerge in good shape. During the recovery from the Global Financial Crisis (GFC), some key developments affecting the market’s underlying Another notable “false charge” scared investors in early August liquidity became increasingly apparent. To address the unsafe 2007 with the Quant Crash, when a confluence of events led to levels of leverage in the U.S. banking system that helped to losses of 30% or more, primarily in quantitatively driven strat- precipitate the GFC, the Dodd-Frank legislation effectively egies with highly levered equity capital. These strategies bet barred financial institutions backed by federal deposit guar- on the mean-reverting relationships between overvalued and antees from providing market liquidity. Consequently, when undervalued securities. Since such strategies are not neces- markets fall to attractive levels, these potential buyers with big sarily betting on the direction of equity markets, broader market balance sheets are less able to buy when others are frantically participants were only marginally affected. Because managers selling regardless of price. of quantitative strategies often have similar, if not identical, trades with varying degrees of leverage, their equity at stake is Meanwhile, as a result of SEC regulations to promote efficient subject to counterparty risk. markets, high-frequency trading firms assumed a growing presence in the most liquid markets. These firms, with their However liquid the underlying factor exposures were, the lever- highly automated order-generation processes, aggressively age needed to make those strategies profitable enough to pursue tested the market’s bids and offers to identify pending trades with scale was a key issue. When significant losses occurred, from larger market-moving investors like mutual funds. Being even if not realized, the counterparties could take full control of able to discern when to trade in front of those orders became those positions to protect themselves while demanding more a profitable business. equity capital from the affected manager. The highly leveraged quant managers unable to provide that capital realized losses On May 6, 2010, the combined effect of the sidelining of when the prime brokers liquidated their positions. Others with massive balance sheets and rise of high-frequency traders less leverage, or more equity capital to contribute, were able to contributed to a self-sustaining market sell-off. With the retain positions, even while the liquidation process caused the Greek debt crisis agitating investors, the Dow Jones Industrial relative value spreads to widen to more painful levels.
Recommended publications
  • The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction By
    “The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction” Speech given by Charles Bean, Deputy Governor for Monetary Policy and Member of the Monetary Policy Committee, Bank of England Given at the Schumpeter Lecture, Annual Congress of the European Economic Association, Barcelona 25 August 2009 I am grateful for the assistance of Adrian Penalver. The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of either the Bank of England or the Monetary Policy Committee. 1 All speeches are available online at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/default.aspx Summary Charles Bean, the Bank of England’s Deputy Governor, Monetary Policy, was invited to deliver the Schumpeter lecture at the Annual Congress of the European Economic Association. The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction, looks back at the causes of the financial crisis and subsequent recession. He argues that much of what went wrong can be analysed using standard economic tools. The Great Moderation was a period of unusually stable macroeconomic activity in advanced economies. This was partly thanks to good luck, including the integration of emerging market countries into the global economy, and partly a dividend from structural economic changes and better policy frameworks. The longer this stability persisted, the more markets became convinced of its permanence and risk premia became extremely low. Real short and long term interest rates were also low due to a combination of loose monetary policy, particularly in the US, and strong savings rates in a number of surplus countries. Low interest rates and low apparent risk created strong incentives for financial institutions to become highly geared.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tale of Two Great Crises
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Fratianni, Michele; Giri, Federico Working Paper The tale of two great crises FinMaP-Working Paper, No. 51 Provided in Cooperation with: Collaborative EU Project FinMaP - Financial Distortions and Macroeconomic Performance, Kiel University et al. Suggested Citation: Fratianni, Michele; Giri, Federico (2015) : The tale of two great crises, FinMaP-Working Paper, No. 51, Kiel University, FinMaP - Financial Distortions and Macroeconomic Performance, Kiel This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/125823 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu The Tale of Two Great Crises Michele Fratianni∗ Federico Giriy December 14, 2015 Abstract The great depression of 1929 and the great financial crisis of 2008 have been the two big events of the last 75 years.
    [Show full text]
  • What Is Past Is Prologue: the History of the Breakdown of Economic Models Before and During the 2008 Financial Crisis
    McCormac 1 What is Past is Prologue: The History of the Breakdown of Economic Models Before and During the 2008 Financial Crisis By: Ethan McCormac Political Science and History Dual Honors Thesis University of Oregon April 25th, 2016 Reader 1: Gerald Berk Reader 2: Daniel Pope Reader 3: George Sheridan McCormac 2 Introduction: The year 2008, like its predecessor 1929, has established itself in history as synonymous with financial crisis. By December 2008 Lehman Brothers had entered bankruptcy, Bear Sterns had been purchased by JP Morgan Chase, AIG had been taken over by the United States government, trillions of dollars in asset wealth had evaporated and Congress had authorized $700 billion in Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) funds to bailout different parts of the U.S. financial system.1 A debt-deflationary- derivatives crisis had swept away what had been labeled Alan Greenspan’s “Great Moderation” and exposed the cascading weaknesses of the global financial system. What had caused the miscalculated risk-taking and undercapitalization at the core of the system? Part of the answer lies in the economic models adopted by policy makers and investment bankers and the actions they took licensed by the assumptions of these economic models. The result was a risk heavy, undercapitalized, financial system primed for crisis. The spark that ignited this unstable core lay in the pattern of lending. The amount of credit available to homeowners increased while lending standards were reduced in a myopic and ultimately counterproductive credit extension scheme. The result was a Housing Bubble that quickly turned into a derivatives boom of epic proportions.
    [Show full text]
  • Lessons from the Great American Real Estate Boom and Bust of the 1920S
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LESSONS FROM THE GREAT AMERICAN REAL ESTATE BOOM AND BUST OF THE 1920S Eugene N. White Working Paper 15573 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15573 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2009 For their comments and suggestions, I would especially like to thank Lee Alston, Michael Bordo, Richard Grossman, Kris Mitchener, Carolyn Moehling, John Landon-Lane, Hugh Rockoff, Kenneth Snowden, Peter Temin, and the participants of seminars at Columbia University, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Free University of Brussels, the German Historical Institute (Washington, D.C.), the Harvard Business School, the NBER Summer Institute, Rutgers University, the Universitat Pompeu Fabra, the University of Oslo, and the XVth World Economic History Conference, Utrecht. The view expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2009 by Eugene N. White. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Lessons from the Great American Real Estate Boom and Bust of the 1920s Eugene N. White NBER Working Paper No. 15573 December 2009 JEL No. E5,G01,G18,G21,N12,N22 ABSTRACT Although long obscured by the Great Depression, the nationwide “bubble” that appeared in the early 1920s and burst in 1926 was similar in magnitude to the recent real estate boom and bust.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Market Bubbles and Crashes
    Financial Market Bubbles and Crashes One would think that economists would by now have already developed a solid grip on how financial bubbles form and how to measure and compare them. This is not the case. Despite the thousands of articles in the professional literature and the millions of times that the word “bubble” has been used in the business press, there still does not appear to be a cohesive theory or persuasive empirical approach with which to study bubble and crash conditions. This book presents what is meant to be a plausible and accessible descriptive theory and empirical approach to the analysis of such financial market conditions. It advances this framework through application of standard econometric methods to its central idea, which is that financial bubbles reflect urgent short side – rationed demand. From this basic idea, an elasticity of variance concept is developed. The notion that easy credit provides fuel for bubbles is supported. It is further shown that a behavioral risk premium can probably be measured and related to the standard equity risk–premium models in a way that is consistent with conventional theory. Harold L. Vogel was ranked as top entertainment industry analyst for ten years by Institutional Investor magazine and was the senior entertainment industry analyst at Merrill Lynch for seventeen years. He is a chartered financial analyst (C.F.A.) and served on the New York State Governor’s Motion Picture and Television Advisory Board and as an adjunct professor at Columbia University’s Graduate School of Business. He also taught at the University of Southern California’s MFA (Peter Stark) film program and at the Cass Business School in London.
    [Show full text]
  • Regulatory Reform and the Federal Reserve by Allan H. Meltzer the Allan H. Meltzer University Professor of Political Economy A
    Regulatory Reform and the Federal Reserve By Allan H. Meltzer The Allan H. Meltzer University Professor of Political Economy and Visiting Scholar at the American Enterprise Institute Testimony, July 9, Subcommittee on Monetary Policy, House Committee on Financial Services Thank you for the opportunity to present my appraisal of the administration’s proposal for regulatory changes. I will confine most of my comments to the role of the Federal Reserve as a systemic regulator and will offer an alternative proposal. I share the belief that change is needed and long delayed, but appropriate change must protect the public, not bankers. During much of the past 15 years, I have written three volumes entitled A History of the Federal Reserve. Working with two assistants we have read virtually all of the minutes of the Board of Governors, the Federal Open Market Committee, and the Directors of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. We have also read many of the staff papers and internal memos supporting decisions. I speak from that perspective. Two findings are very relevant to the role of the Federal Reserve. First, I do not know of any clear examples in which the Federal Reserve acted in advance to head off a crisis or a series of banking or financial failures. We know that the Federal Reserve did nothing about thrift industry failures in the 1980s. Thrift failures cost taxpayers $ 150 billion. AIG, Fannie and Freddie will be much more costly. Of course, the Fed did not have responsibility for the thrift industry, but many thrift failures posed a threat to the financial system that the Fed should have tried to mitigate.
    [Show full text]
  • Moral Hazard Misconceptions: the Case of the Greenspan Put∗
    Moral Hazard Misconceptions: the Case of the Greenspan Put∗ Gideon Bornstein Guido Lorenzoni Northwestern University Northwestern University December 2017 Abstract Policy discussions on financial regulation tend to assume that whenever a correc- tive policy is used ex post to ameliorate the effects of a crisis, there are negative side effects in terms of moral hazard ex ante. This paper shows that this is not a gen- eral theoretical prediction, focusing on the case of monetary policy interventions ex post. In particular, we show that if the central bank does not intervene by monetary easing following a crisis, an aggregate demand externality makes borrowing ex ante inefficient. If instead the central bank follows the optimal discretionary policy and intervenes to stabilize asset prices and real activity, we show examples in which the aggregate demand externality disappears, reducing the need for ex ante intervention. ∗For very useful comments we thank Eduardo Davila, Olivier Jeanne, the editor, and two referees. 1 1 Introduction Many economists and commentators have remarked that the conduct of interest policy by the central bank can affect the incentives of the financial sector. In particular, a com- mon complaint is that the so called “Greenspan put” encourages excessive leverage and risk taking by banks. The argument goes as follows. Suppose that when an adverse shock drives down asset prices, the central bank intervenes systematically by lowering interest rates. This becomes an implicit commitment to prop up asset prices in times of distress and encourages banks and other financial players to borrow more and take on more risk ex ante.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Bank Activism Duke Law Journal, Vol
    Central Bank Activism Duke Law Journal, Vol. 71: __ (forthcoming) Christina Parajon Skinner † ABSTRACT—Today, the Federal Reserve is at a critical juncture in its evolution. Unlike any prior period in U.S. history, the Fed now faces increasing demands to expand its policy objectives to tackle a wide range of social and political problems—including climate change, income and racial inequality, and foreign and small business aid. This Article develops a framework for recognizing, and identifying the problems with, “central bank activism.” It refers to central bank activism as situations in which immediate public policy problems push central banks to aggrandize their power beyond the text and purpose of their legal mandates, which Congress has established. To illustrate, the Article provides in-depth exploration of both contemporary and historic episodes of central bank activism, thus clarifying the indicia of central bank activism and drawing out the lessons that past episodes should teach us going forward. The Article urges that, while activism may be expedient in the near term, there are long-term social costs. Activism undermines the legitimacy of central bank authority, erodes its political independence, and ultimately renders a weaker central bank. In the end, the Article issues an urgent call to resist the allure of activism. And it places front and center the need for vibrant public discourse on the role of a central bank in American political and economic life today. © 2021 Christina Parajon Skinner. Draft 2021-05-27 20:46. † Assistant Professor, The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania. This article benefited from feedback provided by workshop or conference participants at The Wharton School, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York .
    [Show full text]
  • Lessons from the Great American Real Estate Boom and Bust of the 1920S
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LESSONS FROM THE GREAT AMERICAN REAL ESTATE BOOM AND BUST OF THE 1920S Eugene N. White Working Paper 15573 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15573 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2009 For their comments and suggestions, I would especially like to thank Lee Alston, Michael Bordo, Richard Grossman, Kris Mitchener, Carolyn Moehling, John Landon-Lane, Hugh Rockoff, Kenneth Snowden, Peter Temin, and the participants of seminars at Columbia University, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Free University of Brussels, the German Historical Institute (Washington, D.C.), the Harvard Business School, the NBER Summer Institute, Rutgers University, the Universitat Pompeu Fabra, the University of Oslo, and the XVth World Economic History Conference, Utrecht. The view expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2009 by Eugene N. White. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Lessons from the Great American Real Estate Boom and Bust of the 1920s Eugene N. White NBER Working Paper No. 15573 December 2009 JEL No. E5,G01,G18,G21,N12,N22 ABSTRACT Although long obscured by the Great Depression, the nationwide “bubble” that appeared in the early 1920s and burst in 1926 was similar in magnitude to the recent real estate boom and bust. Fundamentals, including a post-war construction catch-up, low interest rates and a “Greenspan put,” helped to ignite the boom in the twenties, but alternative monetary policies would have only dampened not eliminated it.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding the Greenspan Standard by Alan S. Blinder And
    Understanding the Greenspan Standard by Alan S. Blinder and Ricardo Reis Princeton University September 12, 2005 Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City symposium, The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the Future, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 25-27, 2005. The authors are grateful for helpful discussions with Donald Kohn, Gregory Mankiw, Allan Meltzer, Christopher Sims, Lars Svensson, John Taylor, and other participants at the Jackson Hole conference—none of whom are implicated in our conclusions. We also thank Princeton’s Center for Economic Policy Studies for financial support. I. Introduction Alan Greenspan was sworn in as Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System almost exactly 18 years ago. At the time, the Reagan administration was being rocked by the Iran-contra scandal. The Berlin Wall was standing tall while, in the Soviet Union, Mikhail Gorbachev had just presented proposals for perestroika. The stock market had not crashed since 1929 and, probably by coincidence, Prozac had just been released on the market. The New York Mets, having won the 1986 World Series, were the reigning champions of major league baseball. A lot can change in 18 years. Turning to the narrower world of monetary policy, central banks in 1987 still doted on money growth rates and spoke in tongues—when indeed they spoke at all, which was not often. Inflation targeting had yet to be invented in New Zealand, and the Taylor rule was not even a gleam in John Taylor’s eye. European monetary union seemed like a far-off dream. And the world-famous Jackson Hole conference was not yet world-famous.
    [Show full text]
  • The End of the Great Moderation
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive How better monetary statistics could have signaled the financial crisis Barnett, William A. and Chauvet, Marcelle University of Kansas 15 June 2010 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/24721/ MPRA Paper No. 24721, posted 31 Aug 2010 04:18 UTC How Better Monetary Statistics Could Have Signaled the Financial Crisis By William A. Barnett, University of Kansas and Marcelle Chauvet, University of California at Riverside June 15, 2010 ABSTRACT: This paper explores the disconnect of Federal Reserve data from index number theory. A consequence could have been the decreased systemic-risk misperceptions that contributed to excess risk taking prior to the housing bust. We find that most recessions in the past 50 years were preceded by more contractionary monetary policy than indicated by simple-sum monetary data. Divisia monetary aggregate growth rates were generally lower than simple-sum aggregate growth rates in the period preceding the Great Moderation, and higher since the mid 1980s. Monetary policy was more contractionary than likely intended before the 2001 recession and more expansionary than likely intended during the subsequent recovery. KEY WORDS: Measurement error, monetary aggregation, Divisia index, aggregation, monetary policy, index number theory, financial crisis, great moderation, Federal Reserve. JEL CLASSIFICATION CODE: E40, E52, E58, C43, E32 1. Introduction 1.1. The Great Moderation and the Current Crisis Over the past couple of decades, there has been an increasingly widely accepted view that monetary policy had dramatically improved. In fact, some attribute this as the cause of the “Great Moderation” in the economy‟s dynamics, by which output volatility had decreased substantially since the mid 1980s.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tale of Two Great Crises
    The Tale of Two Great Crises Michele Fratianni∗ Federico Giriy February 1, 2016 Abstract The great depression of 1929 and the great financial crisis of 2008 have been the two big events of the last 75 years. Not only have they produced serious economic consequences but they also changed our view of economics and policymaking. The aim of this work is to compare these two great crises and highlight similarities as well as differences. Monetary policy, the exchange rate system and the role of the banks are our fields of investigation. Our findings are that two big events have more similarities than dissimilarities. Keywords: Great Depression, Great Financial Crisis, gold standard, Eurozone, money multiplier, shadow banking. JEL classification : E5, E31, E42, G21. ∗Indiana University, Universit`aPolitecnica delle Marche and MoFiR, email:[email protected] yUniversit`aPolitecnica delle Marche, email: [email protected]. 1 I. Introduction The Great Depression of 1929-1933 (GD) and the Great Financial Crisis of 2008-2009 (GFC) have not only been colossal and worldwide events, but have challenged our \consensus" view of economics. Policymakers as well have had to learn new lessons and adopt, at times improvising, new strategies in response to events. The GD started 86 years ago and has been studied, interpreted and re-interpreted by an army of scholars. It never seems to go out of fashion. The GFC, being barely seven years old, cannot claim the pedigree of the GD nor its monumental literature. Yet, sufficient time has passed since 2008 to justify a comparative exercise, perhaps historically an early one, of the GD and GFC.
    [Show full text]