Real Interest Rates: What Accounts for Their Recent Rise?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Real Interest Rates: What Accounts for Their Recent Rise? Real Interest Rates: What Accounts for Their Recent Rise? A. Steven Holland OMINAL interest rates have risen to unprece- Proxies for the expected rate of inflation frequently dented levels in the last five years, and the common are based on weighted averages of past inflation rates perception is that expected real rates of interest — or the predicted values from regression equations in rates minus expected inflation — have risen as well. which the inflation rate depends on past inflation These higher rates are blamed for a variety of eco- rates, past rates of money growth and a number of nomic ills including reduced capital investment and other variables.’ Because empirical results can be sen- slowdowns in such interest-sensitive sectors as hous- sitive to assumptions about the way expectations are ing and automobiles. formed, however, a potentially more fruitful approach is to use “observed” inflation forecasts to estimate Thispaper is concerned, first, with establishing that expected inflation.’ In this article, data from surveys of real interest rates have indeed been higher during the both short- and long-term inflation expectations are 1980s than in the previous two decades and, second, used to estimate short- and long-term expected real with examining possible causes of this major shift. Potential causes include changes in the expected rate rates of interest. of inflation, monetary policy, the state of the economy, This analysis oversimplifies the problem, since it taxes, federal budget deficits and the declining relative applies only to the expected real before-tax yield. price of energy. Since interest payments are taxable as earned income, the expected real after-tax yield )r*) is: ESTIMATES OF BEFORE- AND (3) r~= i — ti — AFTER-ThX REAL INTEREST BATES = (1—Ui — The real interest rate is not known with certainty at the time a security is purchased, but the purchaser where t is the marginal tax rate. An estimate of the has an expectation of it. The nominal interest rate, i, is average marginal tax rate on personal income is used the sum of the expected real rate of interest, r, and the below to estimate expected after-tax real interest rates. expected rate of inflation, fr: The estimates presented in this article are intended to represent the pattern of recent real interest rate (1) i = r + ~‘.‘ movements, not to provide completely accurate esti- The expected real rate, thus, can be estimated accord- mates of real interest rates at any point in time. Poten- ing to the formula: tial sources of error in the estimates include (but are not limited to): (a) measurement error in calculating (2) r = i — fr, the expected rate ofinflation, (b) the effects of different as long as an estimate of the expected inflation rate is available. ‘As pointed out by Santoni and Stone (1982), however, the difficulty with this procedure is that any change in economic policy or any A. Steven Holland is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. structural change or “shock” that affects inflation expectations will Louis. Jude L. Naes, Jr., provided research assistance. not be incorporated in the estimate of expected inflation. ‘This equption itt a’widely used approximation of the “Fisher equa- ‘For an example of the sensitivity of empirical results to assumptions tion.” See Fisher (1965). about expectations formation, see Holland (1984). 18 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SI. LOUIS DECEMBER 1984 Chart 1 Percent Nominal and Real 1-Year Interest Rates Percent 16 Semiannual data 16 12 12 8 8 4 4 0 0 -4 -4 1960 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 1984 NOTE: Dashed lines represent overage levels of before- and after-tax real interest rates over selected time periods. marginal tax rates across market participants and (c) the Livingston survey from 1960 to the first half of the difference between the marginal tax rate expected 1984.’ Between 1960 and 1970, the nominal rate rose to hold at the time interest payments are receivedand from around 3 percent to over 7 percent. Estimates of 4 the current rate. Whenever real interest rates are re- ferred to in the following discussion, it will mean cx- ‘Joseph Livingston of The Philadelphia Inquirer conducts a survey of pected real interest rates. economists each spring and fall, requesting respondents to indicate their predictions of the consumer price index (CPI). Because the Estimates ofShort-Term Real survey results published, for example, in June contain predictions for the following December and June, Livingston refers to them as Interest Rates six- and 12-month-ahead forecasts as this article does. Becausethe respondents to the June survey are thought to know only the April Chart 1 plots nominal returns and estimates of the CPI, however, they are actuallypredicting eight- and 14-month rates before-and after-tax realreturns on one-year Treasury of change. For a detailed discussion of the Livingston expectations data, see Carlson (1977). This article uses the data in Carlson’s securities, based on one-year inflation forecasts from revised form updated to the present. The nominal interest rates used in the charts and table are the quarterly averages of the rates 4 for the quarter in which the Livingston survey was taken. The same 1n addition, the return that is relevant for decision-making depends calculations were made for six-month Treasury bills based on six- on risk and the tax burden on alternative uses of funds. More will be month inflation forecasts. Since the pattern of movements was said about risk later in the article. See Ezrati (1982) and Mehra nearly identical, however, only the one-year rates are reported. The (1984) for discussions of the implications of taxes on alternative estimate of the average marginal tax rate comes from Chase Econo- uses of funds. metrics. 19 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS DECEMBER 1984 Chart 2 Nominal and Real 10-Year Interest Rates Percent Semiannual data Percent 16 — — 16 12 12 ~±i /~ 8 8 ~naIrate ~_ 4 4 —— \~{7/\I Selore-tax real rate 0 -r 0 After-tax real rale -4 -4 1960 62 64 66 68 10 12 74 16 78 80 82 1984 the expected real rate indicate this was due primarily 1960s or 1970s. Short-term real interest rates, however, to higher expected inflation, since both the before- did not break with precedent until 1981 when before- and after-tax real rates appear to have risen only tax real rates climbed above the 6 percent level; they slightly, if at all, over the period. continued to rise through early 1982. After-tax real rates behaved in a similar fashion and, on average, Between 1971 and 1980, short-term nominal interest have been higher since 1981 than in the previous two rates, on average, were much higher than in the 1960s; decades. The difference isnot as great, however, as it is real rates, for the most part, were tower. In fact, esti- for before-tax real rates. Both nominal and real rates mated before-tax real rates were below 1 percent from have declined since early1982, but they remain at very the second half of1974 to the first halfof 1978 and were high levels relative to past history. even negative in late 1976 and early 1977. After-tax real rates were negative for nearly the entire period from 1974 to 1980. Nominal rates increased dramatically after 1977, with increases of about 200 basis points Estimates ofLong-Term Real occurring in late 1978 and again in late 1979. These Interest Rates increases, however, served only to bring real rates We expect long-term real interest rates to behave in closer to the levels that had prevailed before 1974. a manner broadly similar to short-term real rates; if From late 1979 to early 1982, short-term nominal short-term rates rise, long-term rates are forced up so interest rates were higher than at any time during the that realyields over any holding period are compara- 20 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF St LOUIS DECEMBER 1984 tile whether one holds short- or long-term bonds.’ Chart 2 plots the nominal yield on 10-year Treasury Because of data limitations, however, it is much more securities since 1960, as well as estimates of the 10- difficult to get an accurate representation of the mar- year, before- and after-tax real rates since 1978 based ket’s expectation of inflation over the distant future on the mean inflation forecasts from the survey. As than over the near future! In fact, it isonly since 1978 expected, the pattern of movements in long-term that a survey of expected inflation over periods sub- nominal rates during the 1960s and 1970s is similar to stantially longer than ayear has beenundertaken. The that in short-term rates. In particular, when short- survey, known as the Decision-Makers Poll, provides term nominal rates shot upward in the late 1970s, so estimates of expected inflation over the next five and did long-term nominal rates - Long-term real rates also 10 years.’ reached heights comparable to those of short-term real rates in 1981 and 1982? Thus, it appears that the increase in long-term real rates occurred at roughly ‘This assumes the absence of segmented markets. In other words. there is a high degree of substitutability between short- and long- the same time and was of roughly equal size as the term securities. This is not meant to imply that the term structure of increase in short-term real rates. interest rates does not change over time, only that short- and long- term interest rates behave in a broadly similar fashion. 7 The Term Structure of Real 1t is also more difficult to know the appropriate tax rate to use in calculating the after-tax yield, since interest payments are made Interest Rates much farther in the fUture.
Recommended publications
  • Inflation, Income Taxes, and the Rate of Interest: a Theoretical Analysis
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Inflation, Tax Rules, and Capital Formation Volume Author/Editor: Martin Feldstein Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-24085-1 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/feld83-1 Publication Date: 1983 Chapter Title: Inflation, Income Taxes, and the Rate of Interest: A Theoretical Analysis Chapter Author: Martin Feldstein Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11328 Chapter pages in book: (p. 28 - 43) Inflation, Income Taxes, and the Rate of Interest: A Theoretical Analysis Income taxes are a central feature of economic life but not of the growth models that we use to study the long-run effects of monetary and fiscal policies. The taxes in current monetary growth models are lump sum transfers that alter disposable income but do not directly affect factor rewards or the cost of capital. In contrast, the actual personal and corporate income taxes do influence the cost of capital to firms and the net rate of return to savers. The existence of such taxes also in general changes the effect of inflation on the rate of interest and on the process of capital accumulation.1 The current paper presents a neoclassical monetary growth model in which the influence of such taxes can be studied. The model is then used in sections 3.2 and 3.3 to study the effect of inflation on the capital intensity of the economy. James Tobin's (1955, 1965) early result that inflation increases capital intensity appears as a possible special case.
    [Show full text]
  • Philip R Lane: Determinants of the Real Interest Rate
    SPEECH Determinants of the real interest rate Remarks by Philip R. Lane, Member of the Executive Board of the ECB, at the National Treasury Management Agency Dublin, 28 November 2019 Introduction It is a pleasure to address the Annual Investee and Business Leaders’ Dinner organised by the National Treasury Management Agency (NTMA).[1] I plan today to explore some of the factors determining the evolution of the real (that is, inflation-adjusted) interest rate over time. This is obviously relevant to the NTMA in its role as manager of Ireland’s national debt and also to its other business areas (Ireland Strategic Investment Fund; State Claims Agency; NewEra; National Development Finance Agency) and related entities (National Asset Management Agency; Strategic Banking Corporation of Ireland; Home Building Finance Ireland). More generally, the real interest rate is at the core of many financial valuation models, while simultaneously acting as a fundamental macroeconomic adjustment mechanism by reconciling desired savings and desired investment patterns. My primary focus today is on the real interest rate on sovereign bonds, which in turn is the baseline for pricing riskier bonds and equities through the addition of various risk premia. The real return on government bonds in advanced economies has undergone pronounced shifts over time. Chart 1 shows that, since the 1980s, the real return on sovereign debt has registered a steady decline towards levels that are low from a historical perspective. Looking at the 1970s, ex-post calculations of the real interest rate were also low during this period, since inflation turned out to be unexpectedly high.
    [Show full text]
  • Macro-Economics of Balance-Sheet Problems and the Liquidity Trap
    Contents Summary ........................................................................................................................................................................ 4 1 Introduction ..................................................................................................................................................... 7 2 The IS/MP–AD/AS model ........................................................................................................................ 9 2.1 The IS/MP model ............................................................................................................................................ 9 2.2 Aggregate demand: the AD-curve ........................................................................................................ 13 2.3 Aggregate supply: the AS-curve ............................................................................................................ 16 2.4 The AD/AS model ........................................................................................................................................ 17 3 Economic recovery after a demand shock with balance-sheet problems and at the zero lower bound .................................................................................................................................................. 18 3.1 A demand shock under normal conditions without balance-sheet problems ................... 18 3.2 A demand shock under normal conditions, with balance-sheet problems ......................... 19 3.3
    [Show full text]
  • On Falling Neutral Real Rates, Fiscal Policy, and the Risk of Secular Stagnation
    BPEA Conference Drafts, March 7–8, 2019 On Falling Neutral Real Rates, Fiscal Policy, and the Risk of Secular Stagnation Łukasz Rachel, LSE and Bank of England Lawrence H. Summers, Harvard University Conflict of Interest Disclosure: Lukasz Rachel is a senior economist at the Bank of England and a PhD candidate at the London School of Economics. Lawrence Summers is the Charles W. Eliot Professor and President Emeritus at Harvard University. Beyond these affiliations, the authors did not receive financial support from any firm or person for this paper or from any firm or person with a financial or political interest in this paper. They are currently not officers, directors, or board members of any organization with an interest in this paper. No outside party had the right to review this paper before circulation. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bank of England, the London School of Economics, or Harvard University. On falling neutral real rates, fiscal policy, and the risk of secular stagnation∗ Łukasz Rachel Lawrence H. Summers LSE and Bank of England Harvard March 4, 2019 Abstract This paper demonstrates that neutral real interest rates would have declined by far more than what has been observed in the industrial world and would in all likelihood be significantly negative but for offsetting fiscal policies over the last generation. We start by arguing that neutral real interest rates are best estimated for the block of all industrial economies given capital mobility between them and relatively limited fluctuations in their collective current account.
    [Show full text]
  • What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates?
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates? Gauti B. Eggertsson Staff Report no. 402 November 2009 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in the paper are those of the author and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author. What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates? Gauti B. Eggertsson Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 402 November 2009 JEL classification: E52 Abstract Tax cuts can deepen a recession if the short-term nominal interest rate is zero, according to a standard New Keynesian business cycle model. An example of a contractionary tax cut is a reduction in taxes on wages. This tax cut deepens a recession because it increases deflationary pressures. Another example is a cut in capital taxes. This tax cut deepens a recession because it encourages people to save instead of spend at a time when more spending is needed. Fiscal policies aimed directly at stimulating aggregate demand work better. These policies include 1) a temporary increase in government spending; and 2) tax cuts aimed directly at stimulating aggregate demand rather than aggregate supply, such as an investment tax credit or a cut in sales taxes. The results are specific to an environment in which the interest rate is close to zero, as observed in large parts of the world today.
    [Show full text]
  • Notes for Econ202a: Consumption
    Notes for Econ202A: Consumption Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas UC Berkeley Fall 2015 c Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 2015, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. Disclaimer: These notes are riddled with inconsistencies, typos and omissions. Use at your own peril. Many thanks to Sergii Meleshchuk for spotting and removing many of them. Contents 1 Introduction 4 2 Consumption under Certainty 4 2.1 A Canonical Model . .4 2.2 Questioning the Assumptions . .5 2.3 The Intertemporal Budget Constraint . .6 2.4 Optimal Consumption-Saving under Certainty . .7 2.5 A Special case: when beta R=1 . .8 2.6 The Permanent Income Hypothesis . .8 2.7 Understanding Estimated Consumption Functions . .9 2.8 The LifeCycle Model under certainty . .9 2.9 Saving and Growth in the LifeCycle Model . 11 2.10 Interest Rate Elasticity of Saving . 12 2.10.1 The 2-period case with y1 = 0 .................... 14 2.10.2 The 2-period case with y1 6= 0 .................... 14 2.10.3 Savings and Interest Rates, a recap. 16 2.11 The LifeCycle Model under Certainty Again . 18 3 Consumption under Uncertainty: the Certainty Equivalent Model 19 3.1 The Canonical Model . 20 3.1.1 the set-up . 20 3.1.2 Recursive Representation . 21 3.1.3 Optimal Consumption and Euler Equation . 22 3.2 The Certainty Equivalent (CEQ) . 24 3.3 Tests of the Certainty Equivalent Model . 27 3.3.1 Testing the Euler Equation . 27 3.3.2 Allowing for time-variation in interest rate: the log-linearized Euler equation . 29 3.3.3 Campbell and Mankiw (1989) . 31 3.3.4 Household level data: Shea (1995), Parker (1999), Souleles (1999) and Hsieh (2003) .
    [Show full text]
  • Permanent Income Hypothesis and the Cost of Adjustment Gerald F
    Iowa State University Capstones, Theses and Retrospective Theses and Dissertations Dissertations 1994 Permanent income hypothesis and the cost of adjustment Gerald F. Parise Iowa State University Follow this and additional works at: https://lib.dr.iastate.edu/rtd Part of the Economic Theory Commons Recommended Citation Parise, Gerald F., "Permanent income hypothesis and the cost of adjustment " (1994). Retrospective Theses and Dissertations. 11304. https://lib.dr.iastate.edu/rtd/11304 This Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by the Iowa State University Capstones, Theses and Dissertations at Iowa State University Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Retrospective Theses and Dissertations by an authorized administrator of Iowa State University Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. INFORMATION TO USERS This manuscript has been reproduced from the microfilm master. UMI filmg the text directly from the original or copy submitted. Thus, some thesis and dissertation copies are in typewriter face, while others may be from any type of computer printer. The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations and photographs, print bleedthrough, substandard margins, and improper alignment can adverse^ affect reproduction. In the unlikely event that the author did not send UMI a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized copyright material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Oversize materials (e.g., maps, drawings, charts) are reproduced by sectioning the original, beginning at the upper left*hand comer and continuing from left to right in equal sections vtdth small overlap.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring Expected Inflation and the Ex-Ante Real Interest Rate in the Euro Area Using Structural Vector Autoregressions
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Gottschalk, Jan Working Paper Measuring Expected Inflation and the Ex-Ante Real Interest Rate in the Euro Area Using Structural Vector Autoregressions Kiel Working Paper, No. 1067 Provided in Cooperation with: Kiel Institute for the World Economy (IfW) Suggested Citation: Gottschalk, Jan (2001) : Measuring Expected Inflation and the Ex-Ante Real Interest Rate in the Euro Area Using Structural Vector Autoregressions, Kiel Working Paper, No. 1067, Kiel Institute of World Economics (IfW), Kiel This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/17891 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Kiel Institute of World Economics Duesternbrooker Weg 120 24105 Kiel (Germany) Kiel Working Paper No.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation Expectations, Real Interest Rate and Risk Premiums
    INFLATION EXPECTATIONS,REAL INTEREST RATE AND RISK PREMIUMS— EVIDENCE FROM BOND MARKET AND CONSUMER SURVEY DATA Dong Fu Research Department Working Paper 0705 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS In‡ation Expectations, Real Interest Rate and Risk Premiums— Evidence from Bond Market and Consumer Survey Data Dong Fuy June 2007 Abstract This paper extracts information on in‡ation expectations, the real interest rate, and various risk premiums by exploring the underlying common factors among the actual in‡ation, Univer- sity of Michigan consumer survey in‡ation forecast, yields on U.S. nominal Treasury bonds, and particularly, yields on Treasury In‡ation Protected Securities (TIPS). Our …ndings suggest that a signi…cant liquidity risk premium on TIPS exists, which leads to in‡ation expectations that are generally higher than the in‡ation compensation measure at the 10-year horizon. On the other hand, the estimated expected in‡ation is mostly lower than the consumer survey in‡ation forecast at the 12-month horizon. Survey participants slowly adjust their in‡ation forecasts in response to in‡ation changes. The nominal interest rate adjustment lags in‡ation move- ments too. Our model also edges out a parsimonious seasonal AR(2) time series model in the one-step-ahead forecast of in‡ation. JEL classi…cation: E43, G12, C32 Key words: In‡ation Expectations, Treasury In‡ation Protected Securities (TIPS), Survey In‡ation Forecast, Kalman Filter I would like to thank Nathan Balke for continuous guidance and encouragement. I also gratefully acknowledge comments and suggestions from Thomas Fomby, Esfandiar Maasoumi, Mark Wynne, Tao Wu, John Duca, Jahyeong Koo, Jonathan Wright, seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, O¢ ce of the Comptroller of the Currency and SERI, participants at the LAMES 2006 and the SEA 2006 annual meeting.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Have Interest Rates Fallen Far Below the Return on Capital?
    BIS Working Papers No 794 Why have interest rates fallen far below the return on capital? by Magali Marx, Benoît Mojon and François R Velde Monetary and Economic Department July 2019 JEL classification: E00, E40 Keywords: secular stagnation, interest rates, risk, return on capital BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS. This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2019. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISSN 1020-0959 (print) ISSN 1682-7678 (online) Why Have Interest Rates Fallen Far Below the Return on Capital? Magali Marx Banque de France Benoît Mojon Bank for International Settlements François R. Velde∗ Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago December 20, 2019 Abstract Risk-free rates have been falling since the 1980s while the return on capital has not. We analyze these trends in a calibrated OLG model with recursive preferences, designed to encompass many of the “usual suspects” cited in the debate on secular stagnation. Deleveraging cannot account for the joint decline in the risk free rate and increase in the risk premium, and declining labor force and productivity growth imply only a limited decline in real interest rates. If we allow for a change in the (perceived) risk to productivity growth to fit the data, we find that the decline in the risk-free rate requires an increase in the borrowing capacity of the indebted agents in the model, consistent with the increase in the sum of public and private debt since the crisis.
    [Show full text]
  • The Early History of the Real/Nominal Interest Rate Relationship
    THE EARLY HISTORY OF THE REAL/NOMINAL INTEREST RATE RELATIONSHIP Thomas M. Humphrey The proposition that the real rate of interest equals century classical and neoclassical monetary theorists, the nominal rate minus the expected rate of inflation (3) that it was presented in its modern form by the (or alternatively, the nominal rate equals the real end of the century, and therefore (4) that the notion rate plus expected inflation) has a long history ex- that it is a 20th century invention is totally erroneous. tending back more than 240 years. William Douglass In documenting these points, the article traces the articulated the idea as early as the 1740s to explain pre-20th century evolution of the real/nominal rate how the overissue of colonial currency and the re- analysis from its earliest origins to its culmination in sulting depreciation of paper money relative to coin Fisher’s Appreciation and Interest. As a preliminary raised the yield on loans denominated in paper com- step, however, it is necessary to sketch the basic pared to the yield on loans denominated in silver coin. outlines of this traditional analysis in order to demon- In 1811 Henry Thornton used the same notion to ex- strate how earlier writers contributed to it. plain how an inflation premium was incorporated into and generated a rise in British interest rates during Key Propositions the Napoleonic wars. Jacob de Haas, writing in 1889, employed the real/nominal rate idea to account for the As usually presented; the real/nominal interest “third (inflationary) element” in interest rates, the rate relationship expresses the nominal rate as the other two being a reward for capital and a payment sum of the real rate and a premium for expected for risk.
    [Show full text]
  • Explain That Interest Rates Are Determined in a Market for Loanable Funds.”
    Macroeconomics Topic 4: “Explain that interest rates are determined in a market for loanable funds.” Reference: Gregory Mankiw’s Principles of Macroeconomics, 2nd edition, Chapter 13. Interest Rates and the Loanable Funds Framework Some Economic Terms and Definitions: · Private Saving: The income that a private citizen has left over after paying taxes and buying consumption goods. · Public Saving: Government tax revenue left after spending. If the government spends more than it collects in taxes, the government runs a budget deficit. If the government collects more revue than it spends, the government runs a budget surplus. · National Saving (Saving): Total Saving of a nation or country, including both private and government saving. Saving = Private Saving + Government Saving · Investment: Spending on new buildings, factories or equipment primarily from businesses in order to improve future productive capacity. For example, if a car company spends $100 million to build a new factory, this would be investment spending. Introduction to the Loanable Funds Market The market for Loanable Funds is where borrowers and lenders get together. As with other markets, there is a supply curve and a demand curve. In the loanable funds framework, the supply represents the total amount that is being lent out at different interest rates or the amount being saved in the economy while the demand curve represents the total demand for borrowing at any given interest rate. Lending in the loanable funds framework takes many forms. Any time a person saves some of his or her income, that income becomes available for someone to borrow. Money saved in a bank savings account is part of the supply of loanable funds.
    [Show full text]