Capital Accumulation and Potential Growth

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Capital Accumulation and Potential Growth Richard Wo Kopcke* From 1950 to 1965 the average annual growth of output per hour for nonfarm, nonresidential business was 2.5 percent; from 1965 to 1978 labor productivity grew only 1.5 percent per year, a decline of 1 percentage point. In manufacturing, the decline was somewhat less, .6 of a percentage point. This erosion of productivity growth suggests that the rate of expansion of potential Gross National Product (GNP) may have dropped a full percent- age point in recent years--whereas potential growth was commonly believed to be almost 4 percent until the mid-1960s, many now believe it is nearer 3 percent. ~ This study concludes that much of the slump in productivity and poten- tial GNP growth resulted from a slower rate of capital accumulation. One- half of the decline in labor productivity for nonfarm nonresidential business is due to slower growth of the stock of plant and equipment. For manufactur- ing, slower capital accumulation may account for the entire drop in produc- tivity growth. Much of the decline in the demand for capital can be attributed to rising inflation since the late 1960s. From the mid-1950s to the early 1970s invest- ment tax incentives increased the demand for capital, but since then rising inflation rates generally have raised business income tax burdens, thereby depressing the demand for capital. The postwar incentives for investment caused the capital stock to grow much faster than employment, temporarily boosting the expansion of poten- tial GNP. Since 1965, however, rising inflation has depressed investment incentives and the rate of capital accumulation, temporarily retardihg the expansion of full-capacity GNP. This study’s analysis suggests that a policy designed to insulate the demand for capital from high inflation could achieve a potential growth rate of 3.5 percent or more during the remainder of this century. * Assistant Vice President and Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. The author is grateful to Jarius DeWalt for his research assistance. ~ See, for example, various issues of the Economic Report of the President; the issues published in 1962, 1965, and 1979, among others, provide useful comparisons. This paper is not suggesting that 1965 is the year when productivity fell. Analysts first noted a slower productivity growth in the late 1960s and early 1970s. Because 1965 roughly divides the postwar period in half, separating the period of high growth from the years of slower growth, and because the pace of capital accumulat.ion began to drop after 1965, this year provides a useful benchmark for mea- suring the recent productivity slump. The growth of output per hour did not drop dramatically in any single year, rather it has progressively declined over many years perhaps commencing as early as 1965. 26 CAPITAL ACCUMULATION KOPCKE 27 The first two sections of this paper, particularly the second, describe this study’s analytical techniques. Section III compares the growth of output with the employment of capital and labor to show how slower capital accumula- tion since the mid-1960s has depressed the growth of labor productivity. Sec- tions IV and V then describe how the higher income tax burdens on capital, due to higher inflation rates since the mid-1960s, have depressed capital accu- mulation, thereby reducing the growth of potential output. The last section summarizes the study’s principal conclusions. I. The Production Function Two common methods for studying the sources of productivity and out- put growth use either "growth accounting" or production functions. Growth accounting assumes that the earnings of each factor of production equals the value of its product when it is fully employed.2 Output growth may then be attributed to labor or capital by weighing the growth in hours worked and the expansion of the capital Stock by. their respective earnings. For many well- known reasons, though, the earnings of labor and capital may seldom match the value of their product, even in years of "full employment," so growth accounting may poorly describe the sources of productivity growth.3 The production function compares output with the employment of labor and capital services directly to isolate the sources of productivity growth. Accordingly, output is a function of labor and capital inputs. Q = F (K, L). This approach shares one weakness with growth accounting: it is difficult to measure the overall quantity of.labor and capital services because differences in quality among people or plants are difficult to assess? According to the production function, current engineering knowledge determines the maximum, or potential, output per "unit" of material input that can be produced with a given stock of labor and capital. The growth of potential output is then determined by the expansion of the labor force and 2 In many cases, it is the marginal product which presumably equals the factor cost. 3 First, the market value of corporate capital (essentially the prospective value of its prod- uct) seldom equals its replacement cost. In many respects, skilled labor and managers, like plant and equipment, represent an investment whose product may also seldom match its cost. Second, a growing business may hire more labor and Capital than it needs to satisfy current orders if it is preparing to increase future capacity. Third, businesses often do not know in advance howmuch of their product they can sell at particular prices; consequently, the value of labor’s product, for example, may sometimes exceed its wage, and, at other times, this product may fall short of labor’s wage. Wages may not even match the average value of labor’s product because risk- averse firms may hire labor only so long as the expected value of its product exceeds the wage by some protective margin. Fourth, whenever businesses or labor do not merely passively supply their products or services at market prices over which they exert no influence, the earnings of capital and labor are not determined solely by their productivity. For these reasons, among others, factor earnings reflect more than factor productivity alone. 4 1 do not use a "weighted" measure of the labor force for example. See footnote 3. 28 THE DECLINE IN PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH the capital stock as well as by the pace of technical progress that enables a given stock of labor and capital to produce more output from a given flow of material inputs. If the flow of output is compared to the use of only one factor of production--labor, for example--then its productivity depends not only on overall technical progress but also on the employment of the other factors of production--the more capital labor uses, the more output labor can produce. The growth of output per hour worked, therefore, depends on technical pro- gress and the growth of the capital stock. The specific production function used in this study is translogarithmic: (1) In (Q/H) = ao + aeln(E/H) + asln(S/H) +/3e~ln(E)~ + flesln(E)ln(S) + flehln(E)ln(H) + flesln(E)ln(S) ~ + Bssln(S) +/3shln(S)ln(H) + ~3~ ln(E)ln(H) + ~3s~ln(S)ln(H) + fl~ln(H)2 + a(T), E: the stock of producers’ durable equipment; H: hours; Q: value-added; S: the stock of nonresidential structures; o~(T): productivity and technical change. The function, as defined above, has constant returns to scale, and the last term is intended to represent Hicks-neutral technical change and secular variations in total factor productivity.5 II. Estimation of the Production Function Using a Bayesian technique, the parameters of the production function are estimated from postwar data. The stochastic representation of (1) is: (2) In(Q/H) = o~o + o~eln(E/H) + o~sln(S/H) + Oee(ln(E)~ + ln(H)2 - 21n(E)ln(H)) + ties(In(H)2 + ln(E)ln(S)- ln(H)ln(E)- ln(H)ln(S))~ + ~3eh(ln(S)2 + ln(H)2 - 21n(S)ln(H)) + oq(T) + o~2(T)2 + o¢3(T)3 + ~, where T represents a time trend.6 ~ Energy is not a factor of production for value-added. See the extensive discussion in Appendix A. 6 T is unity in 1950:1 and 116 in 1978:4. CAPITAL ACCUMULATION KOPCKE 29 (3) y = X3,+ ~ ~t = P et-I +vt vt~N(O,°2), where y is a vector of n observations on In(Q/H), X is a matrix com- prised of observations on the right-hand-side variables of (2), and y contains the parameters of the production function. The errors, ct, may be represented by a first-order Markov process driven by a normal random variable, v .7 The prior distribution for 3’ is normal with mean g~ and precision matrix (inverse of the variance matrix) N~. The conditional posterior distribution for ~ is defined by the following statistics for each of ten discrete values for p(p= .li, 1 = O ..... 9): (4) let R = -o 10 ...0 [x/~-pZ0p- 1 000...01 0 00 ...1 then N2 = (XtRtRX/a 2 + N~) g2 = N2-t(XtRtRy/a2 + N~gt), where ~2 is the mean squared residual from the normal projection of Ry onto RX. For a given value of p, then, the posterior is conditional on both p and ~2 7 Rather than estimate the more common share equations, the production function is esti- mated directly. The share equations impose strong assumptions about the pricing policy of busi- ness, and, having imposed these assumptions, these share equations suffer from "simultaneous equations problems" at least as severe as the production function itself. For example, a rise in business tax rates will depress capital’s share of after-tax value-added, ceteris paribus, while it raises the marginal user cost of capital.
Recommended publications
  • Exports and Externalities: the Other Side of Trade and Ecological Risk
    University of Heidelberg Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series No. 481 Exports and Externalities: the other side of trade and ecological risk Travis Warziniack, David Finnoff, Jason F. Shogren, Jonathan Bossenbroek, and David Lodge April 2009 Exports and Externalities: the other side of trade and ecological risk∗ Travis Warziniack,y David Finnoff and Jason F Shogren,z Jonathan Bossenbroek,xDavid Lodge{ Abstract This paper develops a general equilibrium model to measure welfare effects of taxes for correcting environmental externalities caused by domestic trade, focusing on exter- nalities that arise through exports. Externalities from exports come from a number of sources. Domestically owned ships, planes, and automobiles can become contaminated while visiting other regions and bring unwanted pests home, and species can be in- troduced by contaminated visitors that enter a region to consume goods and services. The paper combines insights from the public finance literature on corrective environ- mental taxes and trade literature on domestically provided services. We find that past methods for measuring welfare effects are inadequate for a wide range of externalities and show the most widely used corrective mechanism, taxes on the sector imposing the environmental externality, may often do more harm than good. The motivation for this ∗Thanks to ISIS team members (http://www.math.ualberta.ca/ mathbio/ISIS/), grants from the Na- tional Sea Grant network, and the NSF (DEB 02-13698) for financial support. yUniversity of Heidelberg, Bergheimer Strasse 20, 69115 Heidelberg, Germany; [email protected] heidelberg.de zUniversity of Wyoming xUniversity of Toledo {University of Notre Dame 1 paper is the expansion of invasive species' ranges within the United States.
    [Show full text]
  • Karl Marx's Thoughts on Functional Income Distribution - a Critical Analysis
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Herr, Hansjörg Working Paper Karl Marx's thoughts on functional income distribution - a critical analysis Working Paper, No. 101/2018 Provided in Cooperation with: Berlin Institute for International Political Economy (IPE) Suggested Citation: Herr, Hansjörg (2018) : Karl Marx's thoughts on functional income distribution - a critical analysis, Working Paper, No. 101/2018, Hochschule für Wirtschaft und Recht Berlin, Institute for International Political Economy (IPE), Berlin This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/175885 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Institute for International Political Economy Berlin Karl Marx’s thoughts on functional income distribution – a critical analysis Author: Hansjörg Herr Working Paper, No.
    [Show full text]
  • Sustainability Through the Lens of Environmental Sociology: an Introduction
    sustainability Editorial Sustainability through the Lens of Environmental Sociology: An Introduction Md Saidul Islam Division of Sociology, Nanyang Technological University Singapore, 14 Nanyang Drive, Singapore 637332, Singapore; [email protected]; Tel.: +65-6592-1519 Academic Editor: Marc A. Rosen Received: 10 March 2017; Accepted: 15 March 2017; Published: 22 March 2017 Abstract: Our planet is undergoing radical environmental and social changes. Sustainability has now been put into question by, for example, our consumption patterns, loss of biodiversity, depletion of resources, and exploitative power relations. With apparent ecological and social limits to globalization and development, current levels of consumption are known to be unsustainable, inequitable, and inaccessible to the majority of humans. Understanding and achieving sustainability is a crucial matter at a time when our planet is in peril—environmentally, economically, socially, and politically. Since its official inception in the 1970s, environmental sociology has provided a powerful lens to understanding the challenges, possibilities, and modes of sustainability. This editorial, accompanying the Special Issue on “sustainability through the Lens of Environmental Sociology”, first highlights the evolution of environmental sociology as a distinct field of inquiry, focusing on how it addresses the environmental challenges of our time. It then adumbrates the rich theoretical traditions of environmental sociology, and finally examines sustainability through the lens of environmental sociology, referring to various case studies and empirical analyses. Keywords: environmentalism; environmental sociology; ecological modernization; treadmill of production; the earth day; green movement; environmental certification; global agro-food system 1. Introduction: Environmental Sociology as a Field of Inquiry Environmental sociology is the study of how social and ecological systems interact with one another.
    [Show full text]
  • The Seven Factors of Production
    British Journal of Applied Science & Technology 5(3): 217-232, 2015, Article no.BJAST.2015.021 ISSN: 2231-0843 SCIENCEDOMAIN international www.sciencedomain.org The Seven Factors of Production Sunday Okerekehe Okpighe 1* 1Department of Project Management Technology, Federal University of Technology, Owerri, Nigeria. Author’s contribution This whole work was carried out by the author SOO. Article Information DOI: 10.9734/BJAST/2015/12080 Editor(s): (1) Xueda Song, Department of Economics York University, Canada. Reviewers: (1) Anonymous, East China University of Science, China. (2) Anonymous, Katarzyna Rostek, Warsaw University of Technology, Poland. (3) Lam Wong, Engineering, Cuyahoga Community College, USA. (4) Anonymous, Jimma University, Ethiopia. (5) Ali Besharat, Economics, University of Tabriz , Iran. (6) Md. Moyazzem Hossain, Department of Statistics, Islamic University, Kushtia-7003, Bangladesh. Complete Peer review History: http://www.sciencedomain.org/review-history.php?iid=760&id=5&aid=6609 Received 17 th June 2014 th Review Article Accepted 20 August 2014 Published 23 rd October 2014 ABSTRACT The review of the Factors of Production is reported. The dynamics and response of globalization has rubbished the age long definition of factors of production. General management as entrenched in operations and production in the past centuries gave birth to non-responsive and dormant factors of production which dictated public service bureaucracy. Information and Time change were of no essence. Bureaucracy has been swept off the stage in the face of the emerging technology-driven global markets were competitiveness demands that the consumer/customer is king. In this era, Information and Time are considered of great essence to the success or failure of products/project delivery to the consumer.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 40, the Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking
    Portland State University PDXScholar Working Papers in Economics Economics 12-15-2019 Working Paper No. 40, The Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking Justin Pilarski Portland State University Follow this and additional works at: https://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/econ_workingpapers Part of the Economic History Commons, and the Economic Theory Commons Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Citation Details Pilarski, Justin "The Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking, Working Paper No. 40", Portland State University Economics Working Papers. 40. (15 December 2019) i + 16 pages. This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access. It has been accepted for inclusion in Working Papers in Economics by an authorized administrator of PDXScholar. Please contact us if we can make this document more accessible: [email protected]. The Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking Working Paper No. 40 Authored by: Justin Pilarski A Contribution to the Working Papers of the Department of Economics, Portland State University Submitted for: EC456 “American Economic History” 15 December 2019; i + 16 pages Prepared for Professor John Hall Abstract: This inquiry seeks to establish that Henry George’s writings advanced a distinct theory of political economy that benefited from a meteoric rise in popularity followed by a fall to irrelevance with the turn of the 20th century. During the depression decade of the 1870s, the efficacy of the laissez-faire economic system came into question, during this same timeframe neoclassical economics supplanted classical political economy. This inquiry considers both of George’s key works: Progress and Poverty [1879] and The Science of Political Economy [1898], establishing the distinct components of Georgist economic thought.
    [Show full text]
  • Capitalism and Morality ______
    Capitalism and Morality _________________________ “LUDWIG VON MISES ON PROFIT, LOSS, THE ENTREPRENEUR, AND CONSUMER SOVEREIGNTY” G. Stolyarov II The insights of Ludwig von Mises (1881-1973) into the function of real-world market processes help explain why, in seeking to serve their own interests, market entrepreneurs must abide by the wishes of consumers. Mises’s idea of consumer sovereignty clarifies the manner in which markets determine what is produced, and his analysis shows profits and losses to be dynamic, disequilibrium phenomena resulting from entrepreneurs’ attempts to adjust economic production to consumer demand. Mises uses his positive economics to refute fallacies concerning profit and loss—including the zero-sum and exploitative views of profit. Mises’s ideas were taken in new directions by Israel M. Kirzner, who originated the idea of entrepreneurial alertness and made a case for the necessity of profits as incentives for using entrepreneurial alertness to maximize consumers’ economic well-being. Capitalists, Entrepreneurs, and Capitalist-Entrepreneurs A discussion of Mises’s view of the market presupposes a classification of the various economic functions of agents in the marketplace. These economic functions can coincide in the same person, but they are distinct roles in the market process. Gains from the production process accrue in the form of payments to laborers who work on the process, capitalists whose capital goods are used in the process, and entrepreneurs who make the decision of what to produce and take the initiative to actually produce and market it. Sometimes the same person can perform all three functions. Mises writes, “The excess of gross receipts over expenditures which the classical economists called profit includes the price for the entrepeneur’s own labor employed in the process of production, interest on the capital invested, and finally entrepreneurial profit proper” (Mises 1949, p.
    [Show full text]
  • An Externality Is an Unintended Consequence of a Choice That Falls on Someone Other Than the Decision-Maker
    © 2010 Pearson Education Canada An externality is an unintended consequence of a choice that falls on someone other than the decision-maker. Externalities may be positive or negative Externalities may arise in consumption or production © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Production Externalities Production externalities drive a wedge between the marginal private cost (MC) that is borne by the producer, and the marginal social cost (MSC) that is the total cost to society. MSC = MC + marginal external cost The marginal external cost is the cost of producing one more unit of a good or service that falls on people other than the producer. © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Negative Production Externalities © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Negative Production Externalities: Pollution Production and Pollution: How Much? In the market for a good with an externality that is unregulated, the amount of pollution created depends on the equilibrium quantity of the good produced. © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Negative Externalities: Pollution Figure 16.2 shows the equilibrium in an unregulated market with an external cost. The quantity produced is where marginal private cost equals marginal social benefit. © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Negative Externalities: Pollution At the market equilibrium, MSB is less than MSC, so the market produces an inefficient quantity. At the efficient quantity, marginal social cost equals marginal social benefit. With no regulation, the market overproduces and creates a deadweight loss. © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Consumption Externalities Consumption externalities drive a wedge between the marginal private benefit (MB) that is borne by the producer, and the marginal social benefit (MSB) that is the total cost to society.
    [Show full text]
  • Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6)
    Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Lectures 09-10 Feb 06/09 2017 Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Production The theory of the firm describes how a firm makes cost- minimizing production decisions and how the firm’s resulting cost varies with its output. The Production Decisions of a Firm The production decisions of firms are analogous to the purchasing decisions of consumers, and can likewise be understood in three steps: 1. Production Technology 2. Cost Constraints 3. Input Choices Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.1 THE TECHNOLOGY OF PRODUCTION ● factors of production Inputs into the production process (e.g., labor, capital, and materials). The Production Function qFKL= (,) (6.1) ● production function Function showing the highest output that a firm can produce for every specified combination of inputs. Remember the following: Inputs and outputs are flows. Equation (6.1) applies to a given technology. Production functions describe what is technically feasible when the firm operates efficiently. Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.1 THE TECHNOLOGY OF PRODUCTION The Short Run versus the Long Run ● short run Period of time in which quantities of one or more production factors cannot be changed. ● fixed input Production factor that cannot be varied. ● long run Amount of time needed to make all production inputs variable. Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.2 PRODUCTION WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT (LABOR) TABLE 6.1 Production with One Variable Input Amount Amount Total Average Marginal of Labor (L) of Capital (K) Output (q) Product (q/L) Product (∆q/∆L) 0 10 0 — — 1 10 10 10 10 2 10 30 15 20 3 10 60 20 30 4 10 80 20 20 5 10 95 19 15 6 10 108 18 13 7 10 112 16 4 8 10 112 14 0 9 10 108 12 -4 10 10 100 10 -8 Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.2 PRODUCTION WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT (LABOR) Average and Marginal Products ● average product Output per unit of a particular input.
    [Show full text]
  • Factors of Production with Examples
    Factors Of Production With Examples streamierTwiggiest AylmerKalil jaywalk imbody his that curd syllabicity. consociates habitually. Marcelo homogenizing passim? Davin still liquor fadedly while Was the labor How does Tim Horton's use feedback five factors of productionFactors of ProductionExamples at Tim How us ed Horton'sNatural resourcesLandCoffee. Start ad fetching googletag. By contrast to start with a good or service. What is sweat translated into equity accumulated knowledge or reused through. If she wants to expand her factory, what does that require? There after four factors of production The factors of production include natural resources labor capital the entrepreneur These factors of production are very. Without finally getting bewildered as an example, and mental labour. If something have a tent about Factors of Production, then we ask Paul. Capital includes the buildings, tools and machines that employees use case make powerful and services. A alter of note main characteristics of stay four factors of production are. Investments eventually lead to finished goods and services. Supply goods with no productive resource categories: factors are examples include fertile land. We know that very early on, however, they began shaping stones into tools, apparently for use in butchering animals. Factors of Production Land and Capital Entrepreneur. We will then look at the roles played by technology and entrepreneurs in putting these factors of production to work. Robinhood Financial LLC provides brokerage services. Depending on the specific circumstances, one or more factors of production might be more important than the others. This resource takes the risk of organizing production BEFORE anything is produced and with no guarantee that production will be successful.
    [Show full text]
  • Land As a Distinctive Factor of Production Mason Gaffney
    Land as a Distinctive Factor of Production Mason Gaffney e classical economists treated land as distinct from capital: "land, labour and capital" were the three basic "factors of production". They were mutually exclusive. They were comprehensive, including all economic agents. Each was also "limitational," meaning at least some of each was needed for all economic activity (v. A- 9, below)" They made a coherent system. Neo-classical economists denied the distinction and undertook to purge land from economese. Many of them, following John B. Clark and Frank Knight, still deny the distinction as I explain in The Corruption of Economics, a companion volume in this series. Many treat the matter by seizing on and stressing all similarities of land and capital, while ignoring all differences. Some invent gray areas that seem to fuse land and capital, present them as typical, and quickly move on. Many more simply ignore land, which has the effect of accepting the Clark-Knight verdict in practice. Others uneasily finesse and blur the issue by writing "land" in quotes, or trivializing its value, or referring vaguely to "quasi-rents" to comprehend a broad spectrum of incomes both from land and other factors. Whatever possessed the neo-classicals to leave such a mess? One needs to know something of their times and politics. J.B. Clark and E.R.A. Seligman of Columbia University were obsessed with deflecting proposals, strongly supported at the time and place they wrote, to focus taxation on land. Henry George, after all, was nearly elected Mayor of New York City in 1886 and 1897.
    [Show full text]
  • Production Modes, Marx's Method and the Feasible Revolution
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by European Scientific Journal (European Scientific Institute) European Scientific Journal November 2016 edition vol.12, No.31 ISSN: 1857 – 7881 (Print) e - ISSN 1857- 7431 Production Modes, Marx’s Method and the Feasible Revolution Bruno Jossa retired full professor of political economy, University ”Federico II”, Naples doi: 10.19044/esj.2016.v12n31p20 URL:http://dx.doi.org/10.19044/esj.2016.v12n31p20 Abstract In Marx, the production mode is defined as a social organisation mode which is typified by one dominant production model which confers significance on the system at large. The prominence of production modes in his overall approach provides clues to the identification of the correct scientific method of Marxism and, probably, of Marx himself. The main aim of this paper is to define this method and to discuss a type of socialist revolution which appears feasible in this day and age. Keywords: Marx’s method, producer cooperatives, production modes, socialism Introduction It is not from scientific advancements – Gramsci argued – that we are to expect solutions to the issues on the traditional agenda of philosophical research. Fresh inputs for philosophical speculation have rather come from notions such as ‘social production relations’ and ‘modes of production’, which are therefore Marx's paramount contributions to science.1 In a well-known 1935 essay weighing the merits and 1 For quite a long time, Marxists used to look upon the value theory as Marx’s most important contribution to science. Only when the newly-published second and third books of Capital revealed that Marx had tried to reconcile his value theory with the doctrine of prices as determined by the interplay of demand and supply did they gain a correct appreciation of the importance of the materialist conception of history.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 18: the Markets for the Factors of Production Principles of Economics, 8Th Edition N
    Chapter 18: The Markets for the Factors of Production Principles of Economics, 8th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1 1. Introduction a. Why do people have different earnings? i. While it is popular to view earnings as being just fate (aren’t we all victims) or discrimination, supply and demand has a significant influence. ii. Education is important because it increases productivity (and as we will see demand), but it also tends to limit the supply in any category of labor. (1) No surprise, education tends to lead to a higher income. iii. Three fourths of national income is paid in the form of wages and fringe benefits. (1) Much to the rest is a result to savings from wages. iv. The demand for the factors of production is a derived demand. v. The factors of production are the inputs used to produce goods and services. P. 362. (1) Tradition has divided the factors of production into land, labor and capital, although their description is much more complicated than that. vi. This chapter only deals with competitive firms. 2. The Demand for Labor a. Labor markets are different from most other markets because labor demand is a derived demand. b. Figure 1: The Versatility of Supply and Demand. P. 363. c. The Competitive Profit Maximizing Firm i. Two assumptions: (1) There is competition in both the product and input markets. (2) The firm is a profit maximizer. ii. The Production Function and the Marginal Product of Labor (1) Table 1: How the Competitive Firm Decides How Much Labor to Hire.
    [Show full text]