SHOULD the TERM of COPYRIGHT PROTECTION BE EXTENDED OR SHORTENED in the UK? 6Pm – 8:30 Pm Thursday 29 Th September 2005

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

SHOULD the TERM of COPYRIGHT PROTECTION BE EXTENDED OR SHORTENED in the UK? 6Pm – 8:30 Pm Thursday 29 Th September 2005 SHOULD THE TERM OF COPYRIGHT PROTECTION BE EXTENDED OR SHORTENED IN THE UK? 6pm – 8:30 pm Thursday 29 th September 2005 The Durham Street Auditorium, RSA , 8 John Adam Street, London WC2N The Labour Manifesto committed the Government to “modernise copyr ight and other forms of protection of intellectual property rights so that they are appropriate for the digital age”. The Department for Culture, Media and Sport is currently undertaking a review of copyright with the aim of developing an IP framework tha t balances the needs of consumers, creators and businesses. However, most attention and press speculation has centred on the possible extension of copyright term, particularly in sound recordings, in the UK. This evening seminar, organised jointly by the ippr, PCM LP and the RSA, sought to directly consider the question “should the term of copyright protection be extended or shortened in the UK?” and to provide discussion around the pros and cons of alternative approaches in the context of supporting creat ive industries, and creativity, in the UK . Speakers: • Professor Lawrence Lessig , Professor of Law, Stanford University and founder of the Centre for Internet and Society, Stanford • John McVay, Chief Executive, Pact • Adam Singer , CEO, MCPS -PRS Alliance Ch air: John Howkins, RSA Presentations were followed with a question and answer session. LAWRENCE LESSIG Lawrence Lessig began by detailing the history of copyright and accused current policy makers as having forgotten this history . Inst ead of discussion over fair length of term and limits, there was now a race for perpetual copyright motivated largely by a process of ‘harmonisation’. Turning to the topic of the seminar, Lessig asked, if copyright is about encouragement and incentive for artists, will an extension in term improve incentive? In considering this question we should distinguish between prospective and retrospective change. In terms of prospective change, is the current fifty year term enough of an incentive to create? How much more valuable is a 95 year term? Lessig claimed the difference in income is tiny. If we consider the discount rate of value of creative content as 10 per cent, then the difference in income receive from a 50 year term and a 95 year term is 1 per cen t. Lessig denied that restricting the length of term and not increasing prospective value of copyright by 1 per cent would deter any would be creators from creating. In terms of retrospective change, the benefits of extending length of copyright term to society are nil. The 1 per cent increase will make people richer but would essentially be a gift that bore no requirement for re -investment in new creative works. Thus, if we focus on the principle of copyright, i.e. providing an incentive to create, the re is no reason for extending term. Looking at the issue pragmatically, Lessig thought that copyright term would be extended but, he said, there was no reason to extend it indiscriminately. A vast amount of works still protected under copyright are comme rcially unviable and, as such, unavailable for access. In a large number of cases, where attempts could be made to place such creativity in the public domain these are restricted since it is impossible to trace the copyright owner. Thus while public inst itutions such as the British Library work to digitise cultural heritage and provide public access, there work is made more difficult by being unable to trace the owners of many works, a situation which is likely to get worse if copyright is further extende d. Lessig proposed a solution introducing discrimination into awarded copyright. Copyright could be kept at the current length of term. If, once this is facing expiration, you want to extend protection copyright holders should be made to re - register and to pay a nominal sum of £1 to do so. The vast majority of rightsholders would not re -register. JOHN McVAY Speaking as someone representing rightsholders, John McVay stated that he would not like to see a decrease in length of term as this would work as a deterrent for investment, much of which comes from the city for high fixed costs productions such as films etc. It was important to recognise the important of television and film content to the UK economy - the UK is second only to the US in global TV exports – and the importance of copyright term in attracting investments and getting a return on these. There are concerns in the creative industries about where intellectual property rights could stifle legitimate access and creativity as many creators are users of rights as well as rightsholders. McVay emphasised the need for creating a sustainable, flexible regime. He referred to the work undertaken by the Government IP Forums who have recently produced a manifesto for creativity, under the banner C REATE (Creativity, Respect, Education, Access, Trust, and Economics ). ADAM SINGER Adam Singer defended the creative industries’ reactions to such things as creative commons and so on, saying there is a lot of fear amongst industries that are seeing their traditional revenue models threatened. The main question we must seek to answer, he said, is what is the right structure to ensure a creative community? With manufacturing in decline, intellectual property is growing in economic importance. We need to think about how we can encourage investment in the creative industries. DISCUSSION Re -registering Copyright Previously, registering copyright was seen as too burdensome and costly for creators and thus copyright is awarded automatically. However, we now have the technologies which are capable of making this process much less troublesome: we are quite happy to re -register domain names every few years for example. There was some debate not about whether re -registering was right or wrong, but at which poin t re -registration should be demanded. Moral Rights There was much discussion concerning moral rights, and whether they should be perpetual and / or inalienable. There was some opinion that the moral right system should be the one to focus on during the in ternet age. Lessig stated we should seek to distinguish between strong control for your work and strong control over others building on works. We need to recognise the importance of encouraging derivative works. Copyright is also different for derivativ e works in music and film for example, in music several artists can cover the same song however film makers cannot make different films from the same book. It was felt that, on occasion, we could be realising more value for creative works if it weren’t fo r the legal systems. There was a different perception in the importance of moral rights depending on what medium of creativity was being used. For example, in the context of text we don’t question the legitimacy of using sections for criticism and parody but there aren’t these norms in film and music etc. As people become multi media producers, there was a sense that the gap between the markets would shrink. Assigning Copyright There was concern over creators assigning their copyright over to large corp orations and not seeing the benefits should there be significant return later in the copyright term. In copyright transfers there is a legal right for the original creator to terminate transfer after 35 years. Assigning or giving up copyright has been one of the music industry’s major criticisms of Creative Commons. Lessig announced Creative Commons is working on a project to allow for people to ‘get back’ copyrighted material they have previously released under a creative commons license. The role of contract was also discussed. In the US, copyright is only granted to authors rather than authors and a proprietor therefore being able to make money from your creation is in some ways inalienable. Tracing Copyright Many institutions attempting to put cr eative heritage online have faced problems in tracing owners of protected works. The collecting societies have largely provided an economy of scale in enabling people to exploit works without having to enter new negotiations for every single use. Collect ion societies have lowered the costs of law and lessened transaction costs but they are territory based, which is not in line with the global nature of the Internet. They also cannot create scarcity therefore the question was posed as to whether a monopol y system was the best way of achieving value. The Public Domain The panel was asked why we are so worried about the public domain now, given that in some senses it is stronger than in the 18 th century for example. Lessig did not agree the public domain w as more robust. The scope of copyright is much broader and a smaller group of people, through media concentration, have much greater control. There is a range of new ways to use culture which are currently being restricted by intellectual property rights . For example, Google has recently been working to scan books to make them available online, for people to search for specific words and phrases. For Lessig, this represented an important advance in access to knowledge. However, in some cases Google wer e unable to establish who owned copyright for some works. They offered to remove any books if the owner asked them to. However, the plan has now been suspended due to objections from rightsholders. There is also an emerging conflict in the way people ar e using new technologies to interpret culture. A large stock of creativity is now found in remixing existing culture and presenting it in different ways rather than creating something entirely ‘new’. This conflict is apparent in education, but also in n ew forms of creativity which incorporate samples from other media.
Recommended publications
  • 01-618. Eldred V. Ashcroft
    1 IN THE SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES 2 - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -X 3 ERIC ELDRED, ET AL., : 4 Petitioners : 5 v. : No. 01-618 6 JOHN D. ASHCROFT, ATTORNEY : 7 GENERAL : 8 - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -X 9 Washington, D.C. 10 Wednesday, October 9, 2002 11 The above-entitled matter came on for oral 12 argument before the Supreme Court of the United States at 13 10:03 a.m. 14 APPEARANCES: 15 LAWRENCE LESSIG, ESQ., Stanford, California; on behalf of 16 the Petitioners. 17 THEODORE B. OLSON, ESQ., Solicitor General, Department of 18 Justice, Washington, D.C.; on behalf of the 19 Respondent. 20 21 22 23 24 25 1 Alderson Reporting Company 1111 14th Street, N.W. Suite 400 1-800-FOR-DEPO Washington, DC 20005 1 C O N T E N T S 2 ORAL ARGUMENT OF PAGE 3 LAWRENCE LESSIG, ESQ. 4 On behalf of the Petitioners 3 5 ORAL ARGUMENT OF 6 THEODORE B. OLSON, ESQ. 7 On behalf of the Respondent 25 8 REBUTTAL ARGUMENT OF 9 LAWRENCE LESSIG, ESQ. 10 On behalf of the Petitioners 48 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 2 Alderson Reporting Company 1111 14th Street, N.W. Suite 400 1-800-FOR-DEPO Washington, DC 20005 1 P R O C E E D I N G S 2 (10:03 a.m.) 3 CHIEF JUSTICE REHNQUIST: We'll hear argument 4 now in Number 01-618, Eric Eldred v. John D. Ashcroft. 5 Mr. Lessig. 6 ORAL ARGUMENT OF LAWRENCE LESSIG 7 ON BEHALF OF THE PETITIONERS 8 MR.
    [Show full text]
  • Focus Papers: Duke Conference on the Public Domain
    Digital Information, Digital Networks, and The Public Domain Pamela Samuelson* I. Introduction Whether the public domain is a virtual wasteland of undeserving detritus or the font of all new creation is the subject of some debate.1 Those who adhere to the former perspective do not worry about “threats” to this domain any more than they would worry about scavengers who go to garbage dumps to look for abandoned property. Adherents of the latter view are, interestingly enough, not of one mind about “threats” to this domain. Some believe that propertizing value residing in the public domain will produce more social benefit than letting content languish there,2 while others regard propertization itself as the main threat to the public domain.3 At the risk of seeming a contrarian, I concur with all three views: some of what is in the public domain is detritus; some of what is valuable in the public domain might be better utilized if propertized to some degree; other parts of the public domain need to remain open and unownable as sources for future creations. In the course of explaining why I embrace this seemingly contradictory perspective, I will offer a map of the public domain.4 * Chancellor's Professor of Law and of Information Management, University of California at Berkeley. This draft has been prepared for a conference on the public domain at Duke University Law School on November 9-10, 2001. My thanks to James Boyle, David Lange, and J.H. Reichman for convening this event and inviting me to participate in it, as well as for the many works they have contributed to the literature on this subject.
    [Show full text]
  • Harmonizing Copyright's Internationalization With
    HARMONIZING COPYRIGHT’S INTERNATIONALIZATION WITH DOMESTIC CONSTITUTIONAL CONSTRAINTS A quick glance through recent copyright legislation suggests that we are in the midst of a “second enclosure movement,” this time fenc- ing off the “intangible commons of the mind” instead of the physical commons of the land.1 In 1992 the Copyright Renewal Act2 (CRA) abolished the longstanding renewal requirement for nearly all works; in 1998 the Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act3 (CTEA) ex- tended the term of copyright protection by twenty years and the Digi- tal Millennium Copyright Act4 (DMCA) heightened penalties for copy- right infringement on the Internet and provided copyright owners with an increased ability to control access to their copyrighted digital me- dia. These are simply a few examples drawn from the larger set of copyright legislation enacted within the past two decades, a set that taken as a whole provides worrisome evidence of a one-way ratcheting up of copyright protection. No surprise, then, that there is widespread feeling among many copyright scholars that Congress has unabashedly ceded to the lobby- ing pressures of the copyright industries and steadily cut into the heart of the public domain.5 Scholars have unleashed a flurry of articles in the past decade warning about the public harms of copyright exten- sions and, cognizant of the skewed political economy, calling for meas- ––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––– 1 James Boyle, The Second Enclosure Movement and the Construction of the Public Domain, LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS., Winter/Spring 2003, at 33, 37 (internal quotation mark omitted). 2 Pub. L. No. 102-307, 106 Stat. 264 (1992).
    [Show full text]
  • ELDRED V. ASHCROFT: the CONSTITUTIONALITY of the COPYRIGHT TERM EXTENSION ACT by Michaeljones
    COPYRIGHT ELDRED V. ASHCROFT: THE CONSTITUTIONALITY OF THE COPYRIGHT TERM EXTENSION ACT By MichaelJones On January 15, 2003, the Supreme Court upheld the constitutionality of the Copyright Term Extension Act ("CTEA"), which extended the term of copyright protection by twenty years.2 The decision has been ap- plauded by copyright protectionists who regard the extension as an effec- tive incentive to creators. In their view, it is a perfectly rational piece of legislation that reflects Congress's judgment as to the proper copyright term, balances the interests of copyright holders and users, and brings the3 United States into line with the European Union's copyright regime. However, the CTEA has been deplored by champions of a robust public domain, who see the extension as a giveaway to powerful conglomerates, which runs contrary to the public interest.4 Such activists see the CTEA as, in the words of Justice Stevens, a "gratuitous transfer of wealth" that will impoverish the public domain. 5 Consequently, Eldred, for those in agree- ment with Justice Stevens, is nothing less than the "Dred Scott case for 6 culture." The Court in Eldred rejected the petitioners' claims that (1) the CTEA did not pass constitutional muster under the Copyright Clause's "limited © 2004 Berkeley Technology Law Journal & Berkeley Center for Law and Technology. 1. Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act, 17 U.S.C. §§ 108, 203, 301-304 (2002). The Act's four provisions consider term extensions, transfer rights, a new in- fringement exception, and the division of fees, respectively; this Note deals only with the first provision, that of term extensions.
    [Show full text]
  • Guarding Against Abuse: the Costs of Excessively Long Copyright Terms
    GUARDING AGAINST ABUSE: THE COSTS OF EXCESSIVELY LONG COPYRIGHT TERMS By Derek Khanna* I. INTRODUCTION Copyrights are intended to encourage creative works through the mechanism of a statutorily created1 limited property right, which some prominent think tanks and congressional organizations have referred to as a form of govern- ment regulation.2 Under both economic3 and legal analysis,4 they are recog- * Derek Khanna is a fellow with X-Lab and a technology policy consultant. As a policy consultant he has never worked for any organizations that lobby or with personal stakes in copyright terms, and neither has Derek ever lobbied Congress. He was previously a Yale Law School Information Society Project Fellow. He was featured in Forbes’ 2014 list of top 30 under 30 for law in policy and selected as a top 200 global leader of tomorrow for spear- heading the successful national campaign on cell phone unlocking which led to the enact- ment of copyright reform legislation to legalize phone unlocking. He has spoken at the Con- servative Political Action Conference, South by Southwest, the International Consumer Electronics Show and at several colleges across the country as a paid speaker with the Fed- eralist Society. He also serves as a columnist or contributor to National Review, The Atlan- tic and Forbes. He was previously a professional staff member for the House Republican Study Committee, where he authored the widely read House Republican Study Committee report “Three Myths about Copyright Law.” 1 See Edward C. Walterscheld, Defining the Patent and Copyright Term: Term Limits and the Intellectual Property Clause, 7 J.
    [Show full text]
  • 01-618, Eldred V. Ashcroft
    (Slip Opinion) OCTOBER TERM, 2002 1 Syllabus NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued. The syllabus constitutes no part of the opinion of the Court but has been prepared by the Reporter of Decisions for the convenience of the reader. See United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co., 200 U. S. 321, 337. SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES Syllabus ELDRED ET AL. v. ASHCROFT, ATTORNEY GENERAL CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT No. 01–618. Argued October 9, 2002—Decided January 15, 2003 The Copyright and Patent Clause, U. S. Const., Art. I, §8, cl. 8, provides as to copyrights: “Congress shall have Power . [t]o promote the Progress of Science . by securing [to Authors] for limited Times . the exclusive Right to their . Writings.” In the 1998 Copyright Term Extension Act (CTEA), Congress enlarged the duration of copy- rights by 20 years: Under the 1976 Copyright Act (1976 Act), copy- right protection generally lasted from a work’s creation until 50 years after the author’s death; under the CTEA, most copyrights now run from creation until 70 years after the author’s death, 17 U. S. C. §302(a). As in the case of prior copyright extensions, principally in 1831, 1909, and 1976, Congress provided for application of the en- larged terms to existing and future copyrights alike. Petitioners, whose products or services build on copyrighted works that have gone into the public domain, brought this suit seeking a de- termination that the CTEA fails constitutional review under both the Copyright Clause’s “limited Times” prescription and the First Amendment’s free speech guarantee.
    [Show full text]
  • Intellectual Property: the Law and Economics Approach
    Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 19, Number 2—Spring 2005—Pages 57–73 Intellectual Property: The Law and Economics Approach Richard A. Posner he traditional focus of economic analysis of intellectual property has been on reconciling incentives for producing such property with concerns T about restricting access to it by granting exclusive rights in intellectual goods—that is, by “propertizing” them—thus enabling the owner to charge a price for access that exceeds marginal cost. For example, patentability provides an additional incentive to produce inventions, but requiring that the information in patents be published and that patents expire after a certain time limit the ability of the patentee to restrict access to the invention—and so a balance is struck. Is it an optimal balance? This question, and the broader issue of trading off incentive and access considerations, has proved intractable at the level of abstract analysis. With the rise of the law and economics movement, the focus of economic analysis of intellectual property has begun to shift to more concrete and manage- able issues concerning the structure and texture of the complicated pattern of common law and statutory doctrines, legal institutions and business practices relating to intellectual property. Among the issues discussed in this paper are the length of protection for intellectual property, the rules that allow considerable copying of intellectual property without permission of the originator, the rules governing derivative works, and alternative methods of providing incentives for the creation of intellectual property. The emphasis is on copyright law, which, perhaps because of its complex legal structure and the relative neglect by economists of the arts and entertainment, has tended to be slighted in the conventional economic analysis of intellectual property, relative to patent law, where economic analysis can draw on an extensive literature concerning the economics of innovation.
    [Show full text]
  • Copyrights in Perpetuity: Peter Pan May Never Grow up Jennifer S
    Penn State International Law Review Volume 24 Article 18 Number 4 Penn State International Law Review 5-1-2006 Copyrights in Perpetuity: Peter Pan May Never Grow Up Jennifer S. Green Follow this and additional works at: http://elibrary.law.psu.edu/psilr Recommended Citation Green, Jennifer S. (2006) "Copyrights in Perpetuity: Peter Pan May Never Grow Up," Penn State International Law Review: Vol. 24: No. 4, Article 18. Available at: http://elibrary.law.psu.edu/psilr/vol24/iss4/18 This Comment is brought to you for free and open access by Penn State Law eLibrary. It has been accepted for inclusion in Penn State International Law Review by an authorized administrator of Penn State Law eLibrary. For more information, please contact [email protected]. SComments I Copyrights in Perpetuity: Peter Pan May Never Grow Up Jennifer S. Green* I. Introduction 2004 was known as "The Year of Peter Pan" throughout the United h Kingdom.' The country celebrated the 1 0 0t anniversary of the stage play, Peter Pan, with picnics in Neverland, charity balls, treasure hunts, and appearances by Peter Pan characters in the London Marathon. 2 A movie about author James Matthew Barrie's life leading up to the premiere of Peter Pan's first appearance on the London stage was * J.D. Candidate, The Dickinson School of Law of the Pennsylvania State University, 2006; B.A., University of Pittsburgh, 2003. This paper won the local level first place prize in the 2006 Nathan Burkan Memorial Comptition. This work is for my parents, Louise and Jan, who have given me their perpetual love and support.
    [Show full text]
  • Study 30: Duration of Copyright
    86th Congress} COMMITTEE PRINT 2d Session COPYRIGHT LAW REVISION STUDIES PREPARED FOR THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON PATENTS, TRADEMARKS, AND COPYRIGHTS OF THE COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY UNITED STATES SENATE EIGHTY-SIXTH CONGRESS, SECOND SESSION PURSUANT TO S. Res. 240 STUDIES 29-31 30. Duration of Copyright Printed for the use of the Committee on the Judiciary UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 62348 WASHINGTON: 1961 COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY JAMES O. EASTLAND, MissisSippi, Chairman ESTES KEFAUVER, Tennessee ALEXANDER WILEY, Wisconsin OLIN D. JOHNSTON, South Carolina EVERETT McKINLEY DIRKSEN, Illinois THOMAS C. HENNINGS, JR., Missouri' ROMAN L. HRUSKA, Nebraska JOHN L. McCLELLAN, Arkansas KENNETH B. KEATING, New York JOSEPH C. O'MAHONEY, Wyoming NORRIS COTTON, New Hampshiro SAM J. ERVIN, JII., North Carolina JOHN A. CARROLL, Colorado THOMAS J. DODD, Connecticut PHILIP A. HART, Michigan SUBCOMMITTEE ON PATENTS, TRADEMARKS, AND COPYRIGHTS JOSEPH O. O'MAHONEY, Wyoming, C1'alrman OLIN D. JOHNSTON, South Carolina ALEXANDER WILEY, Wisconsin PHILIP A. HART, Michigan ROBERT L. WRIGHT, Chle' CoulI,el JOHN C. STEDMAN, Auoelate Coun..l STEPHEN G. HAASER, cu« Clerk • The late Hon. Thomas C. Hennings, Jr., while a member of this committee, died on Sept. 11, 1000. D FOREWORD This committee print is the tenth of a series of such prints of studies on Copyright Law Revision published by the Committee on the Judi­ ary Subcommittee on Patents, Trademarks, and Copyrights. The studies have been prepared under the supervision of the Copyright Office of the Library of Congress with a VIew to considering a general revision ofthe copyright law (title 17,U.S. Code). Provisions of the present copyright law are essentially the same as those of the statute enacted in 1909, thoug-h that statute was codified in 1947 and has been amended in a number of relatively minor re­ spects.
    [Show full text]
  • Eldred V Ashcroft And
    12 Tex. Intell. Prop. L.J. 1 Texas Intellectual Property Law Journal Fall 2003 Articles ELDRED V. ASHCROFT AND THE (HYPOTHETICAL) COPYRIGHT TERM EXTENSION ACT OF 2020 Thomas R. Leea1 Copyright (c) 2003 State Bar of Texas, Intellectual Property Law Section; Thomas R. Lee Table of Contents I. Introduction 1 II. The CTEA and the Eldred Challenge 3 III. The CTEA and the Eldred Opinion 7 IV. Marshall Mathers and the Eldred Opinion 12 A. Eldred and the Case for Constitutionality of the Mathers Act 13 B. Eldred and the Case for Unconstitutionality of the Mathers Act 16 V. Conclusion 19 I. Introduction The Supreme Court’s decision in Eldred v. Ashcroft1 establishes, at least for now, Congress’s power under the Copyright Clause to extend the copyright term applicable to existing works. In upholding the 20-year extension conferred by the Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act of 1998 (CTEA),2 the Eldred decision establishes that there is no categorical constitutional bar to a legislative extension of an existing copyright term. Justice Ginsburg’s opinion for the Court in Eldred rejected the petitioners’ argument that the CTEA “is an impermissible exercise of Congress’ power under the Copyright Clause,”3 and in so doing held that the CTEA *2 is reconcilable with both the “limited times” provision and the “progress of science” preamble of the Copyright Clause.4 But while the Eldred opinion conclusively upholds the constitutionality of the CTEA, it leaves open some important questions as to the ultimate extent of Congress’s power to enact further extensions. The opinion relies on a number of different strands of analysis that may point in opposite directions under any further extensions enacted by Congress, creating an ambiguity as to the ultimate extent of Congress’s power under the Copyright Clause.
    [Show full text]
  • Perpetual Property Sarah K
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Chicago-Kent College of Law Chicago-Kent College of Law Scholarly Commons @ IIT Chicago-Kent College of Law All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship January 2009 Perpetual Property Sarah K. Harding IIT Chicago-Kent College of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.kentlaw.iit.edu/fac_schol Part of the Property Law and Real Estate Commons Recommended Citation Sarah K. Harding, Perpetual Property, 61 Fla. L. Rev. 285 (2009). Available at: http://scholarship.kentlaw.iit.edu/fac_schol/272 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Scholarly Commons @ IIT Chicago-Kent College of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Scholarly Commons @ IIT Chicago-Kent College of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. DRAFT COPY--NOT FOR CIRCULATION OR DISTRIBUTION 8/28/2008 3:12:19 PM Perpetual Property SARAH HARDING∗ INTRODUCTION Property interests, unlike contract, tend to adhere to a limited set of specific forms – the numerus clausus principle.1 This distinction has been the subject of much scholarship in the past decade in an attempt to understand both the nature of and the reasons for the limitation on property forms that exist within the common law.2 While these limitations on form are both intriguing and central to the common law, equally significant are the temporal limitations embedded in property law – property interests are typically defined by and thus only defensible for a specific time period.
    [Show full text]
  • A Short History Of'copyright in the West, in the Ottoman Empire and in Turkey
    Türk Kütüphaneciliği 28, 4 (2014), 638-644 A Short History of'Copyright in the West, in the Ottoman Empire and in Turkey Batı Dünyası, Osmanlı İmparatorluğu ve Türkiye’de Telif Hakları Tarihçesi Nadide Güher Erer* Abstract The legal regulations concerning copyright came into existence as a result of certain historical developments. One of 'the most important agents in the historical process of copyright was the introduction of printing press. The advent of the printing press, which has been a magnetic topic in the discussions about the “history of the book”, played a crucial role in the development of copyright on the global scale. Therefore, in order to understand the historical process, it would be worthwhile to look at the evolution of copyright in Europe, in the Ottoman Empire and finally in Turkey. Keywords: Copyright; printing press; Europe; Ottoman Empire; Turkey. Öz Telif hakları ile ilgili yasal düzenlemeler bazı tarihi olaylar sonucunda ortaya çıkmıştır. Telif haklarının tarihi gelişiminde en önemli etkenlerden birisi matbaanın bulunması olmuştur ‘Kitabın tarihçesi’ ile ilgili tartışmalarda çekici bir konu olan matbaa, uluslararası arenada telif haklarının gelişmesinde çok önemli bir rol oynamıştır. Bu sebeple telif haklarının geçirdiği tarihsel süreci anlamak için, bu sürecin gelişimini Avrupa, Osmanlı İmparatorluğu ve Türkiye ekseninde ele almak uygun olacaktır. Anahtar Sözcükler: Telif hakları; matbaa; Avrupa; Osmanlı İmparatorluğu; Türkiye. History of Copyright Today’s copyright laws are the result of certain social events that took place throughout the history. It is generally acknowledged that the history of copyright starts with the introduction of the printing press. In the ancient times or middle ages the concept of copyright did not yet take shape, although there were certain regulations even before the concept of copyright emerged.
    [Show full text]