<<

The End of Conventional Wisdom? Dr. Jonathan Luckhurst* Economic Governance after the World Economic Crisis

Abstract 1980s, have been undermined by the world economic crisis of 2008-09. This had the effect of increasing doubts about existing economic policy This article examines how the conventional wisdoms of laissez-faire, options in a way that could encourage policy supply-side economic policy discourse innovation now and in the . Core have constrained international assumptions have been displaced or at least policymaking, but also how the world economic crisis of 2008-09 led to greater brought into question by an economic crisis that discursive contestation that weakened the grew from the rationality of orthodox policy influence of this formerly-prevalent discourse, rather than deviance from it. discourse. The so-called „Keynesian revival‟ of the crisis period continues to Consequently the standard solutions no longer impact international policymaking, at seem to offer an obvious path out of the least to the extent that the supply-side economic crisis, as several national economies approach is no longer so readily accepted as „commonsense‟ by many policy actors. continue to endure problems with debt; poor Now there is no single of conventional growth; weak housing and financial markets; wisdoms on economic strategy that is currency fluctuations; and general uncontested amongst international policy about economic prospects. élites. I also examine the effects of „repoliticization‟ as a political strategy The following examines how and a tool of politics. Such a discursive strategy can be a highly effective tool for conventional wisdom and dominant discourses policy actors to achieve political goals. tend to constrain policymakers during normal

periods of economic growth, or even during periods of recession in which core elements of

the economy still seem to function in a normal Introduction way. It argues for a specifically political

This article analyzes how „conventional conception of economic policymaking that wisdoms‟ on economic governance, especially includes skepticism about dominant discourses from the „Washington consensus‟ and neoliberal and eschews general in favor of a focus on policy strategies that became popular after the the particularities of a context, e.g. within a 2

specific region or country. The first section context in which policies are applied. focuses on this broad issue by analyzing how This article presents a philosophical „repoliticization‟ becomes possible during discussion of key issues of economic moments of crisis. It also argues that even though policymaking following the world economic there might be pressures to revert to conventional crisis. It also constitutes a critical discussion of wisdom or the rationalities of dominant governance and public policymaking beyond discourses once a crisis period has passed, questions of and political economy, nevertheless good public policymaking, or more especially concerning the significance of broadly „good governance‟, should include a „conventional wisdom‟ and political discourse for heightened skepticism about common wisdom public policymaking. I conclude that a greater and stay focused on contextual factors. The emphasis on context, a heightened willingness second section analyzes some interesting aspects and confidence to reject core shibboleths of of the international policy responses to the world conventional wisdom, combined with a focus on economic crisis of 2008-09, including the revival innovation and lateral thinking, should enhance of Keynesian policy strategies and the subsequent policymaking and lead to more effective debt crises in certain European countries. Such governance across the gamut of policy issues that developments have raised new questions about must be addressed in the contemporary world. contemporary policymaking trends in the world. However, electoral success in twenty-first The final section examines the long-term century politics will be shaped especially by the consequences of this reevaluation of policy capacity of political actors to construct discursive responses to the world economic crisis, including strategies that enable them to gain advantages in the philosophical question of how public politics. Policy actors who manage to increase policymakers can achieve long-term policy the influence of their favored political discourse success without blindly following fashionable and its articulated conventional wisdoms economic theories. Instead I argue that they effectively are rewriting the rules of the to should develop policy strategies that emphasize, suit their goals. and respond to, the specificities of the particular 3

a way that remains open to new and, potentially, uncomfortable or challenging findings. However such openness can be difficult to sustain, especially in the face of professional Beyond ‘conventional wisdom’: repoliticizing opposition and incentives to conform. economic governance Professional prestige and academic research There are many terms for commonly-held funding can be strong motives in this sense. Also about the correct or best form of scholars and policy practitioners might find it governance for a particular field of policymaking. difficult to engage in some important Terms such as „best practice‟, „commonsense‟, professional debates without accepting, or „accepted norms‟ and „conventional wisdom‟ implicitly accepting by referencing, some imply the sedimentation and broad acceptance of commonly-held assumptions. As Robert Keohane particular strategies or practices for dealing with (2002: 14) notes, when discussing his initial a given issue. Specifically when we talk of the skepticism about the popularity of the term latter, i.e. „conventional wisdom‟, this implies a „globalization‟: “[I]t is frustrating to try to row commonly-held and in scholarly or against a strong tide, or to sail directly into the policy circles it indicates one that is considered wind. To be heard, the scholar has to speak to the appropriate for and opinion-leaders in a concerns of his era in the language of his era.” particular field (Krugman 1996: 725). However, conventional wisdom Paul Krugman has written some sometimes has limitations and might be brought interesting points about the potential into question. The following considers how consequences of conventional wisdom in contestation of such dominant discourses occurs, economic theory and in scholarly work on especially during moments of perceived crisis. I economic development. He argues (ibid.: 732) should emphasize that discursive contestation is that economists and policymakers should not possible at other but it always depends on depend on such common beliefs, but instead whether actors are able to „repoliticize‟ a deploy economic theory and empirical analysis in particular discursive context. Having noted this 4

point — and as the poststructuralist political discourse, as the policy-constraining effects of a theorist Ernesto Laclau has argued, moments of formerly-dominant discourse are weakened and „dislocation‟ become more likely during periods this increases the likelihood that policymakers of increased political uncertainty, as “events that will consider policy options beyond the usual. cannot be symbolized by an existent discursive The broadly commented upon „Keynesian order, and thus function to disturb that order” revival‟ during 2008-09,1 as policy actors sought (Howarth 2000: 111). Keohane (2002: 265) ways to boost world economic growth and also to makes a similar point from a rationalist develop effective new regulatory mechanisms for perspective, with reference to the „prisoner‟s international finance, happened because the dilemma‟ from game theory, asserting that dominant laissez-faire policy discourse was “under conditions of uncertainty in the real discredited by the collapse of the financial sector world, the chain of “inheritability” will be in the United States after September 2008. It is broken, and actors‟ preferences about future useful to consider the linkage between this notion outcomes will not dictate their choices of of dislocation and Jenny Edkins‟ (1999: 126) alternatives in the present” (original emphasis). definition of „the political‟, when she writes that In other words, even supposedly-rational actors “the political represents the moment of openness cannot act to maximize their benefits from or undecidability, when a new social order is on predicted outcomes if the future is no longer the point of establishment, when its limits are predictable, e.g. during moments of political being contested”. By contrast, she considers crisis when key actors and traditional institutional „politics‟ to be “what takes place once the new practices might subsequently cease to comply order is institutionalized… [,] the debate that with previous rules or expectations. occurs within the limits set by that order” (original emphasis). Returning to my example, This dislocatory effect was indicated by „politics‟ in this definition implies the business- the greater openness to policy innovation of as-usual international policy discourse before the influential actors during the economic crisis of financial markets slumped in September 2008. 2008-09. Such a period constitutes an opportunity to challenge the dominance of a particular 1 This „Keynesian revival‟ is discussed below. 5

After the crisis deepened, there was an endorsed by policy élites. interruption of „the political‟ because of Edkins (1999: 125-43) argues that what widespread concern about the general she calls “repoliticization”, which implies functionality of international markets. We cannot increased public awareness of political be sure of the long-term consequences of this contingency and involves the disturbance of a „political‟ moment, indeed the broadened and sedimented discursive formation, could enable contested mainstream policy discourse from the actors to challenge dominant discourses even period 2008-09 might be superseded by a when there is no apparent crisis.2 This indicates reassertion of the earlier boundaries of „politics‟ the strategic consequences of discursive — e.g. through the reconstitution of pre-crisis contestation and implies that repoliticization is relations of power between actors; the reassertion possible at any moment, even though it is easier of earlier policy assumptions or „conventional during perceived periods of crisis. Linked to this, wisdom‟; and/or marginalization of competing she presents an interesting discussion of Stuart claims from Keynesian-influenced policymakers, Hall‟s analysis of „Thatcherism‟ in Britain during economists and scholars that came to the fore the 1980s. Hall (1998: 9) emphasizes that during the crisis period. However this period of Thatcherism was transformative, in terms of its heightened discursive contestation has weakened goal to “make us think and speak its language as the “chain of “inheritability”” that Keohane if there were no other”. This indicates the (2002: 265) mentions, so that any reassertion of strategic and persuasive content of political that discourse would likely be harder to discourse, something Hall claims the British left consolidate and more susceptible to continued had failed sufficiently to appreciate — though, in contestation from Keynesian or other policy his opinion, Thatcher‟s government had perspectives. International economic understood its significance. Thatcher‟s policymaking will, in this case, continue to be more marked by discursive contestation than 2 Edkins‟ usage of “repoliticization” clearly has much in during the preceding decades, when a broadly common with Laclau‟s notion of „dislocation‟ (Howarth „neoliberal‟ policy discourse was widely 2000: 111) and Keohane‟s (2002: 265) claims about the consequences of “conditions of uncertainty in the real world”. 6

government managed in the 1980s to effect a debate, potentially with long-term effects beyond repoliticization of the prevailing British political the moment of crisis. However, this political discourse on the relative merits of the welfare contingency actually exists at all times, not just state and the role of the private sector, especially during crises. This is because the discursive what had been a fairly broad consensus in the context of social relations is never completely country since 1945 about the benefits of a strong fixed, just as perceptions, attitudes and societies welfare state and government intervention to are never static. The contingency of policy support British industry. The „Thatcherite‟ choices might become more evident during repoliticization of this discourse, along broadly moments such as the world economic crisis of „neoliberal‟ philosophical lines, was sustained 2008-09, but it is still possible to deploy beyond the restricted -frame of its own strategies of repoliticization at other times to administration and the early 1980s debates about influence policy debates. This has important the failures of British economic policy of the implications for political strategists and scholars, 1970s. Indeed there has been an enduring especially concerning the benefits of deploying influence, with core elements of „Thatcherite discourse-analytic tools to achieve analytical neoliberalism‟ arguably being incorporated in the insights and political goals. policymaking and policy discourse of each subsequent British government. Hall‟s analysis of the discursive strategies deployed by the Thatcher government to achieve this long-term influence demonstrates the potential impact of an Discursive contestation after 2008 effective strategy of repoliticization. This section examines the international policy My discussion of dislocation and responses to the 2008-09 economic crisis. It repoliticization indicates how the discursive demonstrates the significance of dislocation, context of a political or economic crisis, political contingency and repoliticization for especially, facilitates significant policy subsequent policy strategies and actions by adjustments and broadens the scope of policy leading governments and international 7

. It also indicates that cooperation growth, etc.. However there was a noticeable between states is easier to achieve during crisis trend that indicated a switch in international periods. A key focus here is how the prevalent priorities as the economic crisis became less supply-side economic policy discourse was threatening by the end of 2009. By that time, sufficiently problematized after September 2008 global „recovery‟ rather than „survival‟ had for Keynesian policy strategies to be applied in become the focus for leading international international policymaking to an extent that had institutions and fora such as the International not happened since the 1970s. Monetary Fund (IMF), the G20 and the European Union (EU); amongst leading wealthy states such It would be simplistic to argue that as the United States, Britain, France and mainstream international policy responses to the Germany; also for influential developing world economic crisis, or what some have countries such as China, Brazil and Mexico. labeled „the great recession‟, can be divided into two distinct phases: a broadly-Keynesian strategy I will present a brief survey of the in 2008-09 to boost world economic growth, evidence from this period to demonstrate the followed by a return to neoliberal to general context of discursive contestation. This combat fears of sovereign debt crisis and, in the will then be contrasted with earlier international cases of Greece, Ireland and Portugal, actual debt discourse on the „Asian financial crisis‟ of 1997, crises. In , since the initial responses in demonstrating that some of the earlier September 2008 to the international market conventional wisdoms on economic strategy were collapse that month, there has been continual abandoned during the later economic crisis. The discursive contestation — over strategic and dramatic discursive shift after September 2008 is short-term policy decision-making; on broad indicated by the prevalent conventional wisdom issues of international and domestic strategy; before, amongst academics and policy actors, that about the potential benefits of intergovernmental Keynesian remedies were no longer applicable in coordination through fora such as the Group of the complex economies of the twenty-first Twenty Nations (G20); also the classic debate century, partly due to the perceived effects of about monetary stability versus economic economic globalization (see Bisley 2007: 57; 8

Blair and Schröder 1999; Giddens 2008; Board (FSB) (G20 2009). This was the high point Skidelsky 2005: 25). This discourse contrasted in international cooperation in response to the greatly with the „crisis period‟ policy discourse of economic crisis. It was compatible with the late 2008 and early 2009, when a „Keynesian traditional Keynesian emphasis on public deficit- revival‟ seemed to be heralded by the spending to boost growth during a recession, plus dramatically increased interest in the man and his with Keynes‟ personal in the benefits of ,3 not to mention the application of his using international institutional mechanisms to economic strategies, especially by the British and resolve problems in the world economy. US governments but also as the basis for the Forewarnings about the drastic consequences of a crisis response strategy adopted at the G20 failure to achieve an international strategy, London Summit of April 2009. Indeed, leading supported by the ominous analogy with the scholars, policymakers, governments and failure of international negotiations on economic international institutions such as the IMF and recovery in London in 1933, had increased the World Bank all began to advocate Keynesian pressure on negotiators to reach agreement or policy strategies as the best remedy for the else face potentially drastic economic economic crisis during this period (see Giddens consequences. 2010: 3-4; Stiglitz 2010: 215, 231; HM Treasury The international strategy adopted in 2008: 3; G20 2009; Strauss-Kahn 2009). Actions April 2009 was very different from the strategy followed words, culminating in the that western countries and western-dominated aforementioned strategic plan adopted by the institutions, especially the IMF, had advocated G20 in April 2009, which included the for Asian countries during the 1997 Asian combination of a fiscal stimulus strategy, financial crisis. Accusations of hypocrisy and primarily implemented under the auspices of the double-standards have been leveled at some of IMF; plus enhanced international economic the G20 countries and the IMF for the fact that monitoring and coordination mechanisms, fiscal stimulus was advocated as a counter- especially the creation of the Financial Stability cyclical solution in 2008-09, when the wealthy

3 The perception of a „Keynesian revival‟ during this period states were facing economic crisis; but, by also is evidenced by a google search for the phrase. 9

contrast, during the 1997 Asian crisis the EU Kranke 2010: 2, 19). countries, the USA, the IMF, etc. had instead Despite the G20 agreement in April 2009, advocated the cold, harsh medicine of the IMF‟s there had never been complete consensus structural adjustment programs, with their amongst international policy élites about the austerity measures and deficit-reduction benefits of fiscal stimulus measures. The German emphasis (Stiglitz 2010: xiv-xx). Thus, government of Angela Merkel, in particular, had conventional wisdoms from the „Washington been skeptical about the inflationary risks of such consensus‟ (Williamson 1990) period of the a strategy. Once the British elections of May 1990s were brought into question by the policy 2010 led to the establishment of a Conservative- responses of 2008-09. Some might claim that the led coalition government, the British effectively IMF‟s structural adjustment medicine was just reversed the economic strategy of the previous too strong for the wealthy countries to take; Labour administration and introduced an however, the fact that the crisis in the US austerity budget designed to reduce public financial sector was a consequence of following spending, rather than continue the latter‟s fiscal the core rationality of orthodox laissez-faire stimulus approach. This left Barack Obama‟s economic policy strategy implied that the same government more isolated on the issue of a global philosophical approach might not solve its own fiscal stimulus strategy by late 2010, though 2011 failings. Moreover, the political context had has seen a switch by his administration to a changed. The „Washington consensus‟ had been greater emphasis on the need to reduce the US increasingly criticized for its perceived failings, deficit. Certainly the EU states became especially as a strategy in response to some of the increasingly focused on deficit-reduction in the developing world financial crises of the 1990s, second half of 2010, especially following the e.g. in Mexico and East Asia (Stiglitz 2010: xx; shock of the Greek debt crisis and the need for an Held and McGrew 2007: 226-27; Krugman 1995: EU—IMF bail-out in May 2010. This combined 30-31). Even the IMF seemed to have turned with the growing sense that some of the other EU away from its 1990s approach under the economies, such as Ireland, Portugal and Spain, leadership of Dominique Strauss-Kahn (Lütz and also were under growing pressure from 10

international markets concerned about their public debt levels. Lessons for public policymakers The international economic situation The core lesson from my analysis is that continues to be unstable, with current uncertainty conventional wisdoms should be treated with about the sustainability of the recovery in some skepticism, especially because they do not influential economies like the US and UK always provide the best solutions. Rather than indicating that there might be a need for further present absolute empirical or analytical policymaking adjustments in the coming months certainties about the world, they simply denote (IMF 2011). Whilst it would have been difficult the consolidation and influence of particularly to imagine a Keynesian strategy being advocated fashionable claims in scholarly research and by leading international policymakers prior to policy discourse. These might provide some 2008, now there is a continuing tension between policymaking benefits for a period of time, but this and the earlier orthodoxy of laissez-faire, also they could have more negative effects, supply-side economics. Neither approach is especially by constraining thought and potentially absolutely dominant; arguably this is a period of preventing the adoption of more effective policy greater discursive contestation in international options. economic policymaking and scholarly circles than at any moment since the 1970s. The I have already discussed the advantages „Keynesian revival‟ of 2008-09 may have of discursive strategies of repoliticization for slowed, or partially reversed, but one important overcoming these constraining effects of impact is that a simplistic advocacy of conventional wisdoms. The example of how deregulation is no longer politically-expedient „Thatcherite neoliberalism‟ displaced the broad even in the US. postwar British consensus on the relation between the state, citizens and the private sector

provides a useful demonstration of the potential significance of repoliticization. Similarly, during the 2008-09 economic crisis there was a 11

repoliticization of prevalent assumptions about judgment partly because this simplifies the economic policymaking, one that was thought process. This might have practical particularly significant in the UK and US, and benefits, especially by providing a short-cut to which concerned many issues — especially answers, which might appeal both to public deficits, financial market regulation, credit policymakers and people in general when time- markets and the best strategy for the housing limits are a significant constraint in decision- sector. However we cannot yet be sure whether making, and delays potentially costly (Conlisk this repoliticization will have the kind of long- 1996: 671). term consequences that Thatcher‟s government In light of the preceding point, it is achieved with its own strategy of repoliticization. important to note that my emphasis on the A further issue to discuss is the relevance of the advantages of problematizing conventional notion of „‟, deployed by wisdoms in recent economic governance provides some scholars of (Conlisk lessons especially relevant for political 1996; Kahneman 2003) and rational choice strategists, advocates or scholars wishing to theory (Simon 1955; Sen 1977), for my repoliticize a particular policymaking context. conception of „conventional wisdom‟. References This implies a political strategy deployed to to „bounded rationality‟ have much in common displace the constitutive effects of conventional with what I have written about the constraining wisdoms that are articulated within an opposing effects of dominant discourses, implying that political discourse. Discourse analysis provides rationality is always limited because actors useful analytical tools for such political goals; accept certain conclusions or assumptions also it helps us understand how a dominant without a detailed investigation into their actual discourse can have the effect of constituting the validity. However „bounded rationality‟ implies limits of rationality, thus of the world in which something that is not always expressed when we live, regardless of empirical or analytical discussing the effects of a dominant discourse, evidence. Moreover, when considering the which is the way that individuals might choose to constitutive effects of a dominant discourse on accept a conventional wisdom or someone else‟s economic strategy, a common mistake is to apply 12

such theoretical templates to a particular context strategy in politics. This might include discursive without considering whether it is the best strategy practices such as rhetorical redescription (Skinner for the city, region, country, etc. in question. 2002: 279-80),4 when an actor manages to Policymakers should consider the potential popularize an alternative interpretation of certain lessons from fashionable policy discourses and signifiers, e.g. „modernization‟, „‟, „best also learn from examples of policy practice and practice‟, etc. so that they become equated with implementation in other contexts. However, something quite different from what was effective policymaking must maintain a core previously commonly accepted. This was focus on the needs of the specific context in demonstrated by Krugman‟s (1996) examination which policies are being applied, because of the apparently cyclical trends in the conventional wisdoms might be problematical if interpretation of „best practice‟ in international applied without in-depth, contextual analysis of discourse on economic development policy. If their potential effects in what could be an done effectively, managing to displace one unsuitable location or policy area. political discourse for another can produce discursive resources that are very useful in Much of this discussion has focused on politics. This might include the construction of what Edkins (1999: 126) would call „the new forms of political legitimization; more political‟; however, there are some key lessons broadly, it might constitute a discursive context here for the practice of „politics‟. Again Thatcher that generally is more favorable to the political is a useful example, as the repoliticization of goals of an actor that manages to increase the British policymaking conventions that her influence a preferred political discourse, or at government achieved in the 1980s contributed least reduce the capacity of the opposed discourse greatly to its success in British politics, helping to to constrain debate or dominate the political- sustain consecutive Conservative governments discursive context. for an impressive 18 years in office. As noted earlier, displacing the conventional wisdoms of 4 one dominant discourse with another set of Quentin Skinner‟s (2002) analytical usage of „rhetorical redescription‟ is highly compatible with the Nietzschean conventional wisdoms can be a highly successful philosophical of examining how our of the world is constructed rather than revealed. 13

easier to achieve, but there are crucial lessons here for policymakers that are relevant even in

more normal times. Discursive strategies intended to repoliticize particular policy contexts can be highly effective, as demonstrated by the Conclusion Thatcher government in Britain. If successful, A crucial consequence of the 2008-09 world repoliticization of a policy discourse enables economic crisis has been a renewed contestation policy actors to construct a new language of of the earlier prevalent orthodoxy of laissez-faire, politics (see Fairclough 1999), redrawing the supply-side economics in international boundaries of political discourse such that their policymaking circles. This does not necessarily own goals can constitute a new „mainstream‟ or imply the end of conventional wisdom forever; orthodoxy, thus encouraging others to accept indeed, new conventional wisdoms might replace them as the most legitimate and effective the old. However, this „post-crisis‟ context does practices of governance in their particular policy indicate a weakening of the conventional field. wisdoms that were articulated around this once- However, the general aim of this analysis dominant policy discourse. This is partly because is to challenge policymakers to question the core the so-called „Keynesian revival‟ continues to assumptions of influential policy discourses. influence international policymaking, at least to Whilst conventional wisdom is not always the extent that the supply-side approach is no flawed, it does often have the effect of longer so readily accepted as „commonsense‟ by constraining critical thought, of restricting the many policy actors. scope of debate on a particular policy area. This A key focus in my analysis is the analysis has focused on economic policy significance of „repoliticization‟ as a politico- discourse, but also it has broader implications for discursive strategy. Certainly the broad how we think about all policy fields. Blind perception of crisis after September 2008 made in any particular model or conventional wisdom such a repoliticization of economic policymaking should never be an excuse not to analyze the 14

empirical evidence, as noted by Krugman (1996: Edkins, J. (1999) Poststructuralism and International Relations. Boulder: Lynne Rienner. 732). Context is important, so neither should policymakers automatically accept conventional Fairclough, N. (1999) “Global and Critical Awareness of Language”, Language wisdoms that are meant to be applied generally, Awareness, 8(2), 71-83. rather than being linked to the analysis of a G20 (2009) “The Global Plan for Recovery and particular, localized situation. Conventional Reform”, 2 April. wisdoms often end up being contested and Available from the official G20 London Summit website: displaced by other conventional wisdoms.

However, the current climate in international http://www.londonsummit.gov.uk/resources/en/P DF/final-communique. First accessed economic policymaking continues to be 31 May 2009. sufficiently open for a broader range of Giddens, A. (2008) “Author‟s Response to discourses to have some influence. This indicates Reviewers”, Political Studies Review, 6(3), 308- that there is still hope that innovative policy 13. solutions might be found that help to improve the ——— (2010) “The Rise and Fall of New standards of international economic governance. Labour”, New Perspectives Quarterly, 27(3), 32- 37. This might even be sufficient to prevent another serious economic crisis in the foreseeable future. Hall, S. (1998) “The Great Moving Nowhere Show”, Marxism Today, November/December, 9- 14.

Held, D. and McGrew, A. (2007) References Globalization/Anti-Globalization: Beyond the Divide. 2nd Bisley, N. (2007) Rethinking Globalization. edition. Cambridge: Polity Press. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. HM Treasury (2008) Managing the Global Blair, T. and Schröder, G. (1999) “Europe: the Economy through Turbulent Times. London: HM third way/Die Neue Mitte”, London: Labour Treasury. Party. Howarth, D. (2000) Discourse. Buckingham: Conlisk, J. (1996) “Why Bounded Rationality?” Open University Press. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(2), 669-700. IMF (2011) “United Kingdom—2011 Article IV 15

Consultation Concluding Statement of the Economics, 6(1), 15-30. Mission”, 6 June. Available from the official IMF website: Skinner, Q. (2002) Visions of Politics. Vol. II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. http://www.imf.org/external/np/ms/2011/060611. htm. First accessed 7 June 2011. Stiglitz, J. (2010) Freefall: America, Free Markets, and the Sinking of the World Economy. Kahneman, D. (2003) “Maps of Bounded London and New York: W. W. Norton & Rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Company. Economics”, The American Economic Review, 93(5), 1449- Strauss-Kahn, D. (2009) “Beyond the Crisis: 75. Sustainable Growth and a Stable International Monetary System”, Sixth Annual Bundesbank Keohane, R. (2002) Power and Governance in a Lecture, Berlin. Partially Globalized World. London: Routledge. Williamson, J. (1990) “What Washington Means by Policy Reform”, in Williamson, J., ed., Krugman, P. (1995) “Dutch Tulips and Emerging Latin American Adjustment: How Much has Markets”, Foreign Affairs, 74(4): 28-44. Happened? Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics. ——— (1996) “Cycles of Conventional Wisdom on Economic Development”, International Affairs, 71(4), 717-32.

Lütz, S. and Kranke, M. (2010) “The European Rescue of the Washington Consensus? EU and IMF Lending to Central and Eastern European Countries”, LEQS, Paper 22.

Sen, A. (1977) “Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory”, and Public Affairs, 6(4), 317-44.

Simon, H. (1955) “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69(1), 99-118.

Skidelsky, R. (2005) “Keynes, Globalisation and the Bretton Woods Institutions in the Light of Changing Ideas about Markets”, World