What the Return of Private Currencies Could Mean for Central Banks by Susan E

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

What the Return of Private Currencies Could Mean for Central Banks by Susan E FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF KANSAS CITY | JUNE 30, 2021 Déjà Vu All Over Again: What the Return of Private Currencies Could Mean for Central Banks By Susan E. Zubradt and Jesse Leigh Maniff Private digital currencies, or “crypto-assets,” have surged in popularity recently, but they are not new to the payments landscape and may present familiar challenges for central banks. Although they have yet to fulfill the main functions of money, crypto-assets still have the potential to affect financial stability and the implementation of monetary policy. The recent revival of private digital currencies has captured the imagination of those who envision a world where value can be transferred as seamlessly as information. Many individuals across a range of industries, from government to payments to finance, wonder whether private digital currencies may somehow sideline fiat money—the government-issued money that, coupled with reserves at central bank accounts, underpins the global financial system. In this article, we review the history of private currencies, reevaluate whether present private digital currencies satisfy the functions of money, and discuss the implications that “crypto-assets”—whether considered money or not—may have for monetary policy and financial stability. Historical Perspective Private currencies based on commodities have existed for millennia. Since around the sixth century B.C.E, commodity money has been the predominate monetary system (Velde 1998). Metal coins were a useful early means of payment to facilitate everyday transactions. Over time, paper currency, issued by a private entity and backed by a commodity such as gold, became the norm for money in circulation. During the early years of the United States and into the 20th century, paper currency largely consisted of privately issued bank notes. In the past, private currencies have coexisted with currencies issued by central banks (Maniff 2020). In the United States, both were in circulation between 1914 and 1935. Privately issued currencies were phased out as the U.S. Treasury withdrew the government bonds that could serve as security for their issuance (Weber 2015). During this era, some considered private currencies a potential source of bank reserves, possibly threatening the Federal Reserve’s control of reserves and leading to concerns about whether large quantities of private currency in circulation could impede monetary policy. Governments also questioned whether private currencies could affect the safety and stability of financial systems. In recent years, central banks have been the primary issuers of currency, but private currencies have resurfaced as transactions have increasingly become digital. Originally, digital currencies emerged in closed systems, such as airline miles or currencies used in online games. But in the past decade, a different type of digital currency has sparked broader interest—currencies that operate without a central controlling entity and third-party intermediaries, often allowing direct use by the public. These crypto-assets, or cryptocurrencies, have renewed central bank interest in private currencies and raised WWW.KANSASCITYFED.ORG/PSRB 1 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF KANSAS CITY | JUNE 30, 2021 | PAYMENTS SYSTEM RESEARCH BRIEFING questions of whether these new assets are actually money and whether they could affect monetary policy and financial stability. Are Crypto-Assets Money? Since the invention of bitcoin, researchers have continuously questioned whether crypto-assets can be considered money (Yermack 2015; Lee and Martin 2020). To be considered money (and to be called cryptocurrency), crypto-assets need to fulfill three functions: serve as a store of value, a medium of exchange, and a unit of account. Money is a store of value in that 10 dollars today should be worth approximately 10 dollars tomorrow. It is a medium of exchange in that consumers can use it as a means of making payments. And money is a unit of account as it can be used as a measurement of value— prices of goods and services are listed in it. One example of a private currency that could be considered money are carnival tickets: people exchange dollars for tickets and then only transact in tickets. Ride prices are listed in terms of tickets (unit of account), riders hand over tickets to pay for the ride (medium of exchange), and the value of tickets does not fluctuate day-to-day while the carnival is in town (store of value). We agree with previous analyses that crypto-assets have yet to fulfill the three functions of money. First, as recent price swings in 2021 so far indicate, crypto-assets are generally not a stable store of value. Many crypto-assets rely on a fixed supply, meaning that like commodities, a finite amount of the asset will be issued. If the supply of the asset is fixed, the price increases as demand increases. This is especially true when there are questions about the asset’s intrinsic value. Speculation remains a common use for crypto-assets. In fact, many early adopters of crypto-assets hoped for a price increase so they could make a return on holding the asset. Thus, most crypto-assets are currently too volatile to be a stable store of value. A subset of crypto-assets, informally known as stablecoins, have attempted to remove price volatility by tying the value of the asset to something more stable, such as fiat currency. The majority of crypto-assets, however, continue to be volatile. Second, consumers are not yet using crypto-assets in a manner consistent with a medium of exchange. Many payment providers have recently announced plans for engaging with crypto-assets with little evidence of consumer demand to use crypto-assets for payments. In fact, studies have shown that consumers are purchasing crypto-assets as investment vehicles rather than to make payments (Hundtofte and others 2019; Henry and others 2019). If consumers expect a crypto-asset to appreciate, they will keep the asset rather than using it. Although stablecoins have the potential to act as a medium of exchange, as consumers are unlikely to hold them for investment, there is little sign that stablecoins are actually being used to purchase goods and services. Instead, they are predominately used in exchange for other crypto-assets; because stablecoin can exist entirely on an exchange, it is easier to trade a stablecoin than to move fiat currency on and off of an exchange. Third, crypto-assets have yet to establish themselves as a new unit of account. Many crypto-assets remain highly volatile; using them would require merchants to frequently re-price goods and services, making crypto-assets a poor unit of account. Even where crypto-assets are accepted as a means of payment, the unit of account will likely remain in fiat currency. Today, most stablecoins are pegged directly to fiat currency, which makes listing the price in stablecoins seem redundant. WWW.KANSASCITYFED.ORG/PSRB 2 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF KANSAS CITY | JUNE 30, 2021 | PAYMENTS SYSTEM RESEARCH BRIEFING What Crypto-Assets May Mean for Central Banks Although crypto-assets do not currently fulfill the three functions of money, they may still—like the private currencies of the early 20th century—have the potential to affect monetary policy and financial stability. If actors in the financial and payments industries use crypto-assets to fulfill at least one of the three functions of money, crypto-assets could indeed affect the economy. If crypto-assets are considered a store of value, especially one that may appreciate or depreciate compared with other assets, concerns related to monetary policy and financial stability are similar to those for other financial assets. Imagine a scenario where institutions buy crypto-assets with the expectation that prices will increase. If, for example, the crypto-asset market crashes and crypto-asset purchases are debt-financed, contagion across financial markets is possible. Even those who never purchased crypto-assets may be affected by a crash, which could threaten financial stability and weaken the transmission of monetary policy (Stevens 2017). If crypto-assets are used as a medium of exchange, the network may grow large enough to become a “systemically important payment system,” a payment system whose failure could threaten financial stability. Although systemically important payment systems exist now, involving crypto-assets may exacerbate financial stability concerns. For example, because crypto-asset networks are often decentralized, with no controlling entity accountable for operating the network and managing risks, the networks lack a tool commonly used to address financial stability concerns: oversight by a regulator. With no controlling entity to regulate, there may be no way of protecting against a disruption to the system or ultimate failure. Lastly, in the unlikely situation that crypto-assets become units of account, monetary policy may become “irrelevant” (He 2017, p. 15). If prices are listed in terms of crypto-assets, the potential exists for real, permanent substitutability between fiat currencies and crypto-assets. If a large number of holders permanently substitute crypto-assets for fiat currency, demand for currency in circulation and reserve balances will likely decrease. In this case, fiat currency may no longer serve as base money. If controlling the fiat money supply no longer has a substantial effect on the economy, the central bank may have difficulty pursuing its economic goals. While concerns about monetary policy and financial stability are not new, certain fiat currencies face a question that was irrelevant in the early 20th century: Could crypto-assets, and private currencies more broadly, affect the status of reserve currencies? Reserve currencies are held in significant quantities by other central banks and used in international trade and financial transactions. Researchers have identified four key elements in determining reserve currency status: the economic size and dominance of reserve issuers, the credibility of reserve issuers, the transactional demand of reserve holders, and inertia (Iancu and others 2020).
Recommended publications
  • Monetary Policy in a World of Cryptocurrencies∗
    Monetary Policy in a World of Cryptocurrencies Pierpaolo Benigno University of Bern March 17, 2021 Abstract Can currency competition affect central banks’control of interest rates and prices? Yes, it can. In a two-currency world with competing cash (material or digital), the growth rate of the cryptocurrency sets an upper bound on the nominal interest rate and the attainable inflation rate, if the government cur- rency is to retain its role as medium of exchange. In any case, the government has full control of the inflation rate. With an interest-bearing digital currency, equilibria in which government currency loses medium-of-exchange property are ruled out. This benefit comes at the cost of relinquishing control over the inflation rate. I am grateful to Giorgio Primiceri for useful comments, Marco Bassetto for insightful discussion at the NBER Monetary Economics Meeting and Roger Meservey for professional editing. In recent years cryptocurrencies have attracted the attention of consumers, media and policymakers.1 Cryptocurrencies are digital currencies, not physically minted. Monetary history offers other examples of uncoined money. For centuries, since Charlemagne, an “imaginary” money existed but served only as unit of account and never as, unlike today’s cryptocurrencies, medium of exchange.2 Nor is the coexistence of multiple currencies within the borders of the same nation a recent phe- nomenon. Medieval Europe was characterized by the presence of multiple media of exchange of different metallic content.3 More recently, some nations contended with dollarization or eurization.4 However, the landscape in which digital currencies are now emerging is quite peculiar: they have appeared within nations dominated by a single fiat currency just as central banks have succeeded in controlling the value of their currencies and taming inflation.
    [Show full text]
  • Complementary Currencies: Mutual Credit Currency Systems and the Challenge of Globalization
    Complementary Currencies: Mutual Credit Currency Systems and the Challenge of Globalization Clare Lascelles1 Abstract Complementary currencies—currencies operating alongside the official currency—have taken many forms throughout the last century or so. While their existence has a rich history, complementary currencies are increasingly viewed as anachronistic in a world where the forces of globalization promote further integration between economies and societies. Even so, towns across the globe have recently witnessed the introduction of complementary currencies in their region, which connotes a renewed emphasis on local identity. This paper explores the rationale behind the modern-day adoption of complementary currencies in a globalized system. I. Introduction Coined money has two sides: heads and tails. ‘Heads’ represents the state authority that issued the coin, while ‘tails’ displays the value of the coin as a medium of exchange. This duality—the “product of social organization both from the top down (‘states’) and from the bottom up (‘markets’)”—reveals the coin as “both a token of authority and a commodity with a price” (Hart, 1986). Yet, even as side ‘heads’ reminds us of the central authority that underwrote the coin, currency can exist outside state control. Indeed, as globalization exerts pressure toward financial integration, complementary currencies—currencies existing alongside the official currency—have become common in small towns and regions. This paper examines the rationale behind complementary currencies, with a focus on mutual credit currency, and concludes that the modern-day adoption of complementary currencies can be attributed to the depersonalizing force of globalization. II. Literature Review Money is certainly not a topic unstudied.
    [Show full text]
  • Competitive Supply of Money in a New Monetarist Model
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Competitive Supply of Money in a New Monetarist Model Waknis, Parag 11 September 2017 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/75401/ MPRA Paper No. 75401, posted 23 Sep 2017 10:12 UTC Competitive Supply of Money in a New Monetarist Model Parag Waknis∗ September 11, 2017 Abstract Whether currency can be efficiently provided by private competitive money suppliers is arguably one of the fundamental questions in monetary theory. It is also one with practical relevance because of the emergence of multiple competing financial assets as well as competing cryptocurrencies as means of payments in certain class of transactions. In this paper, a dual currency version of Lagos and Wright (2005) money search model is used to explore the answer to this question. The centralized market sub-period is modeled as infinitely repeated game between two long lived players (money suppliers) and a short lived player (a continuum of agents), where longetivity of the players refers to the ability to influence aggregate outcomes. There are multiple equilibria, however we show that equilibrium featuring lowest inflation tax is weakly renegotiation proof, suggesting that better inflation outcome is possible in an environment with currency competition. JEL Codes: E52, E61. Keywords: currency competition, repeated games, long lived- short lived players, inflation tax, money search, weakly renegotiation proof. ∗The paper is based on my PhD dissertation completed at the University of Connecticut (UConn). I thank Christian Zimmermann (Major Advisor, St.Louis Fed), Ricardo Lagos (Associate Advisor, NYU) and Vicki Knoblauch (Associate Advisor, UConn) for their guidance and support. I thank participants at various conferences and the anonymous refer- ees at Economic Inquiry for their helpful comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Cryptocurrency: the Economics of Money and Selected Policy Issues
    Cryptocurrency: The Economics of Money and Selected Policy Issues Updated April 9, 2020 Congressional Research Service https://crsreports.congress.gov R45427 SUMMARY R45427 Cryptocurrency: The Economics of Money and April 9, 2020 Selected Policy Issues David W. Perkins Cryptocurrencies are digital money in electronic payment systems that generally do not require Specialist in government backing or the involvement of an intermediary, such as a bank. Instead, users of the Macroeconomic Policy system validate payments using certain protocols. Since the 2008 invention of the first cryptocurrency, Bitcoin, cryptocurrencies have proliferated. In recent years, they experienced a rapid increase and subsequent decrease in value. One estimate found that, as of March 2020, there were more than 5,100 different cryptocurrencies worth about $231 billion. Given this rapid growth and volatility, cryptocurrencies have drawn the attention of the public and policymakers. A particularly notable feature of cryptocurrencies is their potential to act as an alternative form of money. Historically, money has either had intrinsic value or derived value from government decree. Using money electronically generally has involved using the private ledgers and systems of at least one trusted intermediary. Cryptocurrencies, by contrast, generally employ user agreement, a network of users, and cryptographic protocols to achieve valid transfers of value. Cryptocurrency users typically use a pseudonymous address to identify each other and a passcode or private key to make changes to a public ledger in order to transfer value between accounts. Other computers in the network validate these transfers. Through this use of blockchain technology, cryptocurrency systems protect their public ledgers of accounts against manipulation, so that users can only send cryptocurrency to which they have access, thus allowing users to make valid transfers without a centralized, trusted intermediary.
    [Show full text]
  • Cryptocurrencies As an Alternative to Fiat Monetary Systems David A
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Digital Commons at Buffalo State State University of New York College at Buffalo - Buffalo State College Digital Commons at Buffalo State Applied Economics Theses Economics and Finance 5-2018 Cryptocurrencies as an Alternative to Fiat Monetary Systems David A. Georgeson State University of New York College at Buffalo - Buffalo State College, [email protected] Advisor Tae-Hee Jo, Ph.D., Associate Professor of Economics & Finance First Reader Tae-Hee Jo, Ph.D., Associate Professor of Economics & Finance Second Reader Victor Kasper Jr., Ph.D., Associate Professor of Economics & Finance Third Reader Ted P. Schmidt, Ph.D., Professor of Economics & Finance Department Chair Frederick G. Floss, Ph.D., Chair and Professor of Economics & Finance To learn more about the Economics and Finance Department and its educational programs, research, and resources, go to http://economics.buffalostate.edu. Recommended Citation Georgeson, David A., "Cryptocurrencies as an Alternative to Fiat Monetary Systems" (2018). Applied Economics Theses. 35. http://digitalcommons.buffalostate.edu/economics_theses/35 Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.buffalostate.edu/economics_theses Part of the Economic Theory Commons, Finance Commons, and the Other Economics Commons Cryptocurrencies as an Alternative to Fiat Monetary Systems By David A. Georgeson An Abstract of a Thesis In Applied Economics Submitted in Partial Fulfillment Of the Requirements For the Degree of Master of Arts May 2018 State University of New York Buffalo State Department of Economics and Finance ABSTRACT OF THESIS Cryptocurrencies as an Alternative to Fiat Monetary Systems The recent popularity of cryptocurrencies is largely associated with a particular application referred to as Bitcoin.
    [Show full text]
  • The Nature of Decentralized Virtual Currencies: Benefits, Risks and Regulations
    MILE 14 Thesis | Fall 2014 The Nature of Decentralized Virtual Currencies: Benefits, Risks and Regulations. Paul du Plessis Supervisor: Prof. Dr. Kern Alexander 1 DECLARATION This master thesis has been written in partial fulfilment of the Master of International Law and Economics Programme at the World Trade Institute. The ideas and opinions expressed in this paper are made independently, represent my own views and are based on my own research. I confirm that this work is my own and has not been submitted for academic credit in any other subject or course. I have acknowledged all material and sources used in this paper. I understand that my thesis may be made available in the World Trade Institute library. 2 ABSTRACT Virtual currency schemes have proliferated in recent years and have become a focal point of media and regulators. The objective of this paper is to provide a description of the technical nature of Bitcoin and the reason for its existence. With an understanding of the basic workings of this new payment system, we can draw comparisons to fiat currency, analyze the associated risks and benefits, and effectively discusses the current regulatory framework. 3 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page 1. Introduction .............................................................................................. 4 2. The Evolution of Money .......................................................................... 6 2.1. Defining Money ................................................................................. 6 2.2. The Origin of Money ........................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Seigniorage Is Profit from Money Creation, a Way for Governments To
    Copyrighted Material seigniorage money system, seigniorage revenue is given by the product of the inflation rate and the inflation tax base. This inflation tax base reflects the purchasing power of the public’s money holdings and is the level of real money balances (nominal money holdings divided by the price level). Undertaking more rapid monetary expansion causes the inflation rate to rise, but the revenue effects are partially offset as indi- viduals attempt to quickly spend the extra money before it depreciates further. If people spend money faster thanitis beingprinted, therateof price increase comes to exceed the rate of money issuance. Hyperinflation Agovernmentthatisunableto fund its expenditures through conventional taxes or bond sales may become dependent on seigniorage revenues to maintain its existence. Attempts to raise seigniorage revenues are, however, not only infla- tionary but eventually self-defeating. Under cir- cumstances where the decline in real money balances seigniorage becomes proportionately larger than the rise in the Seigniorage is profit from money creation, a way for inflation rate, the inflationary policy actually back- governments to generate revenue without levying fires and lowers seigniorage revenue. The economist conventional taxes. In the days of commodity Phillip Cagan’s classic analysis of hyperinflations, money, seigniorage revenue was the difference be- with inflation rates exceeding 50 percent per month, tween the face value of the minted coins and the suggested instances where the process had, in fact, actual market value of the precious metal they con- been pushed beyond the revenue-maximizing point. tained. When this markup was insufficient for the It is possible that lags in the adjustment of inflation government’s revenue needs, the authorities might expectations may actually have allowed continued substitute less valuable base metal for some of the seigniorage gains, however, and subsequent analysis precious metal that was supposed to be in the coins.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tax-Foundation Theory of Fiat Money
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Goldberg, Dror Working Paper The tax-foundation theory of fiat money Working Paper, No. 2009-05 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University Suggested Citation: Goldberg, Dror (2009) : The tax-foundation theory of fiat money, Working Paper, No. 2009-05, Bar-Ilan University, Department of Economics, Ramat-Gan This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/96068 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu The Tax-Foundation Theory of Fiat Money Dror Goldberg Department of Economics Bar Ilan University Abstract A government can promote the use of an object as the general medium of exchange by accepting it in tax payments.
    [Show full text]
  • The Future of Money
    STUDY Requested by the ECON committee Monetary Dialogue, December 2019 The Future of Money Compilation of papers Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies Directorate-General for Internal Policies PE 642.364 - November 2019 EN The Future of Money Compilation of papers This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs. AUTHORS Salomon FIEDLER, Klaus-Jürgen GERN, Ulrich STOLZENBURG (Kiel Institute for the World Economy) Eddie GERBA (London School of Economics and Political Science), Margarita RUBIO (University of Nottingham) Alexander KRIWOLUZKY, Chi Hyun KIM (DIW) Grégory CLAEYS, Maria DEMERTZIS (Bruegel) ADMINISTRATOR RESPONSIBLE Drazen RAKIC Dario PATERNOSTER EDITORIAL ASSISTANT Janetta CUJKOVA LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE EDITOR Policy departments provide in-house and external expertise to support EP committees and other parliamentary bodies in shaping legislation and exercising democratic scrutiny over EU internal policies. To contact the Policy Department or to subscribe for updates, please write to: Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies European Parliament L-2929 - Luxembourg Email: [email protected] Manuscript completed: November 2019 Date of publication: November 2019 © European Union, 2019 This document is available on the internet at: http://www.europarl.europa.eu/supporting-analyses DISCLAIMER AND COPYRIGHT The opinions expressed in this document are the sole responsibility of the authors and do not necessarily represent the official position of the European Parliament. Reproduction and translation for non-commercial purposes are authorised, provided the source is acknowledged and the European Parliament is given prior notice and sent a copy. For citation purposes, the study should be referenced as: European Parliament, The Future of Money, Study for the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs, Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies, European Parliament, Luxembourg, 2019.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Bank Digital Currency in Historical Perspective: Another Crossroad in Monetary History1
    Central Bank Digital Currency in Historical Perspective: Another Crossroad in Monetary History1 Michael D. Bordo, Rutgers University, NBER and Hoover Institution, Stanford University Economics Working Paper 21113 HOOVER INSTITUTION 434 GALVEZ MALL STANFORD UNIVERSITY STANFORD, CA 94305-6010 July 14, 2021 Digitalization of Money is a crossroad in monetary history. Advances in technology has led to the development of new forms of money: virtual (crypto) currencies like bitcoin; stable coins like libra/diem; and central bank digital currencies (CBDC) like the Bahamian sand dollar. These innovations in money and finance have resonance to earlier shifts in monetary history: 1) The shift in the eighteenth and nineteenth century from commodity money (gold and silver coins) to convertible fiduciary money and inconvertible fiat money; 2) the shift in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries from central bank notes to a central bank monopoly;3) Then evolution since the seventeenth century of central banks and the tools of monetary policy. This paper makes the case for CBDC through the lens of monetary history. The bottom line is that the history of transformations in monetary systems suggests that technical change in money is inevitably driven by the financial incentives of a market economy. Government has always had a key role in the provision of outside money, which is a public good. Government has also regulated inside money provided by the private sector. This held for fiduciary money and will likely hold for digital money. CBDC could make monetary policy more efficient, and it could transform the international monetary and payments systems. Keywords: digitalization, financial innovation, evolution, central banks, monetary policy, international payments JEL Codes: E5, F4, N2.
    [Show full text]
  • The Future of Money: How New Currencies Create Wealth, Work and a Wiser World
    The Future of Money © Bernard Lietaer March 1999 The Future of Money: How New Currencies Create Wealth, Work and a Wiser World (Book #2 - US Version) June 1999 Copyright by Bernard A. Lietaer 1 The Future of Money © Bernard Lietaer March 1999 • The Information Age has already spawned new kinds of currencies: frequent flyer miles are evolving toward a “corporate scrip” ( a private currency issued by a corporation) for the traveling elite; a giant corporation you never heard of is issuing its own “Netmarket Cash” for Internet commerce; even Alan Greenspan, Chairman of the Federal Reserve, foresees “new private currency markets in the 21st century.” • 2,600 local communities in the world, including over a hundred in the US, are now issuing their own currency, independently from the national money system. Some communities, like in Ithaca, New York, issue paper currency; others in Canada, Australia, the UK or France issue complementary electronic money. 2 The Future of Money © Bernard Lietaer March 1999 TABLE OF CONTENTS [New Numbering] TABLE OF CONTENTS 3 PART TWO: CHOOSING YOUR FUTURE OF MONEY 6 Chapter by Chapter Outline 9 CHAPTER 5: WORK-ENABLING CURRENCIES 11 An Important Distinction 12 The Connection to Public Health 13 The Money Connection 13 Unemployed? Who? Me? 14 Today’s Job Problem 14 The Age of Downsizing 16 Economic Consequences 19 Keynes’ Foresight 21 Socio-Political Consequences 22 Case Studies 26 Traditional Solutions 27 Neither Left, nor Right, but Forward? 34 The Path not Taken in the 1930s 38 1930’s Problems: Some Differences and Parallels 39 1930s Solutions 39 The German Wara System 42 Wörgl Stamp Script 45 US Depression Scrips 47 Some Political Lessons 50 Today’s systems 53 Clarifying Some Distinctions 54 LETS 56 WIR 62 Regional Development Currencies 65 Financing Small Businesses 69 Local Loyalty Schemes 70 Conclusion: Complementary Currencies as “Early Prototypes”.
    [Show full text]
  • Public and Private Currency Competition
    Public and Private Currency Competition James Bullard President and CEO Central Bank Research Association 2019 Annual Meeting Columbia University and Federal Reserve Bank of New York July 19, 2019 New York, N.Y. Any opinions expressed here are my own and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Open Market Committee. 1 Introduction 2 Some published monetary theory • I am a policymaker, but I am also a research economist who has contributed to the literature on “private money.”* • I will give some of my views based selectively on this literature along with other observations.† • The exact results from this math-econ literature are model-dependent and so require some interpretation to be understood in a policymaking context. * C. Azariadis, J. Bullard and B.D. Smith, “Private and Public Circulating Liabilities,” Journal of Economic Theory, July 2001, 99(1-2), 59-116; J. Bullard and B.D. Smith, “The Value of Inside and Outside Money,” Journal of Monetary Economics, March 2003, 50(2), 389-417. † This talk is closely related to J. Bullard, “Non-Uniform Currencies and Exchange Rate Chaos,” remarks presented at CoinDesk, Consensus 2018, New York, N.Y., May 14, 2018. 3 Key themes in this talk • The literature suggests that public and private currencies can compete and co-exist as part of an equilibrium. • Cryptocurrencies are creating drift toward a non-uniform currency in the U.S., a state of affairs that has existed historically but was disliked and eventually replaced. • The international monetary system features non-uniform currency arrangements, but the volatile exchange rates that characterize the system have long been criticized.
    [Show full text]