Solow-Swan Growth Model Analytical Solution, Numerical Solution, Linearization, and Relaxation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Solow-Swan Growth Model Analytical Solution, Numerical Solution, Linearization, and Relaxation Solow-Swan Growth Model Analytical Solution, Numerical Solution, Linearization, and Relaxation Production Functions Box-Cox Transformation Let us introduce symbols for output (Y), capital stock (K , labor (N), and technology (A). ClearAll t, yy, kk, nn, aa * do not use caps for Mma symbols! * Macroeconomists usually focus on production relationshipsL that can be written as t yy aa @ a * t kk + b * tDnnH L eq1 = %; yy t@ ê Da t kk +@ b tD nn @ D aa t Y A a t K + b t N (1) B F @ D @ D Usually a Î 0, 1 and b = 1 - a. AH particularlyê L H popularL H choiceL for t is the Box-Cox transformation: ClearAll tH, x,L b xb - 1 t x_ := b @ D eq1 @ D yy b -1 + -1 + kkb a -1 + nnb b aa + b b b I M H L H L Implied Production Technology Let us look at the implied production technology. We can determine the implied relationship between output and inputs by using Solve: ClearAll yy, kk, nn * do not use caps for Mma symbols! * Solve eq1, yy Flatten Simplify Quiet bc`yy = %; @ D H 1 L yy ® @aa 1 + -D1êê+ kkb a + êê-1 + nnb b b êê : I I M I M M > 2 Solow_continuous.nb 1 b Y = A 1 - a - b + aKb + bNb (2) You are most familiar with this whenê b = 1 - a. IH L M Constant Returns to Scale ces`yy = bc`yy . b ® 1 - a Simplify 1 yy ® aa -nnb -1 + a + kkb a b ê 8 < êê 1 b Y A a Kb + 1 - a Nb (3) : I H L M > This is known as the constantê elasticity of substitution (CES) production function. A H L E Linear Production Technology When b 1, the CES becomes the linear production function lpt`yy = bc`yy . b ® 1 Simplify yy ® aa 1 + -1 + kk a + -1 + nn b Y = A 1 - a - bê +8a K + b<Nêê (4) When8 b =H1 - aH, the linearL technologyH L becomesL< Y AHaHK + 1 - aL N L (5) Cobb-Douglas Production Technology H H L L When b ® 0, we get a log-linear technology. Clear x, b Limit t x , b ® 0 Log x @ D @ @ D D x (Here’s one way to see that this is the case. Let Y e and use L’Hopital’s rule to show t Y ® x.) So our@ D production relationship is linear in logs: + a + b ln Y = ln A ln K ln L H L (6) bc`yy yy . bc`yy b0`yy = Limit %, b ® 0 1 yyê® aa 1 + -1 + kkb a + -1 + nnb b b @ D 1 aa 1 + -1 + kkb a + -1 + nnb b b : I I M I M M > aa kka nnb I I M I M M Y = A Ka Nb (7) When b = 1 - a this gives us the famous Cobb and Douglas (1927) production function (previously used by Wicksell). Solow_continuous.nb 3 b0`yy . b ® 1 - a Y = A Ka N1-a (8) ê 8 < Application Growth Accounting Solow Model: Analytical Solution Population Growth but No Technical Change ClearAll s, aa, k, a, d, n Fundamental@ DynamicD Equation Define capital per capita k := K N. nt Assuming N = N0 e n ³ 0 , capital per capita evolves according to K N K k = - ê N N N H L (17) K = - n k N The accounting relationship K = S - d K makes this S k = - n + d k (18) N We assume the behavior S = s Y , and we define y = Y N, so we get the fundamental dynamic equa- tion of theH SolowL model: k = s y - d + n k (19) ê Production Technology H L Under constant returns to scale in capital and labor, Y = F K, N y = Y N = F K N, 1 = f k (20) We often assume a Cobb-Douglas production technology, so that @ D Y = AKa N1-a ê @ ê D @ D (21) y = A ka y k_ := aa * ka @ D 4 Solow_continuous.nb Production Technology: Graphical Illustration To illustrate this technology graphically, we need to assume values for our model parameters. * choose parameters to match NFR * prms`core = aa ® 5.0, a ® 0.36, b ® 0.9, d ® 0.075, n ® 0.01 ; Plot y k . prms`core, k, 0, 20 , HPlotLabel ® "Cobb-Douglas ProductionL Function", AxesLabel ® k, y 8 < @ @ D ê 8 < Cobb-Douglas Production Function y 8 <D 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 k 5 10 15 20 Steady State of the Solow-Swan Model: C-D Technology Solve vs. Reduce Recall our fundamental dynamic equation for the Solow-Swan model. With a Cobb-Douglas production technology this becomes k = s A ka - d + n k (22) kdot k_ := s * aa * ka - d + n * k At the steadyH stateL we have k = 0, so we can see that @ D 1 H L s A k = 1-a (23) ss d+n To get this solution from Mathematica, we need to make our assumptions explicit. But because of the non-integerI M exponent on k, this is not quite enough. Solve primarily handles polynomial (or even ratio- nal) functions. $Assumptions = 1 > s > 0 && aa > 0 && k ³ 0 && k0 > 0 && 1 > a > 0 && 1 > d > 0 && 1 > n > 0 && g ³ 0; Solve kdot k 0, k Solve::nsmet: This system cannot be solved with the methods available to Solve. a Solve@aa k @s D- k n + dD 0, k When Solve fails, we can sometimes succeed by turning to Reduce, which also looks for a fuller charac- terization@ of the possibleH Lsolutions.D Solow_continuous.nb 5 Reduce s * aa * ka - d + n * k 0 && k ³ 0, k, Reals Simplify 1 n + d -1+a k 0 k @ aa s H L D êê Note that Reduce characterizes solutions as equalities. ÈÈ The first solution is a good reminder that there is more than one steady state. The second solution yields the result we were looking for. s * aa 1 ss`k = Power , n + d 1 - a 1 aa s 1-a n + d B F In sum, the non-trivial steady state of the model can be characterized in terms of this steady-state value ofK k: O 1 s A k = 1-a (24) ss n+d Transformations Can Help Solve I M To help Mathematica along, look for ways to rewrite the equality we are trying to solve. Solve kdot k k 0, k Simplify Solve::ifun: Inverse functions are being used by Solve, so some solutions may not be found; use Reduce for complete solution information. @ @ D ê D êê 1 n + d -1+a k ® aa s Note that Solve returns the solutions it finds as rules. :: >> The other obvious transformation does not work immediately (in Mathematica 9). Solve kdot k ka 0, k Simplify Solve::nsmet: This system cannot be solved with the methods available to Solve. Solve@k-a aa@ Dkêa s - k n + Dd êê 0, k However, we can again push things along by giving Mathematica a some guidance. Here is one approa@ch: H H LL D FullSimplify kdot k ka Solve % 0, k Simplify - 1-a + d aa s k n @ @ D ê D Solve::ifun@ : Inverse functionsD êê are being used by Solve, so someHsolutionsL may not be found; use Reduce for complete solution information. 1 n + d -1+a k ® aa s A related approach is to recognize that if we define z = k1-a we can solve a linear equation in z: :: >> 6 Solow_continuous.nb Clear a, s, aa, d, n, z Solve s * aa - d + n * z 0, z ss`z = z . % 1 @aa s D z ® @ H L D n + d ê P T aa s :n:+ d >> We then reverse the transformation to find the implied soln for kss. 1 ss`z 1-a % ss`k 1 aa s 1-a n + d True K O Graphical Illustration of the Steady State prms`s20 = Append prms`core, s ® 0.20 ; Plot Evaluate s * aa * ka, d + n * k . prms`s20 , k, 0, 60 , AxesLabel ® k, "s y\n d+n k" , PlotLegends ® "s y", " d+n k" , Epilog ® Gray, Dashed@ , Line ss`k,D0 , ss`k, s * y ss`k . prms`s20 @ @8 H L < ê D 8 < s y d+n k 8 H L < 8 H L < 8 @88 < 8 @ D<< ê D<D 5 H L 4 s y 3 d+n k 2 H L 1 k 10 20 30 40 50 60 Solutions for y and c Our steady-state value of k implies values for y and c. Clear ss`y, ss`c ss`y, ss`c = y ss`k Simplify, 1 - s * ss`y aa s a aa s a aa @ 1-a , aa D1 - s 1-a 8 n + d < 8 @ D êên + d H L < : K O H L K O > Solow_continuous.nb 7 Comparative Statics ss`kyc = ss`k, ss`y, ss`c ; ss`exogs = s, aa, d, n ; ss`dkdx = D ss`k, ss`exogs Simplify ss`dkdx 8 Sign Simplify< ss`k8 1 1< -1 -1 ss`dkdx @ 8, , <D êê, Simplify 1 - a s aa n + d n + d êê êê 1 1 1 1 aa s aa s aa s aa s 1-a 1-a 1-a 1-a n+d n+d n+d n+d - , - : , >,êê s -1 + a aa -1 + a H -1L+ a H n +Ld -1 + a n + d 1,I1, -M1, -1 I M I M I M : > TrueH L H L H L H L H L H L 8 < ss`dydx = D ss`y, ss`exogs Simplify ss`dydx Sign Simplify a ss`y 1 1 -1 -1 ss`dydx @ 8 , <,D êê , Simplify 1 - a s a * aa n + d n + d êê êê a a 1 1 aa s aa s aa s aa s aa a 1-a 1-a a 1-a a 1-a n+d n+d n+d n+d - , : , , > êê s -1 + a 1 - a s -H1 + a L sH -1 +La 1, 1, -I1, -M1 I M I M I M : > True H L H L H L 8 < Exercise: explain why the following is false.
Recommended publications
  • MA Macroeconomics 10. Growth Accounting
    MA Macroeconomics 10. Growth Accounting Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Autumn 2014 Karl Whelan (UCD) Growth Accounting Autumn 2014 1 / 20 Growth Accounting The final part of this course will focus on \growth theory." This branch of macroeconomics concerns itself with what happens over long periods of time. We will discuss the factors that determine the growth rate of the economy over the long run and what can policy measures do to affect it. This is closely related to the crucial question of what makes some countries rich and others poor. We will begin by covering \growth accounting" { a technique for explaining the factors that determine growth. Karl Whelan (UCD) Growth Accounting Autumn 2014 2 / 20 Production Functions We assume output is determined by an aggregate production function technology depending on the total amount of labour and capital. For example, consider the Cobb-Douglas production function: α β Yt = At Kt Lt where Kt is capital input and Lt is labour input. An increase in At results in higher output without having to raise inputs. Macroeconomists usually call increases in At \technological progress" and often refer to this as the \technology" term. At is simply a measure of productive efficiency and it may go up or down for all sorts of reasons, e.g. with the imposition or elimination of government regulations. Because an increase in At increases the productiveness of the other factors, it is also sometimes known as Total Factor Productivity (TFP). Karl Whelan (UCD) Growth Accounting Autumn 2014 3 / 20 Productivity Growth Output per worker is often labelled productivity by economists with increases in output per worker called productivity growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring the “Ideas” Production Function
    1%(5 :25.,1* 3$3(5 6(5,(6 0($685,1* 7+( ³,'($6´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³,GHDV´ 3URGXWLRQ )XQWLRQ (YLGHQH IURP ,QWHUQDWLRQDO 3DWHQW 2XWSXW 0LKDHO ( 3RUWHU DQG 6RWW 6WHUQ 1%(5 :RUNLQJ 3DSHU 1R 6HSWHPEHU -(/ 1R 26 26 2 $%675$&7 7KLV SDSHU HVWLPDWHV WKH SDUDPHWHUV RI WKH ³LGHDV´ SURGXWLRQ IXQWLRQ HQWUDO WR UHHQW PRGHOV RI HRQRPL JURZWK :H GR VR E\ HYDOXDWLQJ WKH GHWHUPLQDQWV RI ³LQWHUQDWLRQDO´ SDWHQWLQJ UDWHV DURVV WKH 2(&'6 ZKHUH DQ LQWHUQDWLRQDO SDWHQW LV RQH JUDQWHG E\ WKH 86 SDWHQW RIILH WR D IRUHLJQ HVWDEOLVKPHQW 7DNLQJ DGYDQWDJH RI YDULDWLRQ LQ WKH IORZ RI LGHDV SURGXHG E\ GLIIHUHQW RXQWULHV RYHU WLPH6 ZH SURYLGH HYLGHQH IRU WKUHH PDLQ ILQGLQJV )LUVW6 DW WKH OHYHO RI WKH SURGXWLRQ RI LQWHUQDWLRQDO SDWHQWV6 RXQWU\OHYHO 5>' SURGXWLYLW\ LQUHDVHV SURSRUWLRQDOO\ ZLWK WKH VWRN RI LGHDV DOUHDG\ GLVRYHUHG6 D NH\ SDUDPHWUL UHVWULWLRQ DVVRLDWHG
    [Show full text]
  • ECON3102-005 Chapter 4: Firm Behavior
    ECON3102-005 Chapter 4: Firm Behavior Neha Bairoliya Spring 2014 • The representative firm demands labor and supplies consumption goods. Review and Introduction • The representative consumer supplies labor and demands consumption goods. Review and Introduction • The representative consumer supplies labor and demands consumption goods. • The representative firm demands labor and supplies consumption goods. • Production Function Y = zF (K; Nd ) • Because this is a one-period model, we treat K as a fixed input. In the SR, firms cannot vary their capital input. • z is called the total factor productivity, as an increase in z makes both K and Nd more productive. • Y is output of consumption goods. The Representative Firm • Assume a representative firm which owns capital (plant and equipment), hires labor to produce consumption goods. • Because this is a one-period model, we treat K as a fixed input. In the SR, firms cannot vary their capital input. • z is called the total factor productivity, as an increase in z makes both K and Nd more productive. • Y is output of consumption goods. The Representative Firm • Assume a representative firm which owns capital (plant and equipment), hires labor to produce consumption goods. • Production Function Y = zF (K; Nd ) • z is called the total factor productivity, as an increase in z makes both K and Nd more productive. • Y is output of consumption goods. The Representative Firm • Assume a representative firm which owns capital (plant and equipment), hires labor to produce consumption goods. • Production Function Y = zF (K; Nd ) • Because this is a one-period model, we treat K as a fixed input.
    [Show full text]
  • Input Demands
    Economics 326: Input Demands Ethan Kaplan October 24, 2012 Outline 1. Terms 2. Input Demands 1 Terms Labor Productivity: Output per unit of labor. Y (K; L) L What is the labor productivity of the US? Output is rouhgly US$14.7 trillion. The labor force is roughly 153 million people. Therefore, the aggregate labor productivity for the US is: $96; 000 How is this di¤erent from GDP per capita. The main di¤erence is that we are measuring output per work- ing person not output per person living in the US. Marginal Product: The additional output from an addition unit of input: @F = Marginal Product of Labor @L @F = Marginal Product of Capital @K @F = Marginal Product of Land @T Declining Marginal Productivity: We usually assume that the marginal product of an input declines with input usage. Think about farm production. We have land, labor and capital. If we start with 2 people and 40 acres of land and zero capital and we then buy a tractor, output will increase a lot. If we then buy a second tractor, output might increase less than with one tractor because the second trator will probably not be used as often as the …rst. If we then buy a third tractor, the increase in output will be very low. (Show graph). 2 Input Demands The producer solves the pro…t maximization problem choosing the amount of capital and labor to employ. In doing so, the producer derives input demands. These are the analogues of Marshallian Demand in consumer theory. They are a function of prices of inputs and the price of output.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Lecture Notes - Production Functions - 1/5/2017 D.A
    1 Lecture Notes - Production Functions - 1/5/2017 D.A. 2 Introduction Production functions are one of the most basic components of economics • They are important in themselves, e.g. • — What is the level of returns to scale? — How do input coeffi cients on capital and labor change over time? — How does adoption of a new technology affect production? — How much heterogeneity is there in measured productivity across firms, and what ex- plains it? — How does the allocation of firm inputs relate to productivity Also can be important as inputs into other interesting questions, e.g. dynamic models of • industry evolution, evaluation of firm conduct (e.g. collusion) For this lecture note, we will work with a simple two input Cobb-Douglas production function • 0 1 2 "i Yi = e Ki Li e where i indexes firms, Ki is units of capital, Li is units of labor, and Yi is units of output. ( 0, 1, 2) are parameters and "i captures unobservables that affects output (e.g. weather, soil quality, management quality) Take natural logs to get: • yi = 0 + 1ki + 2li + "i This can be extended to • — Additional inputs, e.g. R&D (knowledge capital), dummies representing discrete tech- nologies, different types of labor/capital, intermediate inputs. — Later we will see more flexible models yi = f (ki, li; ) + "i yi = f (ki, li,"i; ) (with scalar/monotonic "i) yi = 0 + 1iki + 2ili + "i 3 Endogeneity Issues Problem is that inputs ki, li are typically choice variables of the firm. Typically, these choices • are made to maximize profits, and hence will often depend on unobservables "i.
    [Show full text]
  • The Historical Role of the Production Function in Economics and Business
    American Journal of Business Education – April 2011 Volume 4, Number 4 The Historical Role Of The Production Function In Economics And Business David Gordon, University of Saint Francis, USA Richard Vaughan. University of Saint Francis, USA ABSTRACT The production function explains a basic technological relationship between scarce resources, or inputs, and output. This paper offers a brief overview of the historical significance and operational role of the production function in business and economics. The origin and development of this function over time is initially explored. Several various production functions that have played an important historical role in economics are explained. These consist of some well known functions, such as the Cobb-Douglas, Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES), and Generalized and Leontief production functions. This paper also covers some relatively newer production functions, such as the Arrow, Chenery, Minhas, and Solow (ACMS) functions, the transcendental logarithmic (translog), and other flexible forms of the production function. Several important characteristics of the production function are also explained in this paper. These would include, but are not limited to, items such as the returns to scale of the function, the separability of the function, the homogeneity of the function, the homotheticity of the function, the output elasticity of factors (inputs), and the degree of input substitutability that each function exhibits. Also explored are some of the duality issues that potentially exist between certain production and cost functions. The information contained in this paper could act as a pedagogical aide in any microeconomics-based course or in a production management class. It could also play a role in certain marketing courses, especially at the graduate level.
    [Show full text]
  • Aggregate Production Functions Are NOT Neoclassical
    Aggregate Production Functions are NOT Neoclassical Stefano Zambelli∗ May 15, 2014 Submitted for presentation at the 55th Trento Conference of the Societa' Italiana degli Economisti. Not to be quoted or reproduced without permission. Abstract The issue of whether production functions are consistent with the neoclassical postulates has been the topic of intensive debates. One of the issues is whether the production of an aggregate economic system can be represented as if it was a simple neoclassical well-behaved production function with inputs the aggregate capital K, homogeneous with output Y , and aggregate labor, L. Standard postulates are those of the marginal productivities - and the associated demand of labor and capital - are negatively related with the factor prices, namely the wage rate and the profit rate. The cases where the neoclassical properties do not hold are often regarded as anomalies. In this paper we use real input-output data and we search for these anomalies. We compute the aggregate values for capital, production and labour. We find that for the dataset considered the neoclassical postulates do not hold. We consider this to be a very robust result. The implication is that standard models relying on the neoclassical aggregate Cobb-Douglas-like production functions do not hold. Keywords: Aggregate Neoclassical Production Function, Cobb-Douglas, CES, Technological Change, Macroeconomics, Growth. JEL classifications: C61, C63, C67, O47 D r a f t ∗Department of Economics and Management, Algorithmic Social Sciences Research Unit (ASSRU - www.assru.economia.unitn.it), University of Trento; via Inama, 5, 38100 Trento, Italy; E-mail: ste- [email protected] 1 1 Introduction It is a widespread practice among most (macro) economists to use the \neoclassical" aggre- gate production function while constructing (macro)economic models.
    [Show full text]
  • Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6)
    Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Lectures 09-10 Feb 06/09 2017 Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Production The theory of the firm describes how a firm makes cost- minimizing production decisions and how the firm’s resulting cost varies with its output. The Production Decisions of a Firm The production decisions of firms are analogous to the purchasing decisions of consumers, and can likewise be understood in three steps: 1. Production Technology 2. Cost Constraints 3. Input Choices Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.1 THE TECHNOLOGY OF PRODUCTION ● factors of production Inputs into the production process (e.g., labor, capital, and materials). The Production Function qFKL= (,) (6.1) ● production function Function showing the highest output that a firm can produce for every specified combination of inputs. Remember the following: Inputs and outputs are flows. Equation (6.1) applies to a given technology. Production functions describe what is technically feasible when the firm operates efficiently. Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.1 THE TECHNOLOGY OF PRODUCTION The Short Run versus the Long Run ● short run Period of time in which quantities of one or more production factors cannot be changed. ● fixed input Production factor that cannot be varied. ● long run Amount of time needed to make all production inputs variable. Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.2 PRODUCTION WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT (LABOR) TABLE 6.1 Production with One Variable Input Amount Amount Total Average Marginal of Labor (L) of Capital (K) Output (q) Product (q/L) Product (∆q/∆L) 0 10 0 — — 1 10 10 10 10 2 10 30 15 20 3 10 60 20 30 4 10 80 20 20 5 10 95 19 15 6 10 108 18 13 7 10 112 16 4 8 10 112 14 0 9 10 108 12 -4 10 10 100 10 -8 Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.2 PRODUCTION WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT (LABOR) Average and Marginal Products ● average product Output per unit of a particular input.
    [Show full text]
  • Production Functions and Productivity Slides
    Production Functions and Productivity Paul T. Scott NYU Stern [email protected] PhD Empirical IO Fall 2017 1 / 84 Intro Overview I Brief background on industry dynamics I Methods for estimating production functions: I Olley Pakes (1995) I Ackerberg, Caves, and Frazer (2015) I What production analysis can say about market power: I De Loecker and Warzynski (2012) I These tools are highly relevant outside IO, notably in trade, macro, and development 2 / 84 Intro Some Questions I Role of entry and exit in driving growth? I Impact of events like trade liberalization and deregulation on productivity? I Persistence of productivity within plant/firm? I What are the factors driving plant/firm-level changes in productivity and growth? 3 / 84 Firm size distribution The firm size distribution I A very robust finding: the firm size distribution has a long upper tail. I ... this holds within the vast majority of industries, countries, and after conditioning on observable characteristics. I Typically, the size distribution is approximated with a lognormal or Pareto distribbtion. I Broader theme: almost any variable we look at exhibits tremendous heterogeneity across firms 4 / 84 Firm size distribution Gibrat’s Law: a trivial model of growth and heterogeneity I Gibrat’s law states that if the growth rate of a variable is independent of its size and over time, it will have a log-normal distribution in the long run. I Let Yit denote firm i’s size (employment or output) in year t . Suppose it evolves according to the following process: (Yi,t+1 − Yit )/Yit = εit where εit is i.i.d.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 3: National Income (Long-Run Neoclassical Theory)
    Chapter 3: National Income (Long-Run Neoclassical Theory) The economy uses inputs (or factors) of labor (L) and capital (K) to produce the output or GDP (Y). The wage and rent are denoted by W and R, respectively. We want to answer two questions Q1: How to use K and L to produce Y? So where does national income come from? Q2: How are W and R determined? So how is the national income distributed among owners of labor and capital? Mathematically, the production process is captured by the production function of Y = F(K, L) We assume (1) ̅ ̅, so the quantity of both inputs are fixed in long term. (2) Both K and L are fully utilized. So there is no unemployment. Assumptions (1) and (2) imply that_________ (3) Let ( ) ( ) denote the marginal product of labor, ( ) ( ) the marginal product of capital. As K or L rises, Y rises. Mathematically __________ 1 (4) As K or L rises, Y rises but at decreasing rate. This assumption is called decreasing marginal product. Mathematically, __________________. We can draw the graph (Figure 3-3) that represents a typical production function as (5) The production function has the property of constant returns to scale. That is, ( ) (1) So if both inputs are doubled ( =2), the output is doubled as well. A production function with constant returns to scale has the property of (2) This result is called Euler’s theorem. Proof (Optional) 2 (6) The firm is competitive in both output market and input market. In other words, the firm takes the output price (P) and the input prices (W, R) as given.
    [Show full text]
  • Redalyc.Aggregate Production Functions, Neoclassical Growth
    Estudios de Economía Aplicada ISSN: 1133-3197 [email protected] Asociación Internacional de Economía Aplicada España FELIPE, JESUS; FISHER, FRANKLIN M. Aggregate production functions, neoclassical growth models and the aggregation problem Estudios de Economía Aplicada, vol. 24, núm. 1, abril, 2006, pp. 127-163 Asociación Internacional de Economía Aplicada Valladolid, España Available in: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=30113179006 How to cite Complete issue Scientific Information System More information about this article Network of Scientific Journals from Latin America, the Caribbean, Spain and Portugal Journal's homepage in redalyc.org Non-profit academic project, developed under the open access initiative E STUDIOS DE ECONOMÍA APLICADA VOL. 24-1, 2006. P ÁGS. 127-163 Aggregate production functions, neoclassical growth models and the aggregation problem JESUS FELIPE(*) y FRANKLIN M. FISHER(**) (*) Macroeconomics and Finance Research Division. Economics and Research Department. Asian Development Bank. Manila, Philippines; (**) Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Cambridge, MA 02139-4307 E-mails: (*) [email protected] - (**) ffi [email protected] ABSTRACT Lawrence R. Klein pioneered the work on aggregation, in particular in production functions, in the 1940s. He paved the way for researchers to establish the conditions under which a series of micro production functions can be aggregated so as to yield an aggregate production function. This work is fundamental in order to establish the legitimacy of theoretical (neoclassical) growth models and empirical work in this area (e.g., growth accounting exercises, econometric estimation of aggregate production functions). This is because these models depend on the assumption that the technology of an economy can be represented by an aggregate production function, i.e., that the aggregate production function exists.
    [Show full text]
  • 14.452 Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth
    14.452 Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 8, 13 & 15, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lectures 5-7 November8,13&15,2018 1/83 Introduction Introduction Foundations of Neoclassical Growth Solow model: constant saving rate. Ramsey or Cass-Koopmans model: differs from the Solow model only because it explicitly models the consumer side and endogenizes savings. This model specifies the preference orderings of individuals and derives their decisions from these preferences. It also Enables better understanding of the factors that affect savings decisions. Enables to discuss the “optimality” of equilibria Clarifies whether the (competitive) equilibria of growth models can be “improved upon”. Beyond its use as a basic growth model, also a workhorse for many areas of macroeconomics. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lectures 5-7 November8,13&15,2018 2/83 Introduction Preliminaries Preliminaries Consider an economy consisting of a unit measure of infinitely-lived households. I.e., an uncountable number of households: e.g., the set of households could be represented by the unit interval [0, 1]. H Emphasize that each household is infinitesimal and will have no effect on aggregates. Can alternatively think of as a countable set of the form H = 1, 2, ..., M with M = ¥, without any loss of generality. H f g Advantage of unit measure: averages and aggregates are the same Simpler to have as a finite set in the form 1, 2, ..., M with M large but finite. H f g Acceptable for many models, but with overlapping generations require the set of households to be infinite.
    [Show full text]