Time-dependent Multi-stage Compound Real

Model and Application∗

Pu Gong∗∗, Zhi-Wei He, Jian-Ling Meng School of Management Huazhong University of Science and Technology Wuhan, P.R.China, 430074

Abstract

The simple compound option model has many limitations when applied in practice. The research on compound option theory mainly focuses on two directions. One is the extension from two-stage to multi-stage, and the other is the modification of the stochastic difference equations which describe the movement of underlying asset value. This paper extends the simple compound option model in both two directions and proposes the Time-dependent Volatility Multi-stage Compound Real Option Model. Due to the introduction of time-dependent volatility, it is difficult to derive the closed-form solution by the traditional analytical approach. This paper presents the pricing governing partial differential equation, proposes the boundary conditions and terminal conditions, and then gets the numerical solution by Finite Differential Methods. Finally this paper applies Time-dependent Volatility Multi-stage Compound Real Option Model to evaluate venture capital investment. The numerical results show that the Fixed Volatility Multi-stage Compound Real Option Model underestimates significantly the intrinsic value of venture capital investment as well as threshold of later stages, but overestimates the exercise threshold of earlier stages.

Keywords: Time-dependent volatility, Multi-stage compound real option, Contingent Claim Analysis, Finite Differential Method, Venture capital investment

1 INTRODUCTION

Compound option is option on option[1]. Research about compound option model began with the path breaking work on option pricing of Black and Scholes. They view the stock as option on the firm value, and if the firm value can be viewed as the option of the liability of firm, then the stock can be modelled as the compound option on liability of firm. Since Geske derived the closed form solution for the simple two-stage compound European option model[2][3], compound option model has been widely used. In essence, compound option model reflects one right sequence which compounds each other. So it is suitable to describe problems involved sequential decision. Generally R&D projects have multi-stage nature[4]. Only when the research or management goal of earlier stage is achieved, project can enter the next stage. Venture capital investment is another typical multi-stage investment[5]. If the given goal during the operation is not achieved, the venture capitalist can cancel the investment of next stage. Another multi-stage decision example is the firm strategy decision[6]. In fact, when the management make the strategy, they are not only interested in the direct predictable cash flow, but also the potential future investment opportunities

∗ This research is supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (70471043). ∗∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +86-27-8755-6489; Fax: +86-27-8755-6437; E-mail addresses: [email protected]

1 accompanying the current investment, which generate considerable cash flow in the future or make the firm stay in favour competition position. The above three examples are full of management flexibility and strategy flexibility. Such multi-stage decision problems can be modelled as compound option. The simple compound option model is based on the Black-Scholes framework. The assumption that the underlying asset value follows Geometric Brown Motion is very strict. Furthermore, the two-stage setting seems too simple. In practice, the simple compound option model has many limitations. The current research about compound option model mainly focus on the development of simple compound option model in two directions. One is the extension from two-stage to multi-stage. Dixit and Pindyck make use of multi-stage compound option to model the sequential investment[7]. They adopt Dynamic Programming and Contingent Claims Analysis (CCA) to derive the governing partial differential equation(PDE), and then give the analytical solution for value function and exercise threshold of compound option under some specific boundary conditions. However, numerical methods are required to solve such a two dimensions parabolic PDE under most conditions. Alvarez and Stenbacka develop a mathematical approach based on the Green representation of Markovian functionals to find the value function of compound option and the optimal exercise rules[8]. Lin extends directly the conclusion of simple compound option to multi-stage compound real option, presented the closed form solution, and compared several numerical calculating method for the solution[5]. The main shortcoming lies in the existence of nested high-dimension integral. Since the computing complexity and cost increase rapidly with the total stage number, the traditional analytical approach is hardly used, and it is difficult to derive the closed form solution. The calculation costs large computing resource. The other research direction is the improvement of stochastic differential equations which describe the movement of the underlying asset value. In the simple situation, model only consider single underlying asset, and assume that the movement of underlying asset value can be modelled as Geometric Brownian Motion. However, in the multi-stage situation, the sensitivity of the underlying motion parameters is amplified and then the simple assumption of fixed volatility and fixed return rates appears more unpractical. Buraschi and Dumas derive a solution for the valuation of compound options when the underlying asset value follows a general diffusion process[9]. The solution can be expressed as a forward integral of the price surface of European plain vanilla options. Geman, El Karoui[10] and Rochet, and Elettra and Rossella[11] focus on relaxation of the Geometric Brownian Motion assumption and introduce the time-dependent volatility. In their model they also consider the time-dependent interest rate and extend the model into two underlying asset situation. They derive the analytical solution for two-stage European compound option. However the solution still includes high-dimension integrals. Herath and Park extend the binomial lattice framework to model a multi-stage investment as a compound real option on several uncorrelated underlying variables[12]. However, they don’t consider the accuracy and convergence of the numerical solution, and the calculation of the exercise threshold. Only in few specific situations we can derive the analytical solution for compound option model. Many researcher adopted modern numerical technique to find the solution. Trigeorgis presents a numerical method called Log-Transformed Binomial Numerical Analysis Method[13], to value complex investments with multiple interacting options, including compound option. The method can achieve good consistency, stability, and efficiency. Breen presents Accelerated Binomial Option Pricing Model based on the binomial and Geske-Johnson models[14], which is faster than

2 the conventional binomial model and applicable to a wide range of option pricing problems. Though the numerical methods based on Binomial Option Pricing Model is easy to use, but in multi-stage situation the convergence of numerical solution is very slow and the computing cost will be very large. In fact, there are many other available numerical techniques, such as Finite Differential Method (FDM), Finite Elements Method, and etc, which are applicable for more complex problems and achieve better accuracy, convergence and stability. In this paper we develop the simple compound option both in two directions. We introduce time-dependent volatility into the multi-stage compound real option model, based on the Fixed Volatility Multi-stage Compound Real Option Model (FV-MCROM) presented by Lin[5]. Because of the introduction of the time-dependent volatility, it is hard to derive the analytical solution for the Time-dependent Volatility Multi-stage Compound Real Option Model (TV-MCROM). We use CCA to establish the governing PDE, and then propose the boundary conditions and terminal conditions. But in this paper we don’t try to derive the analytical solution, but apply FDM to find the numerical solution. Finally we present one application of the TV-MCROM in venture capital investment evaluation, in which we can conclude that such a development does really make sense. In the next section we briefly review the FV-MCROM. And section 3 proposes the TV-MCROM and presents the governing PDE, terminal conditions and boundary conditions. We detail the solving procedure of PDE by FDM in section 4. In Section 5 we apply the TV-MCROM to evaluate the venture capital investment with. Section 6 concludes.

2 REVIEWS OF THE FIXED VOLATILITY MULTI-STAGE COMPOUND REAL OPTION MODEL

The right sequence of investor embedded in a multi-stage project can be viewed as a series of real option. Its value consists of two components: one is value of current direct cash flow; the other is value of following investment right. In each stage the investor receives the cash flow of that stage and at the same time decides whether he will exercise the real option or not. If exercising, the investor will purchase the real option, i.e. investment right, of next stage at a certain exercise price, i.e. investment outlay, thus the project continues. If not, the investor keeps the investment outlay and abandons the following investment right, thus the project is abandoned. The investor repeats this decision procedure till the end of the project. Such right sequence can be modelled as a multi-stage compound real option. Lin uses FV-MCROM to evaluate an investment project involving high-tech industry[5]. In this model Lin supposes that the decision-making time points are given ahead, and decisions can only be made at these time points. Furthermore, Lin supposes that cash flow only occurs at maturity.

C0 C1 C2 Cn−1 Cn Vt t t t t t t 0 1 2 n−2 n−1 n Figure 1. Fixed Volatility Multi-stage Decision Model

Figure 1 shows the fixed volatility multi-stage decision model, in which t,I(kkk = 0,… ,n) represent respectively the given decision-making time point and the planned investment outlay at that time point; Vt represents the underlying project value at t ; Ck represents the payoff function of the investor at tk : Cmax(FI,0kkk= − )( k0,,n= … −1), where Fk represents real option value, i.e. investment right, at k -th stage, i.e. between tk and tk1+ . If Fk≥ Ik, investor

3 will pay Ik to purchase the investment real option of next stage, with value of Fk ; or he will abandon the project. Cmax(VI,0nnn=−) represents the terminal payoff of the investor. If

VIn≥ n, he will pay In to purchase underlying asset with a value of Vn ; or he will abandon the project. Lin assumes that the underlying project value followed a Geometric Brownian Motion, i.e.

dVtt / V=+α V dtσ V dz , where αV and σV represent separately the instantaneous expected return rate and the instantaneous volatility rate of Vt , dz represents the standard Wiener produce. Lin assumed that there existed equivalent traded “twin security” in the market, which has the same risk nature as the underlying project. Between the return rate of the “twin security” and that of the project value there existed return rate shortfall, δ . From CAPM, it can be verified that δ must satisfies: δ =+r ρλσVM M V − α V , where r represents the riskfree interest rate, ρVM represents the correlation coefficient between the return rate of “twin security” and that of market portfolio,

λM ≡−(r)/αMσM represents the market price of risk of market portfolio, αM and σ M represent separately the expected return rate and the instantaneous volatility rate of market portfolio. According to Risk Neutral Pricing Theory, the natural measure was transformed into the risk neutral measure. In the risk neutral world, the expected return rate of any asset (tradable or non-tradable) is exactly the riskfree interest rate[15]. So the current value of any asset is the discounted value of expected future cash flow at the riskfree interest rate. Since all real options,

Fk ()⋅ ,(k =−0,… ,n 1), are European style contingent claims written on Vt , we can get the value of real options, by discounting the terminal payoff backward stage by stage. Lin presents the closed form solution: ni− −−δτ(tni t ) −r J Fi=−V i eΦΗni−−− ( ni ;R ni )∑ e IJ+ iΦ J ( K J ;R J ), ( i= 0,...,n− 1) J1=

J×J τ m where RRJmn=∈R ; R(m1,2,J;n1,2,== =J);τ = tt− ; () mn τ n J iJ+ i

J ×1 J ×1 Η J≡∈(h i,1 ,h i,2 ,… ,h i,J− 1 ,h i,J )′ R ; Κ J≡ (k i,1 ,k i,2 ,… ,k i,J− 1 ,k i,J )′∈ R ;

⎧ ⎛⎞ Vi 1 2 ⎪ln⎜⎟+−+ ( rδσV )( tij+ − t i ) V ∗ 2 ⎪ ⎝⎠ij+ ( j= 1,2,...,n−− i 1) ⎪ ⎪ σVijitt+ − hi,j = ⎨ ; ⎪ ⎛⎞V lni +−+ ( rδσ1 2 )( t − t ) ⎪ ⎜⎟I 2 V ni ⎪ ⎝⎠n (j=− n i) ⎪⎩ σVntt− i

khi,j=− i,jσ V tt i+ j − i ; ∗ Vij+ is the exercise threshold at tij+ , and satisfies Fij+ (Xij+ )= Iij+ ;

hh 1 i,J i,1 − 1 xRT1− x ΦΗJ (;R)JJ= e2 dxdx1 J,( J= 1,...,n ) . J 1/ 2 ∫∫−∞ −∞ (2π )2 R

To get the final solution F0 , we need to calculate high dimension integrals: Φ J ( J= 1,...,n ) , and compute the root of equations: Fij++(Xij+ )− Iij= 0, which is a nonlinear nested high dimension integral function. Thus calculation will cost large computing resource. Especially when the total stage number is large, it is difficult to handle the accuracy and convergence of numerical solution.

4 3 TIME-DEPENDENT VOLATILITY MULTI-STAGE COMPOUND REAL OPTION MODEL: AN GENERALIZATION

Though the FV-MCROM can reflect the multi-stage nature of high-tech project investment, the fixed volatility assumption is still unreasonable. In this section we introduce time-dependent volatility to reflect the fact that the multi-stage project usually has different risk-return nature at different stages. For simplification, we suppose that the underlying asset generate cash flow only at maturity. The analysis about the situation that cash flow occurs before maturity has no essential difference in our framework. Then we also assume that the decision-making time points are given ahead and decision can be made only at those time points, at which when option value is larger than the investment outlay the option will be exercised, i.e. investment continue; or project will be abandoned.

C0 C1 C2 Cn−1 Cn V01 V12 V(n− 2)(n− 1) V(n− 1)n t t t t t t 0 1 2 n−2 n−1 n Figure 2. Time-dependent Volatility Multi-stage Decision Model

Figure 2 shows the time-dependent volatility multi-stage decision model, in which

V(t)(k0,,n1k(k+ 1) =−… ) represent the company value at time point t at the k -th stage, t[t,t]∈ kk1+ . Other denotations are the same as above. Different from the fixed volatility [5] assumption of Lin , we assume that V(tk( k+ 1) ) obeys the following procedure:

dVk( k++ 1) / V k(k 1)= α k(k + 1)dt+σ k(k + 1) dz k , (1) where αk(k+ 1) and σ k(k+ 1) represent separately the instantaneous expected return rate and the instantaneous volatility rate of V(tk( k+ 1) ), which vary with k ; dzk represents the standard

Wiener produce, and var( dzkk ,dz′ )= 0 , (k,k′ = 0,1,… n−≠ 1;k k′ ). Again we assume that there exists equivalent traded “twin security” in the market. Then the return rate shortfall δk(k+ 1) between the return rate of the “twin security” and that of the risky company value at the k -th stage is δ k( k++ 1) =+r ρλσkM M k(k 1) − α k(k+ 1) , where ρkM represents the relationship coefficient between the return rate of the risky company value at the k -th stage and the market security portfolio. According to the Risk Neutral Pricing Theory, we can transform the natural measure into risk neutral measure and then equation (1) transforms as dVk(k++ 1) / V k( k 1) = ( r−+δ k(k + 1) )dtσ k( k + 1) dz Since the decision-making time points are known ahead, Fkk(k1)(V+ ,t ) is European style contingent claim written directly on Fk1+++(V (k1)(k2) ,t ), and indirectly on Vk( k+ 1) , with maturity

Ttk1++=− k1t k. Though our model is very similar to the fixed volatility model, it is too difficult to derive the closed form solution by means of discounting the terminal payoff backward stage by stage. We firstly present the pricing governing partial differential equation (PDE) which every real option Fkk(k1)(V+ ,t ) , (k=−∈ 0,… ,n 1;t [tkk1 ,t+ ]) satisfy, from Contingent Claim Analysis (CCA): 2 1 22 ∂∂FFkk∂Fk σδV(+ r)−+k(k++ 1)V k( k 1) −rFk =0 (2) 2 k( k++ 1) k( k 1) 2 ∂∂VVk(k++ 1) k(k 1) ∂t In compound option model the earlier option and the later option compound with each other, so the terminal conditions and the boundary conditions differ with each other. For the last stage, the real option Fn1− ()⋅ is similar to European financial written on stock with continued dividend. Thus the terminal condition is

5 Fn1− (V n ,T n )= max(Vn− I n ,0) . (3) When the company value is zero, i.e. bankruptcy occurs, the value of the real option is zero too. Thus the lower boundary condition is

Fn1− (0,t)= 0 . (4) And when company value is far larger than the exercise threshold, it is almost sure that the option will be exercised. So if we don’t consider the effect of dividend, the only difference between the option and the underlying asset is exercise outlay. Thus the upper boundary condition is

F(Vn1−− (n1)n ,t) →→1, (V(n− 1)n +∞ ) (5) −−r(Tn t ) −−δ(n− 1)n(T n t) [V(n− 1)n− I n e ]e Now let’s track back and consider the earlier stages ( kn= −−2,n3,,1,0… ). As discussed previously, Fk ()⋅ is European style contingent claim written indirectly on Vk( k+ 1) , and all impact of the following option Fk1+ ()⋅ is reflected in the terminal condition:

Fkk1k1(V++ ,T )= max(Fk1k1+ (V + )− I k1 + ,0) (6) Similar to the plain vanilla option, value of compound option is increase with the underlying ∗ assets value. So from (5) we can get the exercise threshold value Vk of the real option

Fk ()⋅ (k= 0,1,… ,n− 1), from

∗ Fkk(V ,0)= I k. (7)

Then for Fk ()⋅ , the upper boundary condition is

Fk (0,t)= 0. (8) And the lower boundary condition is

F(Vkk(k1)+ ,t) →→1, (Vk( k+ 1) +∞ ) . (9) −−r(Tk1+ t ) −−δk( k++ 1)(T k 1 t) [Fk1++ (V k(k1) ,0)− I k1 + e ]e Since the value function of later option enter the terminal condition of earlier option, it is difficult to derive the analytical solution to our problem (2)~(9). Notice that the solving domain is regular half-zonal domain (t,Vk( k++ 1) )∈ {[t k ,t k 1 ],[0,+∞ ]}, and the boundary conditions and terminal conditions are the Dirichlet boundary conditions. So it is simple and efficient to solve the model by Finite Differential Method (FDM).

4 NUMERICAL CALCULATION

In previous section we present the governing PDE, and terminal conditions and boundary conditions for the TV-MCROM. In this section we detail the numerical calculation procedure with FDM.

Firstly, let zln(Vk( k+ 1)= k( k+ 1) ) and divide the domain (t,zk(k+ 1) ) into following uniform mesh:

TIk1+ = Δt, zzJzk(k1)+ − k(k1)++= Δ k(k1),

where t[t,t]∈ kk1+ , z[z,zk( k+++ 1)∈ k( k 1) k(k 1) ], zln(Vk( k++ 1)= k( k 1) ), zln(Vk( k++ 1)= k( k 1) ),

6 Vk( k+ 1) ( Vk( k+ 1) ) represents the maximum (minimum) underlying asset value, which need be predetermined definitely ahead and is generally given as a very large (small) number.

We adopt following implicit differential scheme:

i1+ i ii 2 iii ∂F Fk,j− F k,j ∂F FF− ∂ F F2FF−+ k ≈ ; k ≈ k,j+ 1 k,j− 1 ; k ≈ k,j+ 1 k,j k,j− 1 , 22 ∂ttΔ ∂z2zkkΔ (k+1)∂zzk(k++ 1) Δ k(k 1)

i where FF(zjz,itk,j =+kk(k1)++Δ k(k1)Δ). Applying the scheme into the equation system (2)~(9) and ignoring the higher order term gives

iiii+1 α FFFk,j+− 1++βγ k,j k,j 1 =F, k,j (i= 0, ,I−= 1; j 1, ,J −= 1;k 0,1, … ,n − 1) (10)

σΔ22t(r−− δ1 σ ) σΔ2 t where, α −−k( k++ 1) k( k 1)2 k( k+ 1) ; βΔ k( k+ 1) + rt+ 1; 2 2 2zΔΔk( k++ 1) 2zk( k 1) Δzk( k+ 1)

(r−−δ 1 σΔσ22) tΔ t γ k(k++ 1)2 k( k 1) − k(k + 1) . 2 2zΔΔk(k++ 1) 2zk( k 1)

Rewriting (10) into matrix form we obtain

ii+1i ⎡⎤βγ ⎛⎞⎛FFFk,1 k,1−α k,0 ⎞ ⎜⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎢⎥FFii+1 ⎢⎥αβγ ⎜⎟⎜k,2 k,2 ⎟ ii ⎢⎥αβγ ⎜⎟⎜FFk,3 k,3 ⎟ ⎢⎥⎜⎟⎜= ⎟, (i= 0, ,I− 1) (11) ⎢⎥ ⎜⎟⎜⎟ ⎢⎥αβγ⎜⎟⎜FFii+1⎟ ⎢⎥⎜⎟⎜k,J−− 2 k,J 2 ⎟ ⎜⎟⎜ii+1i⎟ ⎣⎦⎢⎥αβ⎝⎠⎝FFFk,J1−− k,J1− k,J⎠

The terminal condition (3) and boundary conditions (4)(5) transform as

I zjz(n−− 1)n+ Δ (n 1)n Fmax(en1,j− =−= I,0),(j0,,n J), (12)

F i = 0,(i= 0, ,I) n1,0− , (13)

F i =−[ez((n−− 1)n I e−−r(Tn iΔ t ) ]e−−δΔ(n 1)nT n it) ,(i= 0, ,I) n1,J− n . (14) And for earlier stages ( kn2,n3,,1,0=− −… ) terminal condition (6) are changed as

I 0 Fmax(FI,0),(j0,,Jk,j =−=k+ 1,j k1+ ). (15)

Here, we can calculate the threshold value

∗ ∗ ∗ zk(k++ 1)zjz k(k 1)+ Δ k(k+ 1) Vek == e (k= 0,1,… ,n− 1), where j∗ satisfies

0 Fk,j∗ = Ik . (16)

And boundary conditions (8)(9) transform as

7 F i = 0,(i= 0, ,I ) k,0 , (17)

F i0=−Fe−−δΔk(k1)++(T k1 it) Ie −+− ( δk(k1)+ r)(T k1 + it) Δ,(i0,,I = ) k,J k+ 1,J k1+ . (18) Thus equation systems (12)~(18) define the value of our multi-stage compound real option model along the edges of the mesh. Computing the linear equation system (11) backward stage by stage, we can get the value of the TV-MCROM in every grid node (t,zk(k+ 1) ). Because the differential scheme adopted in this paper is implicit differential scheme, we can achieve good stability and convergence, and error is almost zero when as I →∞ and J →∞. That is to say, the numerical solution will converges to the solution of the PDE if I and J are large enough. The method we adopted is robust[1].

5 EVALUATION OF VENTURE CAPITAL INVESTMENT: AN EXAMPLE

Venture capital investment is a typical multi-stage investment activity with high-risk and high-return. In practice, venture capital investment is generally multi-stage investment. This multi-stage pattern corresponds to the high-risk and high-return characteristic, the irreversibility of investment outlay, and the information asymmetric nature of venture capital investment. Firstly, the multi-stage investment pattern can greatly reduce the risk of venture capitalist and bring more return. Since investment outlay is generally irreversible, once management fails capitalist can't often recover the initial investment. Under the multi-stage investment pattern, venture capitalist can make proper responses to the new arrival information. If management fails or the unfavourable situation appears, venture capitalist can reduce the investment scale, delay investment, even abandon the project to avoid further loss; when market potentiality of new product appears gradually, venture capitalist can grasp the opportunity by expanding the investment scale. So the multi-stage pattern is full of operation flexibility and strategetic flexibility. Secondly, the multi-stage investment pattern can reduce the management risk due to asymmetric information between entrepreneur and venture capitalist. In practice, even when the risk company faces bankruptcy, entrepreneur still has incentive to maintain operation, utilizing the information asymmetry, which will bring extra risk to venture capitalist. Under the multi-stage investment pattern, venture capitalist can get more inside information about management of the project, hence reduce the management risk. Finally the multi-stage investment pattern can give more restriction to entrepreneur. When management fails, venture capitalist will exercise the right to refuse the follow-up investment. This signal passes the inside information that the management fails, which will make it difficult for entrepreneur to win venture capital from other venture capitalists. The company will suffer from the threat that company will go into bankruptcy. That will make entrepreneur to put more effort into management and do his best to reach the management goal. So venture capital investment is generally the multi-stage investment. Just because venture capital investment is an investment activity with high-risk and high-return and has multi-stage nature, traditional NPV method and other approaches based on discounted cash flow, which cannot reflect the flexibility which the venture capitalist can utilize when new information arrives, are not suitable to evaluate the venture capital investment. Real option

8 seed startup growth expansion t0 t1 t2 t3 t4 bridge t5 IPO

Succeed investment and exit investment Abandon for investment salvage value investment abandon investment abandon abandon abandon abandon

Figure 3. The multi-stage (sequential) decision procedure of venture capital investment approach becomes a powerful tool, which reflects properly the management flexibility and strategic flexibility[7][15]. To apply real option approach to price venture capital investment, we must adopt one appropriate model which can reflect the aforementioned special nature of venture capital investment.

The existing compound real option models have limitation when they are applied to value the venture capital investment. Venture capital investment is generally divided into the many stages: the seed stage, the start up stage, the growth stage, the expansion stage and the bridge stage, as shown in Figure 3. Since the risk company has different goal and task at different stages, the risk characteristic differs at different stages. Risky company’s task at early stages is R&D of new product, so the main uncertainty at initial stages is technology uncertainty. In contrast with the uncertainty in management and market exploration at late stages, that uncertainty is greater and more difficult to control. However correspondingly, once the R&D succeeds, relying on the protection of the intellectual property, company can build the key competitiveness and stay in favorable market competitive position, gain short-term excess monopoly profit and etc. So the real option pricing model of venture capital investment needs not only to reflect the high-risk and high-return and multi-stage nature, but also reflect the fact that venture capital investment has

Table 1 Selection of Parameters

Current risky firm value: V0 [40,110] Risk-free interest rate: r 0.0279

Instantaneous expected return rate of risky firm value: αV 0.05

Instantaneous expected volatility of risky firm value: σV [0.1,0.5,0.9]

Market price of risk of market security portfolio: λM 0.4 Correlation coefficient between return rate of “twin 0.1 security” and that of market portfolio ρVM

Investment outlay at t0 : I0 3

Investment outlay at t1 : I1 5

Investment outlay at t2 : I2 5

Investment outlay at t3 : I3 10

Investment outlay at t4 : I4 15

Investment outlay at t5 : I5 30 Total stage number: n 5

9 different risk-return characteristics at different stages. In this section, we apply the TV-MCROM to evaluate venture capital investment.

The TV-MCROM has better adaptability. If we let all αi( i+ 1)≡ α V and σ i( i+ 1 )≡ σ V , the model will be the FV-MCROM of Lin (2002). In following analysis, we firstly compare FDM with the analytical computing approach, letting αi( i+ 1)≡ α V and σ i( i+ 1 )≡ σ V . And then we discuss the impact of introduction of time-dependent volatility to the compound real option value and the exercise threshold. Finally we perform sensitivity analysis of volatility. Since the venture capital investment is generally divided into five stages, we suppose that n is 5, and the interval is 1.5 years. The other parameters are chosen as Table 1. The riskfree interest rate consults the present interest rate of 5 years fixed deposit of Chinese banks.

5.1 Comparison between the FDM and the Analytical Approach

In this subsection we let αi( i+ 1)≡ α V and σ i( i+ 1 )≡ σ V , and compare the numerical and analytical approach. As a reference, in analytical approach we choose the Monte-Carlo algorithm for multivariate normal probabilities proposed by Genz [16], and choose the Brent algorithm[17] to search the root, which was originated by T. Dekker[18] and combine bisection, secant and inverse quadratic interpolation methods. In the calculating procedure we make the error of each numerical integral computation less than 10-5 and the error of root finding less than 10-6. In FDM we set

I=50 , J=200 , V0.k(k+ 1) = 01, Vk(k+ 1) = 10000 , (k= 0,1,… ,n− 1).

Table 2 presents the results of the of compound real option value and the exercise threshold with FDM approach and analytical approach, in three cases of σV = 0.1,σV = 0.5 , and σV = 0.9 . From the results we find that the accuracy of the two approaches is very close. The absolute difference has the magnitude of 10-1, and the relative difference is less than 3% on an average.

Table 2. Comparison about the accuracy in the degradation case

Company value at Value of option (F ) Exercise threshold Volatility 0 beginning Analytical Analytical σV FDM FDM (V0) Approach Approach

* 30 0.0001 0.0010 V0 48.5501 47.3151

* 40 0.1878 0.2596 V1 50.3619 50.1187

* 50 4.0175 4.0947 V2 49.6486 50.1187

* 60 13.5713 13.7219 V3 49.1841 50.1187

* 0.1 70 24.8764 24.9774 V4 42.5977 42.1697

80 36.3225 36.4129

90 47.7378 47.8671

100 59.1740 59.3233

110 70.6050 70.7797

* 0.5 10 0.0899 0.0853 V0 25.8008 25.1189

* 20 1.3633 1.3414 V1 31.2752 31.6228

* 30 4.6918 4.6478 V2 33.4310 33.4965

* 40 9.2247 9.7239 V3 40.6464 39.8107

* 50 15.9160 16.0733 V4 39.8662 39.8107

60 24.4612 23.3145

10 70 32.4575 31.1807

80 38.9697 39.4950

90 47.6572 48.1470

100 57.9423 57.0472

110 66.1362 66.1562

* 10 1.6213 1.5998 V0 13.8256 14.1254

* 20 6.0006 5.9505 V1 18.6871 18.8365

* 30 11.7001 11.687 V2 20.5185 21.1349

* 40 18.3880 18.206 V3 29.6695 29.8538

* 50 24.9698 25.219 V4 33.5195 33.4965

0.9 60 32.3129 32.573

70 39.5358 40.172

80 48.3225 47.956

90 55.8858 55.886

100 64.0545 63.929

110 71.7779 72.073

However, the FDM has much advantage over the analytical approach about computational speed, as shown in Figure 4. With the analytical approach we need to compute the integral of 1 dimension, 2 dimensions, till n dimensions, and need to seek the root of integral function of 1 dimension, 2 dimensions, till (n-1) dimensions. Thus the analytical approach is much slower and computing time increases rapidly with n. But the FDM need only solve some linear equation systems, the computing time is approximately linear with n. Furthermore, we can get the value of real option in all the grid nodes once. The FDM is much more efficient that the analytical approach.

Figure 4. Comparison of computing time

11 5.2 Impact of Variable Volatility on Value of Real Option and Exercise Threshold As discussed previously, in practice the risk-return characteristics of venture capital investment differs at different stages. In this subsection we suppose that the volatility of the seed stage is largest, and volatility decreases with n: σ01 = 0.9 , σ12 = 0.5 , σ 23 = 0.3 , σ 34 = 0.2 , σ 45 = 0.1 . Since the FV-MCROM cannot allow the volatility to change with n, we select an average volatility: σV = 0.4 , as a benchmark. The other parameters are same as the previous subsection. The result is shown in Figure 5 and Table 2. We find that the FV-MCROM underestimates significantly the value of venture capital investment. Furthermore, we find that the FV-MCROM overestimates the exercise threshold of the earlier stages (the seed stage and the startup stage), and underestimates that of the later stages (the growth stage, the expansion stage and the bridge stage). Hence if we select the same volatility, we will set the extra barrier and lose good opportunity at the earlier stages; but at later stages we may lower the threshold and bring extra risk. So the fixed volatility multi-stage compound real option model is not suitable to price venture capital investment.

Figure 5. Comparison of TV-MCROM and FV-MCROM

Table 2. Comparison of exercise threshold

exercise threshold at FV-MCROM TV-MCROM

t0 30.9030 16.7880

t1 36.3078 33.8844

t2 38.0189 42.6580

t3 43.6516 48.4172

t4 41.2098 42.6580

12 5.3 Sensitivity Analysis of Volatility Lin (2002) found that the value of the FV-MCROM does not always increase with volatility. When the underlying company value is large enough, option value decreases with volatility, which is different from the conclusion in financial option theory. We also find similar observation. Consider following three cases:

Case I: σ01 = 0.6 , σ12 = 0.5 , σ 23 = 0.3 , σ 34 = 0.2 , σ 45 = 0.1;

Case II: σ01 = 0.7 , σ12 = 0.6 , σ 23 = 0.4 , σ 34 = 0.3 , σ 45 = 0.2 ;

Case III: σ01 = 0.8 , σ12 = 0.7 , σ 23 = 0.5 , σ 34 = 0.4 , σ 45 = 0.3 . The value of compound real option in the three cases is shown in Figure 6. When the underlying company value is small, value of real option increases with volatility. However, when the underlying company value is very large, value of real option decreases with volatility. It is because that the underlying company is non-tradable. On the one hand, δ increase with the product of ρ and σ . And in the other hand, the greater the company value is, the greater the impact of δ on value of options is. Hence, the volatility effects the value of option in two ways at the same time . Firstly, increase of the volatility make it more possible that the company value reach to the threshold, and hence increase the value of option. Then the increase of volatility also increases δ , and hence decreases the value of the option. The final effect of volatility depends on the contrast. When the company value is small, δ has less effect on value of options. Hence in this case, value of real option increases with volatility. When the company value is very large, δ has main effect on value of options. Hence in this case, value of real option decreases with volatility.

Figure 6. Sensitivity Analysis of Volatility

6 CONCLUSIONS

We compare the FDM and the analytical approach in the degradation case, and find that FDM has close accuracy as the analytical approach, and significant advantage about the computation speed. Then we find that the FV-MCROM underestimates the value of venture capital investment. In the same time it overestimates the exercise threshold of the earlier stages, which set the extra barrier

13 and lose good opportunity in the earlier stages, and underestimates that of the later stages, which lower the threshold and bring extra risk. Finally we perform the sensitivity analysis of volatility, and find that there exists the non-monotone observation which was also emphasized by Lin, which is because that the underlying company is non-tradable asset.

Reference

[1] Kwok,Y.K. Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives[M]. Springer, 1998:77,212-224. [2] Geske,R. The valuation of corporate liabilities as compound options[J]. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 1977, 12, November:541-552. [3] Geske,R. The valuation of compound options[J]. Journal of Financial Economics, 1979, 7(1):63-81.

[4] Lee,J., and Paxson,D.A. Valuation of R&D real American sequential exchange options[J]. R&D Management, 2001, 31:191-201.

[5] Lin,W.T. Computing a Multivariate Normal Integral for Valuing Compound Real Options[J]. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 2002, 18(2):185–209.

[6] Sylvia,P., and Trigeogis,L. Multi-stage Real Options: The Cases of Information Technology Infrastructure and International Bank Expansion[J]. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 1998, 38, Special issue: 675-692.

[7] Dixit,A.K.,Pindyck,R.S. Investment under Uncertainty [M]. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994: 93-132,135-136. [8] Alvarez,L.H.R., and Stenbacka,R. Adoption of uncertain multi-stage technology projects: a real options approach[J]. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 2001, 35:71-97. [9] Buraschi,A.,and Dumas,B. The forward valuations of compound options[J]. Journal of Derivatives, 2001, 9:8-17. [10] Geman,H.,El Karoui,N.,and Rochet,J.C. Changes of numeraire, changes of probability measure and option pricing[J]. Journal of Applied Probability, 1995, 32:443–458. [11] Elettra,A.,and Rossella,A. A generalization of the Geske formula for compound options[J]. Mathematical Social Sciences, 2003, 45:75–82. [12] Herath,H.S.B., and Park,C.S. Multi-Stage Capital Investment Opportunities As Compound Real Opions[J]. The Engineering Economist, 2002, 47(1): 1-27. [13] Trigeorgis,L. A Log-Transformed Binomial Numerical Analysis Method for Valuing Complex Multi-Option Investments[J]. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 1991, 26: 309-326. [14] Breen,R. The Accelerated Binomial Option Pricing Model[J]. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 1991, 26: 153-164. [15] Trigeorgis,L. Real Option, Managerial Flexibility and Strategy in Resource Allocation[M]. Massachusetts: The MIT Press, 1996:23-68. [16] Genz,Alan. Numerical Computation of Multivariate Normal Probabilities. J. Comp. Graph Stat. 1(1992),pp141-149. [17] Brent, R., Algorithms for Minimization Without Derivatives, Prentice-Hall, 1973. [18] Dekker, T. J., “Finding a Zero by Means of Successive Linear Interpolation.” Constructive Aspects of the Fundamental Theorem of Algebra in Dejon and Henrici (1969).

14