<<

Positive and the Public Provision of Transportation Infrastructure: An Evolutionary Perspective

ULRICH BLUM Dresden University of

ABSTRACT Do transportation systems, comprising infrastruc- ture, service, and use, produce external benefits? If they do, should positive externalities be accounted for in the evaluation of infrastructure investments? This paper argues that while direct, technological, external benefits from transportation are difficult to find, meaningful positive externalities can arise from transportation systems in at least two ways. First, transportation infrastructure can reduce pre- existing negative externalities, and the reduction of external cost must be considered an external bene- fit. Second, because transportation is essentially a derived demand its effects are broadly diffused throughout the primary markets that induce trans- portation demand. To the extent that changes in transportation infrastructure induce positive exter- nalities in these primary markets, external benefits should be attributed to transportation.

A ONE-SIDED EXTERNALITIES DEBATE? The general discussion on externalities of trans- portation—be they monetary or technological— usually concentrates on negative effects. In this paper, we concentrate on positive effects, although

Professor Dr. Ulrich Blum, Chair of Re- search, Dresden University of Technology, D-01062, Dresden, Germany. Email: [email protected].

81 most scholars would question their existence—and external benefits (e.g., the beauty of a in the in most cases they are right if the external effect is case of infrastructure) or something comparable to defined purely on a technological basis, leaving out “positive emissions.” The very abstract concept of monetary effects. mental maps derived from a high degree of mobil- Consequently, most of the approaches used to ity and facilitating extended interaction spaces evaluate the effects of externalities relate to the dif- might be useful, though very unlikely. ficulty of pricing negative technological external The question is: what is ground zero? To what effects.1 We may distinguish between: sort of alternative do we compare the existing Ⅵ The approach. The value of the exter- transportation system? If we know the reference nality is defined by the corresponding resource point, all effects “below” may be referred to as price of the private , which in most cases negative externalities, all effects “above” as posi- relates to prices for damage or repair. tive externalities. Of course we know that this Ⅵ The avoidance approach. The value of the exter- objective reference point does not exist, and there nality is defined by the possibility of substituting is no chance to objectively derive it. Thus, reduc- the resource, the technology, or the good in tions in negative externalities may be considered as question for a resource, technology, or good net positive externalities. without the external properties. A more challenging issue seems to be that trans- Ⅵ The risk approach. The value of the portation demand is derived from other markets. If is defined by the discounted expected monetary external effects exist in these “primary markets,” value based on an evaluation of risk. they are in a causal sense transferred from one Ⅵ The utility approach. The value of the external- place to another. This link is not restricted to geo- ity is defined by the willingness to pay in order graphical locations; it may also refer to other met- to reduce negative effects. rics, that is, product space. The capacity of these The scientific argument behind this apparent links may be an important factor in the transfer of one-sidedness—which only accounts for negative externalities. At the limit, without the transfer no effects—is that the positive effects of transporta- market would exist and, thus, no externality issue. tion investments are immediately captured by mar- In this paper, we investigate the external benefits kets, unless market failure impedes it, whereas of transportation stemming from spatial transfers most negative effects remain external. This view is from one primary market to another or from sup- reflected in most of the literature.2 Policy measures ply to demand. From what is known about spatial not correcting for this asymmetry must necessarily analysis (Blum 1996), it is clear that once markets lead to allocation failures. or points of production and consumption are The most intuitive examples of negative exter- linked by means of interaction (i.e., transportation nalities might be the adverse effects of infrastruc- in geographical markets, substitutive exchange in ture, for example, dividing up a or product markets), the derived transportation vehicle emissions. It is very difficult to imagine demand (or transfer) function reflects excess demand and supply as well as underlying external- ities. Furthermore, the effect will depend on the 1 The willingness to pay for reduced noise normally differs from costs for technological improvements in cars or actu- degree of perfection of these markets, that is, the al costs incurred in the medical sector. more they are monopolized, the smaller the trans- 2 The analysis of negative externalities of transportation in fer effect. Germany reveals costs that vary between 44 bn DM and 221 bn DM p.a. (IWD 1996). Growth effects are mostly Let us look at some intriguing examples: analyzed within the framework of production models Ⅵ A vaccine prevents the spread of a disease once (Blum 1982). External benefits have been reported in a sufficient proportion (below 100%) of a pop- Germany by Aberle (1992, 1994), who especially stressed ulation has been vaccinated. Thus, all those who the spatial aspects, the aspects of market integration, and cost savings; however, it has been argued that these bene- are not vaccinated benefit from an external ben- fits are not external at all as they are included in the allo- efit. If such a vaccine is shipped into a new mar- cation via the price system. ket, external benefits emerge there, and their

82 JOURNAL OF TRANSPORTATION AND STATISTICS OCTOBER 1998 level will depend on demand that, again, will be sumption of such a good leads to no subtraction partly influenced by transportation costs— from any other individual’s consumption of that which makes the institutional setting of the good.” As a consequence, consumers cannot be transportation market of crucial importance. excluded from consumption and there exists no Ⅵ Knowledge produced in one region is trans- rivalry for consumption. ferred to another region by means of commerce: In this definition, the pure public goods are one the level of external benefits in the sense of pole of a continuum that extends to pure private spontaneous adjustments to the will goods at the other end. It was quickly discovered, depend on the intensity of this transfer, and it however, that ideal public goods rarely exist in will be difficult to capture these effects from the reality and that private allocation is possible once beginning because of the existence of non- mechanisms can be found that: knowledge or uncertainty (Knight 1921). Ⅵ prevent the free use of these public goods, and Market integration, however, triggered by the Ⅵ force groups to reveal their preferences, at trans- same system may produce sufficient action costs that do not reduce demand to zero. information to grasp the issue and internalize it. Symmetrically, pure private goods are also only Ⅵ The existence of a transportation system allows an ideal counterpart to the ideal ; the production and consumption nodes to interact, spectrum between these poles may be seen as a enabling them to produce of scale continuum that we will address later. This leaves and of scope, and network economies. Accord- unresolved the question of what type of good a ing to the new growth theory, they are external really is, for instance. In fact, it is easy to find to the firm and can only be captured once suffi- or other types of infrastructure that can be cient information is available. positioned at different points on this continuum. Ⅵ Visitors to a resort island benefit from the beau- The following observations may serve as a first ty of nature, depending on the number of peo- challenge to the easy categorization of infrastruc- ple allowed on the island. ture: All these external benefits are surpluses in the Ⅵ there is no such thing as rivalry per se; it de- transportation demand system; in the price-volume pends on congestion and thus may vary widely diagram, a social transportation demand function for the same infrastructure. Once a motorway is with a higher reservation price reflects the level of filled to capacity, the situation is different from demand if all positive externalities were properly when it was empty. accounted for by the individuals. Ⅵ exclusion depends on the relative weight of The structure of the rest of this paper is as fol- transaction costs that vary in space and time. lows: the next part classifies goods according to Some of these transaction costs are “natural,” demand and supply characteristics; then, a model while some are created in order to force the rev- is proposed to link the characteristics of goods to elation of preferences. varying congestion levels, a dominant characteris- Ⅵ the quality of the public good may depend on tic of the use of infrastructure. Finally, we show location, that is, a constant quality and/or quan- that this classification provides new insights into tity is not guaranteed.3 the way infrastructure allocation is organized and In fact, we see that given a fixed infrastructure costs and benefits are evaluated. capacity, exclusion reduces congestion and there- fore also rivalry. INFRASTRUCTURE, PUBLIC GOODS, Our main argument is as follows: the quality of AND EXTERNALITIES a public good is not only a supply-side characteris- tic but also relates to demand (i.e., preferences). As Public Goods Following the classic definition by Samuelson (1954, 387), goods are public “which all enjoy in 3 Security is an example of the thinning out of a public common in the sense that each individual’s con- good in a spatial setting (Blum and Dudley 1991).

BLUM 83 a consequence, the usual one-dimensional classifi- without a transfer through the market mechanism. cation of goods from pure public to pure private The transfer may be prevented because of missing no longer applies. This interaction of supply and institutional arrangements: in the case of external demand was implicitly mentioned by Buchanan diseconomies, there is no automatic incentive to (1965) when defining the optimal size of a club capture these effects; in the case of external good.4 In fact, the issue of optimal size of a club economies, market imperfections may prevent relates to the problem of how to measure in real inclusion in the price system. terms what goods people want if the market prin- ciple is not completely applicable. The club good Incentive Structure and Externalities then is characterized by the ability to exclude con- If positive external economies are produced by the sumers, but no rivalry in consumption exists. It is existence of infrastructure, changes in prices, worth noting that: for example, occur as consumer demand (use) Ⅵ All club goods can be declared public goods if increases. Even if the initial externalities have been capacity is set above zero price demand. For internalized, there is no guarantee that all effects transportation, this is often the case for a high- stemming from this change in demand (and thus way in a sparsely populated area. congestion) are accounted for—be they positive or Ⅵ The same holds true for private goods, if the negative—by transaction costs.6 Thus, institutional government floods the market with free goods arrangements may play a decisive role. Positive (i.e., if mass transit is declared free, as is the case external economies may be sufficiently strong to in some European ). overcome the level of transaction costs that inhibits Ⅵ Club goods can be changed into private goods, internalization directly, or that may trigger the for- that is, by selling individual seats instead of sell- mation of new institutional arrangements. How- ing to groups in a charter flight. ever, what happens if these changes are not feasible Ⅵ A true public good cannot be turned into a club because the institutional arrangement has been or a private good. If it is not a true public good, adapted? What happens—in the sense of the initial however, then privatization is possible if control discussion—if the necessary volume of vaccines and exclusion costs become manageable, e.g., cannot be transported because the infrastructure decoding units in the field of communications. capacity is inadequate or too expensive (or both), It becomes clear from the arguments given if information exchange is incomplete because the above that capacity and how it is used may be key flow of goods is hindered, or if visitors cannot to the proper categorization of goods. access the empty island? Seemingly, the ability to transfer externalities Categories of Externalities depends on the institutional setting of the trans- External effects are impacts of activities in one portation system, or more concretely, on the organ- market on another market without compensation.5 ization of infrastructure. We propose two They affect the property rights of persons not par- classifications7: ticipating in the latter market. A distinction can be 1. The basic question of supply is to what extent— made between externalities of cost that are, by def- given a certain technology—rivalry exists and inition, captured by a market, and technological exclusion is possible. In the case of no rivalry externalities (Scitovski 1949/50), where the activi- and no exclusion, a public good is a given. The ty in one market affects the individual production combination of exclusion without rivalry or the individual utility function in another market defines the club good. Both rivalry and exclu- sion are conditions for private procurement. 4 A club good is one where the members of the club enjoy a public good and others are excluded. Some argue that highways are a club good, since one needs a motor vehi- 6 The issue of transaction costs and their impact on exter- cle to be in the club that enjoys the good. nalities was recently discussed by Demsetz (1996), with a 5 See, for instance, Arrow (1970) and Cornes and Sandler focus on possible internalization strategies of the public. (1993). 7 For an example, see Blum and Mönius (1998).

84 JOURNAL OF TRANSPORTATION AND STATISTICS OCTOBER 1998 2. The basic question of demand is what prices— 1. Positive (external) economies, that is, economies given a certain capacity—are applicable or set, of scale, of scope, and network externalities for example, by policymakers. For prices q = 0 imply that the yield increases more than propor- we have a public good; for prices q > 0 we tionately with input. In many cases, these exter- obtain a club or a private good. nal economies are a direct consequence of

The general structure is given in table 1; tc are market integration enabled by transportation or exclusion costs for club goods, tp for private goods, communications networks. tp > tc. It is evident that the actual exclusion prices 2. Control is the ability to monitor, exclude con- for public goods are zero, as nobody is excluded; sumers, and manage a good; it depends on the hypothetical exclusion costs are extremely high. transaction costs and, thus, the institutional For example, if a single driver has random access to structure (Coase 1937; Williamson 1975) that a public road system, under the institutional setting influences internalization mechanisms. of a public good, his exclusion would be extremely With increasing use, congestion and thus rivalry costly to enforce—thus exclusion prices are zero may grow. It may be operationalized by the (posi- and all drivers have free access. This dichotomy tive) opportunity costs of supplying additional also holds for other types of goods: without a quantities to maintain the competition at the exist- change of institutional setting, actual exclusion ing level. Furthermore, positive (external) econ- prices for a certain type of good are always higher omies may be reduced, thus lessening the “public” than if the hypothetical exclusion mechanisms for or “club” element in the good. Once total rivalry another type of good had been chosen. exists and results in the need to exclude additional In table 1, rivalry and excludability characteris- consumers, either a pure club good or a private tics of goods are matched with demand, where good emerges. Club goods are likely outcomes if prices are given exogenously (e.g., set by ). joint consumption of the club can be maintained, Examples are in parenthesis. otherwise a private good is likely. Mobility facilitates the transfer of external ben- External Economies and Control Costs efits, which might otherwise go unrealized, from If external economies and costs emerging from one place to another. Take, for instance, an under- setup, exclusion, and rivalry, which we now call utilized mass transit system offered as a public control costs, are characteristics of markets, two good; users only pay marginal costs with fixed criteria permit us to classify the allocation of costs financed by general . The externalities of goods: one market can easily be transferred to another market. If a road with little congestion is privately

TABLE 1 Demand and Supply Categories of Markets

Demand/ q = 0 q > 0; q – tc > 0 > q–tp q > 0; q – tp > 0 Supply

No exclusion, Public — — no rivalry (neighborhood street) (not offered) (not offered)

Exclusion, Public* Club Private* or club no rivalry (, toll road (opera seats toll possible) in the same row)

Exclusion Public* Club* Private and rivalry (congested highway, (congested toll road) (chewing gum) toll possible)

* Asterisks show inefficient allocations, and the arrows give the direction of efficient change.

BLUM 85 offered and users have to pay fixed costs, the trans- where q is the price of the private good, k is the fer between markets will become more expensive control costs incurred by the household for the and externalities will no longer spill over with the nonprivate good, and B is the budget. Let us same intensity. assume that x satisfies the same needs as y, that is, Once demand increases, congestion can be pre- x is the private substitute for a nonprivate y. vented by charging user fees and organizing clubs, Because of positive spillovers and with increased for example, through electronic road pricing. If demand, unit costs fall: congestion continues to increase and the exclusion of some potential consumers becomes too expen- sive (they might revolt), the system will collapse— (3) any transport then would have to become private. However, if with more funds invested in the system where ␭ is an externality factor, for example, a the system would produce above proportional participation index. Forming the Langrangian L yields (i.e., equal to carrying capacity), then these and taking first derivatives, we obtain: additional transactions could be offset and the sys- tem could remain stable. It is clear that if external economies exist, they might overcome additional costs. This leads us to a model that allows us to formally delimit the differ- ent goods’ characteristics.

CATEGORIZATION OF GOODS Nonprivate procurement would be preferred if: The Basic Model What is the path from private to club and public goods? Is it possible to derive functions that dis- criminate between these three categories? The fol- (7) lowing model is based on the assumption that if If households are unable to distinguish between the more than one person demands the same stemming from x and y and if the good is good, a occurs because of the non-exclu- either demanded totally or not at all because of sion principle. Economic efficiency is achieved indivisibility, we may derive for nonprivate pro- when the sum of all individuals’ marginal rates of curement: substitution curves between this public good and all other private goods and equals the marginal (8) rates of transformation for the infrastructure in question. that is, positive external economies have to over- Let us start with the maximization of a utility compensate for the relative costs of nonpublic function for two goods, a private good x and a allocation if they are to be beneficial. We may set nonprivate good y—the latter of which may later q = 1 and simplify to: turn out to be either a club or a public good: (9) max:U(x,y). (1) Let us now assume that the system is more gener- al. Following our description in the preceding part, This function is subject to a budget constraint: three goods are available: a public good (y), a club good (z), and a private good (x). The respective q • x + k • y = B, (2) costs or prices are k, p, and q. The system then becomes:

86 JOURNAL OF TRANSPORTATION AND STATISTICS OCTOBER 1998 (10) FIGURE 1 The Two Dimensions of Goods Space + Club good subject to (D) (setup and exclusion) (E) (11) Positive (external) economies (B) ␭ Public good We start with an externality factor for the club (setup) Private good good and an externality factor ␮ for the public (A) (setup, exclusion, rivalry) good, ␮ > 1. The choice for a public good becomes: – – Control costs +

(12) good is preferable, otherwise the club good be- comes more advantageous. The delimitation is given by the hyperbola line from the upper left cor- Again, we may simplify by assuming that house- ner to the center. We see that: holds consider y and z to be identical. Then the sys- Ⅵ If (external) benefits decrease, then goods previ- tem reduces to: ously provided as public or club goods may have to become private as they no longer can (13) win back their setup costs (A) or their exclusion costs (B). Ⅵ If control costs for public goods increase, then If we further assume that the offer of the (smallest the provision as club goods (D) and, ultimately, possible) club good has to match the price of the as private goods (E) becomes more likely in private good, we may set p = q, and as q = 1: order to overcome the rising costs of the now inefficient institutional arrangement. (14) Generally, any shift in congestion would amount to changes in control costs, which makes the efficient goods provision—as already shown in The delimitation between club goods and public table 1—a function of demand and capacity. goods is thus a hyperbola: the more positive exter- Furthermore, increased levels of congestion would nalities public goods comprise, the larger their impede market integration and reduce economies domain. of scale and scope, and network economies, thus limiting the yield of the existing arrangement. We Organization of Goods and the Impact of may argue that the two externality indices, ␭ and Congestion ␮, are decreasing functions of congestion and that In figure 1, positive external economies and con- control costs, k, increase with congestion, because trol (exclusion) costs are the two principal dimen- of their relation to rivalry and exclusion. Whereas sions; the relationship is shown by a line from the private provision needs an optimal degree of uti- lower left to the upper right corner. Above that lization, this may be difficult to control in a public line, the benefits supplying the good on a nonpri- or a club environment. Overutilization would then vate basis exceed the unit costs of setup and exclu- lead to private arrangements unless it can be com- sion under the institutional setting of a public or a pensated for by falling unit control costs or addi- club good. The lower triangle constitutes the tional externalities. region of private goods. Furthermore, the choice The bottom line of this argument is that external- between public goods and club goods rests with ity problems may be solved in cases of congestion by the question of whether rising control costs can be changing the institutional structure, that is, by priva- offset by (external) benefits or not. If so, the public tizing slots for road use as well as by actions that

BLUM 87 maintain the public good character of transportation Arrow, K. 1970. The Organization of Economic Activity: infrastructure (e.g., expanding capacity). This is com- Issues Pertinent to the Choice of Markets versus Non- patible with Knight’s (1924) proposition that the Market Allocation. Public Expenditures and Policy Analysis. 59–73. implementation of Pigou-taxes can be avoided if con- Blum, U. 1982. Effects of Transportation Investments on gestion allows privatization.8 Furthermore, this inter- Regional Growth: A Theoretical and Empirical In- nalization may produce sufficient profits to induce vestigation. Papers of the Regional Science Association additional traffic, which may be one reason why 49:169–184. induced traffic is so difficult to forecast (Blum 1998). ____. 1996. Benefits and External Benefits of Transport: A Spatial View. The Full Costs and Benefits of Trans- CONCLUSION portation. Edited by David L. Greene and Mark A. De- lucchi. Berlin, Germany: Springer Verlag. Positive technological external effects9 can spill over ____. 1998. What Is Induced Traffic: A Restatement, from supply to demand or from one market to anoth- Infrastructure-Induced Mobility, Round Table 105, er once the infrastructure is offered efficiently, that is, European Ministers of Transport, Paris, 223–226. according to the level of congestion that influences Blum, U. and L. Dudley. 1991. A Spatial Model of the State. setup, exclusion, and rivalry costs, as well as the yield Zeitschrift für die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft (Journal of through economies of scale and scope, and network Institutional and Theoretical Economics) 147, no. 2: economies in the primary markets. In the case of a 312–336. pure private procurement—when demand reaches Blum, U. and J. Mönius. 1998. Congestion and the Structure levels where public or club provision becomes unsus- of Goods. Mimeo. tainable—pricing may even capture some of the exter- Buchanan, J. 1965. An Economic Theory of Clubs. nal benefits as it forces people to reveal (to a greater Economica 32:1–14. or lesser extent) preferences (e.g., make the partici- Coase, R. 1937. The Nature of the Firm. Economica 4:3 86–405. pants in the market pay for the externalities stemming from vaccines, from knowledge transfer, or from the Cornes, R. and T. Sandler. 1993. The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods. Cambridge, England: amenities of an uninhabited island). Cambridge University Press. If, however, congestion is low, the emergence of Demsetz, H. 1996. The Core Disagreement Between Pigou, external benefits is only possible if transfer is not the Profession, and Coase in the Analysis of the Extern- “too expensive,” as forcing users to pay the full price ality Question. European Journal of Political Economy of infrastructure would completely eliminate the very 12:565–579. transfers that generate positive external benefits. Institut der Deutschen Wirtschaft (IWD). 1996. Kostenfrage bleibt ungeklärt. Wochenbericht 34. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Knight, F. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. Boston, MA: Houghton-Mifflin. The author is indebted to T.R. Lakshmanan, ____. 1924. Some Fallacies in the Interpretation of Social J. Mönius, and three anonymous referees for valu- Cost. Quarterly Journal of Economics 38:582–606. able comments. Samuelson, P. 1954. A Pure Theory of . The Review of Economics and Statistics 36:387–389. REFERENCES Scitovski, T. 1949/50. Two Concepts of External Economies. Review of Economic Studies 17:47–59. Aberle, G. 1992. Theoretische Grundlagen zur Erfassung und Williamson, O. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. Analysis and Bewertung des volkswirtschaftlichen Nutzens. Inter- Antitrust Implications. New York, NY: The Free Press. nationales Verkehrswesen 43, no. 5:169–175. ____. 1994. Volkswirtschaftliche Beurteilung des Straßen- güterverkehrs. Internationales Verkehrswesen 46, nos. 1 and 2:13–19.

8 The author is indebted to an anonymous referee for this valuable information. 9 The concept can easily be transferred to monetary exter- nal effects.

88 JOURNAL OF TRANSPORTATION AND STATISTICS OCTOBER 1998