The Commons Angela Mitropoulos Fellow, School of Humanities and Communication Arts University of Western Sydney, Australia

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Commons Angela Mitropoulos Fellow, School of Humanities and Communication Arts University of Western Sydney, Australia CHAPTER 12 The Commons Angela Mitropoulos Fellow, School of Humanities and Communication Arts University of Western Sydney, Australia The idea of ‘‘the commons’’ is derived from the Latin communis and the Old French comun. It is part of a series of concepts whose meanings draw on ‘‘common,’’ such as community, communion, commodity, communism, and commerce. Common means attributes or prop- erties that are prevalent or shared alike by two or more things or groups of people. As with any word its significance can be shaped by context. Yet the systematic use of a word as a concept involves a framework through which that concept makes sense. For the commons, such systematic use implies the use of legal concepts and history even if that history is not always known or explicit. The commons is a key tenet in the history of common law. That is, the idea of the commons emerged from the property law concept of res communes (meaning ‘‘it is in common’’ or is common property). It did so in contradistinction to the concept of res nullius (‘‘it is no one’s,’’ or no one’s property) and relied on the methodological principle of the recta ratio, or ‘‘right reasoning.’’ This involves principles of valid reasoning, not least how to think about what prevalence means or implies, or what is beyond reasonable debate and should be taken as an indisputable premise. In the ‘‘black letter’’ terms of common law (those things that are taken to be beyond reasonable debate, and usually pertain to property and contract law), ‘‘the commons,’’ or res communes, means ‘‘things common to all; that is, those things which are used and enjoyed by everyone, even in single parts, but can never be exclusively acquired as a whole’’ (Black 1968, 1469). As a tenet of property law, the commons involves assumptions about what it means to share properties and what it means to posit a notion of commonality or preponderance as the basis for resolving questions about the just distribution of goods and resources. The salient concepts in the history of property law in this regard are ius gentium (often translated as ‘‘law, or justice, of nations’’) and ius naturale (or ‘‘law, or justice, of nature’’). During the Middle Ages and the early modern period in Europe, Catholic scholars developed natural law theories (i.e., legal theories developed on the basis of a moral philosophy that posits that the norms or laws that govern humanity are derived from the God-given nature of human beings). By drawing on these theories as well as readings of the ancient Greek philosophers Plato (c. 429–c. 347 BCE) and Aristotle (384–322 BCE), concepts such as gentium and naturale nevertheless have their contemporary analogues; for example, German feminist sociologists Maria Mies and Veronika Bennholdt-Thomsen write of ‘‘the social and the natural household’’ (2001, 1021). Some theories of the commons have retained this historical sense in the emphasis on oikonomia, or ‘‘the law of the household,’’ in the qualitative distinction drawn between social and natural domains, or in the meanings 165 COPYRIGHT 2016 Macmillan Reference USA, a part of Gale, Cengage Learning WCN 02-200-210 Chapter12:TheCommons accorded to concepts such as ecologies, as derived from oikos, to mean a knowledge or ‘‘logos’’ of household management or law (Mitropoulos 2012). This chapter begins by summarizing some of the key concepts in theories of the commons, such as res nullius, res communes,gifteconomy,andoikonomia.Thenext section summarizes the three broad approaches within commons literature: the natural law or normative approaches; the pragmatic or conventionalist approaches of common- pool resource theories and the new institutionalism theories of global governance; and critical theories of the commons. It then proceeds to a brief discussion of the classical commons and highlights the relationships among property law, metaphor, and the recurrent analogical bundling of gender, nature, and property in classical ideas of the commons. The final section outlines the terms of ‘‘the global commons,’’ as this is the context in which contemporary understandings of the commons, as well as the history of its conceptual apparatus, has taken shape.Althoughtheliteratureonthecommons is vast and debates are ongoing, the principal purpose of this chapter is to highlight perspectives on these debates from queer, decolonial, feminist, and critical race schol- ars. Some of the work of this chapter is therefore constructive, drawing together a range of sources both within and beyond discussions on the commons so as to emphasize the historical and epistemological frameworks that underpin theories and concepts of the commons. KEY CONCEPTS RES NULLIUS, TERRA NULLIUS, AND RES COMMUNES Res nullius implies neither regularity nor number, nor does it describe a capacity to reason. It pertains to those goods that are deemed to be unproductive because they are not transformed by labor, and, therefore, as both Dutch jurist Hugo Grotius (1583–1645) and English philosopher John Locke (1632–1704) argued (Miura 2013, 49), the land on which they took place could justifiably be colonized as res nullius.Thatis,res nullius has a similar rhetorical status in Grotian property law as ‘‘the state of nature’’ does in classical Lockean contract theories, in that ‘‘the state of nature’’ is a narrative device that serves to vindicate the emergence of property regimes and colonial possession (Brace 2004, 227). The initial codification of res nullius occurs in contradistinction to res communes (Schermaier 2009). From the eighteenth century on, res nullius refers to ‘‘things which are not the Goods of any Person or Number of Men’’ (Tomlins 2010, 119n81). There is no suggestion in any legal or economic history of res communes that, as with terra nullius (nobody’s land), ‘‘the commons . [is] a wasteland, a res nullius, a place having no owner and no value’’ (Bollier and Helfrich 2012a, 25). The conflation of ‘‘wastes’’ with res nullius is a consequence of Lockean concepts of cultivated land as productive land, an idea that, in turn, has on occasion been used to justify wholesale land transfers and use-conversion, such as that of the 1984 Wasteland Develop- ment Programme in India sponsored by the World Bank (Shiva 1986, 613). Thus deduced from ‘‘the economic nature of man’’ (Lurye 1947, 184) both private property and res communes were distinguished from res nullius in natural law understandings of the commons. Unlike res nullius then, res communes involves a calculus of two or more goods through the use of ‘‘right reasoning’’—the recta ratio. That is, unlike other forms of collective property- holding or use (family estates, the joint-stock company from the sixteenth century that became the modern corporation, or the body corporate of real estate law), ‘‘the commons’’ refers to the means by which to judge the ‘‘right ratio’’ of goods. 166 MACMILLAN INTERDISCIPLINARY HANDBOOKS COPYRIGHT 2016 Macmillan Reference USA, a part of Gale, Cengage Learning WCN 02-200-210 Chapter12:TheCommons IUS GENTIUM AND IUS NATURALE Ius is sometimes rendered as ‘‘law,’’ although it can be translated as ‘‘justice,’’ which places the emphasis not on law in a broad sense but on the just distribution of the good or goods. The means of deciding the valid form of this just distribution falls to the recta ratio. In Christian canon law, the ius commune forms the basis of a theology of contracts. By the end of the seventeenth century, principally through the works of the Spanish scholastics, this theology of contracts would regard them as ‘‘the inevitable means enabling man to navigate his way either to salvation or to the destruction of his material goods—and of his soul’’ (Decock 2012, xviii). Naturale,ofcourse,means ‘‘nature,’’ and concepts of nature are crucial to understandings of the basis on which arguments are made within theories of the commons about the just distribution of the good. Gentium is a far more complex term than nature in some respects, but not unrelated. For some Roman scholars it implied ‘‘the human race,’’ for others ‘‘a race,’’ ‘‘a people,’’ or ‘‘a nation,’’ and still for others a specific family, clan, or tribe (Radin 1914). From the eighteenth century on, these ideas would converge with statistics and were increasingly rendered as the geometric progression of variables and constants pertaining to unique biological entities (Malthus 1960; Hardin 1968; Weeks 1981, 159–163). Contrary to this, some have argued that the biological sciences borrowed its classical model of biological taxa and property inheritance (as with concepts of the transmission of genetic traits as substantive properties) from laws concerning legitimate property ownership and inheritance (Lo´pez-Beltra´n 2007) and that this occurred in the mutually enforcing conjuncture of the similarly ‘‘restricted economies’’ that linked sex to race and nation as a means to affirm (or ascertain the threats to) the nation’s unique reproducibility over time (Weinbaum 2004; Mitropoulos 2012). THE GIFT ECONOMY For some theorists, the commons makes it possible to revive an idea of precapitalist gift economies, which they argue points beyond the transactional logics of the market and the hierarchical form of the state (Vaughan 2007; Polanyi 1983). For others, there is a question as to whether, by contrast, this revival indicates a mythical narrative of origins and ends that hinges on the simultaneous idealization and exploitation of women’s work and nature (Mies and Bennholdt-Thomsen 2001; Mitropoulos 2012; Federici 2012). Inspired by anthropological studies (Mauss 1954) and by Hungarian philosopher of science and economist Michael Polanyi’s definition of the commons as a premodern, nonmarket gift economy (1983), others have suggested that ‘‘the emergent commons movement is providing us with ideas about governance and property that are different than what we have seen with the modern state and market’’ (Milun 2015).
Recommended publications
  • Privatization: Issues in Local and State Service Provision by ELISABETH R
    Center for Local, State, and Urban Policy Policy Report Number 1 • February 2004 UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Privatization: Issues in Local and State Service Provision BY ELISABETH R. GERBER, CHRISTIANNE K. HALL, AND JAMES R. HINES JR. Summary hile many states and localities are turning to privatization as a way to provide services to their citizens, surprisingly little is known about these choices. Much of the debate over Wprivatization pays little attention to the rationales and consequences of private vs. public service provision. With an eye toward advancing understanding about privatization, the University of Michigan’s Offi ce of Tax Policy Research (OTPR) and Center for Local, State, and Urban Policy (CLOSUP) sponsored a series of studies on privatization. This empirically grounded research can provide policymakers with a sound basis for assessing whether and how privatization should be undertaken. This report begins by providing a historical background of privatization and a discussion of the nature and prevalence of privatization in the United States. Section II provides an overview of the empirical research on cost savings, quality, equity, employment, and political effects of privatization. The fi ndings from the papers commissioned by OTPR and CLOSUP are presented alongside fi ndings from other previously published research. Our review of the literature suggests the following conclusions about privatization: • Private providers may or may not be more effi cient than public providers. Whether privatization leads to greater cost savings depends largely on whether there is competition in service provision. • The quality of privatized services may or may not be higher than publicly provided services. Gov- ernments can play an important quality assurance role by monitoring and evaluating the delivery of privatized services.
    [Show full text]
  • A Critique of John Stuart Mill Chris Daly
    Southern Illinois University Carbondale OpenSIUC Honors Theses University Honors Program 5-2002 The Boundaries of Liberalism in a Global Era: A Critique of John Stuart Mill Chris Daly Follow this and additional works at: http://opensiuc.lib.siu.edu/uhp_theses Recommended Citation Daly, Chris, "The Boundaries of Liberalism in a Global Era: A Critique of John Stuart Mill" (2002). Honors Theses. Paper 131. This Dissertation/Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the University Honors Program at OpenSIUC. It has been accepted for inclusion in Honors Theses by an authorized administrator of OpenSIUC. For more information, please contact [email protected]. r The Boundaries of Liberalism in a Global Era: A Critique of John Stuart Mill Chris Daly May 8, 2002 r ABSTRACT The following study exanunes three works of John Stuart Mill, On Liberty, Utilitarianism, and Three Essays on Religion, and their subsequent effects on liberalism. Comparing the notion on individual freedom espoused in On Liberty to the notion of the social welfare in Utilitarianism, this analysis posits that it is impossible for a political philosophy to have two ultimate ends. Thus, Mill's liberalism is inherently flawed. As this philosophy was the foundation of Mill's progressive vision for humanity that he discusses in his Three Essays on Religion, this vision becomes paradoxical as well. Contending that the neo-liberalist global economic order is the contemporary parallel for Mill's religion of humanity, this work further demonstrates how these philosophical flaws have spread to infect the core of globalization in the 21 st century as well as their implications for future international relations.
    [Show full text]
  • The Contribution of Higher Education to Public and Common Good(S), East and West
    Tsinghua University Institute of Education Seminar 1 on 21 June 2019 The contribution of higher education to public and common good(s), East and West Simon Marginson Department of Education, University of Oxford ESRC/HEFCE Centre for Global Higher Education Higher School of Economics, Moscow The problem of ‘public’ or ‘social’ goods in higher education We can think we can measure private goods associated with higher education, such as augmented earnings … (though the extent to which they are really caused by the higher education? that’s another story …) … but public good, or public goods, or ’social goods’, are more elusive, especially goods collectively consumed. These public goods tend to be under-recognised, and hence are probably under-funded and under-provided The contribution of higher education to public and common good(s), East and West • Contributions of higher education – individual and collective • Higher education as a public sphere • Higher education as public good(s) - Economic definition - Political definition - Combining the two definitions • Higher education as common good(s) • Global public and common good(s) in higher education • Concepts of ‘public’ and ‘common’ in China Mapping the contributions of higher education: Individualised and collective Individualised 1 Individualised national goods 2 Individualised global goods Greater agency freedom Cross-border mobility and Better social position employability Augmented earnings and Communications facility employment rates Knowledge of diverse Lifetime health and financial languages and cultures outcomes, etc Access to global science national global 3 Collective national goods 4 Collective global goods Ongoing development of Universal global science professions/occupations Diverse knowledge fields Shared social literacy, Common zone of free critical opportunity structure inquiry Inputs to government Systems for exchange, Stronger regions, cities collaboration, mobility collective 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Privatization of Governmental Services, Assets and Functions the Privatization Study Was Adopted at the League Lost and Jobs May Be Cut
    LWVUS Privatization Study: Privatization of Governmental Services, Assets and functions The Privatization study was adopted at the League lost and jobs may be cut. In some instances, this may of Women Voters of the United States convention in have a detrimental effect on the “common good” or 2010. Our study and consensus meetings are scheduled public well-being. for March 13 and April 10. One state, for instance, has declared as a matter of state Scope of the Privatization Study: law and policy that “using private contractors to provide public services formerly provided by state “The purpose of this study is to identify those employees does not always promote the public interest. parameters and policy issues to be considered To ensure that citizens …… receive high quality public in connection with proposals to transfer services at low cost, with due regard for tax payers…… federal, state or local government services, and the needs of public and private workers, the assets and/or functions to the private sector. (legislature) finds it necessary to regulate such It will review the stated goals and the privatization contracts throughout the state.” community impact of such transfers, and identify strategies to ensure transparency, Those promoting privatization claim that: accountability, and preservation of the • the private sector can provide increased efficiency, common good.” better quality and more innovation in services than the Today many nations are faced with financial challenges. government; In the United States these problems are apparent at the • a smaller government will reduce costs to the federal, state and local levels. Encouraged by taxpayer; proponents of a conservative political philosophy, • less regulation will provide a better environment for many people look to privatization as a simple answer to business, thus creating more jobs.
    [Show full text]
  • Commons-Based Peer Production and Artistic Expression
    NMS0010.1177/1461444813511929new media & societyKostakis and Drechsler 511929research-article2013 Article new media & society 2015, Vol. 17(5) 740 –754 Commons-based peer © The Author(s) 2013 Reprints and permissions: production and artistic sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/1461444813511929 expression: Two cases nms.sagepub.com from Greece Vasilis Kostakis Ragnar Nurkse School of Innovation and Governance, Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia; P2P Lab, Ioannina, Greece Wolfgang Drechsler Ragnar Nurkse School of Innovation and Governance, Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia Abstract This essay narrates, from a creator-observation perspective, the production of two works of fiction, a book of short stories and a play, based on the principles and technologies of Commons-based peer production. This is potentially interesting from both the Commons-based peer production and the literary perspective. Even though both seem well-matched by their prima facie lack of profit orientation, Commons- based peer production case studies rarely deal with fiction, and regarding plays, artistic creativity is still mostly associated with one, maybe two authors. After tracing and analysing the Commons-based peer production phenomenon, the case studies show concretely the fate of the specific projects as well as how, nowadays, people can get involved in collaborative artistic projects inspired and catalysed by Commons-oriented principles and technologies. Keywords Arts, collaboration, commons, distributed creativity, literature,
    [Show full text]
  • Reestablishing the Commons for the Common Good
    Reestablishing the Commons for the Common Good Howard Gardner Abstract: For individuals living in a small community, the notion of “common good” seems almost nat- ural; it can be thought of simply as neighborly morality. However, in a complex modern society, it is far more challenging for individuals to de½ne and agree upon what is the common good. Nonetheless, two Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/daed/article-pdf/142/2/199/1830201/daed_a_00213.pdf by guest on 29 September 2021 contemporary roles would bene½t from embracing a broader sense of the good: 1) membership in a pro- fession; and 2) membership in a polity. Drawing on ½ndings from the GoodWork Project, I describe how the common good can become a guiding value in the professional and civic realms; discuss threats to such guiding values; and suggest some ways to promote the common good in contemporary American society. As high-end primates, human beings in earlier eras presumably had some notion of “common good.” Parents made sacri½ces for their children, and later in life, the favor was often returned. Siblings and more distant relatives cared for one another and, perhaps, for a broader group of persons. Precisely when such solidarity transcended blood relationships will likely never be known. The work of anthropologist Robin Dunbar hints at the scope of early conceptions of the common good.1 Dunbar argues that individuals can comfortably maintain relationships with up to 150 people: the maximum HOWARD GARDNER number of individuals in a clan or small tribe who , a Fellow of see each other regularly, and whose behavior– the American Academy since 1995, is the John H.
    [Show full text]
  • Transforming Government Through Privatization
    20th Anniversary Edition Annual Privatization Report 2006 Transforming Government Through Privatization Reflections from Pioneers in Government Reform Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher Governor Mitch Daniels Governor Mark Sanford Robert W. Poole, Jr. Reason Foundation Reason Foundation’s mission is to advance a free society by developing, apply- ing, and promoting libertarian principles, including individual liberty, free markets, and the rule of law. We use journalism and public policy research to influence the frameworks and actions of policymakers, journalists, and opin- ion leaders. Reason Foundation’s nonpartisan public policy research promotes choice, competition, and a dynamic market economy as the foundation for human dignity and prog- ress. Reason produces rigorous, peer-reviewed research and directly engages the policy pro- cess, seeking strategies that emphasize cooperation, flexibility, local knowledge, and results. Through practical and innovative approaches to complex problems, Reason seeks to change the way people think about issues, and promote policies that allow and encourage individuals and voluntary institutions to flourish. Reason Foundation is a tax-exempt research and education organization as defined under IRS code 501(c)(3). Reason Foundation is supported by voluntary contributions from individuals, foundations, and corporations. The views expressed in these essays are those of the individual author, not necessarily those of Reason Foundation or its trustees. Copyright © 2006 Reason Foundation. Photos used in this publication are copyright © 1996 Photodisc, Inc. All rights reserved. Authors Editor the Association of Private Correctional & Treatment Organizations • Leonard C. Gilroy • Chris Edwards is the director of Tax Principal Authors Policy Studies at the Cato Institute • Ted Balaker • William D. Eggers is the global director • Shikha Dalmia for Deloitte Research—Public Sector • Leonard C.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Common Rights' - What Are They?
    'Common Rights' - What are they? An investigation into rights of passage and rights of land use (or rights of common) Alan Shelley PG Dissertation in Landscape Architecture Cheltenham & Gloucester College of Higher Education April2000 Abstract There is a level of confusion relating to the expression 'common' when describing 'common rights'. What is 'common'? Common is a word which describes sharing or 'that affecting all alike'. Our 'common humanity' may be a term used to describe people in general. When we refer to something 'common' we are often saying, or implying, it is 'ordinary' or as normal. Mankind, in its earliest civilisation formed societies, usually of a family tribe, that expanded. Society is principled on community. What are 'rights'? Rights are generally agreed practices. Most often they are considered ethically, to be moral, just, correct and true. They may even be perceived, in some cases, to include duty. The evolution of mankind and society has its origins in the land. Generally speaking common rights have come from land-lore (the use of land). Conflicts have evolved between customs and the statutory rights of common people (the people of the commons). This has been influenced by Church (Canonical) law, from Roman formation, statutory enclosures of land and the corporation of local government. Privilege, has allowed 'freemen', by various customs, certain advantages over the general populace, or 'common people'. Unfortunately, the term no longer describes a relationship of such people with the land, but to their nationhood. Contents Page Common Rights - What are they?................................................................................ 1 Rights of Common ...................................................................................................... 4 Woods and wood pasture ............................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • An Introduction to the Digital Commons: from Common-Pool Resources to Community Governance Melanie Dulong De Rosnay, Hervé Le Crosnier
    An Introduction to the Digital Commons: From Common-Pool Resources to Community Governance Melanie Dulong de Rosnay, Hervé Le Crosnier To cite this version: Melanie Dulong de Rosnay, Hervé Le Crosnier. An Introduction to the Digital Commons: From Common-Pool Resources to Community Governance. Building Institutions for Sustain- able Scientific, Cultural and genetic Resources Commons, Sep 2012, Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium. http://biogov.uclouvain.be/iasc/index.php?page=fullpapers. halshs-00736920 HAL Id: halshs-00736920 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00736920 Submitted on 30 Sep 2012 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. An Introduction to the Digital Commons: From Common-Pool Resources to Community Governance Mélanie Dulong de Rosnay, Institute for Communication Sciences of CNRS, Paris Hervé Le Crosnier, University of Caen and Institute for Communication Sciences of CNRS, Paris Abstract This article proposes an introductory analysis of digital resources and commons-based peer production online communities with the framework of the common pool-resources. Trying to go beyond the classic economy dichotomy between physical resources scarcity and informational resources reproducibility, the approach allows to focus not only on the nature of the resources, but mostly on the governance by the communities to produce resources which remain available for all to share and build upon, while avoiding risks of pollution, degradation, underuse or enclosure by the market.
    [Show full text]
  • The Many Sides of John Stuart M I L L ' S Political and Ethical Thought Howard Brian Cohen a Thesis Submitted I N Conformity
    The Many Sides of John Stuart Mill's Political and Ethical Thought Howard Brian Cohen A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Doctorate Graduate Department of Political Science University of Toronto O Copyright by Howard Brian Cohen 2000 Acquisitions and Acquisitions et Bbliogmphïc Services services bibiiimphiques The author has granted a non- L'auteur a accordé une Iicence non exclusive licence allowïng the exclusive permettant à la National Library of Canada to Bibliothèque nationale du Canada de reproduce, loan, distriiute or seil reproduire, prêter, distribuer ou copies of this thesis in microfonn, vendre des copies de cetté thèse sous paper or electronic formats. la forme de microfiche/nlm, de reproduction sur papier ou sur format électronique. The author retains ownefship of the L'auteur conserve la propriété du copyright in this thesis. Neither the droit d'auteur qui protège cette thèse. thesis nor substantial extracts fiom it Ni la thèse ni des extraits substantiels may be printed or otherwise de celle-ci ne doivent être imprimés reproduced without the author's ou autrement reproduits sans son permission. autorisation. This study is an attempt to account for the presence of discordant themes within the political and ethical writings of John Stuart Mill. It is argued that no existing account has adequately addressed the question of what possible function can be ascribed to conflict and contradiction within Mill's system of thought. It is argued that conflict and contradiction, are built into the
    [Show full text]
  • Privatization in Developing Countries: What Are the Lessons of Recent Experience?
    Saul Estrin and Adeline Pelletier Privatization in developing countries: what are the lessons of recent experience? Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Estrin, Saul and Pelletier, Adeline (2018) Privatization in developing countries: what are the lessons of recent experience? World Bank Research Observer, 33 (1). pp. 65-102. ISSN 0257-3032 DOI: 10.1093/wbro/lkx007 © 2018 The Authors This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/87348/ Available in LSE Research Online: March 2018 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final accepted version of the journal article. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. Privatisation in developing countries: What are the lessons of recent experience? Saul Estrin ● Adeline Pelletier This paper reviews the recent empirical evidence on privatisation in developing countries, with particular emphasis on new areas of research such as the distributional impacts of privatisation.
    [Show full text]
  • Four Basic Notions of the Common Good
    St. John's Law Review Volume 75 Number 2 Volume 75, Spring 2001, Number 2 Article 16 Four Basic Notions of the Common Good Brother Daniel P. Sulmasy O.F.M. Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.stjohns.edu/lawreview This Symposium is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals at St. John's Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in St. John's Law Review by an authorized editor of St. John's Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. FOUR BASIC NOTIONS OF THE COMMON GOOD BROTHER DANIEL P. SULMASY, O.F.M.t INTRODUCTION I am delighted to be here among lawyers-it is a rare opportunity for a physician. I am very grateful to John Coughlin, my brother, for asking me to think about the common good. I told him that I never think about the common good and in trying to get me to be a better Franciscan he asked me to do so. I think it flows well from what Professor Harper just spoke to us about. I am going to talk about different ways of thinking about this term common good. The term is frequently tossed about these days, both inside and outside Catholic circles. The term "common good" has a lot of different kinds of meanings and they are not always clearly distinguished. I would like to try to bring a little more conceptual clarity by describing four basic notions of the common good. Each is going to have two subtypes; this makes it a little complex.
    [Show full text]