1.5.5. FIAT Money 1 / 4 - Inflation Before I Start Bashing on Current Monetary System, Do Realise That the System Has Had Some Benefits As Well

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

1.5.5. FIAT Money 1 / 4 - Inflation Before I Start Bashing on Current Monetary System, Do Realise That the System Has Had Some Benefits As Well 1.5.5. FIAT money 1 / 4 - inflation Before I start bashing on current monetary system, do realise that the system has had some benefits as well. More importantly: do realise that most of those benefits are not available for a very large of earth’s population. More than 90% doesn’t have full access to a good working monetary system surrounding them, including loaning, insurance etc. So they don’t have the same access as I have as a Western citizen (and remember: neither do all Western citizens have access!). The money in our current monetary system is called fiat money. As you’ve already learned is fiat money based on trust. And you also know that it consist of two different kinds of money, partially backed debt based money from commercial banks and public money, better known as cash, backed by a central non-commercial / public bank. But both denominated in the same currency name (for example “$” or “€”). This trust is often enforced by law, imposed by rulers or other entities that hold power. For example did the legislators allow for commercial banks to “print” money (of course not actually printed, but recorded in their ledgers). So our money isn't created by the government, despite common believe, but by other centralised entities. Mainly commercial banks and partly centralised banks. Key note: the same three risks of centralised ledgers (dishonesty, loss of record, exclusion) are applicable to our current centralized monetary system. Often we witness for example dishonest behaviour, like huge scale money laundering by entities with banking licenses. Loss of records: just think about the many hacks (and the closed off environments, the “operating behind the scenes”). But also exclusion of course, like mentioned: at least 2 billion people don't have access to a bank account, because they don't have the proper "KYC credentials". Or they don't have money to pay for the fees etc. Keep in mind that these 2.7 billion people are only “the head of household”, so for some reason children, females or elderly are not even taken into account of this count of the unbanked. Even if by now you still don’t think this affects you personally, the next examples or sources might show you the importance of the above, even for you. Not only is the monetary system itself unsustainable (exponential increase of money), currently slowly being confirmed by even banks their-selves (see source further readings from German Bank). Because “money” is the institutions, the story, that almost everybody believes it has a huge impact on the different layers in society. One of the easiest examples are the ones you can actually see for yourself, like in the increasing of stocks or house prices. For example here in the Netherlands, the house prices in Amsterdam rose at 300-400% since 2002. Even my own house nearly doubled in value in 3 years, (Okay, I exaggerate, it "only" went up +55%). Because of inflation, it’s a natural design of the system for prices to rise over time. But the issue here is that home values are outpacing inflation https://www.cnbc.com/2017/06/23/how-much-housing-prices-have-risen- since-1940.html , making it nearly impossible for new and young buyers to enter the market. Insane amounts of course, but a logical outcome if you keep creating money and pump it in the economy. So luxurious goods become more expensive, but one of the things that doesn't rise exponentially are the salaries of people, creating a more and more increasing wedge to those that own assets and those that don’t. Which makes this system difficult to maintain... A good read on this topic is the book ‘Capital’ from Thomas Piketty https://www.amazon.co.uk/Capital-Twenty-First-Century-Thomas- Piketty/dp/067443000X?SubscriptionId=AKIAILSHYYTFIVPWUY6Q&tag=duckdu ckgo-brave-uk- 21&linkCode=xm2&camp=2025&creative=165953&creativeASIN=067443000X, we will post the link in the further readings. So in this session we will discuss examples of problems that centralised ledgers cause or might cause, regarding our monetary system. We do this session, not only because we from KOIOS originate from a financial background, but also because world’s first public ledger (Bitcoin) aims to tackle these problems. So before diving into the world of the new ledgers, you should understand a bit more of the current world so that you can relate and understand some of the proposed solutions these blockchains aim to offer. In this case we selected four different topics where cryptocurrencies like Bitcoin offer alternatives from. We tried to depict these topics as neutral as possible, but remember that this is written by somebody with a high affiliation with cryptocurrencies so stay sharp and critical (and let us know any deficiencies in our story). The four topics (outcomes of centralised ledgers where decentralised offer other alternatives): 1. Inflation 2. Bank runs 3. Errors 4. Cashless society. So the first one up is inflation and hyper-inflation. Whether inflation is good or bad is all up to the experts, of which we will interview several. Also see the different sources in the slides if you want to learn more about benefits and downsides of inflation. Just remember for now that one of the main reasons for inflation is that authorities managing the inflation wants consumers to keep purchasing to grow economies. Because the value of your money drops each year, depending on your region with 1 to 5%, you money gets less and less valuable. Although this might not seem much on one year basis, imagine the impact on a larger time scale. For example the impact on your pension or when your saving up for something (or paying back for your mortgage). Currently (beginning 2020) the inflation rate is dropping, displaying the drop in spending, raising fears of a sharp economic slowdown. Normally you would get compensated for the inflation of your money with interest %, but with current day's negative interest, your money devaluates twice as fast. This is beneficial if you have debts, not so much if you save money. Some people therefore call inflation, “just another form of tax”. Whether inflation is the way to steer an economy, or whether a never ending continuous growth of economy is even possible and desired / sustainable healthy way for this planet remains outside the scope of this session (more about that later in other courses!). So fiat is not limited in supply and therefore not a very good store of value. It is not a good store of value because you lose your purchasing power. Store of value in short = will it keep or improve my purchasing power over time. So an alternative for storing / protecting your purchase power is buying assets like houses or other commodities that can’t be “printed”, like gold or bitcoin. An overview of money supply per country over the years can be found here. BC-1.5.5 Example 1 of centralised risks: (hyper-)inflation of fiat 1. 1971 The gold Standard Source 2. What is “Quantative Easing”? Source 3. Examples Hyperinflation What could go wrong, when you talk about unlimited supplies of money, is the risk of “hyperinflation”. In short = money is growing from trees. Not physical trees, but ledger trees (anno 2020). For example this note of 50.000 Indonesian Rupiah already experiences some hyperinflations. Large denotations are often a sign of a instable currencies or a currency that has been instable in the past. So what is the problem here with hyperinflation? Imagine you worked hard your entire life and you eventually managed to save up to 100.000 Rupiah's. Where 1 rupiah could buy you one bread (= purchase power). All of sudden somebody thinks: "well, hey...let's get rid of the 10 Rupiah note". This for example quite recently happened in a huge country like India, where all of a sudden the 20 rupee note were not "valid" anymore (2014. So Indian Rupees, not Indonesian Rupiahs ). This led of course to huge inflation and devaluation of their currency. All of a sudden your life savings where worth way less than a week before. In other words: you couldn't transfer your time from the past to the future, you couldn't hold down on your Store of Value (SoV). How to save up “money” in those scenario’s? Buying assets like houses isn’t an available option for those that cannot afford it, so they are often struck hardest (once again, see Piketty as well). You often see a lot of different causes for hyperinflation, but keep on pumping money, in Europe's case called "Quantitative Easing", in an economy, might not be a very good idea in the long run. I've added an interesting picture of Germany after World War 2, where children are playing with huge amounts of money. The money was eventually worthless. So if the trust drops in the money, so does the value. To attack a currency, attack the trust that people have in that currency (attack the story!). It is one of the most efficient ways to get a currency down. Especially if it "runs on nothing", has nothing to back it or no other use cases. Conclusion Our current monetary system isn’t flawless. It has a very high percentage of unbanked (people without access to the system) and also runs on the philosophy of inflation. Inflation means that your money loses in purchasing power, so you can buy less with your money each future period. Inflation is invented to motivate people to consume, to grow the economy, and is often felt hardest by those that can’t protect themselves against it.
Recommended publications
  • What the Return of Private Currencies Could Mean for Central Banks by Susan E
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF KANSAS CITY | JUNE 30, 2021 Déjà Vu All Over Again: What the Return of Private Currencies Could Mean for Central Banks By Susan E. Zubradt and Jesse Leigh Maniff Private digital currencies, or “crypto-assets,” have surged in popularity recently, but they are not new to the payments landscape and may present familiar challenges for central banks. Although they have yet to fulfill the main functions of money, crypto-assets still have the potential to affect financial stability and the implementation of monetary policy. The recent revival of private digital currencies has captured the imagination of those who envision a world where value can be transferred as seamlessly as information. Many individuals across a range of industries, from government to payments to finance, wonder whether private digital currencies may somehow sideline fiat money—the government-issued money that, coupled with reserves at central bank accounts, underpins the global financial system. In this article, we review the history of private currencies, reevaluate whether present private digital currencies satisfy the functions of money, and discuss the implications that “crypto-assets”—whether considered money or not—may have for monetary policy and financial stability. Historical Perspective Private currencies based on commodities have existed for millennia. Since around the sixth century B.C.E, commodity money has been the predominate monetary system (Velde 1998). Metal coins were a useful early means of payment to facilitate everyday transactions. Over time, paper currency, issued by a private entity and backed by a commodity such as gold, became the norm for money in circulation.
    [Show full text]
  • Competitive Supply of Money in a New Monetarist Model
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Competitive Supply of Money in a New Monetarist Model Waknis, Parag 11 September 2017 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/75401/ MPRA Paper No. 75401, posted 23 Sep 2017 10:12 UTC Competitive Supply of Money in a New Monetarist Model Parag Waknis∗ September 11, 2017 Abstract Whether currency can be efficiently provided by private competitive money suppliers is arguably one of the fundamental questions in monetary theory. It is also one with practical relevance because of the emergence of multiple competing financial assets as well as competing cryptocurrencies as means of payments in certain class of transactions. In this paper, a dual currency version of Lagos and Wright (2005) money search model is used to explore the answer to this question. The centralized market sub-period is modeled as infinitely repeated game between two long lived players (money suppliers) and a short lived player (a continuum of agents), where longetivity of the players refers to the ability to influence aggregate outcomes. There are multiple equilibria, however we show that equilibrium featuring lowest inflation tax is weakly renegotiation proof, suggesting that better inflation outcome is possible in an environment with currency competition. JEL Codes: E52, E61. Keywords: currency competition, repeated games, long lived- short lived players, inflation tax, money search, weakly renegotiation proof. ∗The paper is based on my PhD dissertation completed at the University of Connecticut (UConn). I thank Christian Zimmermann (Major Advisor, St.Louis Fed), Ricardo Lagos (Associate Advisor, NYU) and Vicki Knoblauch (Associate Advisor, UConn) for their guidance and support. I thank participants at various conferences and the anonymous refer- ees at Economic Inquiry for their helpful comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Cryptocurrency: the Economics of Money and Selected Policy Issues
    Cryptocurrency: The Economics of Money and Selected Policy Issues Updated April 9, 2020 Congressional Research Service https://crsreports.congress.gov R45427 SUMMARY R45427 Cryptocurrency: The Economics of Money and April 9, 2020 Selected Policy Issues David W. Perkins Cryptocurrencies are digital money in electronic payment systems that generally do not require Specialist in government backing or the involvement of an intermediary, such as a bank. Instead, users of the Macroeconomic Policy system validate payments using certain protocols. Since the 2008 invention of the first cryptocurrency, Bitcoin, cryptocurrencies have proliferated. In recent years, they experienced a rapid increase and subsequent decrease in value. One estimate found that, as of March 2020, there were more than 5,100 different cryptocurrencies worth about $231 billion. Given this rapid growth and volatility, cryptocurrencies have drawn the attention of the public and policymakers. A particularly notable feature of cryptocurrencies is their potential to act as an alternative form of money. Historically, money has either had intrinsic value or derived value from government decree. Using money electronically generally has involved using the private ledgers and systems of at least one trusted intermediary. Cryptocurrencies, by contrast, generally employ user agreement, a network of users, and cryptographic protocols to achieve valid transfers of value. Cryptocurrency users typically use a pseudonymous address to identify each other and a passcode or private key to make changes to a public ledger in order to transfer value between accounts. Other computers in the network validate these transfers. Through this use of blockchain technology, cryptocurrency systems protect their public ledgers of accounts against manipulation, so that users can only send cryptocurrency to which they have access, thus allowing users to make valid transfers without a centralized, trusted intermediary.
    [Show full text]
  • Cryptocurrencies As an Alternative to Fiat Monetary Systems David A
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Digital Commons at Buffalo State State University of New York College at Buffalo - Buffalo State College Digital Commons at Buffalo State Applied Economics Theses Economics and Finance 5-2018 Cryptocurrencies as an Alternative to Fiat Monetary Systems David A. Georgeson State University of New York College at Buffalo - Buffalo State College, [email protected] Advisor Tae-Hee Jo, Ph.D., Associate Professor of Economics & Finance First Reader Tae-Hee Jo, Ph.D., Associate Professor of Economics & Finance Second Reader Victor Kasper Jr., Ph.D., Associate Professor of Economics & Finance Third Reader Ted P. Schmidt, Ph.D., Professor of Economics & Finance Department Chair Frederick G. Floss, Ph.D., Chair and Professor of Economics & Finance To learn more about the Economics and Finance Department and its educational programs, research, and resources, go to http://economics.buffalostate.edu. Recommended Citation Georgeson, David A., "Cryptocurrencies as an Alternative to Fiat Monetary Systems" (2018). Applied Economics Theses. 35. http://digitalcommons.buffalostate.edu/economics_theses/35 Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.buffalostate.edu/economics_theses Part of the Economic Theory Commons, Finance Commons, and the Other Economics Commons Cryptocurrencies as an Alternative to Fiat Monetary Systems By David A. Georgeson An Abstract of a Thesis In Applied Economics Submitted in Partial Fulfillment Of the Requirements For the Degree of Master of Arts May 2018 State University of New York Buffalo State Department of Economics and Finance ABSTRACT OF THESIS Cryptocurrencies as an Alternative to Fiat Monetary Systems The recent popularity of cryptocurrencies is largely associated with a particular application referred to as Bitcoin.
    [Show full text]
  • Seigniorage Is Profit from Money Creation, a Way for Governments To
    Copyrighted Material seigniorage money system, seigniorage revenue is given by the product of the inflation rate and the inflation tax base. This inflation tax base reflects the purchasing power of the public’s money holdings and is the level of real money balances (nominal money holdings divided by the price level). Undertaking more rapid monetary expansion causes the inflation rate to rise, but the revenue effects are partially offset as indi- viduals attempt to quickly spend the extra money before it depreciates further. If people spend money faster thanitis beingprinted, therateof price increase comes to exceed the rate of money issuance. Hyperinflation Agovernmentthatisunableto fund its expenditures through conventional taxes or bond sales may become dependent on seigniorage revenues to maintain its existence. Attempts to raise seigniorage revenues are, however, not only infla- tionary but eventually self-defeating. Under cir- cumstances where the decline in real money balances seigniorage becomes proportionately larger than the rise in the Seigniorage is profit from money creation, a way for inflation rate, the inflationary policy actually back- governments to generate revenue without levying fires and lowers seigniorage revenue. The economist conventional taxes. In the days of commodity Phillip Cagan’s classic analysis of hyperinflations, money, seigniorage revenue was the difference be- with inflation rates exceeding 50 percent per month, tween the face value of the minted coins and the suggested instances where the process had, in fact, actual market value of the precious metal they con- been pushed beyond the revenue-maximizing point. tained. When this markup was insufficient for the It is possible that lags in the adjustment of inflation government’s revenue needs, the authorities might expectations may actually have allowed continued substitute less valuable base metal for some of the seigniorage gains, however, and subsequent analysis precious metal that was supposed to be in the coins.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tax-Foundation Theory of Fiat Money
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Goldberg, Dror Working Paper The tax-foundation theory of fiat money Working Paper, No. 2009-05 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University Suggested Citation: Goldberg, Dror (2009) : The tax-foundation theory of fiat money, Working Paper, No. 2009-05, Bar-Ilan University, Department of Economics, Ramat-Gan This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/96068 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu The Tax-Foundation Theory of Fiat Money Dror Goldberg Department of Economics Bar Ilan University Abstract A government can promote the use of an object as the general medium of exchange by accepting it in tax payments.
    [Show full text]
  • The Future of Money
    STUDY Requested by the ECON committee Monetary Dialogue, December 2019 The Future of Money Compilation of papers Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies Directorate-General for Internal Policies PE 642.364 - November 2019 EN The Future of Money Compilation of papers This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs. AUTHORS Salomon FIEDLER, Klaus-Jürgen GERN, Ulrich STOLZENBURG (Kiel Institute for the World Economy) Eddie GERBA (London School of Economics and Political Science), Margarita RUBIO (University of Nottingham) Alexander KRIWOLUZKY, Chi Hyun KIM (DIW) Grégory CLAEYS, Maria DEMERTZIS (Bruegel) ADMINISTRATOR RESPONSIBLE Drazen RAKIC Dario PATERNOSTER EDITORIAL ASSISTANT Janetta CUJKOVA LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE EDITOR Policy departments provide in-house and external expertise to support EP committees and other parliamentary bodies in shaping legislation and exercising democratic scrutiny over EU internal policies. To contact the Policy Department or to subscribe for updates, please write to: Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies European Parliament L-2929 - Luxembourg Email: [email protected] Manuscript completed: November 2019 Date of publication: November 2019 © European Union, 2019 This document is available on the internet at: http://www.europarl.europa.eu/supporting-analyses DISCLAIMER AND COPYRIGHT The opinions expressed in this document are the sole responsibility of the authors and do not necessarily represent the official position of the European Parliament. Reproduction and translation for non-commercial purposes are authorised, provided the source is acknowledged and the European Parliament is given prior notice and sent a copy. For citation purposes, the study should be referenced as: European Parliament, The Future of Money, Study for the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs, Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies, European Parliament, Luxembourg, 2019.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Bank Digital Currency in Historical Perspective: Another Crossroad in Monetary History1
    Central Bank Digital Currency in Historical Perspective: Another Crossroad in Monetary History1 Michael D. Bordo, Rutgers University, NBER and Hoover Institution, Stanford University Economics Working Paper 21113 HOOVER INSTITUTION 434 GALVEZ MALL STANFORD UNIVERSITY STANFORD, CA 94305-6010 July 14, 2021 Digitalization of Money is a crossroad in monetary history. Advances in technology has led to the development of new forms of money: virtual (crypto) currencies like bitcoin; stable coins like libra/diem; and central bank digital currencies (CBDC) like the Bahamian sand dollar. These innovations in money and finance have resonance to earlier shifts in monetary history: 1) The shift in the eighteenth and nineteenth century from commodity money (gold and silver coins) to convertible fiduciary money and inconvertible fiat money; 2) the shift in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries from central bank notes to a central bank monopoly;3) Then evolution since the seventeenth century of central banks and the tools of monetary policy. This paper makes the case for CBDC through the lens of monetary history. The bottom line is that the history of transformations in monetary systems suggests that technical change in money is inevitably driven by the financial incentives of a market economy. Government has always had a key role in the provision of outside money, which is a public good. Government has also regulated inside money provided by the private sector. This held for fiduciary money and will likely hold for digital money. CBDC could make monetary policy more efficient, and it could transform the international monetary and payments systems. Keywords: digitalization, financial innovation, evolution, central banks, monetary policy, international payments JEL Codes: E5, F4, N2.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rise of E-Money and Virtual Currencies Re-Discovering the Meaning of Money from a Legal Perspective June 2018 Table of Contents
    The Rise of e-Money and Virtual Currencies Re-discovering the meaning of money from a legal perspective June 2018 Table of contents Table of contents 2 Introduction 3 Defining money 4 A brief history 4 Money as more than currency 4 Does money have to be ‘legal tender’? 5 Money, sovereignty and a legal framework 6 But what about when the government fails? 7 e-Money 8 Claims on the issuer: e-Money, 8 bank deposits and fiat currency Can e-Money be ‘money’? 8 Understanding money as a debt 9 Debt, damages and breach of duty 10 e-Money in context 10 Regulatory treatment of e-Money 11 Virtual currencies 13 New and old challenges to 13 the meaning of money What are virtual currencies 13 Currency or commodity? 13 Private money 14 Central bank digital currencies – 15 coming back full circle Key contacts 16 Where we work 17 1 The Rise of e-Money and Virtual Currencies – Re-discovering the meaning of money from a legal perspective The Rise of e-Money and Virtual Currencies – Re-discovering the meaning of money from a legal perspective 2 Introduction Defining money Cryptocurrencies, digital coins, tokens, blockchain – In the next section on e-Money, we concentrate on money’s A brief history Money as more than currency whether you are a student trying to figure out how to save role in discharging obligations. In other words, money as One of the most common (economic) definitions of money is Money does not necessarily mean only physical currency the salary from your first job, a café accepting payments debt.
    [Show full text]
  • Digital Currency
    THE FUTURE OF MONEY: DIGITAL CURRENCY HEARING BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON MONETARY POLICY AND TRADE OF THE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED FIFTEENTH CONGRESS SECOND SESSION JULY 18, 2018 Printed for the use of the Committee on Financial Services Serial No. 115–111 ( U.S. GOVERNMENT PUBLISHING OFFICE 31–510 PDF WASHINGTON : 2018 VerDate Sep 11 2014 07:37 Nov 15, 2018 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00001 Fmt 5011 Sfmt 5011 G:\GPO PRINTING\DOCS\115TH HEARINGS - 2ND SESSION 2018\2018-07-18 MPT DIGIT nshattuck on FSR297 with DISTILLER HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES JEB HENSARLING, Texas, Chairman PATRICK T. MCHENRY, North Carolina, MAXINE WATERS, California, Ranking Vice Chairman Member PETER T. KING, New York CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York EDWARD R. ROYCE, California NYDIA M. VELA´ ZQUEZ, New York FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma BRAD SHERMAN, California STEVAN PEARCE, New Mexico GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York BILL POSEY, Florida MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts SEAN P. DUFFY, Wisconsin DAVID SCOTT, Georgia STEVE STIVERS, Ohio AL GREEN, Texas RANDY HULTGREN, Illinois EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri DENNIS A. ROSS, Florida GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota ANN WAGNER, Missouri ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado ANDY BARR, Kentucky JAMES A. HIMES, Connecticut KEITH J. ROTHFUS, Pennsylvania BILL FOSTER, Illinois LUKE MESSER, Indiana DANIEL T. KILDEE, Michigan SCOTT TIPTON, Colorado JOHN K. DELANEY, Maryland ROGER WILLIAMS, Texas KYRSTEN SINEMA, Arizona BRUCE POLIQUIN, Maine JOYCE BEATTY, Ohio MIA LOVE, Utah DENNY HECK, Washington FRENCH HILL, Arkansas JUAN VARGAS, California TOM EMMER, Minnesota JOSH GOTTHEIMER, New Jersey LEE M.
    [Show full text]
  • 13. Chartalism, Metallism, and Key Currencies
    13. Chartalism, Metallism, and Key Currencies In terms of our hierarchy of money and credit, we have so far been paying most attention to currency and everything below it, so our attention has been on two of the four prices of money, namely par and the interest rate. Today we begin a section of the course that looks into forms of money that lie above currency in the hierarchy, and hence at a third price of money, the rate of exchange. Metallism Under a gold standard, the extension of our analysis would be straightforward. Gold is the ultimate international money, an asset that is no one’s liability. Under a gold standard, each currency has its own mint par, and the exchange rate is determined by the ratio of mint pars. In this view of the world, the multiple national (state) systems relate to one another not directly (money to money) but only indirectly (credit to credit) through the international (private) system. Each national currency has an exchange rate with the international money and it is that pattern of exchange rates that sets up a pattern of exchange rates between national currencies. Dollar = x ounces of gold Pound = y ounces of gold Dollar = x/y Pounds [S(1/x)=(1/y)] Exchange Rate in a Metallic Standard World Gold X oz. Y oz. Dollar S=X/Y Pound Deposits Deposits Securities Securities From this point of view, the central bank is a banker’s bank, holding international reserves that keep the national payment system in more or less connection with the international system.
    [Show full text]
  • The Emergence of Fiat Money: a Reconsideration
    THE EMERGENCE OF FIAT MONEY: ARECONSIDERATION Kevin Dowd One of the fundamental questions in monetary economics is why fiat money has value: Why do rational agents trade real resources for intrinsically worthless pieces of paper? Monetary economists have long understood that part of the explanation relates to the superiority of a monetary equilibrium over a barter one. However, it is one thing to explain why fiat money is better than barter, and quite another to explain how fiat money actually emerges. Recognizing this point, a number of recent studies (e.g., Kiyotaki and Wright 1991, 1992, 1993; Ritter 1995; and Williamson and Wright 1995)1 have sought to explain the emergence of fiat money by means of a hypothetical direct jump from barter to a fiat money equilibrium.2 This paper suggests that these attempts are fundamentally miscon- ceived. They suffer from three main problems. The first is the “start problem”3—that is, the difficulty of ensuring an initial demand for fiat money balances. If fiat money is ever to emerge from barter, someone must be the first to exchange real goods for pieces of paper money that, by definition, do not provide any direct consumption Cato Journal, Vol. 20, No. 3 (Winter 2001). © Cato Institute. All rights reserved. Kevin Dowd is Professor of Financial Risk Management at Nottingham University Business School. He thanks Charles Goodhart and George Selgin for very helpful correspondence on the issues discussed in this paper. The usual caveat applies. 1Some of the issues raised in this literature are also discussed by Goodhart (1997) and Selgin (1993, 1994, 1997).
    [Show full text]