Capital., Expectations, and the Market Process

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Capital., Expectations, and the Market Process -g % Capital., Expectations, and the Market Process Essays on the Theory of the Market Economy By Ludwig M. Lachmann Edited with an Introductionby Walter E. Grinder SHEED ANDREWS AND McMEEL, INC. Subsidiary of Universal Press Syndicate Kansas City This edition is cosponsored by the Institute for Humane Studies, Inc., Menlo Park, California, and Cato Institute, San Francisco. Capital, Expectations, and tht Market Proce._ copyright © 1977 by the Institute for Humane Studies, Inc., Menlo Park, California. All rights reserved. Printed in the Um_ed States of America. No part of this book may be used or reproduced in any manner whatsoever without written permission except in the case of reprints in the context of reviews. For information write Sheed Andrews and McMeel, Inc., 6700 Squibb Road, Mission, Kansas. 66202. Librm'y of Congre_ Gttalogiag in Publication Dm Lachmann, Ludwig M Capital, expectations, and the market process (Studies in economic theory) Bibliography: p. Indudes index. I. Austñan school of economics--Addreues, essays, lectures. 2. Economics--Addresses, euay_ iectures. 3. Capital--Addresses, essays, lectures. I. Title. II. Series. HB98.L3 330.15 77-1357 • ISBN 0-8362-0678-9 ISBN 0-8362-0682-7 pl_ The Science of Human Action This is Professor Mises's magnum opus. _ It is a magnum opus in every sense of the word. Its majestic sweep embraces almost the whole fidd of economics and touches, at some point or other, on almost every social issue of our time. Not merely the formal- logical apparatus of economic theory, but the social structure of modern industrial society, its achievements, its weaknesses, and, most of all, its ideologies come under the relentless'scrutiny of one who again and again confounds the smallminded within the precincts of our science and outside it. Perhaps his most out- standing merit is an intellectual courage which in these days of the cult of the "politically possible" has become all too rare. Throughout the 881 pages of the text the argument is presented with a pungency of style which rivals the clarity and vigour ofhis thought. To renderjustice to a work of this nature on the few pages at our disposal is dearly impossible. All we can hope to,do is to select a few topics for discussion. When ten years ago Professor Knight reviewed the original German version 2of the book in thisjournal s and found himself faced with the same dilemma, he selected one topic only for discussion, viz., the theory of capital. Quite possibly this is the best way of going about it. Undoubtedly the theory of capital occupies a prominent place in Professor Mises's doctrinal edi- rice. His theory of the trade cycle as well as bis proof of the inadequacy of some recent "models" for a socialist market economy depend largely on his view of capital. ThisarticleappearedinEcmondm18(November1951):412-27. 94 The Science o["Human /lction 95 Yet we shall not follow the method Profesor Knight adopted ten years ago. Unable though we are to take the reader on an extensive tour of the palace and to show hito every part of the building, it scems to us wrong to confine our insl_ction to the bascment. The wide vistas to be gained from some of the win- dows on the upper floors are too enchanting for that. Hunum dction is, of course, far more than a treatise on the methodology of the social sciences. But its centre of gravity certainly lies in its first seven chapters which are devoted to the discussion of method in the social sdences. We shaU therefore have to deal at some length with the issues raised in these chapters. 1. In the study of human thought on any subject it is a funda- mental principle that we cannot succeed in understanding what an author "really means" unless we understand the questions he is trying to answer. And an appraisal of Professor Mises's views on the methodology of the social sciences requires at least some knowledge of the history of the problems he is dealing with. In reading this book we must never forget that it ís the work of Max Weber that ís being carñed on here. Now, Max Weber's methodological writings had a dual pur- pose: to convince the historians who, at his time and in the German environment in which he grew up, were apt to claim a methodological monopoly for their "individualising" methods, that the social sciences offered justas much, if not more, scope for generalisation as the natural sciences; and that any historical "explanation" logically presupposes a generalised scheme of cause and effect. But at the same time he strove to uphold the methodological independence of the theoretical social sciences of the natural sciences by stressing the cardinal importance of mea-,,sand ends as fundamental cat¢gories of human action. work has been carried on by others besides Professor Mises. There is Profeuor Hayek's famom e_ay on "Scientism and the Study of Society," weU known to readers ofthisjournal. 4 96 Capital, Expectations, and the Market Process There is the work of Dr. Schtz who has applied Husserl's phenomenology to the logical analysis of the structure of human action) And there is, of course, Professor Robbins's Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science (1932; 2nd ed. 1935), which firmly established the definition ofour science in terms of scarce means and multiple ends. It may be objected that this definition of the subject-matter of economics is too wide. At an election, for instance, each voter has one vote but more than one candidate to give it to; yet the problem is not usually regarded as an economic one. Professor Mises's reply to such objections is that in our search for the causes of the market phenomena we observe, and the explanation of which is the primary task of economists, we have unwittingly strayed into the realm of Praxeology, the Science of Human Action. He therefore distinguishes between Praxeology, the Science of Human Action, and Catallactics, the sdence which deals with market phenomena (233). The theorems of the latter presuppose the categoñes of the former. In other words, what Professor Hayek has called "The Pure Logic of Choice" belongs to Praxeology rather than to Catallactics. In this way what we have come to regard as the main body of economics is seen to belong to two related but disunct fields. "Catallactics is the analysis of those actions which are conducted on the basis of monetary calculation. Market exchange and monetary calcula- fion are inseparably linked together" (235). Professor Mises claims a pr/or/validity for the propogitions of Praxeology. "Its scope is human action as such, irrespectíve ofall environmental, accidental, and individual circumstances of the concrete acts. Its cognition is purely formal and general without reference to the material content and the particular features of the actual case .... Its statements and propositions are not derived from experience. They are, like those of logic and mathematics, a pr/or/. They are not subject to v¢ri.f'w.ationor falsifmation on the ground of experience and facts. They are both logically and temporally antecedent to any comprehension of historical facts. They area necessary t=equirement of an), intellectual grasp of historícal events" (32). At the same time_ The Science of Human Action 97 "Praxeology conveys exact and precise knowledge of real things" (39). These statements raise two fundamental questions: How can Praxeology at one and the same time beapriori true, and "convey knowledge of real things"? Secondly, even if no apriori validity is claimed for the propositions of Catallactícs, is it true that all the fundamental economic theorems that would clearly rail into the field of Praxeology are, like logic and mathematics, apriori valid? As regards our first question, we must remember that the"real things" about which we learn from Praxeology are human ac- tions. They can be studied in two ways: we can study them, as it were, "from outside," by observation and experience, like other phenomena of nature; or we can study them "from inside," that is to say, we interpret them as the products ofp/ans, as manifesta- tions of a directing and controlling mind. Looked at in this way all human action has a logical structure. There is therefore such a thing asa Logic of Action closely linked to the logic of our thought. We act by virtue of the fact that we think before. "The real thing which is the subject matter of praxeology, human action, stems from the same source as human reasoning. Action and reason are congeneric and homogeneous; they may even be called two different aspects of the same thing. That reason has the power to make clear through pure ratiocination the essential features of action is a consequence of the fact that action is an offshoot of reason" (39). Our second question raises a fundamental issue in epistemol- ogy. Ir is not merely a question of whether "means and ends" have the same epistemological status as, for instance, "time and space." Behind it there lurks the even more fundamental ques- tion whether we can have any knowledge not ultimately derived from expeñence. Fortunately this journal is not the proper place to raise such weighty issues in. Economica must not become a batfleground for positivísts and Neo-Kantians. It seems to us, however, that in this particular case it is possible to side with Professor Mises without taking sides on the wider issue. For we can, and in our opinion musL distinguish between different layers of experience. In 98 Caóital, Expectations, and the Market Process economics we are concerned with the action of the adult house- holder and the business man.
Recommended publications
  • Violence Cycle Theory Will Be Introduced in Analogy to the Praxeological Business Cycle Theory (According to Ludwig Von Mises)
    The VOL. 19 | NO. 4 | 330–344 QUArtERLY WINTER 2016 JOURNAL of AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS THE PRAXEOLOGY OF COERCION: A NEW THEORY OF VIOLENCE CYCLES RAHIM TAGHIZADEGAN AND MARC-FELIX Otto ABSTRACT: As the first application of the praxeological discipline of “Cratics” (Taghizadegan and Otto, 2015), a theory of the supply and demand of bads is developed. On this foundation, a violence cycle theory will be introduced in analogy to the praxeological business cycle theory (according to Ludwig von Mises). Central to this approach are the subjective perceptions of threats and possible bluffs regarding the backing of those threats. Such a violence cycle theory can explain the stability of structures of violence and reveal new interpretations of the “long peace” hypothesis. KEYWORDS: Austrian school, praxeology, catallactics, coercion JEL CLASSIFICATION: B53 hose actions and things which render a marginal utility to men can be described as goods. In analogy, those actions and things Twhich cause to expect a “marginal disutility” can be described as bads. Catallactics, i.e., the economics of direct and indirect Rahim Taghizadegan ([email protected]) is director of the academic research institute Scholarium (scholarium.at) in Vienna, Austria, lecturer at several univer- sities and faculty member at the International Academy of Philosophy in Liech- tenstein. Marc-Felix Otto ([email protected]) is equity partner at the consulting firm The Advisory House in Zürich, Switzerland. Both authors would like to thank the research staff at the Scholarium for their help and input. 330 Rahim Taghizadegan and Marc-Felix Otto: The Praxeology of Coercion… 331 exchange, can describe the process of the interaction of men who mutually promise and transfer goods to each other.
    [Show full text]
  • FALL 2015 Journal of Austrian Economics
    The VOL. 18 | NO. 3 | 294–310 QUArtERLY FALL 2015 JOURNAL of AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS PRAXEOLOGY OF COERCION: CATALLACTICS VS. CRATICS RAHIM TAGHIZADEGAN AND MARC-FELIX Otto ABSTRACT: Ludwig von Mises’s most important legacy is the foundation and analysis of catallactics, i.e. the economics of interpersonal exchange, as a sub-discipline of praxeology, the science of human action. In this paper, based both on Mises’s methodical framework and on insights by Tadeusz Kotarbinski and Max Weber, a “praxeology of coercion,” or, more precisely, an analysis of interpersonal actions involving threats, is developed. Our investigation yields both a reviewed taxonomy of human action and a first analysis of the elements of this theory, which we term cratics. This shall establish the basis for adjacent studies, furthering Mises’s project regarding the science of human action. KEYWORDS: Austrian school, praxeology, catallactics, coercion JEL CLASSIFICATION: B53 Rahim Taghizadegan ([email protected]) is director of the academic research institute Scholarium (scholarium.at) in Vienna, Austria, lecturer at several univer- sities and faculty member at the International Academy of Philosophy in Liech- tenstein. Marc-Felix Otto ([email protected]) is equity partner at the consulting firm The Advisory House in Zurich, Switzerland. Both authors would like to thank the research staff at the Scholarium for their help and input, in particular Johannes Leitner and Andreas M. Kramer. 294 Rahim Taghizadegan and Marc-Felix Otto: Praxeology Of Coercion… 295 INTRODUCTION he Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises intended to re-establish economics on a deductive basis, with the subjective Tvaluations, expectations, and goals of acting humans at the center, following the tradition of the “Austrian School” (see Mises, 1940 and 1962).
    [Show full text]
  • Hayek and the Departure from Praxeology
    LIBERTARIAN PAPERS VOL. 2, ART. NO. 24 (2010) HAYEK AND THE DEPARTURE FROM PRAXEOLOGY JAKUB WOZINSKI* TIMES OF UNCRITICALLY ACCEPTING the application of methods of natural science to human science are seemingly gone. In the present age, we usually deal with so-called “crypto-positivism,” which revised certain assumptions, but is still stuck in the ideal of science professed more geometrico. Hans-Hermann Hoppe is a philosopher whose theoretical effort proves that the errors of naturalism and empiricism can be overcome only by praxeology based on a priori argumentation. Historians of philosophy very often note the influence that Epicurus had on Karl Marx. The title of his doctoral thesis was The Difference Between the Democritean and Epicurean Philosophy of Nature. The father of communism was especially interested in the theory of clinamen, i.e. a minimal indeterminacy in the motion of atoms. For Epicurus, this theory was supposed to form a basis for helping him avoid absolute determinism, whereas for Marx it served as an explanation for the exceptional role played by the leaders of the proletariat. Clinamen was an important part of the overall structure of the world and society. But even more relevant were atoms: discrete, undifferentiated elements forming individuals known to us from sensory experience. One may ask here: why do we mention Epicurus in a text that is supposed to deal with Hayek? It is because Epicurus played an important role in shaping his theory as well—indirectly and directly. Hayek’s epistemology and ontology are based directly on philosophical assumptions developed by the founder of the Garden.
    [Show full text]
  • Praxeology As Law & Economics
    Journal of Libertarian Studies Volume 18, no. 2 (Spring 2004), pp. 73Ð89 2004 Ludwig von Mises Institute www.mises.org PRAXEOLOGY AS LAW & ECONOMICS Josef Sima* [The law] has acted in a way contrary to its own end; it has destroyed its own object: it has been employed in abolishing the justice which it was supposed to maintain, in effacing that limit between rights which it was its mis- sion to respect, it has put the collective force at the service of those who desire to exploit, without risk and without scruple, the person, liberty, or property of others; it has converted plunder into a right, in order to protect it, and legitimate defense into a crime, in order to punish it. How has this perversion of the law been accomplished? What have been the consequences of it? Ð FrŽdŽric Bastiat1 The law & economics movement has become one of the most dynamic schools within economics. Its origin is often dated back to the University of Chicago in the 1950s and 1960s, but insights about the interconnections of economics and the law can be found in the works of earlier economists. OLDER APPROACHES TO LAW & ECONOMICS Despite this contemporary idea that the law & economics move- ments started in the 1950s, older scholarly works touched upon the problem of economics and the law, and make cases for other scholars *Deputy Department Chair, Department of Economic Policy, Prague Univer- sity of Economics; and Director for Publications, Liberalni Institut, Prague, Czech Republic. [email protected]. 1FrŽdŽric Bastiat, The Law, in FrŽdŽric Bastiat, Selected Essays on Political Economy (Irvington-on-Hudson, N.Y.: Foundation for Economic Education, 2001), p.
    [Show full text]
  • Liberty, Property and Rationality
    Liberty, Property and Rationality Concept of Freedom in Murray Rothbard’s Anarcho-capitalism Master’s Thesis Hannu Hästbacka 13.11.2018 University of Helsinki Faculty of Arts General History Tiedekunta/Osasto – Fakultet/Sektion – Faculty Laitos – Institution – Department Humanistinen tiedekunta Filosofian, historian, kulttuurin ja taiteiden tutkimuksen laitos Tekijä – Författare – Author Hannu Hästbacka Työn nimi – Arbetets titel – Title Liberty, Property and Rationality. Concept of Freedom in Murray Rothbard’s Anarcho-capitalism Oppiaine – Läroämne – Subject Yleinen historia Työn laji – Arbetets art – Level Aika – Datum – Month and Sivumäärä– Sidoantal – Number of pages Pro gradu -tutkielma year 100 13.11.2018 Tiivistelmä – Referat – Abstract Murray Rothbard (1926–1995) on yksi keskeisimmistä modernin libertarismin taustalla olevista ajattelijoista. Rothbard pitää yksilöllistä vapautta keskeisimpänä periaatteenaan, ja yhdistää filosofiassaan klassisen liberalismin perinnettä itävaltalaiseen taloustieteeseen, teleologiseen luonnonoikeusajatteluun sekä individualistiseen anarkismiin. Hänen tavoitteenaan on kehittää puhtaaseen järkeen pohjautuva oikeusoppi, jonka pohjalta voidaan perustaa vapaiden markkinoiden ihanneyhteiskunta. Valtiota ei täten Rothbardin ihanneyhteiskunnassa ole, vaan vastuu yksilöllisten luonnonoikeuksien toteutumisesta on kokonaan yksilöllä itsellään. Tutkin työssäni vapauden käsitettä Rothbardin anarko-kapitalistisessa filosofiassa. Selvitän ja analysoin Rothbardin ajattelun keskeisimpiä elementtejä niiden filosofisissa,
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Calculation and the Limits of Organization
    Economic Calculation and the Limits of Organization Peter G. Klein conomists have become increasingly frustrated with the text- book model of the firm. The "firm" of intermediate microeco- Enomics is a production function, a mysterious "black box" whose insides are off-limits to respectable economic theory (relegated instead to the lesser disciplines of management, organization theory, industrial psychology, and the like). Though useful in certain contexts, the textbook model has proven unable to account for a variety of real- world business practices: vertical and lateral integration, geographic and product-line diversification, franchising, long-term commercial contract- ing, transfer pricing, research joint ventures, and many others. As an al- ternative to viewing the firm as a production function, economists are turning to a new body ofliterature that views the firm as anorganization, itself worthy of economic analysis. This emerging literature is the best- developed part of what has come to be called the "new institutional eco- nomics."' The new perspective has deeply enhanced and enriched our un- derstanding of firms and other organizations, such that we can no longer agree with Ronald Coase's 1988 statement that "[wlhy firms exist, what determines the number of firms, what determines what firms do . are not questions of interest to most economists" (Coase 1988a, p. 5).The new theory is not without its critics; Richard Nelson (1991), for example, ob- jects that the new institutional economics tends to downplay discretion- ary differences among firms. Still, the new institutional economics-in particular, agency theory and transaction cost economics-has been *Peter G. Klein is assistant professor of economics at the University of Georgia.
    [Show full text]
  • Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative
    [Show full text]
  • Ludwig Von Mises' Praxeology As Seen from a Business Ethics Angle
    Wojciech W. Gasparski Human Action As An Ultimate Given: Ludwig Von Mises’ Praxeology As Seen From A Business Ethics Angle Studia Humana nr 5, 3-14 2013 Studia Humana Volume 2:1 (2013), pp. 3—14 Human Action As An Ultimate Given: Ludwig Von Mises’ Praxeology As Seen From A Business Ethics Angle Wojciech W. Gasparski Business Ethics Centre 1, Ko źmi ński University, Warsaw, Poland e-mail: [email protected] Abstract: Ludwig von Mises (1881 -1973) was one of the two parallel followers of the Espinas ’, a French scholar, human action theory; the other was Tadeusz Kotarbi ński (1886 -1981). The former was the founder of the Austrian praxeology considered as the aprioristic logic of action, and the latter originated the Polish prax iology considered as general methodology , i.e. epistemology of practice or grammar of action. This paper is intended to characterize the Mises ’ approach, closely related to his experience; therefore a number of important facts from the life of the Austrian praxeologist, economist a nd economics philosopher is summarized in the first part of the essay. According to Mises praxeological laws apply to the regularity of phenomena due to the correlations between means and ends which restricts people’s freedom of choice and action. Other re strictions of action have their source in physical laws, to which humans must adjust their behavior if they want to live, and physiological laws, i.e. a set of constitutive qualities characteristic of each individual, defining that individual’s disposition and susceptibility to environmental. Mises presented his theory in the book Human Action: A Treatise on Economics , over nine hundred pages long opus magnum that comprises forty chapters.
    [Show full text]
  • The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economics Studies in Economic Theory Laurence S
    í' The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economics Studies in Economic Theory Laurence S. Moss, Editor America's Great Depression, Murray N. Rothbard (1975) The Economics of Ludwig ron Mises: Toward a Critical Reappraisal, ed. Laurence S. Moss (1976) The Foundations ofModern ,dustrian Economics, ed. Edwin G. Dolan (1,976) The Economic Point of View, Israel M. Kirzner (1976) -,,.' The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economlcs Edited with an Introduction by Edwin G. Dolan SHEED & WARD, INC. Subsidiary of Univer-_L!Press Syndicate KansasCity This edition is cosponsored by the Institute for Humane Studies, Inc., Menlo Park, California. The Foundation_ of Modern dustrian Economics Copyright © 1976 by the Institute for Humane Studies Al ñghts reserved. Printed in the United States of America. No part of this book may be used or repro- duced in any manner whatsoever without written permission except in the case of reprints in the context of reviews. For information write Sheed & Ward, Ira:., 6700 Squibb Road, Mission, Kansas 6620"2. Library of Congress Cataloging in Publi¢ation Data Main entry under title: The Foundations of modern Austrian economics. (Studies in economic theory) Proce.edings of a con ference sponsored by the Insti- tute for Humane Studies and held at Royalton College, South Royalton, Vt., in June 1974. Bibliography: p. lncludes index. 1. Austrian school of economists -- Congresses. I. Dolan, Edwin G. II. Instítute for Humane Studies. I11. Series. HB98.F68 330'.09436 76-5894 ISBN 0-8362-0653-3 ISBN 0-8362-.0654-1 pbk. -g CONTENTS PREFACE vii PART 1 INTRODUCTION Austrian Economics as Extraordinary Science 3 Edwin G.
    [Show full text]
  • Ludwig Von Mises's Praxeology As the Foundation of Christian Economic Personalism
    STUDIES IN LOGIC, GRAMMAR AND RHETORIC 57 (70) 2019 DOI: 10.2478/slgr-2019-0001 Jacek Gniadek SVD Society of the Divine Word e-mail: [email protected] LUDWIG VON MISES’S PRAXEOLOGY AS THE FOUNDATION OF CHRISTIAN ECONOMIC PERSONALISM Abstract. What can an economist and agnostic tell a theologian about man? In contrast to mainstream economics, which today dominate all universities in the world, Ludwig von Mises (+1973) is interested in real man in action, not a fictitious homo oeconomicus. At one time Gregory M. A. Gronbacher (1998), an American philosopher, proposed a synthesis of Christian personalism with the free market economy developed by the Austrian School of Economics. His idea prompted me to use Mises’s praxeology to understand and describe human action in the socio-economic sphere from the perspective of Catholic Social Teaching. At that time I understood how important were economic laws for the proper moral evaluation of human action. Mises in his treaty on economics Human Action developed his own anthro- pological concept of man. The Austrian economist never used the expression “person” to describe and analyze human action, but analyzing his economic system I was able to discover that he did not understand the free market econ- omy as an abstract being composed of mechanical elements. According to him, the prerequisite for human activity is the desire to replace a less satisfactory state of affairs with a more satisfying one. Mises’s man is guided by his own scale of values and builds it up on the basis of a goal he freely chooses.
    [Show full text]
  • Tensions Between Theory and History in Von Mises’S Critique of Socialism
    Revista de Economia Contemporânea (2018) 22(2): p. 1-23 (Journal of Contemporary Economics) ISSN 1980-5527 http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/198055272221 elocation - e182221 www.ie.ufrj.br/revista | www.scielo.br/rec TENSIONS BETWEEN THEORY AND HISTORY IN VON MISES’S CRITIQUE OF SOCIALISM Emmanoel Boffa aProfessor da Universidade Federal Fluminense (UFF). Manuscript received on 2017/06/13 and accepted for publication on 2018/03/13.1 ABSTRACT: The article investigates the relation between praxeology and history in the critique Mises directs at the possibility of the long-term existence of a socialist commonwealth. We argue that Mises makes no clear distinction between the praxeological concept of 'private property' (associated with the possession of means of production) and the historical concept of the ideal-type 'private property' (associated to property rights – see HODGSON, 2015). The lack of precision between the theoretical and the historical concepts of private property prevents Mises’s critique from being an 'exact law', as he would have it. Finally, we show in the last section the consequences for Mises’s critique of socialism of having a historical and a praxeological concept of private property. KEYWORDS: Mises; socialism; socialist calculation; critique. JEL CODE: B13, B14, B15. Corresponding Author: Emmanoel Boff Contact: [email protected] All the contents of this journal, except where otherwise noted, is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution Rev. Econ. Contemp., v. 22, n. 2, p. 1 -23, mai./ago. 2018: e182221 1 DOI: 10.1590/198055272221 License. BOFF, E. Tensions between theory and history in von mises’s critique of socialism TENSÕES ENTRE TEORIA E HISTÓRIA NA CRÍTICA DE VON MISES AO SOCIALISMO RESUMO: O artigo investiga a relação entre a praxeologia e a história na crítica que von Mises dirige à possibilidade da existência de socialismo no longo prazo.
    [Show full text]
  • Catallactics Misapplication: It Impact on Africa's Economy
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Catallactics misapplication: it impact on Africa’s economy Tweneboah Senzu, Emmanuel Bastiat Institute Ghana, Cape Coast Technical University, Banking Finance Dept., Economic Dept. Leicester University 20 July 2015 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/79548/ MPRA Paper No. 79548, posted 07 Jun 2017 05:33 UTC Catallactics misapplication: it impact on Africa’s economy Emmanuel Tweneboah Senzu [email protected] P a g e 1 | 34 1.0 ABSTRACT The paper seeks to solve the macroeconomic error that emerged from the dispensing of the monetary policy by the Central Banks of Africa. These monetary policies is unable to address the desired economic growth expected by individual developing and underdeveloped economies. It conclusively present a new mathematical model to determine the exact health status of an economy in developing and underdeveloped countries in Africa. Keywords: Monetary Economics, Monetary Policy, Fiscal Policy, Macroeconomics, Developmental Economics JEL Class.: E2-E23, E5-E51-E58, O2-O23 2.0 INTRODUCTION The research study and purpose of this paper is to contribute to the knowledge body of this faculty of studies and help improve on the error which emerged from the careless use of imaginary construction in the direct and indirect exchange activities of the market and it methodological application by the Central Banks in Africa to dispense their monetary policy. This result in fallacious economic predictions and policy constructions directed to the future of the market. The latter result, is the frustration of the employment of capital and labour for the development of the economy of Africa. Blanchard (2003) posited ‘Monetary policy can have large and long lasting effects on the real interest rates and the implication on activities.’ She further indicated that, in her Conference paper presented in honour of James Tobin at MIT School, which state that, “the large empirical literature based on structural VRA, suggests that the effect of an innovation in money on activity peaks after a year or so.
    [Show full text]