“Capitalism and the Jews” (1972-1985) Nicolas Vallois1 Cléo Chassonnery-Zaïgouche2

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

“Capitalism and the Jews” (1972-1985) Nicolas Vallois1 Cléo Chassonnery-Zaïgouche2 A history of Milton Friedman’s provocative “Capitalism and the Jews” (1972-1985) Nicolas Vallois1 Cléo Chassonnery-Zaïgouche2 Very first draft, please do not quote without the authors’ permission. Introduction In a 1971 letter to Ralph Harris, Friedman exposed briefly the subject of his forthcoming Presidential Lecture at the Mont Pèlerin Society (MPS) at the Montreux meeting in Switzerland (1973). I have long been interested in, and have given a number of unwritten and unpublished lectures on, “Capitalism and the Jews”—the theme being that a) no people owe so much to capitalism; b) none have done so much to destroy it by writing and political actions.3 The speech circulated as a reprint (Friedman, 1972) and Capitalism and the Jews (hereafter C&J) was eventually published in three different forms in the 1980s: in a 1984 exemplary of The Encounter, the literary and political review of Irving Kristol (Friedman, 1984); in a 1985 collective book edited among others by Kenneth Boulding and Walter Block after a Symposium held by the Fraser Institute on “Morality and the market” (Friedman, 1985); a last publication in The Freeman, a review published by The Foundation for Economic Education. Written in the early 1970s, no substantial changes occurred during the ten years of times to publication. C&J is focused on the following paradox: in the post-war decade, political collectivism in practice has backed up, however, as an idea, it has been increasingly advocated. Jewish support for liberal ideas is analyzed as an example of such a paradox: “first, the Jews owe an enormous debt to free enterprise and competitive capitalism; second, for at least the past 1 CRIISEA, University of Picardie Jules Verne. Corresponding author, email: [email protected] 2 Centre Walras-Pareto, University of Lausanne. 3 Friedman to Ralph Harris 29/09/71, Box 87 Folder 1, MFA. 1 century the Jews have been consistently opposed to capitalism and have done much on an ideological level to undermine it” (Friedman, 1985, p.403). His essay is focuses mainly on this paradox he identified. Our objective is to analyze what role this oft repeated paradox played in Friedman’s thought. At first, its constant combination with anecdotes and jokes, especially during oral presentation, with the crude argument in favor of free market convey the sense of a rhetorical example: free market caused Jewish economic success, not government intervention; Hence, government should not intervene, especially concerning minorities. In fact, Friedman did some research to back up his claims and send numerous letters to ask advices and comments from friends and scholars with expertise on Jewish history and sociology. Beyond the classical theme of the religious origins of capitalism, Friedman’s short text combine an attempt to theorize the relation between markets and the economic status of minorities and an intellectual reaction to the 1960s decade of American liberalism. While part of the researched topic of antisemitism in the history of economic thought, our focus is rather on Friedman’s reflexive point of view with the objective to enlighten the way he articulates C&J to its vision of economic and political theory. Besides the several versions of C&J, our main sources are Friedman’s archives (essentially correspondence on C&J) and Friedman’s account on market and discrimination in other context. Section 1 describes how Friedman came to write C&J and what’s the arguments and sources he uses. Section 2 analyzes C&J both the political and intellectual context of the early 1970s, when C&J gets written, in relation to main discussions in economics on discrimination. A crucial element to understand how the Jews example functions in Friedman’s thought is how he analyzes Kennedy and then Johnson administration’ anti-discrimination laws and then, Affirmative Action programs led by the Nixon Administration. Section 3 is focused on the context of publication in the 1980s in relation to the renewal of neoconservative thought, especially within Jewish intellectual circles. 1. The making of “Capitalism & the Jews” 1.1. Capitalism and the Jews: a recurrent theme in Friedman’s works 2 Let’s first describe briefly the arguments of C&J. Friedman starts by analyzing each one of the two propositions of his paradox separately. He first argues that the Jews have “benefited” from capitalism and free competition—these two expressions being used as synonyms— because the system is “colour-blind”: “where there is free competition, only performance counts”. “Monopolistic systems” on the contrary open the possibility of discrimination according to arbitrary criteria such as the “colour of skin, religion, national origin or what not” (p.404). This claim is substantiated by a personal anecdote about Friedman’s participation in a banking conference and by various references to Jewish history. According to Friedman, Jews have been most prosperous throughout the history of the Diaspora in the most capitalistic places and times (such as the Netherlands in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, Germany in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century) whereas it is “no accident that Nazi Germany and Soviet Russia, the two most totalitarian societies in the past two thousand years […] also offers the most extreme examples of official and effective anti-Semitism” (p.405). In more recent times, Jews flourished most in sectors that have the freest entry such as law, accountancy, the movie industry and are under-represented in state-regulated sectors such as large industry or banking. A last justification comes from Israel, a country that benefited largely from the aid of capitalist countries, particularly the US (compared to the Soviet aid to Egypt) and also developed mainly from private initiative rather than collectivist politics. The second proposition about the “anti-capitalist mentality of the Jews” is justified by a few examples of Jewish anti-capitalist thinkers (Marx, Trotsky, Marcuse) and more generally by Jewish political behavior (the preference of Jews for liberalism in the US, and their over- representation in revolutionary movements). Justification for this proposition is shorter than for the first one (only two short paragraphs), but Friedman substantiates his claims here about Jewish political behavior by references to works in sociology (Glazer, 1961; Fuchs, 1956). Friedman then seeks to solve the paradox. He first rejects the explanation proposed by the sociologist Lawrence Fuchs that this leftist mentality among Jews would be the direct consequence of Jewish religion and culture. According to Friedman, the opposition of the Jews to capitalism is only two centuries long, whereas Judaism as a religion that has existed for more than two millennia (p.407-408). Friedman then analyzes Werner Sombart’s alternative thesis that Judaism actually created capitalism (pp.408-409), published in his controversial book The Jews and Modern Capitalism (Sombart, 1913). As we shall see later in greater details, Sombart’s work is now commonly interpreted as anti-Semitic. Friedman 3 recognizes that Sombart’s book has “a highly unfavorable reception among both economic historians in general and Jewish intellectuals in particular” but “there is nothing in the book itself to justify any charge of anti-Semitism”. Friedman simply adds that he interprets “the book as philo-Semitic” (p.409). Yet it does not explain the paradox: if the Jews have created capitalism, why the “anti- capitalist mentality”? Friedman then considers two more balanced views, which he concedes, have only a limited validity to explain the paradox. The first one is Nathan Glazer’s claim in The social basis of American communism that the Jews’ over-representation among intellectuals explain also their over-representation among anti-capitalists, since intellectuals would be relatively more inclined to anti-capitalist tendencies (Glazer, 1961). Thought more credible than Fuchs’ for Friedman, his “impression” is that Jewish intellectuals are significantly more anti-capitalist than other intellectuals (p.410). He found another explanation in from Werner Cohn’s unpublished PhD dissertation (Cohn, 1956).4 According to Cohn, secularization and emancipation of the Jews has been a major component in the program of leftist parties since the early political revolutions in Europe. This would explain why that these parties have always been a “natural choice” for the Jews, contrary to right- wing parties. Yet Friedman notes that the explanation does not work in the US, in which Protestant and Puritan elites have always been pro-Semitic. Friedman here quotes Sombart to support his claim: “Puritanism is Judaism” (p.412). According to Friedman, the fundamental explanation of the paradox comes from “the Jewish reaction to the Jewish stereotype” (p.413). Jews have always suffered from the anti-Semitic stereotype of themselves as “money-grabbing, selfish and heartless”. Hence, they would have criticized capitalism and the free-market and lauded the State and political process instead, in order to convince themselves and anti-Semites that they were actually generous, concerned with the public interest and ideals. Friedman supports this claim with a set of alleged oppositions between Jews in Israel and in the Diaspora; the former trying to do exactly the opposite of the latter in order to differentiate themselves from the stereotypes about Jews (in the Diaspora). In the conclusion, Friedman notes that this anti-capitalist “ideology of the Jews” has always been opposed to their self-interest. Yet in the West the conflict is more potential than real: they 4 In the 1984 version of the text, footnote 6 (p.76) states that the dissertation was defended at the “New School for Soviet Research” (sic) rather than at the New York-based New School for Social Research. 4 could preach “socialism as an ideal” and still benefits from capitalism as long as free-market system still operates. Hence the Jews are “in the position of the rich parlor socialists […] who bask in self-righteous virtue by condemning capitalism while enjoying the luxuries paid for by their capitalist inheritance” (p.416).
Recommended publications
  • American Jewish Political Conservatism in Historical Perspective
    AMERICAN JEWISH POLITICAL CONSERVATISM IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE JONATHAN D. SARNA "Jews are by nature conservative,"the American-trained British chief rabbi, Joseph H. Hertz, writes in his prayer book, completed during World War II. Hertz explains that "loyalty to the State is ingrained in the Jewish character," and that "in all those countries in which persecution has not embittered their life," Jews "are no more radical than the non­ Jewish members of the social class to which they belong." 1 Hertz's claim surprises us for at least two reasons. First, he attributes Jewish political behavior to "nature" and "ingrained" characteristics, whereas we would surely attribute such behavior to nurture and acquired characteristics. Second, and even more surprising, he considers Jews to be "naturally conservative," whereas the bulk of those who describe Jewish political behavior in the United States assume, if anything, that Jews are "naturally liberal," and, as heirs of the biblical prophets, always have been.2 Hertz's characterization of Jewish politics might be easily explained 3 away on the basis of his having been a well-known apologist , or as a generalization drawn from his experiences in England. There, the Conservative Party enjoyed at various times substantial Jewish support, especially from the Jewish establishment, although the majority of Jews in Hertz's own day actually backed the Labour Party.4 Just to dismiss Hertz on these grounds, however, would be a mistake. For, as we shall see, political conservatism does draw from a deep wellspring of Jewish political philosophy, law, and historical experience. Even in the United States, where traditional Jewish politics was transformed by the Revolu- 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Werner Sombart's ʻovercomingʼ of Marxism
    CHAPTER 27 Werner Sombart’s ʻOvercomingʼ of Marxism 27.1 The Historical School as ʻDigestive Scienceʼ (Rosa Luxemburg) The ʻolder historical schoolʼ of political economy, whose members included Wilhelm Roscher (1817–94), Bruno Hildebrandt (1812–78) and Karl Knies (1821– 98), emerged in the 1840s. It was a specifically ʻGermanʼ reaction both to the French Revolution and to the ʻWesternʼ cosmopolitanism of classical political economy from Smith to Ricardo.1 It was ostensibly concerned with opposing the ʻsurgical extractionʼ of the economy from the ʻliving bodyʼ of popular life and the life of the state, and in particular the ʻnarrow egotistic psychologyʼ according to which social actors are guided, in their economic behaviour, only by economic considerations, as opposed to ethical motives.2 If Machiavelli banished ethics from politics, Adam Smith performed the same operation for political economy, criticises Knies, who emphasises the significance of the ʻethico-political momentʼ for political economy and speaks of the discipline being ʻelevatedʼ to the status of a ʻmoral and political science’.3 At first glance, this seems to represent an integral approach to studying social practices. But behind this pathos of wholeness, there lies the definition of political economy as a ʻstate economyʼ concerned with ʻjudging men and ruling them’.4 The historical school developed from cameralism, which became the discipline of state science due to the Prussian path of capitalist develop- ment.5 Marx describes cameralism as ʻa medley of smatterings, through
    [Show full text]
  • Cultural Consensus, Political Conflict: the Problem of Unity Among German Intellectuals During World War I
    University of Tennessee, Knoxville TRACE: Tennessee Research and Creative Exchange Masters Theses Graduate School 5-2006 Cultural Consensus, Political Conflict: The Problem of Unity among German Intellectuals during World War I Benjamin Taylor Shannon University of Tennessee, Knoxville Follow this and additional works at: https://trace.tennessee.edu/utk_gradthes Part of the History Commons Recommended Citation Shannon, Benjamin Taylor, "Cultural Consensus, Political Conflict: The Problem of Unity among German Intellectuals during World War I. " Master's Thesis, University of Tennessee, 2006. https://trace.tennessee.edu/utk_gradthes/4498 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at TRACE: Tennessee Research and Creative Exchange. It has been accepted for inclusion in Masters Theses by an authorized administrator of TRACE: Tennessee Research and Creative Exchange. For more information, please contact [email protected]. To the Graduate Council: I am submitting herewith a thesis written by Benjamin Taylor Shannon entitled "Cultural Consensus, Political Conflict: The Problem of Unity among German Intellectuals during World War I." I have examined the final electronic copy of this thesis for form and content and recommend that it be accepted in partial fulfillment of the equirr ements for the degree of Master of Arts, with a major in History. Vejas Liulevicius, Major Professor We have read this thesis and recommend its acceptance: A. Denise Phillips, John Bohstedt Accepted for the Council: Carolyn R. Hodges Vice Provost and Dean of the Graduate School (Original signatures are on file with official studentecor r ds.) To the Graduate Council: I am submitting herewith a thesis written by Benjamin Taylor Shannon entitled "Cultural Consensus, Political Conflict: The Problem of Unity among German Intellectuals during World War I." I have examined the finalpaper copy of this thesis for formand content and recommend that it be accepted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts, with a major in History.
    [Show full text]
  • Technology in Sombart's Sociology
    Technology in Sombart’s sociology Gennaro Iorio Abstract This paper outlines Sombart’s thought in respect to technology. After describing the cultural context, the paper presents Chapter XXIX, entitled “The Spirit of Technology”, of his most important work Modern Capitalism (Sombart 1902/1972), but mostly we will look at an in-depth study done on the essay “Technology and Culture” of 1911, which Sombart presented to the German Sociology Society at its first congress. The conclusions will emphasize how useful a reflection on technology can be, so as to propose once again original excerpts drawn from the thought of a great nineteenth-century European intellectual. Keywords : Technology, Modernity, Capitalism, Culture, Sombart 1. Introduction This essay delineates Sombart’s thought in regard to technology. After having defined the cultural context within which scientific production regarding the topic on technology is assembled, the essay presents Sombart’s thought, utilizing chapter XXIX entitled: “The Spirit of Technology”, of his most important work Modern Capitalism (Sombart 1902/1972). Moreover we shall be going more in depth on the essay “Technology and Culture” of 1911, which Sombart presented at the first congress of the German Sociological Society. In concluding, we will show how useful a reflection on technology can be, by re-proposing unedited excerpts from the thought of a great nineteenth-century German intellectual. 2. Technology and Modernity: the context of the debate in Sombart’s time One of the arguments around which German intellectual reflection is organized, between the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, concerns the character of technology, which increasingly takes on the form of domination regarding the nature and the life of man.
    [Show full text]
  • David Fraser Cowan Phd Thesis
    THE BEST SIN TO COMMIT: A THEOLOGICAL STRATEGY OF NIEBUHRIAN CLASSICAL REALISM TO CHALLENGE THE RELIGIOUS RIGHT AND NEOCONSERVATIVE ADVANCEMENT OF MANIFEST DESTINY IN AMERICAN FOREIGN POLICY David Fraser Cowan A Thesis Submitted for the Degree of PhD at the University of St. Andrews 2012 1. Candidate’s declarations: I, David Fraser Cowan hereby certify that this thesis, which is approximately 80,000 words in length, has been written by me, that it is the record of work carried out by me and that it has not been submitted in any previous application for a higher degree. I was admitted as a research student in September, 2009 and as a candidate for the degree of PhD in May 2010; the higher study for which this is a record was carried out in the University of St Andrews between 2009 and 2012. 2. Supervisor’s declaration: I hereby certify that the candidate has fulfilled the conditions of the Resolution and Regulations appropriate for the degree of PhD in the University of St Andrews and that the candidate is qualified to submit this thesis in application for that degree. Date 7/9/12 signature of supervisor Stephen R. Holmes 3. Permission for electronic publication: In submitting this thesis to the University of St Andrews I understand that I am giving permission for it to be made available for use in accordance with the regulations of the University Library for the time being in force, subject to any copyright vested in the work not being affected thereby. I also understand that the title and the abstract will be published, and that a copy of the work may be made and supplied to any bona fide library or research worker, that my thesis will be electronically accessible for personal or research use unless exempt by award of an embargo as requested below, and that the library has the right to migrate my thesis into new electronic forms as required to ensure continued access to the thesis.
    [Show full text]
  • The German Historical School1): Toward the Integration of the Social Sciences*
    The German Historical School1): Toward the Integration of the Social Sciences* Yukihiro Ikeda Abstract: This article surveys the major secondary literature on the German Historical school produced for the most part from the 1990s onward. Following a brief introduction, and using the customary terms Older, Younger, and Youngest to identify periods of development in the school, I note with critical comment works on the Older Histori- cal school. Then in the following section we turn to work done on the Younger and Youngest members of the School. In the last section, centering on the questions of what has been accomplished and what is necessary to promote further studies, some general suggestions are given regarding future research. JEL classification numbers: B15, B25. “I did not know Schmoller’s works or theories very well; what was impor- tant to me was only that I catch sight of him in the halls of the University of Berlin. I was afraid that he might die before I arrived in Berlin. How fortunate I was. I was sitting in the front hall when I first saw Schmoller, with grey hair and whiskers and wearing a frock coat. I was so very glad to have seen him.”( Koizumi 2001, 432) countries, eagerly sought to see Gustav I Introduction Schmoller, Werner Sombart, or another of The German Historical school contributed a the great Historical school names at least major current in economic thought up to the once in their lifetime. Without exaggeration outbreak of World War I. Countless students, it can be said that these people were among not only from Germany but from many other the economic science superstars of their day.
    [Show full text]
  • Footsteps of Man, Traces of Thought. Vom Menschen of Werner Sombart
    Footsteps of man, traces of thought. Vom Menschen of Werner Sombart Roberta Iannone Footsteps of man, traces of thought. Vom Menschen of Werner Sombart Abstract In his work – Vom Menschen – Sombart wonders “Who is man?”. This article tries to answer this timeless question, by revisiting some of the key points of the work. Sombart, as well as the author of this present work, have a similar objective: to deal in scientific terms, not only with the human being but also with his body language, soul and spirit. The purpose is to portray “a human science with a critical edge”, a “science of rational comprehension”. A question arises in relation to the bond between body, soul, and spirit: do they harmoniously constitute man? Or, do they lead to de-humanization? (a certain deprivation of the constitutive essence of man). These key questions are addressed to the following subjects: a) ancestors, in view of which centuries of theoretical elaborations of fundamental anthropology are reviewed; b) Erfahrungswissen, which is the experience that leads to knowledge of facts and Evidenzswissen, or known evidence, which is the a priori knowledge; c) actions and reasons; d) the spirit. Keywords: man/human being, science of rational comprehension, de-humanization, soul, spirit. 1. Introduction Every age is also a humanistic season; no age passes without taking into account the theme of man and the problems he faces. The literature on this subject is vast and therefore no century in the history of mankind passed without crossing this theme. This explains why I entitled my reflection “footsteps of man, traces of thought”.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 19, Werner Sombart and National Socialism
    Portland State University PDXScholar Working Papers in Economics Economics 3-15-2019 Working Paper No. 19, Werner Sombart and National Socialism Jenica M. Kramer Portland State University Follow this and additional works at: https://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/econ_workingpapers Part of the Economic History Commons, and the Economic Theory Commons Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Citation Details Kramer, Jenica M. "Werner Sombart and National Socialism, Working Paper No. 19", Portland State University Economics Working Papers. 19. (15 March 2019) i + 14 pages. This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access. It has been accepted for inclusion in Working Papers in Economics by an authorized administrator of PDXScholar. Please contact us if we can make this document more accessible: [email protected]. Werner Sombart and National Socialism WORKING PAPER No. 19 Authored by: Jenica M. Kramer A Contribution to the Working Papers of the Department of Economics, Portland State University Submitted for: EC446 “Institutional Economics”, 15 March 2019; i + 14 pages Prepared for Professor John Hall Abstract: This inquiry seeks to establish that Werner Sombart serves as an example of an exponent of the German Historical School of Economic Thought who joined the National Socialists. This thesis is explored in three sections. The first examines the historical context in which Sombart was reared, considering aspects of his family life, economic class, education, and early academic career. In addition, this section explores Sombart’s relations to the Historical School and his mentor Gustav Schmoller, as well as Sombart’s relation to Marxism and socialism.
    [Show full text]
  • Brothers from Another Mother
    VOlume IX, Issue I the.Hillsdale.Forum August 2008 sOUND bITbITESES University of Maryland political science professor Thomas Schaller and Harper’s Magazine Senior Editor Luke Mitchell as quoted in a July 2008 article entitled “High Noon for the Republican Party: Why the GOP Must Die” SCHALLER: To do better than 50.1 percent, the Dem- ocrats are going to have to mobilize some previously under-or-under mobilized groups. And there are a of different possibilities in that regard. MITCHELL: Which groups would you suggest? SCHALLER: Latinos are ob- viously part of it. They in- creasingly tend to vote for Democrats, and they also are increasing as a proportion of the electorate—a double whammy. Unmarried adults likely will soon outnumber married adults, and they don’t seem to like Republi- cans that much. … One out of thirteen new marriages is an interracial marriage, for instance, and that proportion will continue to grow. in.this.ISSUE Brothers From Another Mother the Ultimate Guide to CHRISTINA MILLER new spirit to government.” Sound the answer was not particularly Harvard University now has the Hillsdale College STAFF WRITER familiar? If it makes you think of informative. Obama is great from John F Kennedy School of Govern- PAGES 6-7 Obama’s claim to be a “new kind a script, but stutters in Bushian ment and Obama was editor of the He’s handsome. He talks pretty. of politician,” you might be onto fashion when faced with an open Harvard Law Review. = He dreams big dreams. He may something. forum. If Obama is elected, he will come Summer Movie not be entirely qualifi ed to be pres- Both candidates also seem to be These two candidates have also into a foreign policy situation sim- ident.
    [Show full text]
  • Conservatism a Manifesto by Eric Cohen and Aylana Meisel
    JEWISH CONSERVATISM A MANIFESTO BY ERIC COHEN AND AYLANA MEISEL ONE The Present Condition HE QUESTION Norman Podhoretz asked in his 2009 book—Why Are Jews Liberals?— seems only more consequential after President Obama’s two terms in office. The Obama years were unsettling for Jewish conservatives on many fronts. The Iran nuclear deal, the broader American retreat from the Middle East, and the delegitimation of Israel at the UN left the Jewish state in a weaker geopolitical position. Many religious Jews wor- ried that an activist judiciary and administrative state might eventually force traditional Jewish schools and synagogues to accommodate progressive practices like same-sex marriage or else lose their tax-exempt status. The continued expansion of the progressive welfare state and the intolerant culture of political correctness seemed like a direct as- sault on core conservative beliefs. Viewed historically, the Jewish devotion to liberal politics has deep and under- standable roots. Jewish immigrants to America in the late 19th and early 20th centuries TEric Cohen is executive director of the Tikvah Fund. Aylana Meisel is director of strategic initiatives at the Tikvah Fund. Commentary 15 Cohen_Meisel.indd 15 4/19/17 11:08 AM saw liberals as the best defenders of Jewish rights. and making territorial concessions to the Palestinians Liberals cared for the poor, including the Jewish poor. served true Israeli interests, and he strongly implied Liberals fought against social prejudices and privileg- that opposition to this agenda would only undermine es, including unjust barriers to Jewish advancement. the Jewish people’s proud claim to be at the vanguard And liberalism’s secular understanding of American of progressive values.
    [Show full text]
  • Genealogy of German Intellectual Impacts on Making of Economic Planning in South Korea
    Genealogy of German Intellectual Impacts on Making of Economic Planning in South Korea Young-Sue Han* <Abstract> This paper aims to explore the path of the genealogy of German intellectuals in the making of economic planning. The Schools of Liberalism criticised economic planning implements in communist states during the Cold War era. In spite of the hostile attitude of the liberalists to economic planning, American policy makers in South Korea consistently recommended introducing economic planning in the nation-making period of the last century. This paper will show that the American reliance on economic planning originates from German intellectuals’ influence by performing a three-fold task. First, this paper backgrounds the influx of the German Historical School into wartime economic planning in Imperial Japan. Consequently, this papers explores American scholarship in Germany in the early 20th century. Finally, this paper explores the roles of scholars in making theories on economic planning in Developmental State School. Key words: Economic planning, The German Historical School, Developmental State, Werner Sombart, Karl Mannheim, Lorenz von Stein * International Institute for Regional & Cultural Studies, Sogang University. 32 제9권 1집(통권 제16호, 2018년 3월) Contents Ⅰ. Introduction Ⅳ. German intellectual influences on Ⅱ. Japanese reception of the German the theoreticalization of economic Historical School of Economics planning Ⅲ. German intellectual influences on the Ⅴ. Conclusion formation of economic planning in the USA I. Introduction This paper aims to explore the path of the genealogy of German intellectuals in the making of economic planning. The purpose of this exploration arises from the lack of a considerable body of academic literature on economic development based on the economic planning of South Korea in the last century.
    [Show full text]
  • THE NEW JEWISH POLITICS Edited by Daniel J
    American Jewish Policy Agenda Resource Book No. 1 THE NEW JEWISH POLITICS Edited by Daniel J. Elazar THE JERUSALEM CENTER FOR PUBLIC AFFAIRS/ CENTER FOR JEWISH UNIVERSITY COMMUNITY STUDIES PRESS OF AMERICA fHE AMERICAN JEWISH COMMUTE Library ״Blaustei American Jewish Policy Agenda Resource Book No. 1 THE NEW JEWISH POLITICS Edited by, Daniel J. Elazar THE JERUSALEM CENTER FOR PUBLIC AFFAIRS/ CENTER FOR JEWISH COMMUNITY STUDIES Lanham • New York • London 33H< N C-2 Copyright © 1988 by The Jerusalem Center for Public Affairs/ Center for Jewish Community Studies 4720 Boston Way Lanham, MD 20706 3 Henrietta Street London WC2E 8LU England All rights reserved Printed in the United States of America British Cataloging in Publication Information Available Co-published by arrangement with The Jerusalem Center for Public Affairs/Center for Jewish Community Studies Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data The New Jewish politics. (American Jewish policy agenda ; resource bk. no. 1) 1. Jews—United States—Politics and government. 2. United States—Politics and government—1981- 3. United States—Ethnic relations. I. Elazar, Daniel Judah. II. Series. E184. J5N667 1987 323.1'1924'073 88-12802 ISBN 0-8191-7060-7 (alk. paper) ISBN 0-8191-7061-5 (pbk. : alk. paper) All University Press of America books are produced on acid-free paper. The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of American National Standard for Information Sciences—Permanence of Paper for Printed Library Materials, ANSI Z39.48-1984. TABLE OF CONTENTS The New Jewish Politics - Daniel J. Elazar The Politics of Centrism - Irving Louis Horowitz Are American Jews Becoming Conservatives and Should They? - Jonathan S.
    [Show full text]