<<

WorldDevelopment, Vol. 22, No. 3, pp. 427--436, 1994 Pergamon Elsevier Science Ltd (I) Printed in Great Britain. 0305-7SOX/94 $7.00 + 0.00 0305-750X(94)E0016-D The Politics of in Tunisia: Utility of the Rentier Paradigm?

EVA BELLIN* Harvard University,Cambridge, Massachusetts

.Swnmary.- The analysis of rent-seeking in developing countries has shed light on the nonproductive character of classes and the parasitic nature of state elites in many settings. The "rentier para­ digm" however, is problematic in assuming that all manifestations of state intervention and private are inherently subversive of efficient growth. Evidence from Tunisia suggests that government mediation of profits, and even extensive cronyism, can be compatible with productive investment and growth if appropriate political conditions prevail. The nature of state structure and the logic of the regime's sustaining political coalition will determine the developmental impact of state economic man­ agement.

1. INTRODUCTION hailed for spotlighting a serious problem that plagues many Third World countries - the prevalence of par­ For more than a decade much of the development asitic cronyism in business-state relations that sub­ community has retreated from its faith in state-led verts both economic development and state capacity. development, advocating a central role for the private Still, as an analytic category the term "rentier" is prob­ sector in the development process. Disenchanted with lematic in two ways. First, it assumes a clear distinc­ the sluggishness and inefficiency associated with pub­ tion between productive and unproductive engage­ lic sector growth and inspired by Schumpeter' s vision ment of resources that is actually difficult to define of the ideal-typical entrepreneur, development experts objectively (that is, without getting mired in endless became persuaded that channeling resources to the normative debate). 3 Attempts to borrow a narrow, private sector would release productive energy, non-normative definition of rents from economics heighten economic efficiency, and fuel rapid growth only expand the boundaries of the rentier class to the in the Third World. In stark contrast to the bloated, point of analytic disutility (at least for the political sci­ bureaucratized, and politically hamstrung enterprises entist). Second, the pejorative connotation of the term of the public sector, the private sector came to be seen rentier smuggles in from an as the crucible of efficiency and productivity and so its inherent distrust of government mediation of profits, expansion was widely championed. leading one to assume that such mediation, by defini­ But given such idealization of the private sector, tion, subverts efficient economic growth, societal reality was bound to fall short. More often than not autonomy, and state coherence. In fact, whether gov­ empirical investigation into the character of private ernment mediation of profits produces these untoward sector actors in the Third World failed to tum up a consequences is actually determined by two interven­ class of productive, autonomous entrepreneurs cut in ing variables: the nature of state structure and the the image of Schumpeter's ideal-type. More common character of the regime's sustaining political coali­ were hosts of "crony capitalists," businessmen in tion. The truth is that government mediation of profits, league with (if not doubling as) state bureaucrats, even extensive cronyism, can be wholly compatible focused primarily on harvesting government-medi­ with the goals of efficient growth, autonomy, and ated rents rather than engaging in truly productive enterprise. 1 This "rentier syndrome," pervasive in much of the developing world, had troubling implica­ *My thanks go to John Waterbury, Atul Kohli, Nicholas tions for economy, polity,. and society. Slowed van de Walle, Thomas Callaghy,.and an anonymous reviewer for their helpful comments on¥: earlier version growth, emasculated social forces, and incoherent of this article. Two prior versions were presented at the states were just three of the evils typically associated 1991 American Political Science Association conference with its uncurbed growth. 2 in Washington, DC and the 1992 African Studies The delineation of the rentier syndrome should be Association. Final revision accepted: November 8, 1993.

427 428 WORLDDEVELOPMENT capacity so long as appropriate political conditions their in joint ventures with the state), the public prevail. sector dwarfed the private sector in terms of industrial This argument will be developed by drawing investment, topping 70% of gross fixed capital forma­ upon the Tunisian case. The article will trace the tion in nearly every industrial branch throughout the development of private sector industrialists in course of the decade (Romdhane and Signoles, 1982, Tunisia, testing the applicability and utility of the ren­ p. 73; Gouia, 1976). tier paradigm in describing this class and its relation­ But the state's enthusiasm for playing the leading ship to the state. The article will show that although role in the Tunisia's industrialization was to wane by Tunisian industrialists technically qualify as "rentier," the early 1970s. For reasons explored elsewhere their close relationship to the state has not resulted (Bellin, 1992), poor harvests and fiscal crisis helped in significant losses of growth, autonomy, or capacity precipitate the fall of the state's most ideologically for Tunisia thanks to the nature of state structure committed etatise elite, leading to their replacement and the logic of the regime's sustaining political coali­ by a new executive team committed to a more "lib­ tion. eral" strategy of development. The new elite declared that henceforth the private sector would take the lead in national development; the state would act only as its 2. THE DEVELOPMENT OF PRIVATE handmaiden and guardian. The hope of this elite was SECTOR INDUSTRY IN TUNISIA to corral the energy and resources of private sector entrepreneurs into industrial ventures and ultimately The development of an indigenous class of private hand over the major responsibility for the country's sector industrialists is a relatively recent phenomenon industrialization to that class. As then minister of in Tunisia. The country arrived at independence national economy Chedli Ayari announced: ''The state equipped with a small industrial base but the lion's seeks to create a generation of industrialists who will share of industrial ventures were owned either by be the masters of the country tomorrow" (Signoles, European trusts and banks or foreign nationals 1984, pp. 790-794). (Bellin, 1991, p. 47). During the early years of inde­ To entice Tunisian entrepreneurs into undertaking pendence, the young Tunisian state did try to en­ industrial ventures, the state resorted to a wide battery courage the development of an indigenous in­ of by now familiar measures. These measures dustrial , offering easy credit, generous tax included generous tax breaks, easy credit, protection breaks, and substantial tariff protection to potential from foreign , licensed monopolies for in industry. Tunisian entrepreneurs, how­ production for the domestic market, guaranteed prof­ ever, resisted these inducements in droves, preferring its (through controlled, cost-plus pricing), and guaran­ to risk their capital in real estate and commercial ven­ teed government contracts where possible. In short, tures that could be bought on the cheap from departing the state's strategy was to sweeten the prospects of colons (Romdhane, 1981, p. 200). As a result, invest­ profitability in industry by offering entrepreneurs a ment funds earmarked by the state for industrial pro­ host of opportunities to harvest special rents, 5 rents jects went begging and the industrial sector as a whole available thanks to government intervention in the stagnated between 1956--61 (Gouia, 1976, p. 209). By workings of the market. These measures, it was the early 1960s the threat of negative growth was suf­ hoped, would lure risk-averse entrepreneurs into the ficiently strong to persuade state elites that a new terra incognitaof industry. strategy for the country's industrialization was neces­ The results were not disappointing. Private sary. Rather than rely upon initiative from the private investors responded to these inducements with enthu­ sector, state elites decided to take responsibility for siasm. Over the next decade or so the number of Tunisia's industrialization themselves. private sector industrial enterprises tripled, rising The 1960s was a decade of state-led industrializa­ from a low of 865 in 1970 to a high of 2,866 in 1983.6 tion. State technocrats launched industrial ventures in Private sector enterpreneurs tended to cluster in ven­ nearly every sector (from heavy, "industrializing tures that were technologically simple, least capital industries" 4 such as steel to lighter, consumer-oriented intensive, and most immediately profitable 7 but their industries such as food processing). By 1969 the state presence was felt in nearly every industrial sector. The had established more than 80 public sector industrial private sector's contribution to the economy steadily enterprises, producing everything from sugar, clothes, grew, accounting for nearly 45% of all industrial and ice cream to phosphates, ovens, and tractors investment by the mid 1980s and soon surpassing the (Ayadi, 1969, pp. 4-5). Thanks to the state's stimulus, public sector's contribution to added in three value-added in manufacturing grew at an average sectors (textiles/leather, electro-mechanics, and annual rate of 6.3% (Romdhane and Signoles, 1982, p. diverse industries) while reaching parity in two more 63) and while private sector entrepreneurs were not (chemicals and agro-alimentary). By the rnid-1980s actually discouraged from undertaking industrial ven­ then, a sizeable, diversified, indigenous industrial tures (in fact they were actively encouraged to invest bourgeoisie had indeed emerged in Tunisia. POLmcs OF PROFIT IN TUNISIA 429

3. TUNISIAN INDUSTRIALISTS- labor and entrepreneurial capitalists" for he derived RENTIER? his income "from neither labor nor productive capital . investment" (Kregel, 1987). Thus the term rentier Now given the emergence of this class of private evokes a constellation of negative qualities - passiv­ sector industrialists, three observations should be ity, unproductiveness, even parasitism, qualities that made about the nature of its relationship to the state. inform the layman's usage of the term today. First, there is no question that this class owes a debt Economists, on the other hand, have a much more of origin to the state. A class of private sector industri­ narrow understanding of the term rentier. A rentier is alists emerged in Tunisian in response to generous simply someone who collects rent. Rent, in turn, is inducements offered by the state and thanks to the defined as "payment to a resource owner above the general context of nurturing and sheltering provided amount his resources could command in the next best by the state to this class. alternative use" (that is, it is payment in excess of the Second, there can be no doubt that the profitability resource's opportunity cost) (Tollison, 1982, p. 572). of private ·sector industrial ventures was enhanced In itself, rent is unobjectionable and indistinguishable thanks to government mediation (that is, government from profit so long as perfect market conditions pre­ intervention in the market). Certainly some of these vail. 8 Under such conditions the possibility of earning ventures might have been sustainable and profitable exceptionally high returns (rent) simply attracts even without protection and subsidization by the state resources to their most highly valued use, thereby but clearly all industrial ventures saw their profitabil­ increasing society's overall welfare. Rents are prob­ ity enhanced by the state's measures. lematic only when they are the product of market Third, there can be no doubt that close personal imperfection - either natural monopolies or artificial relations with members of the state elite, that is, scarcities created by government intervention in the "insider contacts," were indeed important to business workings of the market.9 Under these conditions the success in Tunisia. At least until the late 1980s, link between exceptionally high return and increased licenses, loans, and subsidies were all distributed by production of society's most highly valued goods is the state on a discretionary basis and knowing some­ broken - hence the pejorative connotation of the one on the inside was certainly important for getting term rents as "illegitimate" or "excess" profits. Briefly access to these benefits. In fact, the importance of put then, for economists a rentier is someone who knowing someone on the inside for the successful earns "excess profits" thanks to imperfections in the inauguration of an industrial venture was such com­ market, imperfections that are often the product of mon knowledge it was even institutionalized by the government intervention in the market's operation. state. By the late 1970s, the state had created a civil Finally, political economists' use of the term ren­ servant "loan program" called "detachment formal." tier borrows from both the laymen's and the econo­ Under this program civil servants were lent to desig­ mist's understanding of the word. As explained by nated private sector ventures for a limited period of Boone, an entrepreneur is considered a rentier if he time in order to help shepherd the ventures through the meets two criteria, that is, if he engages in generally­ bureaucracy and get them off to a healthy start. unproductive economic activity and if his profits are Recognizing that insider contacts and insider informa­ politically mediated (i.e. mediated by government tion were crucial to business success, state elites rea­ intervention in the market).10 Examples of such pure soned that "loaner" civil servants would provide pri­ rentiers abound. Perhaps best known are what an ear­ vate sector ventures with both. lier generation of political sociologists used to call the Given these three observations - that private sec­ "parasitic bourgeoisie." By definition this class of tor industrialists in Tunisia by and large owe their ori­ entrepreneurs contributes nothing of value to the gins to the state, that the profitability of their ventures national economy. Rather, they enrich themselves by is enhanced by government mediation, and that cozy preying upon the state, trading on insider contacts relations with state elites are essential to business suc­ within the state bureaucracy in ways that enable them cess - should we then argue that Tunisia's private to harvest profits from the mere circulation of goods sector industrialists constitute a rentier bourgeoisie? and . A well-known example of this parasitic Do their operations represent an example of rentier class can be found in the "commission entrepreneurs" ? of Saudi Arabia (Field, 1984). These entrepreneurs The term rentier is both ambiguous and loaded. use their close connections to the Saudi royal family to Intuitively, it calls up the image of the coupon clipper wangle exclusive rights to represent foreign firms in so vilified by Marx, the bond holder passively collect­ the kingdom (say the exclusive dealership of IBM ing his dividend check, interested only in tapping into products) or to act as the state's middleman in contract the circulation of income rather than using his skills negotiations with foreign suppliers (say arms dealers and resources to make a "productive" contribution to such as Adnan Kashoggi). In either case, close per­ the common weal. By the 20th century- the rentier sonal relations with state leaders pay off in the form of came to be viewed as "a parasite living off the effort of hefty commissions simply for adding an additional 430 WORLDDEVELOPMENT layer of middlemen to the distribution circuit in Saudi thanks to government supports (subsidies, tariff pro­ Arabia. Similarly, Egypt's "supply mafia" provides tection, etc.) be considered rentier? After all, the "pro­ another example of a parasitic bourgeoisie ductivity" of such a firm is questionable (given the (Springborg, 1989). These entrepreneurs use personal fact that its efficiency is tainted) and its profits are contacts within the state bureaucracy to commandeer clearly mediated by state intervention in the market. scarce supplies of subsidized (and often rationed) Taking this question of mediation further,just how goods. These goods are then sold on the much government mediation is necessary to deem an at very high prices, pennitting their dealers to skim off enterprise rentier? Is the industrialist who earns an hefty profits for themselves in the process. In both the extra margin of profit thanks to governmental inter­ Egyptian and Saudi cases, these parasitic businessmen vention in the market in the form of tariff protection, fit the political economist's description of the rentier infrastructural subsidies, and guaranteed contracts to for in both cases the businessmen are engaged in be considered rentier? Perhaps, but the fact is that a clearly unproductive activities (they are simply large portion of private sector industrialists every­ adding another layer of middlemen to the distribution where in the world enjoys such profit enhancement circuit) and in both cases the businessmen's profits are thanks to sheltering or nurturing by the state. In the politically mediated (i.e. they are acquired through the United States, for example, the defense industry has manipulation of close personal relations within the long been sustained by near guaranteed contracts from state bureaucracy). the state just as the auto industry has long been buoyed But aside from these parasitic entrepreneurs, the by tariff protection, import quotas, and subsidies. process of identifying other rentier businessmen gets Such governmental intervention is the rule rather than murky. This murkiness derives from certain ambigui­ the exception in most industrialized countries. It is ties in the political economist's definition of the term part of the prevailing logic of "embedded " rentier. Specifically, just what constitutes ''unproduc­ discussed by Callaghy (1989, p. 119) wherein states tive" economic activity and what distinguishes it from compromise principles for the sake of the more productive variety? Furthermore, just how domestic political and economic considerations. Are much government mediation of profits is necessary to we then to consider all entrepreneurs who benefit qualify a businessman as rentier? from embedded liberalism rentier? Strict adherence to Distinguishing productive from unproductive eco­ the economist's definition of rents would rule in the nomic activity turns out to be an extremely thorny affirmative. Rents (and hence rentiers) are created matter. Theoretically, economists consider an activity whenever the state intervenes in ways that artificially productive so long as it augments aggregate social inflate or reduce prices (thereby creating welfare (Colander, 1984, p. 8). But without an objec­ artificial scarcities and hence the opportunity to col­ tive measure of social welfare (a difficult proposition lect inflated profits). given the extremely subjective nature of individual But reliance upon the economist's narrow (if utility functions), economists fall back on a physical precise) definition of rents (perhaps paradoxically) conception of productivity, measuring it in terms of expands-the concept rentier to such a degree that it is contribution to aggregate (physical) output (Colander, robbed of analytic utility. A term that embraces in one 1984, p. 8). The problem then is how is one to evalu­ category groups as different as the supply mafia of ate ventures where there is no physical product? Are Egypt and the automotive industry of the United all enterprises in the service sector to be lumped States is a term so diluted as to lack analytic punch. So together in one category, deemed by definition pro­ defined, the category may be internally consistent, ductive or unproductive? This approach seems unsat­ however, it glosses over essential distinctions isfactory but equally problematic is the formulation of between such ventures (their productivity, their auton­ a nonsubjective standard that would distinguish omy from the state), distinctions that are crucial to the between service sector ventures that enhance the com­ political scientist. On the other hand, falling back on a mon weal (say an efficient bank or insurance agency) more intuitive understanding of the term rentier and those whose contribution is less evident (say, (''unproductive", government-mediated) opens the commission entrepreneurs or scalpers). door to too much imprecision and subjectivity (just Even setting aside the question of the service sec­ what is productive? how much mediation is necessary tor, however, another question poses itself. Just how to qualify as rentier?) to define clear boundaries for efficient must a venture be to be considered produc­ this group. tive? It seems unlikely that a firm that produce goods whose market value is lower than the market value of its inputs should be considered productive even if tan­ 4. UTILITY OF THE RENTIER PARADIGM? gible goods are produced. (It is not clear that the firm is increasing society's aggregate welfare in any real As an analytic category then, the term rentier is way.) On the other hand, should the protected manu­ problematic. But this is not to say that the literature on facturer who produce goods inefficiently but survives rentier capitalism lacks important insights. To the· POLITICS OF PROFIT IN TUNISIA 431 contrary, this research is extremely useful for identify­ stressed that political mediation of profits creates only ing three hazards that emerge whenever profits are the possibility, not the necessity, of such conse­ politically mediated. 11 quences. Whether or not political mediation leads to First, there is the hazard that where profits are losses in general welfare, societal autonomy, or state politically mediated, society as a whole will suffer a capacity turns on a number of intervening political significant welfare loss. The reasoning behind this variables, specifically the nature of state structure claim is that when state elites are given discretionary and the logic of the regime's sustaining political coali­ power over the distribution of resources, they are tion. likely to distribute those resources according to crite­ The evidence is clear from Tunisia. Tunisia's ria that are economically irrational. This in tum leads industrial class does indeed fit a strict definition of a to inefficient use of resources, that is, waste and wel­ render class and its profits are indeed politically medi­ fare loss. Now, the noneconomic criterion that gov­ ated by the state. Although some industrial ventures erns the state-'s discretionary distribution ofresources might survive without government support, nearly all is typically one of two (Bates, 1981, p. 102). Either see their profitability enhanced by government subsi­ state elites will distribute benefits with an eye to per­ dies and protection (all of which have historically sonal gain (for example, government contracts or been distributed on a discretionary basis). Never-the­ interest-free loans will be distributed to the client who less, government mediation of profits has not resulted offers the biggest kickback). Or state elites will dis­ in debilitating welfare loss, societal emasculation, or tribute benefits with an eye to political survival (that state cannibalism (such as one finds in a Zaire) and is, benefits will be distributed with an eye to building this is primarily due to the character of the Tunisian a political clientele). Examples of such economically state and the nature of the regime's sustaining political "irrational" distribution of benefits are many, ranging coalition. from the distribution of state contracts to close friends Consider the first hazard, welfare loss. Clearly and family by state bureaucrats in Egypt for reasons of state intervention in the Tunisian economy has led to personal gain (Sadowski, 1991) to the provision of some market distortion, resulting in less than perfectly subsidies for hopeless industrial ventures in Saudi rational allocation of society's resources. The ques­ Arabia by state elites eager to buy political quiescence tion of significant welfare loss however, ultimately from the middle class (Luciani, 1990). In either case, turns on whether noneconomic logic (specifically state elites distribute benefits in an economically irra­ concern for personal gain or building political cliente­ tional fashion and this leads to welfare loss for society les) overwhelms the state's decision-making process as a whole. in its management of the economy. Second, there is the hazard that where profits are In Tunisia, concern for building political clienteles politically mediated, the entrepreneurial class will has not been a governing consideration in the state's lose its political autonomy. The danger is that where distribution of discretionary benefits to the industrial the economic position of the entrepreneurial class class. This is because industrialists as a group have depends upon currying favor with the state, these never been an important component in the regime's entrepreneurs will be reduced to what Kasfir (1984) political base. To the contrary, the regime has histori­ calls "eunuch capitalists," capitalists who lack the cally sought its popular foundation in a coalition of autonomy to challenge the state or act as a counter­ urban workers and rural peasants (both of whom are vailing force to state elites in the defintion of public linked to the state through the discretionary distribu­ policy. An "emasculated" bourgeoisie is a common tion of benefits, e.g., health benefit cards to loyal peas­ phenomenon in many Third World countries and its ant members of the rural party machine and higher creation is often the conscious policy of the state as wages to loyal organized workers). Its symbols have shown by Iliffe (1983) in Ghana and de Miras (1982) always been populist (even as the ruling party shed the in Cote d'Ivoire. 12 qualifier "socialist" from its name in 1988 it made cer­ Third, there is the hazard that where profits are tain to retain its membership in the international politically mediated, the state will become embroiled alliance of socialist parties) and it has steadfastly in clientalistic relations which can ultimately canni­ refused to renounce its populist constituencies (hence balize the state and undermine its capacity to conduct the state's efforts to shore up the national trade union coherent developmentalist economic policy. Boone's confederation since 1988). The regime has histori­ work on Senegal ( 1990) and Callaghy' s work on Zaire cally kept businessmen at ann's length13 and even (1984) have made clear the negative impact rampant with the recent celebration of entrepreneurs as leaders clientalism can have on state capacity. in the development process, the regime has tended to These three hazards are genuine. Where the state exclude them from the political limelight. (Note that mediates private sector profitability, opportunities are very few businessmen have been invited to join the indeed created for machination that can result in ruling party's central committee.) The relative dis­ welfare loss, the emasculation of social forces, and pensability of businessmen to the regime's political the cannibalization of the state. Still, it must be base has permitted the state to cleave to a develop- 432 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

mentalist logic in its economic policies even when this this irrationality was attributed to administrative logic harms business interests. incompetence and overbureaucratization rather than The best evidence for this is the alacrity with blatant on the part of state officials. which the state implemented IMF-mandated market­ At first glance this claim of "no corruption" might oriented reforms in the late 1980s. When severe for­ seem difficult to square with our earlier observation eign exchange and fiscal crisis loomed in 1986 and the that insider contacts are very important to business International Monetary Fund (IMF) called for price success in Tunisia. In fact the two are compatible so and import , devaluation of the dinar, and long as one realizes that cronyism is distinguishable reductions in public spending, the regime quickly fell from corruption in terms of both cause and effect. in line - so much so that today Tunisia is considered Corruption refers to the misuse of public office for pri­ a model adjuster by the Fund (IMF Survey, November vate ends. It is motivated by the individual's desire for 9 1992, pp. 347-350). This was true despite the fact • personal gain and is deplored because such gain that these measures were destined to reduce substan­ usually comes at the expense of general welfare. tially supports and subsidies to the industrial sector. Cronyism by contrast refers to the provision of prefer­ (For example, the IMF reforms promised to reduce ential treatment to one's chums. Cronyism need not tariff protection as well as the availability of subsi­ necessarily be motivated by the desire for personal dized credit.) State elites adopted these measures payoff. Moreover, it need not necessarily result in (despite the protests of individual industrialists) welfare loss for society as a whole. largely because they could. Industrialists had never In the case of Tunisia cronyism is indeed prevalent been an important part of the regime's sustaining in business-state relations but this is not necessarily political coalition and so the regime could afford to because businessmen and bureaucrats are eager to cre­ compromise their interests for the sake of IMF-enun­ ate "back-scratching" opportunities that will profit ciated (and funded) rationality. 14 them both at the expense of the general public. To the If concern for building political clienteles has not contrary, frequent recourse to cronyism should be been a governing consideration in the state's distribu­ seen as a rational response to an information problem tion of benefits to the industrial class, then neither has faced by both industrialists and state elites. For the concern for personal gain on the part of state elites. If industrialist there is the daunting prospect of dealing we are to take Tunisian industrialists at their word, with a Byzantine state that has long sought to license corruption levels are relatively low in Tunisia's state and control every aspect of business life. A typical bureaucracy, at least in comparison to that of many project may require over 40 separate bureaucratic neighboring states in the region. 15 This is not to say approvals before it can be legally launched. Moreover, that the Tunisian state is entirely corruption-free. the laws and regulations governing business life are Clearly whenever bureaucrats are endowed with sig­ constantly in flux. For this reasons businessmen need nificant supervisory power over businessmen, inci­ contacts on the inside just to get through the system dents of corruption will occur. Tunisia, like many and get the information necessary to play by the gov­ countries, has witnessed some spectacular cases of ernment's rules. corruption especially at the top of the political pyra­ On the state's side there is the fact that state elites mid. (These cases multiplied during the final years of often don't have the technical data and/or training the Bourguiba regime when leadership broke down necessary to assess the projects they are called upon to and a mad scramble to profit before the president's approve. Under these conditions bureaucrats are often demise seized many of the ailing leader's entourage.) forced to fall back on the advice of "friends in the Nevertheless, scores of Tunisian industrialists attested business" to decide whether a project is viable or a to the low incidence of corruption in the state's man­ borrower trustworthy. agement of industry. Yes, petty favors might grease What this means is that cronyism is not necessarily the wheels of low-level interaction with state bureau­ motivated by the desire for personal gain (though on crats. A manufacturer, for example, might slip a free occasion it certainly is); rather, it is often a second­ sample of merchandise to the state labor inspector at best solution to an information problem faced by both holiday time. One did not however, have to give pub­ industrialists and state elites. Moreover, cronyism lic officials a "cut of the action" in order to succeed in should not necessarily be seen as subverting economic business in Tunisia as would be the case in Syria or rationality. Where dependable information is scarce, Iraq. An industrialist could count on getting access to reliance on personal contacts may actually abet the state licenses, subsidies, and supports strictly on the rational allocation of economic resources rather than merits of his project, if that project were sound. At subvert it. 16 bottom, the bureaucracy was guided by a develop­ The political mediation of profits then does not mentalist ethic and if its management of the economy necessarily spell welfare loss. Where state bureaucrats was irrational (many industrialists extravagantly are primarily corruption-free and where economic bemoaned the state's irrationality, complaining of clients are politically dispensable, state supervision of delays and inefficiency in its handling of their affairs), discretionary benefits can be fully compatible with POLITICS OF PROFIT IN TUNISIA 433 economic rationality and efficient growth. But what the less competitive segment of this class. about our second hazard - the political emasculation Consequently the long-term quiescence of private sec­ of social forces? Will dependence upon the state's dis­ tor industrialists cannot be taken as a measure of polit­ cretionary distribution of resources mean that indus­ ical emasculation. Rather, it is an indication of the trialists will hesitate to challenge the state on political industrialists' long-term satisfaction with a state that matters for fear of biting the hand that feeds it? generally anticipated their interests. Here the answer is a bit more ambiguous. Certainly The political mediation of profits then need not such dependence upon the state counsels a certain necessarily mean the political emasculation of private degree of political reticence on the part of private sector sector industrialists. In Tunisia, industrialists have industrialists. Nonetheless, it is interesting to note that benefited from a generous supply of government­ political "rectitude" is not a condition of business suc­ mediated rents, however, they have tended to retain a cess in Tunisia. One need not be a member of the ruling fair degree of political independence (though perhaps party nor need one get the party's imprimaturin order they have fallen short of being outright renegades): to do business in Tunisia. The best evidence for this is But what about our third hazard- that political medi­ the fact that a good portion of the industrialists inter­ ation of profits will embroil the state in clientalistic viewed were not members of the Destour party .17 relations that undermine its capacity to conduct coher­ Moreover, not a few of the most successful business­ ent developmentalist policy and ultimately lead to its men in Tunisia were "political pariahs," men who had own cannibalization? · fallen into disfavor with the regime during the The entanglement of the state in debilitating clien­ Bourguiba era and who had consequently fled to busi­ talistic relations is not unique to Third World cases of ness as a refuge from politics. These men were granted rentier capitalism. It is rather a constant in politics and "the right to make money" free from politically moti­ everywhere acts as a brake upon the pursuit of strictly vated bureaucratic harassment. As one businessman rational economic policy. In the United States, for reported, relations with the bureaucracy are ''personal­ example, it is the government's "entanglement" with ized not politicized." Though it is useful to know some­ certain key constituencies (retirees, farm interests, one on the inside to get access to discretionary benefits, etc.) that prevents it from adopting a purely rational one does not have to pass a political test to get the loans set of policies to close its enormous deficit. and licenses necessary to do business in Tunisia. Ultimately, the issue of entanglement is a matter of None of this is to say that industrialists are at the degree. Whether entanglement leads to state cannibal­ forefront of oppositional party politics in Tunisia. To ization or not, however, turns on the state's capacity to the contrary industrialists in Tunisia have generally "manage" its clients. Can it juggle clients in a way that eschewed such activity for two reasons. First, Tunisia endows it with sufficient autonomy to sustain its own is a relatively small country and members of the elite developmentalist logic? Moreover, does the state have tend to be well known to each other. Businessmen alternate strategies oflegitimation besides client-buy­ enjoy extensive fonnal and informal contact with state ing that can sustain it while client interests are being elites (through dinner parties, social gatherings, and clipped? In Tunisia, clientalism has long constituted a formal government commissions). Consequently, crucial component of the regime's strategy for sur­ when industrialists are unhappy with state policy, they vival. The state's clients, however, have not been lim­ tend to contact state elites directly rather than work ited to rent-gathering industrialists but rather have through organized public forums such as parties. included many other groups such as high-wage work­ Apparently industrialists find they can make the most ers organized by the UG'IT and subsidy-happy con­ effective case for their preferences in private consulta­ sumers of basic commodities. The state's capacity to tion with state elites rather than in the glare of collec­ sustain its developmentalist trajectory derives from its tive, public confrontation. ability to juggle these different groups, "sequencing" Second, industrialists tend not to be at the forefront their injury to avoid the coalescence of their an.8er of oppositional politics in Tunisia because until rela­ against the state and carrying out "reform by stealth" tively recently there was little in state policy to to catch the opposition off-guard. 18 In this way clients oppose. Over the past 20 years a coincidence of inter­ are serviced sufficiently to prevent the ship of state est prevailed between private sector industrialists and from capsizing even as it stays its general develop­ state elites. Both were committed to the country's mentalist course. industrialization and both designated a large role for Of course the most intriguing questions remain - the private sector in the process. Consequently, the why does Tunisia's state elite remain focused on a state generally anticipated the needs of private sector developmentalist course and how is it that the state industrialists and legislated an extremely favorable bureaucracy remains relatively free from colTUption? context for their development. Only in the last few Both of these characteristics of the Tunisian state are years, as the state has bowed to IMF pressures to elim­ essential to explaining why the mediation of profits inate many industrial subsidies and supports, has a does not generate debilitating welfare los·s, societal divergence of interest emerged between the state and emasculation, or state cannibalization in Tunisia. The 434 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

answer most certainly lies in avenues suggested by civil service (Larif-Beatrix, 1988, pp. 229, 248; Kohli (1987) and Evans (1992). Surely, leadership Camau, 1978) has certainly provided the esprit de plays a role - both Presidents Bourguiba and Ben Ali corps and security of tenure which analysts such as personally identified their prestige with the economic Evans (1992) suggest are crucial to the development development of Tunisia. Historical experience also of a professional, incorruptible state bureaucracy. proved to be reinforcing. The country possesses a long Clearly, more research is called for in this area. But tradition of "development from above" that stretches equally clear is the fact that to predict the conse­ back to precolonial times as shown in Brown's (1974) quences of rentier capitalism one need look less at the study of the Tunisia of Ahmed Bey and that was rein­ character of the capitalists themselves (productive? forced during the French colonial era (Brown, 1964). autonomous?) than at the character of the state that Finally, the decent remuneration, secure employment, nurtures them. and specialized training enjoyed by Tunisia's higher

NOTES

1. The term "" is borrowed from point for me. One example of artificially created scarcities Callaghy (1990, p. 260). The phenomenon is further that generate opportunities for reaping monopoly profits (i.e. explored in the case of Egypt by Sadowski (1991), Zaire by rents) would be state limitation of firm number in a given Callaghy (1984) and Macgaffey (1987), Nigeria by Joseph sector (imposed via licensing). (1984), and Saudi Arabia by Field (1984). 10. Boone's definition is clear and precise: "Rentier activ­ 2. These troubling implications will be expanded below. ities are defined as politically mediated opportunities for obtaining wealth through non-productive economic activity" 3. Nicholas van de Walle made this point clear to me. The (1990, p. 427). See her article for an excellent discussion of idea is developed further in Colander (1984, p. 8) and in rentier capitalism in Senegal. Wellisz and Findlay (1984, pp. 57-60). 11. Political mediation is the one quality that both econo­ 4. The term is that of French economist G. Destanne de mists and political economists agree constitutes a defining Bemis who used it to describe the heavy industries he criterion for most rentier situations. believed would spur integrated development in Third World countries by fostering forward and backward linkages with 12. All these citations are from Boone (1990, p. 430). other industries in their economies. 13. Notwithstanding the important role played by mer­ chants in the early years of the Neo-Destour party (prior to 5. An attempt to define the term rent precisely will follow independence). below. 14. Of course, not all industrialists saw their interests com­ 6. Figures are taken from the National Statistical promised by the IMF-inspired reforms. Those industrial Institute' s Industrial Censuses as well as various internal enterprises that were export-oriented and efficient by world document from the INS. They refer to firms employing 10 standards were certain to benefit, on balance, from dinar workers or more. devaluation and easier access to imported inputs. Nevertheless, the lion's share of industrial ventures in 7. That is, they tended to concentrate in subsectors such Tunisia were not so oriented or efficient when the reforms as food processing, textiles, and building materials rather were introduced and so a good portion of these ventures were than in mining or utilities. destined to suffer. Precise statistics on industrial failures between 1989-93 are not available. This past spring how­ 8. This is why many analysts object to any hard and fast ever, Hedi Jelani (president of Tunisia's Union of distinction between profit-seeking and rent-seeking. Both Industrialists, Merchants, and Artisans, UTICA) predicted involve the same "maximizing" behavior on the part of the that 10--20% of the country's private sector industrial firms entrepreneur. The only difference between the two is the would go bankrupt in 1993-94 with further implementation institutional setting in which the maximizing behavior takes of IMF reforms, specifically, liberalization of the country's place, Where perfect market conditions prevail or where the tariff barriers. Without doubt, the regime's reforms have government intervenes in the market (but along the lines of been painful (even if not fatal) for a significant portion of the economic rationality) such maximizing behavior leads to industrial class. Nonetheless, the regime has not been dis­ socially beneficial consequences (increased social surplus). suaded from pursuing these reforms. When such conditions do not prevail, maximizing behavior By contrast, the regime has been more careful to buffer generates social waste. See Buchanan (1980, p. 4) and the impact of structural adjustment on labor. Wage rates have Tollison (1982, p. 577) for more. Jones and Sakong (1980, been steadily increased to keep near pace with inflation; the pp. 267-278) provide empirical evidence of this from the labor code has not been "rationalized" to make labor dis­ Korean case. missal more "flexible," despite insistent recommendations to that effect by foreign experts. In fact, the best argument a 9. Thanks go to Nicholas van de Walle for clarifying this failing industrial venture can make to persuade the state to POLmcs OF PROFIT IN TUNISIA 435

sustain its "irrational" subsidies and protection is to show 16. The impact of cronyism on general welfare (positive or that the venture's failure will result in massive layoffs. negative) depends on the character of the state bureaucracy. Labor's disaffection is considered dangerous to the regime's Jones and Sakong (1980) provide persuasive evidence from political survival and so the regime has modified its eco­ the Korean case that where bureaucracy is guided by a devel­ nomic policy to maintain labor peace even as it takes steps to opmentalist ethic, cronyism can be used to improve general limit labor's organizational autonomy. welfare. Evans (1992) develops this idea further in his dis­ Admittedly, the notion of sustaining coalitions is bor­ cussion of the utility of"embedded autonomy" for successful rowed from the political logic of democratic experience. state-led development. Clearly, authoritarian regimes (that is, regimes whose reign is not beholden to free and fair population election) are sig­ 17. The interviewed sample was selected on a nonrandom nificantly more insulated from the need to sustain popularity basis but was diversified across sector and size category to be than are democracies (see Callaghy, 1993). Nevertheless, no reasonably representative of Tunisian industrialists as a regime survives (long) by coercion alone and even the most whole. authoritarian regime must be attentive to the cultivation of a political base/coalition if it wishes to endure. This is also true 18. These strategies of "reform by stealth" and "sequenc­ for Tunisia. The less than wholly democratic nature of the ing injury" are elaborated by Waterbury (1989). Examples of regime lends it some insulation from popular pressures and such reform by stealth include the regime's policy of grant­ some space for "play" with its traditional constituencies. ing Tunisian workers wage raises on a regular basis, but set­ Nevertheless, over the long term the regime must attend to ting them so as to lag slightly behind the rate of inflation. the interests of those constituencies or else construct a new coalitional base to provide it with popular ballast.

15. These views were reflected in interviews with over 50 industrialists conducted in 1988-89.

REFERENCES

Ayadi, M., "Les Enterprises Publiques en Tunisie," Ph.D. Joan Nelson (Ed.), Fragile Coalitions: The Politics of dissertation (Tunis, Tunisia: ENAT, 1969). Economic Adjustment (New Brunswick: Transaction, Bates, Robert, Markets and States in Tropical Africa 1989), pp. 115-134. (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1981). Callaghy, Thomas, "External actors and the relative auton­ Bellin, Eva, "Civil society resurgent: State and social classes omy of the political aristocracy in Zaire," in Nelson Kasfir in Tunisia," Ph.D. dissertation (Princeton: Princeton (Ed.), State and Class in Africa (London: Frank Cass and University, 1992). Co, 1984), pp. 61-83. Bellin, Eva, ''Tunisian industrialists and the state," in I. W. Camau, Michel, La Structure Hierarchique des Zartman (Ed.), Tunisia: The Political Economy of Reform Renumerations au sein de la Fonction Publiq11e (Boulder, CO: Lynne Reinner, 1991), pp. 45--{i6. Tunisienne (Tunis: ENA, 1978). Boone, Catherine, "The making of a rentier class: Wealth Colander, David (Ed.), Neo-Classical Political Economy: accumulation, and political control in Senegal," The The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 26 (April 1990), pp. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing , 425-449. 1984). Brown, L. Carl, The T11nisiaof Ahmed Bey (Princeton: de Miras, C., "L' entrepreneur ivoirian ou une bourgeoisie Princeton University Press, 1974). priveedesonetat", in Y. A. FaureandJ. F.Medard(Eds.), Brown, L. Carl, Charles Micaud, and Clement Henry Moore, Etat et Bourgeoisie en Cofte d'Ivoire (Paris: Karthala, T11nisia: The Politics of Modernization (New York: 1982). Praeger, 1964). Evans, Peter, "The state as problem and solution: Predation, Buchanan, James, "Rent-seeking and profit-seeking," in embedded autonomy, and structural change," in Stephen James Buchanan, Robert Tollison and Gordon Tullock Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman (Eds.), The Politics of (Eds.), Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society Economic Adjustment: lntematio11al Constraints, (College Station: Texas A & M University Press, 1980), Distrib11tiveConflicts and the State (Princeton: Princeton pp. 3-14. University Press, 1992), pp. 139-181. Callaghy, Thomas, "Vision and politics in the transformation Evans, Peter, "Predatory, developmental and other appara­ of the global political economy: Lessons from the Second tuses: a comparative analysis of the Third World state" in and Third Worlds," in Robert 0. Slater (Ed.), Global Alejandro Portes and Douglas Kincaid (Eds.), Transfonnation and the Third World (Boulder, CO: Sociological Forum, Vol. 4, No. 4 (December 1989), pp. Lynne Rienner, 1993), pp. 161-257. 561-588. Callaghy, James, "Lost between state and market: The poli­ Field, Michael, The Merchants: The Big Business Families tics of economic adjustment in the Third World," in Joan of Saudi Arabia and the Gulf States (New York: Overlook Nelson (Ed.), Economic Crisis and Policy Choice: The Press, 1984). Politics of Adjustment in the Third World (Princeton: Gouia, Ridha, "Les Investissements en Tunisie et leurs Princeton University Press, 1990). Effets Sur la Croissance Economique de 188.l ag Nos Callaghy, Thomas, ''Toward state capabilities and embedded lours,'' Ph.D. dissertation (Paris: University of Parix X, liberalism in the Third World: Lessons for adjustment," in 1976). 436 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Illife, John; The Emergence of African Capitalism North, Douglass, "Rent-seeking and t4e institutional eco­ (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1983). • nomics,'' in Charles K. Rowley (Ed.), Democracy and Jones, Leroy P., and II Sakong, Government Business and Public Choice (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1987). in Economic Development: The Romdhane, Mahmoud Ben, "L' Accumulation du Capital et Korean Case (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, les Classes Sociales en Tunisie Depuis L'Independance," 1980). Ph.D. dissertation (Tunis: University of Tunis, 1981). Joseph, Richard, "Class, state, and prebendal politics in Romdhane, Mahmoud Ben, and Pierre Signoles, "Les Nigeria,'' in Nelson Kasfir (Ed.), State and Class in Africa Fonnes Recentes de !'Industrialisation Tunisienne, (London: Frank Cass and Co., 1984) pp. 21-36. 1970-1980," Georgraphie et Developpement No. 5 Kasfir, Nelson, "Relating class to state in Africa," in Nelson (January 1982). Kasfir (Ed.), State and Class in Africa (London: Frank Sadowski, Yahya, Political Vegetables: Businessmen and Cass and Co., 1984). Bureaucrats in the Developmetlt of Egyptian Agriculture Kohli, Atul, The State and Poverty in India: The Politics of (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1991). Reform (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987). Signoles, Pierre, "Regime d' Accumulation et Modes de Kregel, J. A., "Rentier'' in John Eatwell et al. (Eds.), The New Dependance: le Cas de la Tunisie," Ph.D. dissertation Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (London; (Paris: University of Paris I, 1984), MacMillan Press, 1987), pp. 146-147. Springborg, Robert, Mubarak's Egypt: Fragmentation of the Krueger, Anne 0., "The political economy of the rent-seek­ Political Order (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1989). ing society," The American Economic Review, Vol. 64, Tollison, Robert, "Is the theory of rent-seeking here to stay?" No. 3 (June 1974), pp. 291-303. in Charles K. Rowley (Ed.), Democracy and Public Larif-Beatrix, Asma, Edification Etatique et Environnement Choice (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1987). Culture/: Le Personnel Politico-Administratif dans la Tollison, Robert, "Rent-seeking: A survey,'' Kykl,os Vol. 35 Tunisie Contemporaine (Paris: Publisud, 1988). (1982), pp. 575~02. Luciani, Giacomo, "Arabi Saoudite: L'lndustrialisation d'un Waterbury, John, "The political management of economic Etat Allocataire," Maghreb-Machrek, Vol. 129 (July-Sept adjustment and reform," in Joan Nelson (Ed.), Fragile 1990), pp. 76-93. Coalitions: The Politics of Economic Adjustment (New Luciani, Giacomo, "Allocation vs. production states: A theo­ Brunswick: Transaction, 1989), pp. 39-56. retical framework," in Giacomo Luciani (Ed.), The Arab Wellisz, Stanislaw, and Ronald Findlay, "Protection and State (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990), pp. rent-seeking in developing countries," in David Colander 65-84. (Ed.), Neo-Classical Political Economy: The Analysis of Macgaffey, Janet. Entrepreneurs and Parasites: The Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, MA: Struggle for Indigenous Capitalism in Zaire (New York: Ballinger, 1984). Cambridge University Press, 1987).